View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Intergenerational Health Mobility
in the US
Timothy Halliday, Bhashkar Mazumder, and
Ashley Wong

REVISED
January 2019
WP 2018-02
*

Working papers are not edited, and all opinions and errors are the
responsibility of the author(s). The views expressed do not necessarily
reflect the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal
Reserve System.

Intergenerational Health Mobility in the US

Timothy Halliday
University of Hawaii, Manoa and IZA
halliday@hawaii.edu
Bhashkar Mazumder
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago and University of Bergen
bhash.mazumder@gmail.com
Ashley Wong
Northwestern University
ashley.wong816@gmail.com
January 2019
Abstract: We present the first broad-based estimates of intergenerational health
mobility in the US by using repeated measures of self-reported health status
(SRHS) from the PSID. Our main finding is that there is substantially greater health
mobility than income mobility in the US. A possible explanation is that social
institutions and policies are more effective at disrupting intergenerational health
transmission than income transmission. We also characterize heterogeneity in
health mobility by child gender, parent gender, race, education, geography and
health insurance coverage in childhood. We use a rich set of background
characteristics to highlight potential mechanisms leading to intergenerational health
persistence.

*We thank participants at workshops at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, University of
Queensland, University of Sydney, Labor and Econometric Workshop at Australian National
University, the Australian Departments of Labor and Social Services, the Health and Development
Conference, Academia Sinica, Taiwan, the PSID conference on Life Courses Influences at the
University of Michigan, Lund University, University of Bergen and the NBER Children’s and
Education workshop. We wish to acknowledge funding from the National Institute on Aging (P01
AG029409).

1.

Introduction
A large and growing multi-disciplinary literature on intergenerational

mobility has emerged in recent decades. Its primary motivation has been concerns
over equality of opportunity. Most of the studies in this literature have focused on
income, education or occupation. However, one key aspect of socioeconomic status
that has been vastly understudied is health. 1 This is unfortunate since health is an
especially important component of welfare (Jones and Klenow, 2016). For one
thing, longevity, which depends in large part on health, is clearly a powerful
barometer of lifetime utility. Health also plays an important role throughout the life
course by influencing a wide range of behaviors. For example, a large literature has
highlighted how poor health early in life leads to reduced educational attainment,
worse labor market outcomes, and onset of chronic disease later in life (e.g. Case,
Fertig, and Paxson, 2005; Aizer and Currie, 2014). In addition, health, especially at
later ages is fundamental for decisions related to work, retirement, consumption,
and savings (e.g. Rust and Phelan, 1997; Palumbo, 1999; French and Jones, 2017).
Studying intergenerational health mobility, however, is a formidable task.
First, it requires panel data containing broad-based health measures for adults in
two generations which is difficult to obtain. Second, since the concept of interest is
one that is latent, health is inherently difficult to measure. Morbidity measurements
1
Some studies that have examined intergenerational associations in specific health outcomes such
as birth weight (e.g. Currie and Morretti, 2007; Black et al. 2007), mental health (Johnston et al.,
2013); smoking (Darden and Gilleskie 2016); longevity (e.g. Lach et al., 2008; Hong and Park,
2016, Lindahl et al, 2016), and asthma (Thompson, 2016). Akbulut_Yaksel and Kugler (2016)
look at a range of outcomes including height, weight, asthma and depression comparing
immigrants and native born in the US. Coneus and Spiess (2012) examine intergenerational
associations but only to the first 3 years of life of children. We are only aware of two
intergenerational papers that use a broad measure of health as we do. Kim et al. (2015) use selfreported health data from Indonesia Family Life Survey and finds that having a father in poor
health is associated with an increase of 0.29 in the probability of poor health for women. Pascual
and Cantarero (2009) use self-reported health data from the European household panel and find
sons with father in good or very good health are 5 to 10 percentages points more likely to be in
good health.

2

are typically blunt proxies for a more fundamental underlying latent variable. Third,
lifecycle issues are an important concern in measuring health as long-run latent
health status is often not revealed until relatively later in life when variability in
organ function becomes more pronounced (Steves et al, 2012), chronic diseases
begin to emerge, and functional abilities increasingly become impaired.
We address these issues by using the Panel Study of Income Dynamics
(PSID). The PSID is the world’s longest running longitudinal dataset. It tracks
individuals as they form new households and has been widely used to study
intergenerational mobility. 2 Since 1984, the PSID began collecting information on
self-reported health status (SRHS). SRHS has long been established in the
epidemiology literature as a valid omnibus health measure that is highly predictive
of mortality, even when compared to clinical measures such as chronic illnesses
(e.g. Miilunpalo et al. 1997, Idler and Benyamini, 1997 and DeSalvo et al. 2005).
SRHS has specifically been validated in the PSID using proprietary mortality files,
where the measure predicts mortality even after controlling for baseline
demographic characteristics (Halliday, 2014). Importantly, to our knowledge, the
PSID has collected data on SRHS for longer than any other longitudinal dataset.
Using the PSID, we construct an intergenerational sample of parents and
their adult children. We use all available years of information on health status for
individuals who are at least 30 years old. We employ a method used by the National
Center for Health Statistics to convert SRHS to a continuous measure that is akin
to a quality adjusted life year (see Erickson et al. 1995). 3 Following the income
mobility literature, we then use time averages of this continuous measure to proxy
for lifetime health status. We view time averaging as a method for extracting a time

2

See Mazumder (2018) for a review of studies of intergenerational mobility using the PSID
We follow the methodology employed by Johnson and Schoeni (2011) in their paper. Additional
details provided in Section II.

3

3

invariant latent variable. The use of health reports at multiple points in time, and at
different points of the lifecycle for each of two generations, enables us to overcome
the key obstacles to studying intergenerational health mobility.
Our first measure is the Intergenerational Health Association (IHA) which
is the coefficient on parent health status from a regression of child health on parent
health (adjusting for age). This provides a simple measure of the persistence in
health status that is analogous to the intergenerational income elasticity and reflects
the inverse of mobility. Our other measures are rank-based. Adjusting for age, we
use our time averaged measures of parent and child health to create percentiles in
the health distribution for each generation. One particularly useful set of mobility
measures is based on intergenerational “rank-rank” regressions as popularized by
Chetty et al (2014). We estimate the slope of this regression, the “rank-rank slope,”
as well as measures of the expected rank for a child whose parents were at the 25th
and 75th percentiles of the parent health distribution.
Our estimates of the IHA range from 0.20 to 0.25. This implies that an
additional year of quality life among parents is associated with close to three
additional months of healthy life for children. This suggests that there is only a
modest degree of persistence in health status in the US especially when compared
to persistence in family income which is typically estimated to be in the order of
0.5 or higher. 4 Our estimates of the rank-rank slope (Spearman correlation) ranges
from 0.21 to 0.29 and are also significantly lower than the estimates of 0.39 to 0.47
that we obtain when we use income ranks. We further find that those starting at the
25th percentile experience greater upward mobility in ranks in health compared to

4

See Mazumder (2016) for a brief discussion of papers estimating the intergenerational elasticity
in family income. In our main sample which is not specifically designed to optimally estimate
income mobility, the intergenerational elasticity in family income is estimated to be 0.39.

4

income, and we find greater downward mobility in health rank than income rank
among families starting at the 75th percentile.
It may seem surprising that health persistence is lower than income
persistence as some readers may have expected that there is a larger genetic
component to health than income. However, our finding is roughly consistent with
the aging literature which uses twin based genetic models and finds that heritability
in longevity is only about 25 percent (Steves et al, 2012) suggesting that
environmental factors play a predominant role in long-run health. Furthermore, the
few available estimates of intergenerational associations in birth weight, longevity
and mental health are also around 0.2. 5
We next consider measurement issues. Although SRHS has been validated
and is widely used, it is nonetheless a subjective measure and a variety of arguments
can be made to criticize its use. To address this concern, we combine a set of 21
more objective health measures that have been collected in the PSID since 1999 to
construct an alternative health index (AHI). For a subset of our sample, we compare
estimates of intergenerational health persistence using SRHS to those using the
AHI. Remarkably, we find that the results using the two methods are extremely
similar, further confirming that SRHS appears to be a valid measure of
intergenerational health mobility. 6 We also show that, as is the case with income,
estimates of intergenerational persistence in health rise as we use more years of
parent health. Finally, persistence estimates are higher when we measure parent and
child health when both are at least age 50 consistent with the notion that latent

5

See the papers cited in footnote 1.
In a companion paper (in progress), we show that we obtain identical estimates of rank
persistence and only slightly higher estimates of the IHA (0.3) when using a more sophisticated
Bayesian model of latent health.

6

5

health status is not well captured until later in the life cycle when the variation in
self-reported health status rises and there is more “signal” in the data.
Notably, we also find that families who experience improvements in health
across generations do not necessarily experience concomitant improvements in
income. 7 We show that the correlation in across-generation rank changes in health
and income among families is only 0.25 suggesting that income and health largely
capture distinct dimensions of SES.
We then characterize the variation in health mobility by population
subgroups defined by region, race and parent education level using rank-rank
regressions. For this analysis we focus on gaps in conditionally expected ranks (e.g.
expected ranks at the 25th and 75th percentiles) rather than on measures of “within
group” persistence. We find that those who grew up in the South experience both
lower upward mobility and higher downward mobility. Blacks also have
substantially lower upward mobility and higher downward mobility in health but
these racial gaps are significantly smaller than the comparable gaps in income
mobility. 8 Finally, we show that the gaps in expected health rank are even more
pronounced when comparing individuals by their parents’ education level. This
suggests that the well-known gradient in health by education levels extends to the
subsequent generation. That is, not only is your own health worse if you have less
education, but your child’s expected health as an adult will be worse as well.
Complementary to our heterogeneity analysis by geography, race and
family background, we also document suggestive evidence of a decline in health

7

This is potentially consistent with emerging biomedical research suggesting that socioeconomic
success for low SES individuals may come at the expense of health (Miller et al, 2015).
8
Comparable studies of racial gaps in income mobility include: Hertz (2005), Bhattacharya and
Mazumder (2011), Mazumder (2014), Davis and Mazumder (2018), and Chetty et al (2018).

6

mobility for cohorts born since 1970. 9 Since the cohorts born since 1970 are still
relatively young, future work may be able to better substantiate this change in
mobility.
In the last part of our analysis, we explore potential important mediators for
health mobility. We show that there is greater health persistence among families
lacking health insurance coverage for their children, suggesting a potentially
important role for policy. Finally, we examine the role of early life factors using
data from the PSID’s 2013 Childhood Retrospective Circumstance Study (CRCS).
We find that close to 40 percent of intergenerational health persistence is explained
by early life circumstances.
What explains our main finding of relatively high levels of intergenerational
health mobility in the US? We hypothesize that this is likely due in part, to a
combination of factors that reduce the transmission of health status across
generations including: modern public health infrastructure (e.g. clean air and
water), the availability of high quality medical care for most of the population, and
a variety of social safety net programs (e.g. SNAP, WIC, CHIP, Medicaid). In
contrast, it may well be that opportunities for labor market success, which are
rooted in educational opportunities earlier in life, may be much more unequal and
hence, lead to greater intergenerational income persistence. It may also be the case
that in the past, the rates of income persistence and health persistence were more
similar, but in recent decades, as the labor market returns to schooling has risen and
as income inequality has increased, intergenerational income persistence has also
increased (Aaronson and Mazumder, 2008; Davis and Mazumder, 2017).
2.

Data

9

Several studies have also found a decline in intergenerational income and educational mobility in
recent decades (e.g. Aaronson and Mazumder, 2008; Davis and Mazumder, 2017; Hilger, 2017).

7

We use the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID). The PSID is a U.S.
longitudinal household survey that began in 1968 with a nationally representative
sample of over 18,000 individuals living in 5,000 families. Including the original
and subsequent samples, over 70,000 people have participated in the survey.
Extensive information is collected on a wide range of topics including employment,
income, wealth, childhood development, and education. Individuals in the PSID
families and anyone subsequently born to or adopted by a sample person are
followed over time even if they form separate family units. The unique design of
the PSID allows us to link adult children to their parents across survey waves.
Starting in 1984, the PSID included questions on the health status of
household heads and their spouses. Specifically, they asked, “Would you say your
health in general is excellent, very good, good, fair, or poor?” 10 This question,
commonly referred to as self-reported health status (SRHS), is highly predictive of
mortality even after controlling for other health measures and outperforms other
objective health measures (see Miilunpalo et al. 1997; Idler and Benyamini, 1997,
DeSalvo et al. 2006, and Halliday, 2014). However, as a robustness check, we
supplement our analysis by constructing an alternative health index (AHI) using 21
objective health measures available in survey years beginning in 1999. Details on
the AHI are described in Section III and in Appendix B.
We construct a sample of 8,115 men and women who are at least 30 years
old, provide SRHS in at least one survey year, and who are matched to at least one
parent who also provides SRHS at least once. 11 We collect all values of SRHS

10

This question is now widely used in many U.S. surveys including the Current Population
Survey, the Survey of Income and Program Participation, the National Health Interview Survey,
and the Health and Retirement Survey.
11
In our sample, 62% are matched to both parents, 33% to the mother only and 5% to the father
only.

8

between 1984 and 2013 for each person and, following Johnson and Schoeni
(2011), convert the categorical values into a continuous measure using health
utility-based scale developed for the Health and Activity Limitation Index (HALex)
which is designed to estimate healthy life years. 12 The value ranges for each health
status category are as follows: [95,100] is excellent; [85,95) is very good; [70,85)
is good; [30,70) is fair; and [1,30) is poor. The values correspond to the percentage
of a year that is considered to be of “quality” health. We assign the midpoint of the
interval for each reported health category in each year and then average these values
over all available years for each individual.
In Figure 1, panel A we plot the mean health status over the life cycle
pooling all individuals in both generations. By this measure, health is roughly flat
from age 30 to 40 but then begins to decline roughly linearly through age 80. 13 To
address this lifecycle pattern and in order to compare individuals at different ages
we also construct a regression adjusted measure of health status. 14 In panel B, we
show the standard deviation in health status at each age and find that there is
considerably more variation in health as an individual ages. This is consistent with
greater variation in organ function (Steves et al. 2012) and the rising onset of
chronic diseases at later ages. This suggests that health status is more indicative of
latent health at age 60 than at age 40. It is also consistent with the well-known fact
that inequality in general tends to increase as cohorts age. Deaton and Paxson

12

The HALex for an individual is composed of two components: self-reported health status and
activity limitation (such as limitations in activities for daily living). Because we only observe
SRHS in the PSID, our scale is a less precise index than the HALex, but can be interpreted in the
same way as the percentage of a year considered to be of “quality” health. Additional details for
the construction of this scale and HALex can be found in Johnson and Schoeni (2011) and
Erickson, Wilson, and Shannon (1995).
13
After age 80 the samples are small and the estimates become noisy.
14
We use the residual from a regression of the continuous health status on age and age squared
using separate regressions for our samples of fathers, mothers, daughters and sons using sampling
weights.

9

(1994) provide evidence for consumption; Deaton and Paxson (1998) and Halliday
(2011) provide evidence for numerous health measures including SRHS.
In addition, we collect data on total family income which includes all
taxable income (e.g. earnings, interest and dividends) and cash transfers for all
family members measured in 2013 dollars deflated using the CPI-U. We adjust for
family size by dividing by the square root of the number of family members. We
also average income over all available years. For race, we use the reported race of
the child. To measure educational attainment, we use the last available report on
years of completed education. Finally, region is based on the child’s most often
reported region of residence before the age of 18.
For our analysis of early life influences, we use a subsample of 3,281 adults
in the 2013 PSID who were also part of the Childhood Retrospective Circumstance
Study (CRCS). The CRCS collects data from household heads and spouses on their
childhood and young adulthood experiences. Topics include parental relationship
quality, childhood health, socioeconomic status, neighborhoods, friendships,
school experiences, relationship quality with parents/guardians and young adult
mentoring. For some categories we create indices by taking the largest component
from a principal components analysis (PCA). 15
In Table 1 we present summary statistics for our main sample (using
sampling weights). Panel A shows the characteristics of parents. The mean age is
around 56 and the average of years of education is between 12 and 13. Fewer than
10 percent report that their health is excellent. On average, our sample contains
about 15 years of data on health status. Panel B shows that the children are on

15

Due to the discrete nature of the survey responses, we used the polychoric version of PCA as
recommended by Kolenikov and Angeles (2009). Further details on the index construction can be
found in Appendix A.

10

average 38 to 39 years old with about 14 years of education. Well over half report
being in very good or excellent health.
In Panel C, we report summary statistics for the CRCS sample. We report
the statistics for indices in standardized units. 16 We break down the CRCS
childhood

experience

variables

into

the

following

categories:

family

socioeconomic background, childhood health, childhood stability, school
experience, and childhood relationships. See Appendix A for more detail.
3.

Methodology

Intergenerational Health Association (IHA)
Many studies in the income mobility literature have estimated the
intergenerational elasticity or “IGE”. We start by creating an analogous measure,
which we refer to as the intergenerational health association (IHA). The IHA is
based on estimating the following regression:
(1)

y1i = α + βy0i + γXi +εi

where conceptually, y1i represents the lifetime health of the child in family i, and
y0i is the lifetime health of one or both of the parents. The vector X is a set of
controls and includes the quadratic age terms for both the parent(s) and the child.
The parameter β provides a measure of intergenerational persistence and 1 - β is a
measure of mobility. In our case, y measures the percentage of a healthy life year
in which a value of 100 denotes one year in perfect health and 0 denotes a health
state that is viewed as equivalent to death. If, for example, β is 0.2, this implies that
if the difference in health between two families in the parent’s generation was 10
percent of a healthy year, then we would expect the difference in health to be only

16

Since the indices are constructed and standardized across the entire sample, the indices are on
the same scale for both males and females and we can compare the means directly.

11

about 2 percent of a healthy year in the children’s generation. In this case, most
health differences between families dissipate in a generation, so that the rate of
regression to the mean is quite high. In contrast, if β is 0.8, we would consider
health to be highly persistent so that there is low degree of mobility. Our preferred
estimates combine the health status of both parents (when available) by using an
average of the time averages of each parent and using just a single parent’s health
measure when only one parent is linked to a child. Standard errors are clustered by
family.
Rank Mobility Measures
While the IHA, like the IGE, is useful for characterizing the rate of
regression to the mean in one simple parameter, it is not ideal for all purposes. In
particular, when comparing subgroups of the population (i.e. differences by race
and region) relative to a common distribution, one may prefer to use rank based
measures (Mazumder, 2016). Rank-based measures are also better suited for
distinguishing upward and downward mobility patterns. We calculate the percentile
rank of age-adjusted health separately for each gender in each generation. 17 In
addition to percentile ranks for each parent, we also construct a “both parents”
measure that uses all available health observations from both parents and combines
them into a single rank. 18 Similarly, we also construct an “all children” rank that

17

We use sampling weights in estimating the ranks so that the percentiles correspond to positions
in population.
18
For this analysis, we pool the observations of mothers and fathers and regress the parent health
measure on a quadratic in age interacted with parent type (mother or father), indicators for missing
mother and father, and fraction of the parent health observations in that family that is from the
mother. The age- and gender-adjusted parent health measure is the residual. We then take the
percentile rank of this measure. The adjustment regression and percentile ranking are weighted
using sampling weight of the mother. If mother’s sampling weight is unavailable, then the father’s
sampling weight is used.

12

pools together the age-adjusted child health measures for sons and daughters. We
then estimate regressions 19 of the following form:
(2)

r1i = α + ρr0i + εi

where r1 and r0 now represent the percentile rank of health in each respective
generation. In this case, ρ provides an estimate of persistence in rank position and
1- ρ provides a measure of positional mobility. We will often refer to ρ, which is
equivalent to the Spearman correlation as the “rank-rank slope.” In principle, β and
ρ can differ. It could be for example, that if the health distribution becomes more
compressed in the child distribution than it was in the parent generation, then a
given amount of rank mobility could be more consequential in terms of health as
measured by years of quality life.
In addition to estimates of rank persistence, we use the rank-rank regression
framework to calculate expected ranks at the 25th and 75th percentile. These
estimates at “p25” and “p75” convey information about “directional” (upward or
downward) mobility for a typical child coming from lower and higher health
families. 20 For example, if the expected health rank of individuals coming from the
25th percentile is the 45th percentile then this would suggest upward mobility of
about 20 percentiles. 21 We also construct a parallel set of income rank measures. 22

19

The rank-rank regressions are weighted using the child’s sampling weight and clustered at the
family level.
20
Of course, using the intercept and slope one can easily calculate the expected rank at any
percentile of interest.
21
For some exercises, we divide the parent and children health distributions into quintiles and
examine the fraction of children who escape the bottom (or top) quintile, i.e. children who are not
in the bottom (or top) quintile conditioned on parent being the bottom (or top) quintile. We also
look at the fraction of children who reach the top quintile conditioned on parent being in the
bottom quintile and vice versa.
22
We rank total family income in the same way as for health, by gender and generation, after
performing the same age adjustment. We also construct a “both parents” income measure which is
the average of all available average total family income associated with the mother and father. If

13

When analyzing subgroups (e.g. region, race, education), we calculate ranks
based on the full population enabling us to make mobility comparisons with respect
to the national distribution. However, when we examine trends, parent and child
age adjusted health ranks are estimated based on cohort specific joint distributions
depending on the child’s birth cohort. 23
Alternative Health Index (AHI)
As a robustness check, we develop an alternative health index (AHI) that is
constructed from more objective health measures that are only available in survey
years after 1999. 24 In total, we compile 21 indicators of adverse mental and physical
health conditions that take on the value of 1 if the individual has the health condition
and 0 otherwise. Details on the individual conditions can be found in Appendix B.
We construct a simple index using the fraction of the conditions that the individual
does not have so that a higher index value will indicate better health. We then take
the time average of an age-adjusted AHI over all available years between 1999 and
2013 for each individual. We can then compare estimates of intergenerational
health associations and rank-rank slopes based on the AHI to a similar set of
estimates based on our health measure where we use the identical sample of
individuals and restrict our SRHS data to reports from 1999-2013.
4.

Results

the mother and father are in the same household, this average is merely the total family income of
that year. We regress this measure on quadratic age terms of the mother and father, as well as
indicators for having a missing father or mother. The corresponding income ranks are constructed
from the residuals of this regression. Similarly, we also pool together age-adjusted income
measures for sons and daughters to construct percentile ranks for all children.
23
The trends analysis uses cohorts born in each of the following birth cohort groups: 1950-1960;
1960-1970; and 1970-1979. These cohort groups comprise about 80% of our baseline sample.
24
There were additional health variables available in 2001 or later but for purposes of consistency,
we used all health indicators that were available in all years between 1999 and 2013.

14

We first present our main estimates of intergenerational health mobility in
Section 4.1. We then consider the robustness of these baseline results to
measurement issues in Section 4.2. We next explore the relationship between health
and income mobility in Section 4.3. We then measure how health mobility differs
across subgroups of the population (Section 4.4) and how it has changed over time
(Section 4.5). Finally, in Section 4.7, we consider potential mechanisms that can
explain our results on intergenerational health mobility.
4.1 Intergenerational Health Mobility
Basic Descriptive Patterns
Before presenting our main mobility estimates, we start by showing some
simple associations between parent and child health in Appendix Table A.1 that are
easy to interpret. For this analysis we convert the time averages of our continuous
health measure for each individual back into the original five SRHS categories
using the scale described in Section II. We find that if both parents (or one parent
in the case of single parent families) are in at least good health, then children are
10.9 percentage points more likely to report being in at least good health compared
to children whose parents were not in good health. 25 This differs somewhat by
gender. Sons are 11.8 percentage points more like to be in good health when their
parents are in good health compared to a 9.9 percentage estimate for daughters.
We explore this association along two further dimensions in Table 2. First,
we separately examine the health associations of children with mothers versus
fathers. Second, we investigate how associations differ among parents by different
categories of the SRHS variable: good, very good and excellent health. We find
that relative to having a mother in fair or poor health, having a mother in exactly

25

See the notes under Table A.1 for more specific information on the specification.

15

good health increases the likelihood that a child will be in at least good health by
10.9 percentage points (column 1). Having a mother in very good or excellent
health increases the association even further to about 16 percentage points. The
estimates are fairly similar for sons and daughters as shown in columns (2) and (3).
Columns 4 through 6 show the comparable estimates when we examine the
estimates for fathers’ health on all kids, sons, and daughters. Compared to mothers,
there appears to be a slightly lower association between fathers and children.
Estimates of Intergenerational Health Mobility
In Table 3 we show the estimates of the intergenerational health association
(IHA) for various parent-child groups. We find that when we combine both parents’
health for the pooled sample of sons and daughters (column 1) we obtain an
estimate of 0.23. In terms of years of quality life, the estimate implies that for every
additional year of quality life the parents have, the child, on average, is expected to
have almost three additional months (23% of a year) of healthy life. This is higher
than either using only mother’s health (0.20) or using father’s health (0.17). Note
that the estimates that combine the health status of both parents necessarily take
averages over a larger number of health measures. So, the estimates in the third row
that combine both parents may be higher because they do a better job extracting the
“signal” from the health measures of the parents. We find roughly similar patterns
if we look either at sons (column 2) or daughters (column 3). Both sons and
daughters’ health are more strongly associated with mother’s health than with
father’s health and the highest estimates arise when pooling both parents’ health.
The associations appear to be slightly higher from parents to daughters than sons.
These estimates are all markedly lower than what is typically obtained when
estimating the IGE in family income in the U.S. which tends to be around 0.5 or
higher (Mazumder, 2016). This suggests that there is much greater mobility with
respect to health than with respect to income.

16

We next turn to estimates of rank mobility. In Figure 2A, we show the
binned scatterplot of expected health rank at every percentile of the parent health
distribution for all children in our sample. The relationship is almost linear. For
every 10-percentile rank increase of the parents, the child is expected to be 2.61
percentiles higher in the health distribution of their own generation. In panel A of
Table 4, we show estimates of the rank-rank slopes, expected rank at 25th and 75th
percentile for all parent-child combinations. Estimates for the rank-rank slopes for
the different subsamples range from 0.21 to 0.29. Similar to the intergenerational
health association results, we find the strongest association between mothers and
daughters. We also find that the associations are larger when using mothers than
when using fathers. Both sons and daughters have similar expected ranks when the
mother (or father) is at the 25th percentile of the parent health distribution with
estimates ranging from the 44th to the 47th percentile. Expected rank at the 75th
percentile is also similar across the samples, ranging from 56 to 60th percentile,
though, daughters appear to experience less downward mobility than sons.
We contrast these results with income mobility estimates for the identical
samples in panel B. The corresponding binned scatterplot for the full sample is
shown in Figure 2B. The estimates for the rank-rank slopes range from 0.41 to 0.47,
implying a much greater persistence in income rank than in health rank. 26
Comparing the estimates for the expected rank at p25 and p75 in panels A and B
shows that there is less upward mobility from the bottom, and less downward
mobility from the top, when using income compared to using health.

26

These are higher than the rank-rank slope estimate produced by Chetty et al (2014) using
administrative tax data, but are consistent with estimates in Mazumder (2016) who also uses the
PSID. Mazumder (2016) argues that Chetty et al (2014) estimates are downward biased due to
using short time averages of income and using measures taken at sub-optimal points in the lifecycle, which are issues that can be overcome by using the longer panel data available in the PSID.

17

Alternative Health Index (AHI)
In Table 5, we compare mobility estimates based on self-reported health
status (SRHS) to estimates based on the Alternative Health Index (AHI) using
identical samples. 27 Whether we focus on the IHA or rank mobility estimates, we
find that the estimates are remarkably similar across the two measures; we find no
evidence of systematic downward bias in using SRHS which might have been
expected if SRHS contained greater measurement error than the AHI. For example,
the IHA estimates range from 0.091 to 0.199 when using SRHS and range from
between 0.092 to 0.184 when using the AHI. Note that the estimates in this table
tend to be lower than the estimates of health persistence in the previous two tables
because they employ shorter averages of the health measures which is a point that
we will come back to shortly. This is not surprising given that we find that the two
measures are highly correlated, with correlation coefficients ranging from 0.66 to
0.76 depending on the generation we use. We draw two main conclusions from this
analysis. First, SRHS is at least as informative of latent health as more objective
measures and second, our lower estimates of intergenerational health persistence
compared to income persistence are likely not driven by differences in
measurement error between income and health. This is further bolstered by the fact
that previous studies of intergenerational persistence with respect to birth weight,
longevity and mental health all yield estimates of around 0.2
4.2. Measurement Issues
Time Averaging

27

Recall that for this analysis we limit our data to surveys after 1999. This leads to generally
lower estimates than for our baseline sample due to differences in age and the length of time
averages. See Section 3 and Appendix B for more details on the AHI.

18

Prior research has emphasized the importance of addressing measurement
error/transitory shocks and lifecycle biases in producing accurate estimates of
intergenerational associations in lifetime income (e.g. Solon, 1992; Mazumder,
2005; Haider and Solon, 2006, Mazumder, 2016). Longer time averages of parent
income have been shown to reduce attenuation bias. We analyze whether this is
also the case in the context of health by following the same approach. In order to
avoid having the composition of the sample change as we use longer-time averages,
we hold the sample size fixed by requiring parents to report health in some
minimum number of years (either 5, 7, 10 or 15 years). In all cases we keep the
time average of the child’s health measure fixed by using all available years.
The results for the IHA using a pooled sample of sons and daughters are
shown in Figure 3. We find that increasing the number of years in the parent time
average leads to progressively higher estimates that plateaus once we have a time
average of about 10 years (or more). For example, in Panel A when using the
sample where mother’s health status was observed for at least 15 years, estimates
increase from 0.15 to 0.25 as we increase the length of the time average from 1 year
to 10 years. Similarly, for fathers (Panel B), the estimates roughly double from 0.11
to 0.20 over the same range. These findings suggest that as is the case with income
and occupation (Mazumder and Acosta, 2015) it is critical to use long time averages
of health status to measure the IHA. In Figure 4, panels A to D, we plot analogous
graphs for rank-rank slopes where we estimate the models separately for each
parent-child pair. Although the attenuation bias differs somewhat by parent-child
combination, we find that time averaging may be as important for rank-rank slopes
in health as it is for estimating the IHA. 28 This contrasts with the case of income

28

For example, for the father-daughter sample, the estimates gradually rise from 0.16 to 0.30 as
the time average moves from 1 year to 11 years. In contrast, the mother-son rank-rank slope (Panel
A) estimates quickly increase from 0.19 to 0.25 with just a few years of data on mothers’ health.

19

where Mazumder (2016) and Nybom and Stuhler (2016) have found that rank-rank
slopes are more robust to measurement error and transitory fluctuations.
Life Cycle Bias
We next consider how the estimates differ depending on the age at which
health is measured. For each parent and child, we take an average of all available
years in the following age bins: 30-39, 40-49, 50-59, and 60-69. In panels C and D
of Figure 3, we find that the IHA estimates tend to fall as we measure parents’
health at later ages. For example, the IHA between fathers and the pooled sample
of sons and daughters is 0.25 for fathers between the ages of 30-39 and 0.15 for
fathers between the ages of 60-69. The analogous figures for mothers are 0.22 and
0.17. In panels E and F, we do the same type of exercise where we now vary child
age. Here we see the opposite pattern, the IHA estimates are larger when children’s
health is measured later in the life-cycle, particularly for the father-child IHA.
There are two points worth making here. First, the standard errors are
generally too large to find statistically significant differences across these different
age groupings. Second, when we restrict the sample based on the ages in one
generation, we may mechanically also alter the age composition of the other
generation. To address the issue of compositional bias, in panel A of Appendix
Table A.3, we present a set of IHA estimates for all combinations of parent and
child age bins. These estimates tend to be even noisier. With respect to
compositional biases, we find that when we restrict the sample to older age children
(e.g. over 50), there are many more intergenerational matches with parents whose
health is measured at an older age as well. On the other hand, if we restrict to
samples where parents’ health is measured at an older age, there are many more
matches to children who are between the ages of 30 to 49. Samples that match older
children to older mothers appear to produce the highest mother-child IHA

20

estimates. However, this is not as clear for samples that match older children to
older fathers. We find the highest IHA estimates when the child and father are both
at least 60. Overall, given how noisy the estimates are, we are hesitant to draw any
firm conclusions about how the age structure of the data may affect IHA estimates.
Nevertheless, there is some suggestive evidence that lifecycle biases may be present
and that the highest estimates are obtained when both parents’ and children’s health
are measured later in the lifecycle. This stands in contrast to the income mobility
literature where IGE estimates tend to have the least bias when parents and
children’s income are measured closer to mid-career. 29
In Figure 4 (panels E, F, G and H) and Appendix Table A.3 (panels B and
C), we do a similar set of exercises for the rank-rank slope. 30 In contrast to the IHA,
we find that the rank-rank slope estimates tend to be more stable. Nevertheless, we
again find that the highest estimates generally obtain when both the child and parent
are at least 50 years old and that the highest estimates between fathers and their
children are obtained when both fathers and their children are between 60 and 69.
4.3 Relationship between Health Mobility and Income Mobility
In this section we examine the degree to which families that experience
health mobility also experience income mobility. We begin by documenting the
correlation in levels between health status rank and income rank in each generation.
In Figure 5, we plot the mean health rank at each income percentile for sons,
daughters, mothers and fathers. Across the samples, we find a correlation between

29

See for example, Mazumder (2016). Earlier studies examining the implications of age-related
biases on intergenerational income mobility estimates include Jenkins (1987), Grawe (2006),
Mazumder (2005) and Haider and Solon (2006). Mazumder and Acosta (2015) discuss agerelated biases when studying occupational mobility.
30
Percentile ranks are calculated separately for each age bin.

21

health and income ranks, ranging from 0.33 to 0.48. 31 This is reflective of the wellknown gradient between SES and health.
We now turn to examining the correlation in the change in health rank
across generations and the change in income rank across generations. 32 This allows
us to identify the degree to which health and income mobility is correlated across
families. Figure 6 shows that there is a positive and almost linear relationship
between health and income mobility.

Not surprisingly, the correlation in

differences is lower than in levels and ranges from between 0.23 to 0.26. The fact
that the correlation in differences is somewhat low suggests that those individuals
who move up in income ranks are generally not the same as those who move up in
health ranks. 33 Income and health, therefore, appear to capture related but also
somewhat distinct dimensions of socioeconomic status. Hence, policies that target
income mobility may not necessarily impact health mobility. For example, it is
possible that individuals experiencing income mobility could suffer health
consequences perhaps due to greater stress. 34 One notable historical example
consistent with this idea is the Great Migration of blacks from the South to the

31

The correlations are higher in the parent generation. This is likely due to the fact that we have
more years of data for the parents which allows us to better capture lifetime latent health status
and income and thereby reduce attenuation bias.
32
The change in rank is simply the difference in percentile ranks between the parent and child in
each respective generation. A positive change is indicative of upward mobility while a negative
change implies downward mobility.
33
Appendix Table A.4 shows that the correlations between income and health mobility also differs
substantially across population subgroups. Correlations are generally much higher for whites than
for blacks and tend to rise with parent’s education level.
34
Miller et al. (2015) show that low SES black youth with high levels of self-control experience
improved outcomes such as lower rates of depressive symptoms, substance use, aggressive
behavior, and internalizing problems but faster epigenetic aging based on biomarkers. They
suggest that “outward indicators of success can mask emerging problems with health.” Azagba
and Sharaf (2011) link more stressful jobs to higher medical expenditures.

22

North during the 20th century which led to large income gains but a sharp fall in life
expectancy (Black et al., 2015).
4.4 Health Mobility by Subpopulations
We now use our rank mobility measures to describe how health mobility
varies across different subgroups of the population. For this analysis, we pooled
sons and daughters and combined the health of both parents. 35 In Table 6, we report
the rank-rank slopes and the expected ranks at 25th and 75th percentile by childhood
region, race and parent’s education for all children using both parents’ health.
Figure 7 plots the predicted percentile of the child’s health rank at each percentile
of the parent’s health rank from the associated rank-rank regressions. For
comparisons of subgroups we focus attention on the conditionally expected ranks
since this tells us how groups differ with respect to the overall distribution. 36
We begin by exploring the difference in health mobility across the regions
of the United States in which the child grew up. We find that growing up in the
South is associated with a lower rate of upward mobility. The expected health rank
for a child who grew up in the South with parents at the 25th percentile, is the 42nd
percentile, the lowest of the four regions (Table 6, column 2). In comparison,
children that grew up in the Northeast and North Central are expected to be at the
46th percentile. Downward mobility is also highest among children growing up in
the South. A child from the South with a parent at the 75th percentile in the health

35
Results for each parent-child sample are shown in Appendix Tables A.5 and the corresponding
figures are plotted in Appendix Figures A.6, A.8 and A.10. We also report additional measures of
upward and downward mobility, such as escaping bottom quintile, by subpopulations in Appendix
Table A.5.
36
We find for example, that persistence in health rank is higher for whites than for blacks which
suggests greater mobility within the black population than within the white population. While this
may be interesting, it does not convey how blacks fare in terms of their expected position in the
overall distribution. This is important since the health distributions differs markedly by race.

23

distribution has an expected rank of the 55th percentile, which is lower than in all
other regions. 37 The disparity between regions in health mobility, however, is not
as great as it is for income mobility (Table 6 columns 5 and 6), showing once again
that there may be important distinctions between health and income mobility.
Health mobility also differs substantially by race. We find that blacks
experience both lower upward mobility from the bottom and higher downward
mobility from the top. While whites with parents at the 25th health percentile are
expected to reach the 47th percentile, blacks with parents at the same health
percentile are expected to reach only the 37th percentile. This mobility gap
continues to increase throughout the parent rank distribution with blacks expected
to experience higher rates of downward mobility than whites. The expected rank at
the 75th percentile is almost 15 percentiles lower than for whites.
In contrast, the racial gaps in income mobility are much more pronounced. 38
While whites with parents at the 25th percentile of the income distribution are
expected to reach the 45th percentile, blacks are only expected to reach the 28th
percentile, nearly 17 percentiles lower. Therefore, black-white difference in
expected rank at the 25th percentile in income (in absolute value) is therefore 7
percentiles more than the black-white difference in expected rank at the 25th
percentile in health. In Figure 8A, we plot these black-white “mobility gaps” in
health and income throughout the distribution of health and income.
Lastly, we find that health mobility differs significantly by parent education
level. Children whose parents are at the 25th percentile but have a college degree
are expected to be at the 52nd percentile, but those with parents without a high

37

An F-test shows that the regional differences in upward mobility are statistically significant at
the 10 percent level but that the differences in downward mobility are not statistically significant.
38
See Hertz (2005), Bhattacharya and Mazumder (2011), Mazumder (2014) and Chetty et al.,
(2018) for analyses of differences in intergenerational income mobility by race.

24

school degree are only expected to attain the 37the percentile. This disparity is
evident throughout the parent health distribution (Figure 8B). This highlights that
the well-known disparity in health by education level also persists to the next
generation when looking at offspring health. One explanation is that more educated
parents have access to resources that can improve their children’s health regardless
of their own health status (Case et al. 2002).
4.5 Trends in Health Mobility
We next examine trends in health mobility for three groups of cohorts born
between: 1950-1959; 1960-1969; and 1970-1979. We start with trends in the IHA
which are displayed in Figure 9. For this analysis, we use only health observations
from age 30 to 40 for children and from age 40 to 70 for parents. 39 Figure 9 shows
an increase in the intergenerational health association from 0.18 to 0.26 between
the birth cohorts born in the 1950s and the 1970s. This increase appears for both
the son and daughter subsamples. However, the magnitude of the increase and its
statistical significance are somewhat sensitive to the choice of ages used to measure
parent health. In Appendix Table A.6, we find that the across cohort change is
smaller and not statistically significant when we restrict the samples to measure
parent health between the ages of 50 and 70.
We also investigate how rank mobility differs by birth cohort. In Figure 10,
we plot the rank-rank slopes (Panel A) and expected health ranks at the 25th and
75th percentile (Panel B) for the three cohorts. 40 Unlike the IHA, we find more

39

The age cutoffs are chosen to capture most of the sample. See Appendix Figure A.1 for plots of
the age distributions by generation. Since the age at which child and parent health is measured
matters, we also present results using health measurements at different ages (Table A.6).
40
As with our results for intergenerational health associations, we only use health observations
from age 30 to 40 for the child and from 40 to 70 for the parent. The associated results using
health measures at different ages for each parent-child sample are presented in Appendix Table
A.7.

25

limited evidence of an increase in rank-rank slopes. While the point estimate
increased from 0.23 to 0.27 for the full sample, this change is not statistically
significant. When we examine the expected ranks at the 25th and 75th percentile, we
do find suggestive evidence that upward mobility from the bottom declined and that
downward mobility from the top has increased for more recent cohorts. In
Appendix Table A.7, we examine the changes in rank mobility across the different
parent-child types. We find evidence of significant changes in rank persistence and
upward mobility from the bottom between fathers and sons.
Overall, we believe this constitutes suggestive evidence of a decline in
intergenerational health mobility for more recent cohorts. This finding is potentially
consistent with growing evidence of a decline in intergenerational income mobility
(e.g. Davis and Mazumder, 2017) and a decline in intergenerational educational
mobility reported by Hilger (2017). Nevertheless, since the most recent cohorts
(born since 1970 are still relatively young, future work may be able to better
substantiate whether a change in health mobility has taken place.
4.6 Potential Mechanisms
Does Health Insurance Matter?
Earlier we raised the possibility that social policies and institutions may
explain why there is a lower degree of intergenerational transmission of health
compared to income. A growing literature has linked access to health care,
particularly early in life, to long-run socioeconomic outcomes (e.g. Chay et al,
2009; Goodman-Bacon, 2017; Miller and Wherry, 2017). In this section we
consider the potential role of access to health insurance and whether it might play
a role in reducing the intergenerational transmission of health status. To examine
this issue, we used questions available in the early years (1968-1972) of the PSID
on whether all members of a household were covered by health insurance (during

26

the individual’s childhood years). 41 This requires us to use a subsample of our main
estimation sample for which this data is available. 42 Of course, access to health
insurance coverage is certainly not exogenous and is more likely to be available for
better educated and higher income families. To make some effort to address this
potential confounding factor, we also control for family background (parent
education and family income) in some specifications. 43
The results of this exercise are shown in Table 7. We first show that the
basic rank mobility statistics for the overall subsample are very similar to our
baseline sample. For example, we estimate a rank-rank slope of 0.243 (0.024)
which compares to an estimate of 0.261 (0.017) when we use our full sample (see
Table 4). We then divide this subsample into those who were covered by insurance
at least one year during childhood (age 0-16) and those who never had coverage.
We find that rank-rank slope for the former is 0.21 and the rank-rank slope for the
latter is 0.35. The difference of 0.135 (0.068) is statistically significant at the 5
percent confidence level. We also do an analogous exercise where we first control
for family background characteristics in a regression and then produce rank
mobility estimates using the residuals. We again find a very similar difference in
the rank-rank slopes between the two groups of 0.127 (0.066) which is statistically
significant at the 10 percent level.
We do not take the results of this exercise as definitive given our data
limitations. Ideally, we’d like to combine very large sample sizes with a better

41

Prior to 1999, except for a few exceptions, health insurance coverage data were only collected in
the PSID from 1968-1972, where the head of the household is asked whether he/she is covered
and if the insurance covered the whole family. Only Medicare and Medicaid coverage data were
collected between 1977 and 1997.
42
Specifically, we keep only parent-child pairs where the child was between the age of 0 and 16
and his/her family was surveyed during the years 1968-1972.
43
To control for family background, we use the residuals from regressing health status on age, age
squared, family income and parent education levels for the child’s health measure.

27

research design (e.g. changes in Medicaid expansion) to more credibly assess the
role of health insurance access on health mobility. However, we take these results
as at least suggestive that widespread access to health insurance may contribute to
the relatively low level of health persistence observed in the U.S.
The Role of Childhood Circumstances
Finally, we consider how childhood circumstances affect health mobility by
using a rich set of covariates on childhood circumstances available in the PSID’s
Childhood Retrospective Circumstance Study (CRCS). We begin with estimates of
the IHA from a pooled sample of sons and daughters in which we combine both
parents’ health. The results are depicted graphically in Figure 11 using a dot for the
point estimate and horizontal lines for the 95 percent confidence interval. The
baseline IHA estimate for this sample is 0.241. In Panel A, we then control for
different sets or “categories” of control variables. When we include a set of
measures of socioeconomic status (e.g. parent years of education, family income,
child race and various indices of SES), the IHA falls to 0.169. This finding that SES
can account for a significant share (29%) of the intergenerational association in
health is consistent with previous studies including Currie and Moretti (2007). If
instead of SES controls, we include a set of childhood health measures the IHA
estimate falls to just 0.221. Controlling only for measures of childhood stability,
school experience, or childhood relationships appears to have little effect on the
IHA. Using all the variables together lowers the IHA to 0.154. This accounts for
36% of the unconditional IHA. Finally, panel B, depicts the associated estimates
when controlling for one variable at a time, rather than using whole categories.
In Figure 12, we do an analogous breakdown of the rank-rank slope and
find very similar patterns. Our baseline estimate of 0.292 falls to 0.232 if we control

28

for family SES background variables and 0.223 if we include all of our controls.
Thus, we can account for 24 percent of the rank-rank persistence.
V.

Conclusion
Given the rise of inequality and associated concerns about unequal

opportunity, studies of intergenerational mobility have received growing attention.
Most studies have focused primarily on income, education, or occupation.
However, the extant literature has largely neglected health despite its central
importance to welfare. To fill this void, we provide the first estimates of
intergenerational mobility with respect to a broad-based measure of lifetime health
in the US by using repeated measures of self-reported health status. We find that
there is a substantially higher degree of health mobility than income mobility.
One explanation for this pattern is that policies and institutions in the U.S.
may be more effective at breaking intergenerational linkages in health than in labor
market outcomes. For example, the well-documented gradient in school quality by
income in the U.S. (Reardon, 2011) likely contributes to the intergenerational
income dependence. In contrast, the availability of a modern public health
infrastructure providing clean air and water, combined with access to adequate
nutrition and health care for the vast majority of children, may have diminished the
intergenerational transmission of health status. We find suggestive evidence that
access to health insurance during childhood reduces intergenerational health
persistence. It may also be the case that income persistence in the U.S. had been
more in line with health persistence in the past, but has risen in more recent decades
as inequality and the returns to schooling have grown (Aaronson and Mazumder,
2008; Davis and Mazumder, 2017).
We also find that that there is a relatively low correspondence between
income mobility and health mobility across families. Consequently, some adult

29

children might be as well off in relative terms as their parents in terms of economic
resources, but not necessarily in terms of health (and vice versa). Hence, health
appears to captures a distinct dimension of socioeconomic status than income.
In addition, given recent research suggesting a decline in intergenerational
mobility with respect to education and income (e.g. Hilger, 2017; Davis and
Mazumder, 2017) we also investigate time trends in intergenerational health
mobility. We find suggestive evidence of a decline among more recent cohorts born
since 1970. Further research that follows these cohorts to later ages may be useful
in corroborating this finding.
Finally, we also document important differences in intergenerational health
mobility by region, race and parent education levels. We find that blacks experience
significantly less upward mobility and significantly higher downward mobility than
whites. However, this racial mobility gap in health is smaller than the analogous
racial mobility gaps in income. Children of less educated parents are also similarly
disadvantaged when it comes to health as compared to children of well-educated
parents.

30

References

Aaronson, Daniel, and Bhashkar Mazumder. 2008. “Intergenerational Economic
Mobility in the US: 1940 to 2000.” Journal of Human Resources, 43(1): 139-172.
Aizer, Anna, and Janet Currie. 2014. “The Intergenerational Transmission of
Inequality: Maternal Disadvantage and Health at Birth.” Science, 344 (6186):
856–861.
Akbulut-Yuksel, Mevlude, and Adriana D. Kugler. 2016. “Intergenerational
persistence of health: Do immigrants get healthier as they remain in the U.S. for
more generations?” Economics & Human Biology, 23: 136-148.
Azagba, Sunday, and Mesbah Sharaf. 2011. “Psychosocial working conditions
and the utilization of health care services.” BMC Public Health, 11:642.
Bhattacharya, Debopam, and Bhashkar Mazumder. 2011. “A nonparametric
analysis of black–white differences in intergenerational income mobility in the
United States.” Quantitative Economics, 2(3): 335-379.
Black, Dan A., Seth G. Sanders, Evan J. Taylor and Lowell J. Taylor. 2015. “The
Impact of the Great Migration on Mortality of African Americans: Evidence from
the Deep South.” American Economic Review, 105(2): 477-503.
Black, Sandra, Paul Devereux, and Kjell Salvanes. 2007. “From the Cradle to the
Labor Market? The Effect of Birth Weight on Adult Outcomes.” Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 122(1): 409-439.
Case, Anne, Fertig, Angela and Paxson, Christina, 2005. The lasting impact of
childhood health and circumstance. Journal of Health Economics, 24(2): 365-389.
Case, Anne, Darren Lubotsky, and Christina Paxson. 2002. "Economic Status and
Health in Childhood: The Origins of the Gradient." American Economic
Review, 92(5): 1308-1334.
Chay, Kenneth, Jonathan Guryan, and Bhashkar Mazumder. 2009. “Birth Cohort
and the Black-White Achievement Gap: The Roles of Access and Health Soon
After Birth.” Working Paper.
Chetty, Raj, Nathaniel Hendren, Patrick Kline and Emmanuel Saez. 2014. “Where
is the land of Opportunity? The Geography of Intergenerational Mobility in the
United States.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129(4): 1553-1623.

31

Chetty, Raj, Nathaniel Hendren, Maggie R. Jones, and Sonya R. Porter. 2018
“Race and Economic Opportunity in the United States: An Intergenerational
Perspective.” NBER Working Paper No. 24441.
Coneus, Katja, and C. Katharina Spiess. 2012. “The intergenerational
transmission of health in early childhood—Evidence from the German SocioEconomic Panel Study.” Economics & Human Biology, 10(1): 89-97.
Currie, Janet, and Enrico Moretti. 2007. "Biology as Destiny? Short- and LongRun Determinants of Intergenerational Transmission of Birth Weight." Journal of
Labor Economics, 25(2): 231-264.
Davis, Jonathan, and Bhashkar Mazumder. 2017. “The Decline in
Intergenerational Mobility After 1980” Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
Working Paper 2017-05.
Davis, Jonathan, and Bhashkar Mazumder. 2018. “Racial and Ethnic Differences
in the Geography of Intergenerational Mobility.” Working Paper.
Darden, Michael and Donna Gilleskie. 2016. “The Effects of Parental Health
Shocks on Adult Offspring Smoking Behaviors and Self-Assessed Health.”
Health Economics, 25(8): 939-954.
Deaton, A. and Paxson, C., 1994. Intertemporal choice and inequality. Journal of
political economy, 102(3): 437-467.
Deaton, A.S. and Paxson, C., 1998. Health, income, and inequality over the life
cycle. In Frontiers in the Economics of Aging (pp. 431-462). University of
Chicago Press.
DeSalvo Karen, Vincent Fan, Mary McDonell, and Stephan Fihn. 2006.
“Predicting Mortality and Healthcare Utilization with a Single Question” Health
Services Research, 40(4):1234–46.
Erickson, Pennifer, Ronald Wilson, and Ildy Shannon. 1995. “Years of Healthy
Life.” Healthy People 2000: Statistical Notes from Centers for Disease Control
and Prevention, 7:1-14.
French, Eric, and John Bailey Jones. 2017. “Health, Health Insurance, and
Retirement: A Survey.” FRB Richmond Working Paper no. 17-3.

32

Goodman-Bacon, Andrew. 2017. “The Long-Run Effects of Childhood Insurance
Coverage: Medicaid Implementation, Adult Health, and Labor Market
Outcomes.” Working Paper.
Grawe, Nathan. 2006. “The Extent of Lifecycle Bias in Estimates of
Intergenerational Earnings Persistence.” Labour Economics, 13(5): 551-570.
Haider Steven, and Gary Solon. 2006. “Life-Cycle Variation in the Association
Between Current and Lifetime Earnings.” American Economic
Review, 96(4):1308–20.
Halliday, T.J., 2011. “Health inequality over the life-cycle.” The BE Journal of
Economic Analysis & Policy, 11(3).
Halliday, T. J. 2014. “Unemployment and Mortality: Evidence from the PSID.”
Social Science & Medicine, 113, 15-22.
Hertz, Tom. 2005. “Rags, Riches and Race: The Intergenerational Economic
Mobility of Black and White Families in the United States.” In Unequal Chances:
Family Background and Economic Success, edited by Samuel Bowles, Herbert
Gintis, and Melissa Osborne, pp. 165–91. New York: Russell Sage and Princeton
University Press.
Hilger, Nathaniel. 2017. “The Great Escape: Intergenerational Mobility in the
United States, 1930-2010.” Working Paper.
Hong, Sok and Jiwol Park. 2016. “The Socioeconomic Gradient in the Inheritance
of Longevity: A Study of American Genealogies.” Working Paper.
Idler, Ellen, and Yael Benyamini. 1997. "Self-Rated Health and Mortality: A
Review of Twenty-Seven Community Studies." Journal of Health and Social
Behavior, 38(1): 21-37.
Jenkins, Stephen. 1987. “Snapshots Versus Movies: ‘Lifecycle Biases’ and the
Estimation of Intergenerational Earnings Inheritance.” European Economic
Review, 31(5):1149–58.
Johnson, Rucker, and Robert Schoeni. 2011. “The Influence of Early-Life Events
on Human Capital, Health Status, and Labor Market Outcomes Over the Life
Course.” The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy. 11(3): 2521.

33

Johnston, David W., Stefanie Schurer, and Michael A. Shields. 2013. "Exploring
the Intergenerational Persistence of Mental Health: Evidence from Three
Generations." Journal of Health Economics 32(6): 1077-1089.
Jones, Charles and Klenow, Peter, 2016. Beyond GDP? Welfare across countries
and time. The American Economic Review, 106(9): 2426-2457.
Kolenikov, Stanislav, and Gustavo Angeles. 2009. “Socioeconomic Status
Measurement with Discrete Proxy Variables: Is Principal Component Analysis a
Reliable Answer?” The Review of Income and Wealth, 55(1): 128-165.
Kim, Younoh, Bondan Sikoki, John Strauss, and Firman Witoelar. 2015.
“Intergenerational correlations of health among older adults: Empirical evidence
from Indonesia.” The Journal of the Economics of Ageing, 6: 44-56.
Lach, Saul and Ritov, Yaacov and Simhon, Avi. 2008. “The Transmission of
Longevity Across Generations.” Working Paper.
Lindahl, Mikael, Evelina Lundberg, Mårten Palme, and Emilia Simeonova. 2016.
“Parental Influences on Health and Longevity: Lessons from a Large Sample of
Adoptees.” NBER Working Paper No. 21946
Mazumder, Bhashkar. 2005. “Fortunate Sons: New Estimates of Intergenerational
Mobility in the United States Using Social Security Earnings Data.” Review of
Economics and Statistics, 87(2):235–55
Mazumder, Bhashkar. 2014. “Black-White Differences in Intergenerational
Mobility in the United States.” Economic Perspectives, 38(1).
Mazumder, Bhashkar, and Miguel Acosta. 2014. “Using Occupation to Measure
Intergenerational Mobility.” The ANNALS of the American Academy of Political
and Social Science, 657: 174-193.
Mazumder, Bhashkar. 2016. “Estimating the Intergenerational Elasticity and
Rank Association in the U.S.: Overcoming the Current Limitations of Tax Data.”
in Lorenzo Cappellari , Solomon W. Polachek , Konstantinos Tatsiramos (ed.)
Inequality: Causes and Consequences (Research in Labor Economics, Volume
43) Emerald Group Publishing Limited, pp.83 – 129
Mazumder, Bhashkar. 2018. “Intergenerational Mobility in the US: What We
Have Learned from the PSID.” The ANNALS of the American Academy of
Political and Social Science, 680(1): 213-234.

34

Miilunpalo, Seppo, Ilkka Vuori, Pekka Oja, Matti Pasanen, and Helka Urponen,
1997. “Self-rated health status as a health measure: The predictive value of selfreported health status on the use of physician services and on mortality in the
working-age population.” Journal of Clinical Epidemiology, 50(5): 517-528.
Miller, Gregory, Tianyi Yu, Edith Chen, and Gene Brody. 2015. “Self-control
forecasts better psychosocial outcomes but faster epigenetic aging in low-SES
youth.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of
America, 112(33):10325–10330.
Miller, Sarah, and Laura Wherry. 2017. “Health and Access to Care during the
First 2 Years of the ACA Medicaid Expansions.” New England Journal of
Medicine 376:947-956.
Nyborn, Martin, and Jan Stuhler. 2014. “Heterogeneous Income Profiles and
Lifecycle Bias in Intergenerational Mobility Estimation.” Journal of Human
Resources, 51(1): 239-268.
Palumbo, M.G., 1999. Uncertain medical expenses and precautionary saving near
the end of the life cycle. The Review of Economic Studies, 66(2): 395-421.
Pascual, Marta, and David Cantarero. 2009. “Intergenerational health mobility: an
empirical approach based on the ECHP.” Applied Economics, 41: 451-458.
Reardon, Sean. 2011. “The widening academic achievement gap between the rich
and the poor: New evidence and possible explanations.” In R. Murnane & G.
Duncan (Eds.), Whither Opportunity? Rising Inequality and the Uncertain Life
Chances of Low-Income Children. New York: Russell Sage Foundation Press.
Rust, J. and Phelan, C., 1997. How social security and medicare affect retirement
behavior in a world of incomplete markets. Econometrica: 781-831.
Solon, Gary. 1992. “Intergenerational Income Mobility in the United States.”
American Economic Review, 82(3): 393-408.
Steves, Claire Joanne, Timothy D. Spector, and Stephen H. D. Jackson. 2012.
“Ageing, genes, environment and epigenetics: what twin studies tell us now, and
in the future.” Age and Ageing, 41(5): 581-586.
Thompson, Owen. 2016. “Gene-Environment Interaction in the Intergenerational
Transmission of Asthma.” Health Economics, 26(11): 1337-1352.

35

Figure 1: Health status over life cycle

(a) Mean health status by age

(b) Standard deviation by age
Panel A of Figure 1 plots the mean continuous health measure at each age for the full sample and includes all generations and genders. The mean
at each age is weighted using the most recently available individual weights. The red line is a fitted local cubic polynomial using the Epanechnikov
kernel. The scale reflects the lower cutoffs between reported health status categories on the 0-100 HALex scale where 100 equals perfect health and
zero is equivalent to death: [95,100] is excellent, [85,95) is very good, [70,85) is good, [30,70) is fair and [1,30) for poor health. The continuous
health measure for each individual at a given survey year is the midpoint of the interval corresponding to their reported health category. Panel B
plots the standard deviation at each age for the same sample and is weighted using the most recently available individual weights. The red line is a
fitted local cubic polynomial using the Epanechnikov kernel.

Figure 2: Health and income rank mobility using both parents’ health for all children

(a) Health rank mobility

(b) Income rank mobility
Figure 2 Panel A plots the mean child health percentile rank at each percentile of the parent health distribution using both parents’ health for all
children. Panel B plots the mean child income percentile rank at each percentile of the parent income distribution using both parents’ income for
all children. The red line in each graph is the estimated regression line from the weighted bivariate regression of child rank on parent rank. The
rank-rank slope is the coefficient on parent income percentile. The expected rank at the 25th (or 75th) percentile is the predicted rank from the
rank-rank specification for a child with a parent at the 25th (or 75th) percentile of the parent health or income rank distribution. Health percentile
ranks are constructed from the age-adjusted health measure and are ranked separately for each generation. Income percentile ranks are constructed
from the time-averaged total family income adjusted for age, family size and inflation and are ranked separately for each generation. All means and
regressions are weighted using the most recently available individual sampling weights of the child. Standard errors for the regression coefficients
(in parentheses) are robust to heteroskedasticity and within-family correlation.

Figure 3: Robustness of intergenerational health associations

(a) Attenuation bias: varying years of parent health
measurement using mother’s health

(b) Attenuation bias: varying years of parent health
measurement using father’s health

(c) Life cycle bias: varying age of mother’s health
measurement

(d) Life cycle bias: varying age of father’s health
measurement

Figure 3: Robustness of intergenerational health associations – Continued

(e) Life cycle bias: varying age of child’s health
measurement using mother’s health

(f) Life cycle bias: varying age of child’s health
measurement using father’s health

Figure 3 evaluates the robustness of the estimates of intergenerational health associations to attenuation and life cycle biases.
Panels A and B plot the intergenerational health associations using varying time averages of mother (Panel A) and fathers (Panel
B) health within fixed samples of children with parents with at least 5, 7, 10, or 15 years of health observations. The number of
observations for each fixed sample is reported in parentheses. Panels C and D plot the intergenerational health associations using
parent’s health observations within the 10-year age bins and all available child health observations over age of 30. Panels E and F
plot the intergenerational health associations using child’s health observations within the 10-year age bins and all available parent
health observations over age of 30. In all specifications in Figure 3, the intergenerational health associations are estimated using the
pooled sample of children, which includes both sons and daughters and include as controls the quadratic age terms of parent and
child. Age for both generations is defined as the time-averaged age of the individual at the time of the utilized health observations.
All regressions are weighted using the most recently available individual sampling weights of the child.

Figure 4: Robustness of rank-rank slopes

(a) Attenuation bias: varying years of parent health
measurement for mothers and sons

(b) Attenuation bias: varying years of parent health
measurement for fathers and sons

(c) Attenuation bias: varying years of parent health
measurement for mothers and daughters

(d) Attenuation bias: varying years of parent health
measurement for fathers and daughters

Figure 4: Robustness of rank-rank slopes – Continued

(e) Life cycle bias: varying age of mother’s health
measurement

(f) Life cycle bias: varying age of father’s health
measurement

(g) Life cycle bias: varying age of child’s health
measurement using mother’s health

(h) Life cycle bias: varying age of child’s health
measurement using father’s health

Figure 4 evaluates the robustness of the estimates of rank-rank slopes to attenuation and life cycle biases. Panels A to D plot the
rank-rank slopes using varying time averages of mother (Panel A and C) and fathers (Panel B and D) health within fixed samples of
children with parents with at least 5, 7, 10, or 15 years of health observations. The number of observations for each fixed sample is
reported in parentheses. Panels E and F plot the rank-rank slopes using parent’s health observations within the 10-year age bins and
all available child health observations over age of 30. Panels G and H plot the rank-rank slopes using child’s health observations
within the 10-year age bins and all available parent health observations over age of 30. In all specifications in Figure 4, the rankrank slopes are estimated from weighted bivariate regressions of child health rank on parent health rank using the most recently
available individual sampling weights of the child. Age adjustment and percentile ranks are done separately for each alternative
parent and child health measure.

Figure 5: Correlation in health and income rank by generation

(a) Sons

(b) Daughters

(c) Mothers

(d) Fathers

Figure 5 plots the mean health rank at each percentile of the income rank distribution for sons (Panel A), daughters (Panel B),
mothers (Panel C) and fathers (Panel D). Health percentile ranks are constructed from the age-adjusted health measure and are
ranked separately by gender within each generation. Income percentile ranks are constructed from time-averaged total family
income after adjusting for age, family size and inflation. The red line in each graph is the fitted line. Correlation between health
and income rank at the individual level for each subsample is reported. All means and correlations are weighted using the most
recently available individual sampling weights.

Figure 6: Correlation in health and income rank mobility by generation

(a) Mothers and sons

(b) Fathers and sons

(c) Mothers and daughters

(d) Fathers and daughters

Figure 6 plots the mean change in health rank at each percentile change of the income rank distribution for each parent-child
sample. Change in health (income) rank is the difference between child’s health (income) percentile rank and parent’s health
(income) percentile rank. Health percentile ranks are constructed from the age-adjusted health measure and are ranked separately
by gender within each generation. Income percentile ranks are constructed from time-averaged total family income after adjusting
for age, family size and inflation. The red line in each graph is the fitted line. Correlation between change in health rank and
change in income rank at the individual level for each subsample is reported. All means and correlations are weighted using the
most recently available individual sampling weights of the child.

Figure 7: Health rank mobility by region, race and education

(a) Rank mobility by region

(b) Rank mobility by race

(c) Rank mobility by parent’s education
Figure 7 plots estimated regression lines from the weighted bivariate regressions of child rank on parent rank by childhood region,
race and education using both parents’ health for all children. Region refers to the region the child grew up in, defined as the modal
region in which the household is surveyed before the child is 18. Race refers to the reported race of the child. Education refers to
the highest level attained by at least one of the parents in the most recently available survey. The rank-rank slope, denoted by , is
the coefficient on parent health percentile. The expected rank at the 25th (or 75th) percentile, denoted by p25 (p75 ), is the predicted
rank from the rank-rank specification for a child with parents at the 25th (or 75th) percentile of the parent health rank distribution.
Health percentile ranks are constructed from the age-adjusted baseline health measure and are ranked separately by generation.
All regressions are weighted using the most recently available individual sampling weights of the child. Standard errors for the
regression coefficients (in parentheses) are robust to heteroskedasticity and within-family correlation.

Figure 8: Difference in health and income mobility by race and education

(a) Difference by race

(b) Difference by parent educational level
Panel A of Figure 8 plots the difference in expected rank between whites and blacks for health and income along the parent rank
distribution. Panel B plots the difference in expected rank between children with parents with college degree and children with
parents with less than high school degree for health and income. The predicted ranks are estimated from the weighted bivariate
regressions of child rank on parent rank by race or education for all children using both parent’s health or income measure. Race
refers to the reported race of the child. Parent education is the highest level of education attained by at least one of the parent. Health
percentile ranks are constructed from the age-adjusted baseline health measure and are ranked separately within each generation.
Income percentile ranks are constructed from the time-averaged total family income measure after adjusting for age, family size
and inflation and are ranked separately within each generation. All regressions are weighted using the most recently available
individual sampling weights of the child. 95% confidence interval bands are shown calculated using standard errors that are robust
to heteroskedasticity and within-family correlation.

Figure 9: Trends in intergenerational health associations

(a) All children

(b) Sons

(c) Daughters
Figure 9 plots the intergenerational health associations by child’s birth cohort (1950-1959, 1960-1969, 1970-1979) for all children
(Panel A), sons (Panel B) and daughters (Panel C). The intergenerational health associations are estimated using all available health
measurements that are between age 30 and 40 for the child’s health measure and all available health measurements that are between
age 40 and 70 for the parent’s health measure. The dependent variable for all specifications is the child’s time-averaged continuous
health measure. The parent health measure is the average of the mother’s and father’s health if available. Otherwise, only one
parent’s health measure is used. All specifications include as controls the quadratic age terms of the mother, father and child, and
missing indicators for mother and father. Age for both generations is defined as the time-averaged age of the individual at the time
of health observations. All regressions are weighted using sampling weights of the most recently available individual weights for
the child.

Figure 10: Trends in health rank mobility

(a) Rank-rank slopes by birth cohort

(b) Expected ranks at 25th and 75th percentiles by birth cohort
Figure 10 plots the rank-rank slopes (Panel A), expected ranks at the 25th and 75th health percentile (Panel B) by child’s birth
cohort (1950-1959, 1960-1969, 1970-1979) using both parents’ health for all children. The rank-rank slope is the coefficient on
parent health percentile from the bivariate regression of child rank on parent rank. The expected rank at the 25th (or 75th) percentile
is the predicted rank from the rank-rank specification for a child with a parent at the 25th (or 75th) percentile of the parent health
rank distribution. Health percentile ranks are constructed from the age-adjusted health measure and are ranked separately by birth
cohort within each generation. Child’s health measure is the average of all available health measurements that are between age
30 and 40 and parents’ health measure is the average of all available health measurements that are between age 40 and 70. All
regressions are weighted using the most recently available individual sampling weights of the child.

Figure 11: Effect of childhood factors on intergenerational health associations

(a) Decomposition of IHA by categories of childhood factors

(b) Decomposition of IHA by individual childhood factors
Figure 11 shows how the baseline intergenerational health association is attributable to various childhood factors for the sample of individuals in the child generation who were also part of the 2014
Childhood Retrospective Circumstance Study (CRCS). Panel A plots the intergenerational health associations as groups of childhood factors are added to the baseline regression of child’s health
measure on parent’s health measure. Family SES Background includes mother’s years of education, father’s years of education, family income, SES Index Age 0-5, SES Index Age 6-12, SES
Age 13-16, Neighborhood Quality Index, and controls for race of child (white, black or other). Childhood Health includes Child Health Index, Underweight at 13, Overweight at 13, and Obese at
13. Childhood Stability includes number of times moved in childhood, number of schools attended before 17, if parents were satisfied with their relationship, and if parents ever divorced. School
Experience includes number of times repeat school grade, School Experience Index Age 6-12, School Experience Age 13-16. Childhood Relationship includes Friendship Quality Index Age 6-12,
Friendship Quality Index Age 13-16, Relationship with Mother Quality Index, Relationship with Father Quality Index, and having a mentor at age 17-30. Panel B plots the intergenerational health
associations as individual childhood factors are added to the baseline regression. The dependent variable for all specifications is the child’s time-averaged continuous health measure. The parent
health measure is the average of the mother’s and father’s health if available. Otherwise, only one parent’s health measure is used. All specifications include as controls the quadratic age terms of
the mother, father and child, and missing indicators for mother and father. Age for both generations is defined as the time-averaged age of the individual at the time of health observations. The red
dashed lines denote the baseline intergenerational health association. Additional details on the CRCS variables can be found in Appendix A. All regressions are weighted using individual CRCS
sampling weights of the child. 95% confidence intervals are shown calculated using standard errors that are robust to heteroskedasticity and within-family correlation.

Figure 12: Effect of childhood factors on rank-rank slopes

(a) Decomposition of rank-rank slopes by categories of childhood factors

(b) Decomposition of rank-rank slopes by individual childhood factors
Figure 12 shows how the baseline rank-rank slope is attributable to various childhood factors for the sample of individuals in the child generation
who were also part of the 2014 Childhood Retrospective Circumstance Study (CRCS). Panel A plots the rank-rank slopes as groups of childhood
factors are added to the baseline bivariate regression of child’s health rank on parent’s health rank. Family SES Background includes mother’s years
of education, father’s years of education, family income, SES Index Age 0-5, SES Index Age 6-12, SES Age 13-16, Neighborhood Quality Index,
and controls for race of child (white, black or other). Childhood Health includes Child Health Index, Underweight at 13, Overweight at 13, and
Obese at 13. Childhood Stability includes number of times moved in childhood, number of schools attended before 17, if parents were satisfied with
their relationship, and if parents ever divorced. School Experience includes number of times repeat school grade, School Experience Index Age
6-12, School Experience Age 13-16. Childhood Relationship includes Friendship Quality Index Age 6-12, Friendship Quality Index Age 13-16,
Relationship with Mother Quality Index, Relationship with Father Quality Index, and having a mentor at age 17-30. Panel B plots the rank-rank
slopes as individual childhood factors are added to the baseline regression. Health percentile ranks are constructed from the age-adjusted health
measure and are ranked separately by gender within each generation. The red dashed lines denote the baseline rank-rank slope. Additional details
on the CRCS variables can be found in Appendix A. All regressions are weighted using individual CRCS sampling weights of the child. 95%
confidence intervals are shown calculated using standard errors that are robust to heteroskedasticity and within-family correlation.

Table 1: Summary Statistics
A. Parents
Father
(1)

Mother
(2)

56.72
(10.48)
12.96
(3.10)
59405.94
(50472.40)

56.17
(11.04)
12.51
(2.68)
50318.97
(45929.52)

77.37
(17.08)
7%
35%
34%
22%
2%

75.73
(16.60)
4%
30%
39%
25%
2%

14.81
5,440
2,425

15.48
7,721
3,151

All
(3)

Sons
(4)

Daughters
(5)

38.54
(6.02)
13.96
(2.25)
54303.96
(46086.89)

38.68
(6.09)
13.85
(2.30)
56973.13
(45849.59)

38.41
(5.94)
14.06
(2.20)
51636.98
(46174.67)

82.60
(13.50)
11%
44%
32%
12%
1%

83.38
(13.51)
13%
45%
30%
11%
1%

81.83
(13.44)
9%
43%
34%
14%
1%

Age
Years of Education
Total Family Income (2013 Dollars)

Overall Health Status
Excellent
Very Good
Good
Fair
Poor
Years of Health Measurement (Min=1, Max=22)
Number of Observations
Number of Observations (CRCS)

B. Children

Age
Years of Education
Total Family Income (2013 Dollars)

Overall Health Status
Excellent
Very Good
Good
Fair
Poor

Table 1: Summary Statistics – Continued
Race
White
Black
Other

83%
14%
3%

85%
13%
3%

81%
16%
3%

Childhood Region
Northeast
North Central
South
West
Alaska and Hawaii
Foreign Country

22.4%
28.1%
31.8%
17.4%
0.1%
0.2%

22.1%
28.7%
31.7%
17.2%
0.1%
0.3%

22.7%
27.6%
32.0%
17.6%
0.0%
0.1%

Years of Health Measurement (Min=1, Max=22)
Number of Observations
Number of Observations (CRCS)

8.7
8,115
3,281

8.5
3,828
1,407

8.8
4,287
1,874

All
(6)

Sons
(7)

Daughters
(8)

0.00
(1.00)
0.00
(1.00)
0.00
(1.00)
0.00
(1.00)

0.01
(1.01)
0.01
(1.00)
0.05
(0.95)
-0.02
(1.02)

-0.01
(1.00)
-0.01
(1.00)
-0.04
(1.04)
0.02
(0.98)

0.00
(1.00)
0.06
(0.24)
0.17
(0.38)
0.12
(0.32)

0.08
(0.93)
0.06
(0.23)
0.22
(0.42)
0.14
(0.35)

-0.07
(1.05)
0.06
(0.24)
0.12
(0.33)
0.09
(0.29)

1.04

1.06

1.02

C. CRCS Variables

Family Socioeconomic Background
SES Index Age 0-5
SES Index Age 6-12
SES Index Age 13-16
Neighborhood Quality Index
Childhood Health
Child Health Index
Underweight at 13
Overweight at 13
Obese at 13
Childhood Stability
# Times Moved in Childhood

Table 1: Summary Statistics – Continued
# Schools Attended Before 17
Parents Satisfied with Relationship
Parents Ever Divorced
School Experience
# Times Repeat School Grade
School Experience Index Age 6-12
School Experience Index Age 13-16
Childhood Relationship
Friendship Quality Index Age 6-12
Friendship Quality Index Age 13-16
Relationship with Mother Quality Index
Relationship with Father Quality Index
Had Mentor Age 17-30

(1.81)
3.35
(1.71)
0.72
(0.45)
0.13
(0.34)

(1.82)
3.26
(1.70)
0.75
(0.43)
0.13
(0.33)

(1.80)
3.42
(1.71)
0.70
(0.46)
0.14
(0.34)

0.13
(0.45)
0.00
(1.00)
0.00
(1.00)

0.17
(0.44)
-0.15
(1.00)
-0.13
(1.02)

0.10
(0.45)
0.13
(0.98)
0.11
(0.97)

0.00
(1.00)
0.00
(1.00)
0.00
(1.00)
0.00
(1.00)
0.65
(0.48)

0.01
(0.95)
0.03
(0.97)
0.11
(0.90)
0.02
(0.97)
0.63
(0.48)

-0.01
(1.04)
-0.03
(1.03)
-0.10
(1.07)
-0.02
(1.03)
0.67
(0.47)

Table 1 provides descriptive statistics of the data. Panel A and B reports the summary statistics for the main sample from the 1984-2013 survey years of the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID). This sample includes only
individuals who are matched to at least one parent. Across both generations, only individuals with at least one
health status observation measured at age 30 and older are included. Panel C reports the summary statistics for the
individuals in the child generation who were also part of the 2013 Childhood Retrospective Circumstance Study
(CRCS). Age refers to the mean time-averaged age of the individual at the time of all available health observations. Years of education is the mean total years of education attained reported at most recently available survey.
Total family income reported in 2013 dollars is the mean time-averaged total family income, which includes all
taxable income and cash transfers for all family members after adjusting for family size and inflation. Overall
health status is the time-averaged of all available health observations after converting the ordinal health status into
continuous units on a 0-100 scale. The categories of health status (excellent, very good, good, fair, poor) are the
percentage of individuals whose time-averaged overall health status is in that category according to the HALex
scale. Years of health measurement refers to the mean number of total years of health observations for each individual. The race categories refer to the percentage of the sample that identifies with that race in most recently
available survey. Childhood region categories refer to percentage of the sample that grew up in that region, defined as the modal region in which the household is surveyed before the child is 18. For CRCS variables (Panel
C), all index variables are reported in original units and are constructed using PCA across the full CRCS sample.
Details on the index construction and all other CRCS variables can be found in Appendix A. Standard deviations
are reported in parentheses. All reported means and standard deviations are weighted using the most recently
available individual sampling weight. For the CRCS variables, means and standard deviations are weighted using
the individual CRCS sampling weight.

Table 2: Probability of child in at least good health conditioned on mother or father’s health status

Mother’s Health

Mother’s Health Excellent
Mother’s Health Very Good
Mother’s Health Good
Father’s Health Excellent

Father’s Health

All
(1)

Sons
(2)

Daughters
(3)

All
(4)

Sons
(5)

Daughters
(6)

0.159
(0.0249)
0.152
(0.0163)
0.109
(0.0166)

0.179
(0.0269)
0.144
(0.0223)
0.0955
(0.0232)

0.136
(0.0414)
0.160
(0.0222)
0.121
(0.0220)

0.632
(0.287)

0.145
(0.0222)
0.122
(0.0184)
0.106
(0.0181)
0.344
(0.263)

0.166
(0.0299)
0.123
(0.0279)
0.107
(0.0268)
0.599
(0.306)

0.122
(0.0326)
0.120
(0.0229)
0.103
(0.0236)
0.103
(0.361)

0.571
(0.205)

0.517
(0.289)

7,606
0.048
0.871

3,600
0.052
0.884

4,006
0.046
0.859

5,376
0.039
0.895

2,596
0.037
0.900

2,780
0.043
0.890

Father’s Health Very Good
Father’s Health Good
Constant
Observations
R-squared
Y-mean

Each column of Table 2 reports the coefficients and standard errors from a weighted regression using sampling weights
of the most recently available individual weights for the child. The dependent variable for all specifications is an indicator variable that takes on the value of 1 (and 0 otherwise) if the child’s time-averaged continuous health measure is
in good, very good or excellent health according to the HALex scale. The omitted category for all regressions is parent
(mother or father) health in poor or fair health. All specifications include as controls the quadratic age terms of the parent (mother or father) and quadratic age terms of the child. Age for both generations are defined as the time-averaged
age of the individual at the time of all available health observations. Columns 1 and 4 report the results using all children. Columns 2 and 5 report the results using sons only. Columns 3 and 6 report the results using daughters only.
Y-mean refers to the weighted mean of the dependent variable within the regression sample. Standard errors for the
regressions (in parentheses) are robust to heteroskedasticity and within-family correlation.

Table 3: Intergenerational health associations by parent-child samples

Mother’s Health Only
Father’s Health Only
Both Parents’ Health

All Children
(1)

Sons
(2)

Daughters
(3)

0.204
(0.019)
0.172
(0.017)
0.229
(0.020)

0.200
(0.023)
0.165
(0.023)
0.218
(0.024)

0.206
(0.025)
0.181
(0.025)
0.238
(0.025)

Each cell of Table 3 reports the coefficient and standard error on the parent health measure from a separate regression. The regressions are weighted using sampling weights of the most recently available individual weights for the child. The dependent variable
for all specifications is the child’s time-averaged continuous health measure. The main explanatory variable for specifications using mother’s health or father’s health is the parent’s time-averaged continuous health measure. For regressions using both parents’
health, the parent health measure is the average of the mother’s and father’s health if available. Otherwise, only one parent’s health
measure is used. All specifications include as controls the quadratic age terms of the parent (mother or father) and quadratic age
terms of the child. Age for both generations is defined as the time-averaged age of the individual at the time of all available health
observations. In specifications using both parents’ health, quadratic age terms of the mother and father are included separately. If
the individual is missing health observations from one of the parents, the quadratic age terms for that parent is replaced with a 0.
Two indicator variables, one for mother and one for father, are included that take on the value of 1 (and 0 otherwise) if that parent
is missing. Column 1 reports the results using all children. Column 2 reports the results using sons only. Column 3 reports the
results using daughters only. Standard errors for the regressions (in parentheses) are robust to heteroskedasticity and within-family
correlation.

Table 4: Health and income rank mobility by parent-child samples
A. Health Rank Mobility
Rank-Rank Slope

Mother-Son
Mother-Daughter
Father-Son
Father-Daughter
Both Parents-All Children

Expected Rank at
75th Percentile
(3)

Observations

(1)

Expected Rank at
25th Percentile
(2)

0.243
(0.025)
0.287
(0.022)
0.212
(0.028)
0.251
(0.025)
0.261
(0.017)

44.72
(0.933)
44.137
(0.827)
47.116
(1.113)
47.426
(0.992)
44.342
(0.644)

56.847
(0.979)
58.472
(0.900)
57.706
(1.071)
60.001
(0.995)
57.402
(0.688)

3564

Expected Rank at
75th Percentile
(7)

Observations

(5)

Expected Rank at
25th Percentile
(6)

0.447
(0.024)
0.473
(0.021)
0.406
(0.029)
0.417
(0.024)
0.393
(0.018)

39.508
(0.900)
39.935
(0.771)
43.495
(1.102)
44.284
(0.943)
40.766
(0.684)

61.872
(0.951)
63.58
(0.882)
63.785
(1.098)
65.129
(0.987)
60.439
(0.690)

3564

(4)

3960
2520
2689
7937

B. Income Rank Mobility
Rank-Rank Slope

Mother-Son
Mother-Daughter
Father-Son
Father-Daughter
Both Parents-All Children

(8)

3960
2520
2689
7937

Each row of Table 4 reports the rank-rank slope, expected ranks at the 25th and 75th health (Panel A) or income (Panel B) percentile and number
of observations for each parent-child sample. The rank-rank slope is the coefficient on parent health or income percentile from the bivariate regression of child rank on parent rank. The expected rank at the 25th (or 75th) percentile is the predicted rank from the rank-rank specification for
a child with a parent at the 25th (or 75th) percentile of the parent health or income rank distribution. All regressions are weighted using the most
recently available sampling weight of the child. Standard errors for the regressions (in parentheses) are robust to heteroskedasticity and withinfamily correlation.

Table 5: Health mobility measures using alternative health index (1999-2013 sample)
A. Intergenerational Health Associations
Post-1999 Self-Reported Health Status

Mother’s Health Only
Father’s Health Only
Both Parents’ Health
Y-Mean
Observations

All
Children
(1)

Sons

Daughters

(2)

0.171
(0.017)
0.114
(0.017)
0.179
(0.017)
69.85
5162

Alternative Health Index
Sons

Daughters

(3)

All
Children
(4)

(5)

(6)

0.162
(0.025)
0.091
(0.021)
0.157
(0.025)

0.179
(0.022)
0.14
(0.025)
0.199
(0.022)

0.171
(0.015)
0.094
(0.017)
0.165
(0.016)

0.156
(0.021)
0.092
(0.020)
0.157
(0.021)

0.184
(0.022)
0.094
(0.026)
0.171
(0.024)

69.84
2415

69.86
2747

0.85
5162

0.85
2415

0.84
2747

B. Rank Mobility
Post-1999 Self-Reported Health Status
Rank-Rank
Slope

Mother-Son
Mother-Daughter
Father-Son
Father-Daughter
Both Parents-All Children

Alternative Health Index

Expected
Rank at
75th
Percentile
(9)

Rank-Rank
Slope

(7)

Expected
Rank at
25th
Percentile
(8)

(10)

Expected
Rank at
25th
Percentile
(11)

Expected
Rank at
75th
Percentile
(12)

0.188
(0.027)
0.258
(0.025)
0.142
(0.030)
0.219
(0.029)
0.212
(0.019)

45.946
(1.054)
44.29
(0.961)
49.656
(1.168)
47.591
(1.165)
45.505
(0.718)

55.351
(1.042)
57.212
(0.952)
56.732
(1.187)
58.523
(1.094)
56.092
(0.741)

0.243
(0.026)
0.244
(0.025)
0.169
(0.030)
0.145
(0.030)
0.227
(0.018)

44.373
(1.051)
44.701
(0.986)
47.995
(1.204)
47.999
(1.157)
45.065
(0.716)

56.528
(0.964)
56.915
(0.958)
56.432
(1.086)
55.267
(1.170)
56.398
(0.695)

Table 5 reports the intergenerational health associations and rank-rank slopes using only individuals with health observations at age 30 and
older from 1999-2013. The Post-1999 Self-Reported Health Status is time-averaged continuous health measure analogous to baseline health
measure using only data from survey years 1999-2013. The Alternative Health Index is the time-averaged fraction of 21 adverse health conditions that the individual does not have. Details on the Alternative Health Index is provided in Appendix B. Each cell of Panel A reports
the coefficient and standard error on the parent health measure from a weighted regression of child health on parent health. Specifications
in Columns 1 to 3 use the Post-1999 Self-Reported Health Status as the health measure for both parent and child generations. Columns 4 to
6 use the Alternative Health Index as the health measure for both parent and child generations. Y-mean refers to the weighted mean of the
dependent variable within the regression sample using both parents’ health for that column. Observations is the number of observations in
the regression sample using both parents’ health for that column. See notes to Table 3 for additional details on the intergenerational health
association specifications. Each row of Panel B reports the rank-rank slope, expected ranks at the parent 25th and 75th health percentile and
number of observations each parent-child sample. Columns 7 to 9 use the Post-1999 Self-Reported Health Status to construct percentile
ranks for both parent and child generation separately for each gender. Columns 10 to 12 use the Alternative Health Index to construct percentile ranks for each parent and child generation separately for each gender. See notes to Table 4 for additional details on rank-rank specifications. All regressions are weighted using the most recently available sampling weight of the child. Standard errors for all regressions (in
parentheses) are robust to heteroskedasticity and within-family correlation.

Table 6: Health and income rank mobility by region, race, and education
Health Mobility
Rank-Rank
Slope

Region
Northeast
North Central
South
West
Test of Equality P-Value
Race
White
Black
Test of Equality P-Value
Education
Less than HS
HS Degree
College Degree
Test of Equality P-Value

Income Mobility
Expected
Rank at
75th
Percentile
(3)

Rank-Rank
Slope

(1)

Expected
Rank at
25th
Percentile
(2)

Expected
Rank at
75th
Percentile
(6)

Observations

(4)

Expected
Rank at
25th
Percentile
(5)

0.250
(0.041)
0.230
(0.033)
0.254
(0.031)
0.276
(0.044)
0.864

45.781
(1.573)
45.805
(1.225)
42.137
(1.087)
43.864
(1.854)
0.095

58.306
(1.534)
57.297
(1.225)
54.835
(1.357)
57.646
(1.554)
0.321

0.367
(0.044)
0.381
(0.033)
0.408
(0.030)
0.344
(0.044)
0.649

46.588
(1.758)
41.675
(1.167)
37.255
(1.134)
41.323
(1.752)
0.000

64.926
(1.521)
60.743
(1.339)
57.651
(1.232)
58.51
(1.591)
0.002

1073

0.243
(0.021)
0.130
(0.034)
0.004

46.501
(0.806)
36.849
(1.039)
0.000

58.665
(0.733)
43.337
(1.780)
0.000

0.352
(0.020)
0.265
(0.058)
0.157

44.499
(0.815)
27.957
(1.358)
0.000

62.096
(0.716)
41.226
(2.502)
0.000

4555

0.204
(0.046)
0.197
(0.023)
0.202
(0.042)
0.989

36.925
(1.209)
45.596
(0.807)
51.801
(2.005)
0.000

47.114
(2.548)
55.447
(0.939)
61.891
(1.063)
0.000

0.261
(0.048)
0.26
(0.026)
0.3
(0.039)
0.678

30.269
(1.037)
43.708
(0.892)
51.623
(2.012)
0.000

43.313
(2.657)
56.721
(0.989)
66.648
(0.961)
0.000

2245

(7)

1896
3181
1020

3139

4206
1471

Each row of Table 6 reports the rank-rank slope, expected ranks at the 25th and 75th health (Columns 1-3) or income (Columns 4-6) percentile and number
of observations (Column 7) by subgroups for all children. The parent health (income) rank is constructed from the age-adjusted both parents health (income)
measure. The child health (income) rank is constructed from the pooled age-adjusted child health (income) measure for sons and daughters. Region refers
to the region the child grew up in, defined as the modal region in which the household is surveyed before the child is 18. Race refers to the reported race of
the child. Education refers to the highest level of education attained by at least one of the parents in the most recently available survey. All regressions are
weighted using the most recently available sampling weight of the child. Standard errors for the regressions (in parentheses) are robust to heteroskedasticity and within-family correlation. P-values from F-tests on the equality of the rank-rank slopes, expected ranks at the 25th and 75th percentiles within each
category (region, race, or education) are reported.

Table 7: Heath rank mobility by childhood insurance coverage
Rank-Rank
Slope

Overall
Overall - Adjusted for Family Background
Insurance
Some Coverage
No Coverage
Difference
Insurance - Adjusted for Family Background
Some Coverage
No Coverage
Difference

Expected
Rank at
75th
Percentile
(3)

Observations

(1)

Expected
Rank at
25th
Percentile
(2)

0.243
(0.024)
0.155
(0.024)

45.133
(0.853)
46.939
(0.912)

57.269
(0.985)
54.679
(0.972)

4584

0.212
(0.026)
0.347
(0.063)
-0.135
(0.068)

46.802
(0.916)
34.325
(2.100)
12.477
(2.295)

57.408
(1.019)
51.657
(3.526)
5.751
(3.659)

3797

0.128
(0.026)
0.256
(0.061)
-0.127
(0.066)

48.738
(0.965)
33.062
(2.274)
15.676
(2.469)

55.157
(1.011)
45.849
(3.154)
9.308
(3.300)

3797

(4)

4584

787
4584

787
4584

Each row of Table 7 reports the rank-rank slope, expected ranks at the 25th and 75th health percentile and number of observations for the sample of children who were between age 0 and 16 in the 1968-1972 PSID surveys. The parent health rank
is constructed from the age-adjusted both parents health measure. The child health rank is constructed from the pooled
age-adjusted child health measure for sons and daughters. Adjusting for family background means that the both parents
health measure is adjusted for family income and years of education of the mother and father, in addition to age. Insurance
coverage refers to a child living in a household in 1968-1972 in which all family members are covered. Some coverage
refers to coverage for at least one year during that time period. All regressions are weighted using the most recently available sampling weight of the child. Standard errors for the regressions (in parentheses) are robust to heteroskedasticity and
within-family correlation. Differences (and the corresponding standard errors) in rank-rank slopes, expected ranks at the
25th and 75th percentiles between the sample with some and without insurance coverage are also reported.

For Online Publication
Appendix A. Details on the CRCS variables
The 2014 Childhood Retrospective Circumstances Study (CRCS) is a supplement to the PSID
and collected information from 8,072 household heads and spouses from the 2013 survey. Over
100 questions about their childhood experiences were asked. A subset of this data was restricted
and was not included in our study. We utilize information from the main survey as well as the
CRCS to capture important childhood factors that characterize family socioeconomic
background, childhood health, childhood stability, school experience, and childhood relationship
quality. Due to the large number of survey questions about each of these topics, we used
principal components analysis (PCA) to create a single index for socioeconomic status (age 0-5,
age 6-12, age 13-16), neighborhood quality, school experience (age 6-12, age 13-16), friendship
quality (age 6-12, age 13-16), relationship with mother quality and relationship with father
quality. Because of the discrete nature of the survey responses, we used the polychoric version of
PCA as recommended by Kolenikov and Angeles (2009). For the construction of the final
indices, we utilize only factors that had factor loadings greater than 0.35. Each individual was
then assigned the predicted principal component score using the first component. We describe
below the variables we utilize in our analysis.
Family Socioeconomic Status
We use three variables from the main PSID data, mother’s years of education, father’s years of
education, and family income. Years of education is the total number of education completed
reported in the most recently available survey. Family income is the baseline time-averaged total
family income of the parents. From the CRCS supplement, we also constructed indices for
socioeconomic status for ages 0-5, ages 6-12 and ages 13-16. The survey questions included in
the final construction of the SES Age 0-5 index (with factor loadings >0.35) are how much father
worked, how many times father was unemployed, if there was financial struggle, and if the
family was on welfare for at least three months during ages 0-5. For SES Age 6-12 and SES Age
13-16 indices, the included survey questions are how much father worked, how many times
father was unemployed, how many times mother as unemployed, if there was financial struggle,
and if the family was on welfare for at least three months during the specified ages. Lastly, we
created a neighborhood quality index about the neighborhood the child lived the longest between
age 6-12. The final index included the following survey questions: if it was safe to be alone
outside at night, if it was safe during the daytime for children, if it was safe during the nighttime
for children, if neighbors were willing to help each other out, if neighborhood was close knit, if
the neighborhood was clean and attractive, and if people in the neighborhood took care of their
homes and property.
Childhood Health
From the CRCS, we constructed a childhood health index, which is constructed from the
following: childhood health status on a scale of 1-5, if the child missed at least one month of
school for health reasons, if the child had difficulty hearing, if the child had asthma, diabetes,
respiratory disease, heart trouble, severe headaches or migraines, stomach problems and high
blood pressure. The CRCS also included height and weight at age 13, from which we calculated
the associated BMI to create indicators for underweight, overweight and obese at 13.

Childhood Stability
We used the following variables from the CRCS: number of times the child moved between age
0 and 16, number of schools attended between age 17, if the parents were satisfied with their
relationship with each other, and if the parents ever divorced.
School Experience
From the CRCS, we use the number of times the child repeated school grade and created two
indices pertaining to school experience during ages 6-12 and 13-16. The final indices were
constructed using the following variables: if the child was bullied at or outside of school, if the
child was happy at school, if the child was worried about physical safety at school, and if the
child was a bully at or outside of school during the specified ages.
Childhood Relationships
We created two indices for friendship quality at ages 6-12 and 13-16. The indices were
constructed using the following variables: if the child was lonely for friends, if the child was
comfortable with friends and if the child had no best friend. To capture relationship quality with
parents, we created a relationship quality with mother index and a relationship quality with father
index. The final index for mother is constructed using communication status with mother, how
much mother could understand problems, how much the child could confide in mother, how
much tension with mother growing up, the relationship status with mother, how close the child
was with mother, how much affection mother gave and how much effort mother put into
parenting. The final index for father is constructed using communication status with father, how
much father understood problems growing up, how much the child could confide in father, the
relationship status with father and how close the child was with the father. Lastly, we included an
indicator that takes on the value of 1 if the child had a nonrelative mentor during age 17-30.

Appendix B. Construction of Alternative Health Index
Beginning in 1999, the PSID added a great number of survey questions regarding health status
and health conditions. We utilize information on 20 adverse conditions as well as weight and
height to construct an indicator for obesity. The alternative health index is the fraction of the 21
adverse conditions the individual does not have, so that higher index means better health. The 21
adverse conditions are:
1. Emotional, nervous, or psychiatric problem
2. Learning disorder
3. Mental ability or memory loss
4. Arthritis
5. Asthma
6. High blood pressure
7. Cancer
8. Diabetes
9. Heart attack
10. Heart disease
11. Lung disease
12. Stroke
13. Difficulty bathing
14. Difficulty dressing
15. Difficulty eating
16. Difficulty getting out of bed
17. Difficulty getting outdoors
18. Difficulty using toilet
19. Difficulty walking
20. Disability that limits type of work or amount of work the individual does
21. Obesity (BMI >30) calculated using height and weight

Appendix Figures
Figure A.1: Age distribution by child’s birth cohort and generation

(a) Sons

(b) Daughters

(c) Mothers

(d) Fathers

Figure A.1 shows the age distribution of each generation by gender and birth cohort of the child. Each plot shows the kernel density
estimator by child’s birth cohort using the Epanechnikov kernel and 5-year bandwidths for the baseline sample. All estimates are
weighted using the most recently available individual sampling weights.

Figure A.2: Health transition probabilities by parent-child samples

(a) Transition matrix for mothers and sons

(b) Transition matrix for fathers and sons

(c) Transition matrix for mothers and daughters

(d) Transition matrix for fathers and daughters

Figure A.2 shows the transition probabilities into different health quintiles by parent health quintile for each parent-child sample.
Health quintiles are constructed from the age-adjusted baseline health measure and are created separately by gender within each
generation using the full baseline sample. All estimates are weighted using the most recently available individual sampling weights
of the child.

Figure A.3: Income transition probabilities by parent-child samples

(a) Transition matrix for mothers and sons

(b) Transition matrix for fathers and sons

(c) Transition matrix for mothers and daughters

(d) Transition matrix for fathers and daughters

Figure A.3 shows the transition probabilities into different income quintiles by parent income quintile for each parent-child sample.
Income quintiles are constructed from the time-averaged total family income and are created separately by gender within each
generation using the full baseline sample. All estimates are weighted using the most recently available individual sampling weights
of the child.

Figure A.4: Health rank mobility by parent-child samples

(a) Rank mobility for mothers and sons

(b) Rank mobility for fathers and sons

(c) Rank mobility for mothers and daughters

(d) Rank mobility for fathers and daughters

Figure A.4 plots the mean child percentile health rank at each percentile of the parent health distribution for each parent-child
sample. The red line in each graph is the estimated regression line from the weighted bivariate regression of child rank on parent
rank for that sample. The rank-rank slope is the coefficient on parent health percentile. The expected rank at the 25th (or 75th)
percentile is the predicted rank from the rank-rank specification for a child with a parent at the 25th (or 75th) percentile of the
parent health or income rank distribution. Health percentile ranks are constructed from the age-adjusted baseline health measure
and are ranked separately by gender within each generation. All means and regressions are weighted using the most recently
available individual sampling weights of the child. Standard errors for the regression coefficients (in parentheses) are robust to
heteroskedasticity and within-family correlation.

Figure A.5: Income rank mobility by parent-child samples

(a) Rank mobility for mothers and sons

(b) Rank mobility for fathers and sons

(c) Rank mobility for mothers and daughters

(d) Rank mobility for fathers and daughters

Figure A.5 plots the mean child percentile income rank at each percentile of the parent income distribution for each parent-child
sample. The red line in each graph is the estimated regression line from the weighted bivariate regression of child rank on parent
rank for that sample. The rank-rank slope is the coefficient on parent income percentile. The expected rank at the 25th (or 75th)
percentile is the predicted rank from the rank-rank specification for a child with a parent at the 25th (or 75th) percentile of the parent
income rank distribution. Income percentile ranks are constructed from the time-averaged total family income adjusted for age,
family size and inflation and are ranked separately by gender within each generation. All means and regressions are weighted using
the most recently available individual sampling weights of the child. Standard errors for the regression coefficients (in parentheses)
are robust to heteroskedasticity and within-family correlation.

Figure A.6: Health rank mobility by childhood region

(a) Rank mobility by region for mothers and sons

(b) Rank mobility by region for fathers and sons

(c) Rank mobility by region for mothers and daughters

(d) Rank mobility by region for fathers and
daughters

Figure A.6 plots estimated regression lines from the weighted bivariate regressions of child rank on parent rank by childhood region
for each parent-child sample. Region refers to the region the child grew up in, defined as the modal region in which the household
is surveyed before the child is 18. The rank-rank slope, denoted by , is the coefficient on parent health percentile. The expected
rank at the 25th (or 75th) percentile, denoted by p25 (p75 ), is the predicted rank from the rank-rank specification for a child with a
parent at the 25th (or 75th) percentile of the parent health rank distribution. Health percentile ranks are constructed from the ageadjusted baseline health measure and are ranked separately by gender within each generation. All regressions are weighted using
the most recently available individual sampling weights of the child. Standard errors for the regression coefficients (in parentheses)
are robust to heteroskedasticity and within-family correlation.

Figure A.7: Income rank mobility by childhood region

(a) Rank mobility by region for mothers and sons

(b) Rank mobility by region for fathers and sons

(c) Rank mobility by region for mothers and daughters

(d) Rank mobility by region for fathers and daughters

Figure A.7 plots estimated regression lines from the weighted bivariate regressions of child rank on parent rank by childhood region
for each parent-child sample. Region refers to the region the child grew up in, defined as the modal region in which the household
is surveyed before the child is 18. The rank-rank slope, denoted by , is the coefficient on parent health percentile. The expected
rank at the 25th (or 75th) percentile, denoted by p25 (p75 ), is the predicted rank from the rank-rank specification for a child with
a parent at the 25th (or 75th) percentile of the parent income rank distribution. Income percentile ranks are constructed from the
time-averaged total family income measure after adjusting for age, family size and inflation and are ranked separately by gender
within each generation. All regressions are weighted using the most recently available individual sampling weights of the child.
Standard errors for the regression coefficients (in parentheses) are robust to heteroskedasticity and within-family correlation.

Figure A.8: Health rank mobility by race

(a) Rank mobility by race for mothers and sons

(b) Rank mobility by race for fathers and sons

(c) Rank mobility by race for mothers and daughters

(d) Rank mobility by race for fathers and daughters

Figure A.8 plots estimated regression lines from the weighted bivariate regressions of child rank on parent rank by race for each
parent-child sample. Race refers to the reported race of the child. The rank-rank slope, denoted by , is the coefficient on parent
health percentile. The expected rank at the 25th (or 75th) percentile, denoted by p25 (p75 ), is the predicted rank from the rankrank specification for a child with a parent at the 25th (or 75th) percentile of the parent health rank distribution. Health percentile
ranks are constructed from the age-adjusted baseline health measure and are ranked separately by gender within each generation.
All regressions are weighted using the most recently available individual sampling weights of the child. Standard errors for the
regression coefficients (in parentheses) are robust to heteroskedasticity and within-family correlation.

Figure A.9: Income rank mobility by race

(a) Rank mobility by race for mothers and sons

(b) Rank mobility by race for fathers and sons

(c) Rank mobility by race for mothers and daughters

(d) Rank mobility by race for fathers and daughters

Figure A.9 plots estimated regression lines from the weighted bivariate regressions of child rank on parent rank by race for each
parent-child sample. Race refers to the reported race of the child. The rank-rank slope, denoted by , is the coefficient on parent
income percentile. The expected rank at the 25th (or 75th) percentile, denoted by p25 (p75 ), is the predicted rank from the rank-rank
specification for a child with a parent at the 25th (or 75th) percentile of the parent income rank distribution. Income percentile
ranks are constructed from the time-averaged total family income measure after adjusting for age, family size and inflation and
are ranked separately by gender within each generation. All regressions are weighted using the most recently available individual
sampling weights of the child. Standard errors for the regression coefficients (in parentheses) are robust to heteroskedasticity and
within-family correlation.

Figure A.10: Health rank mobility by parent’s education level

(a) Rank mobility by mother’s education for mothers and
sons

(b) Rank mobility by father’s education for fathers and
sons

(c) Rank mobility by mother’s education for mothers and
daughters

(d) Rank mobility by father’s education for fathers and
daughters

Figure A.10 plots estimated regression lines from the weighted bivariate regressions of child rank on parent rank by parental
education for each parent-child sample. Education refers to the parent’s education level. In the sample with mothers, it refers
to the mother’s highest level of education in the most recently available survey. In the samples with fathers, it refers to father’s
highest level of education in the most recently available survey. The rank-rank slope, denoted by , is the coefficient on parent
health percentile. The expected rank at the 25th (or 75th) percentile, denoted by p25 (p75 ), is the predicted rank from the rankrank specification for a child with a parent at the 25th (or 75th) percentile of the parent health rank distribution. Health percentile
ranks are constructed from the age-adjusted baseline health measure and are ranked separately by gender within each generation.
All regressions are weighted using the most recently available individual sampling weights of the child. Standard errors for the
regression coefficients (in parentheses) are robust to heteroskedasticity and within-family correlation.

Figure A.11: Income rank mobility by parent’s education level

(a) Rank mobility by mother’s education for mothers and
sons

(b) Rank mobility by father’s education for fathers and
sons

(c) Rank mobility by mother’s education for mothers and
daughters

(d) Rank mobility by father’s education for fathers and
daughters

Figure A.11 plots estimated regression lines from the weighted bivariate regressions of child rank on parent rank by parental
education for each parent-child sample. Education refers to the parent’s education level. In the sample with mothers, it refers
to the mother’s highest level of education in the most recently available survey. In the samples with fathers, it refers to father’s
highest level of education in the most recently available survey. The rank-rank slope, denoted by , is the coefficient on parent
income percentile. The expected rank at the 25th (or 75th) percentile, denoted by p25 (p75 ), is the predicted rank from the rank-rank
specification for a child with a parent at the 25th (or 75th) percentile of the parent income rank distribution. Income percentile
ranks are constructed from the time-averaged total family income measure after adjusting for age, family size and inflation and
are ranked separately by gender within each generation. All regressions are weighted using the most recently available individual
sampling weights of the child. Standard errors for the regression coefficients (in parentheses) are robust to heteroskedasticity and
within-family correlation.

Figure A.12: Difference in health and income mobility between whites and blacks

(a) Mothers and sons

(b) Fathers and sons

(c) Mothers and daughters

(d) Fathers and daughters

Figure A.12 plots the difference in expected rank between whites and blacks for health and income along the parent rank distribution.
The predicted ranks are estimated from the weighted bivariate regressions of child rank on parent rank by race for each parent-child
sample. Race refers to the reported race of the child. Health percentile ranks are constructed from the age-adjusted baseline
health measure and are ranked separately by gender within each generation. Income percentile ranks are constructed from the
time-averaged total family income measure after adjusting for age, family size and inflation and are ranked separately by gender
within each generation. All regressions are weighted using the most recently available individual sampling weights of the child.
95% confidence interval bands are shown calculated using standard errors that are robust to heteroskedasticity and within-family
correlation.

Appendix Tables
Table A.1: Probability of child in at least good health conditioned on both parents’ health status

Both Parents’ Health Good, Very Good, Excellent
Constant

Observations
R-squared
Y-mean

All
(1)

Sons
(2)

Daughters
(3)

0.109
(0.0149)
0.613
(0.218)

0.118
(0.0220)
0.567
(0.301)

0.0989
(0.0191)
0.691
(0.307)

7,987
0.048
0.870

3,763
0.047
0.884

4,224
0.056
0.855

Each column of Table A.1 reports the coefficients and standard errors from a weighted regression using sampling weights of the
most recently available individual weights for the child. The dependent variable for all specifications is an indicator variable that
takes on the value of 1 (and 0 otherwise) if the child’s time-averaged continuous health measure is in good, very good or excellent
health according to the HALex scale. The main explanatory variable is an indicator that takes on the value of 1 (and 0 otherwise) if
both the mother’s and father’s time-averaged continuous health measure are in good, very good or excellent health according to the
HALex scale. The omitted category for all regressions is at least one parent’s health is in poor or fair health. All specifications include as controls the quadratic age terms of the mother, father and child. Age for both generations are defined as the time-averaged
age of the individual at the time of all available health observations. If the individual is missing health observations from one of the
parents, the quadratic age terms for that parent is replaced with a 0. Two indicator variables, one for mother and one for father, are
included that take on the value of 1 (and 0 otherwise) if that parent is missing. Y-mean refers to the weighted mean of the dependent variable within the regression sample. Standard errors for the regressions (in parentheses) are robust to heteroskedasticity and
within-family correlation.

Table A.2: Descriptive statistics of self-reported health status and alternative health index (1999-2013 sample)
A. Parents
Father
(1)

Mother
(2)

64.63
(10.29)
13.13
(2.99)
62371.26
(60672.54)

64
(10.94)
12.62
(2.66)
51490.32
(52306.30)

73.5
(20.66)
0.87
(0.12)
2.77
(2.51)
0.75

71.47
(20.28)
0.86
(0.13)
3.01
(2.69)
0.76

6.3
3,216

6.6
4,728

All
(3)

Sons
(4)

Daughters
(5)

41.25
(8.55)
14.05
(2.23)
60062.70
(58431.95)

41.45
(8.73)
13.95
(2.27)
63615.77
(58960.77)

41.05
(8.36)
14.14
(2.18)
56479.02
(57683.93)

Age
Years of Education
Total Family Income (2013 Dollars)

Post-1999 Self-Reported Health Status
Alternative Health Index
Number of Adverse Health Conditions
Correlation between Self-Reported Health and Alternative Health Index
Years of Health Measurement (Min=1, Max=8)
Number of Observations
B. Children

Age
Years of Education
Total Family Income (2013 Dollars)

Table A.2: Descriptive statistics of self-reported health status and alternative health index (1999-2013 sample) – Continued
Post-1999 Self-Reported Health Status

81.63
(14.84)
0.94
(0.08)
1.34
(1.65)
0.675

82.50
(14.93)
0.94
(0.07)
1.25
(1.54)
0.660

80.76
(14.70)
0.93
(0.08)
1.42
(1.74)
0.689

Race
White
Black
Other

84%
13%
3%

86%
11%
3%

83%
14%
3%

Years of Health Measurement (Min=1, Max=8)
Number of Observations

5.1
5,162

5.1
2,415

5.1
2,747

Alternative Health Index
Number of Adverse Health Conditions
Correlation between Self-Reported Health and Alternative Health Index

Table A.2 provides summary statistics of the 1999-2013 survey data. This sample includes only individuals who are matched to at least one
parent. Across both generation, only individuals with at least one alternative health index observation measured at age 30 and older are included. Panel A reports the summary statistics for the parent generation. Panel B reports the summary statistics for the child generation. Age
refers to the mean time-averaged age of the individual at the time of all available health observations in 1999-2013. Years of education is the
mean total years of education attained reported at most recently available survey. Total family income reported in 2013 dollars is the mean
time-averaged available total family income from 1999-2013, which includes all taxable income and cash transfers for all family members
after adjusting for family size and inflation. The Post-1999 Self-Reported Health Status is mean time-averaged continuous health measure
analogous to baseline health measure using only data from survey years 1999-2013. The Alternative Health Index is the mean time-averaged
fraction of 21 adverse health conditions that the individual does not have. Details on the Alternative Health Index is provided in Appendix B.
Number of Adverse Health Conditions refers to the mean implied number of adverse conditions based on the alternative health index. Correlation between Self-Reported Health and Alternative Health Index is the correlation between the time-averaged continuous health measure
using self-reported health status and the time-averaged fraction of 21 adverse health conditions that the individual does not have, weighted
using the most recently available individual sampling weight. Years of health measurement refers to the mean number of total years of health
observations for each individual. By construction, all individuals have same number of years of Post-1999 Self-Reported Health Status and
Alternative Health measures. The race categories refer to the percentage of the sample that identifies with that race in most recently available
survey. All reported means and standard errors are weighted using the most recently available individual sampling weight.

Table A.3: Robustness of health mobility estimates to varying parent and child age
A. Intergenerational Health Associations (All Children)
Mother’s Health

30-39

40-49

50-59
Parent’s Age
60-69
All ages

30-39
(1)

40-49
(2)

0.231***
(0.035)
n=2523
0.194***
(0.024)
n=4174
0.150***
(0.017)
n=5762
0.135***
(0.016)
n=4845
0.171***
(0.018)
n=7208

0.164**
(0.064)
n=588
0.218***
(0.039)
n=1641
0.207***
(0.030)
n=3128
0.184***
(0.025)
n=3495
0.213***
(0.026)
n=4193

Child’s Age
50-59
(3)

0.244***
(0.067)
n=507
0.267***
(0.036)
n=1447
0.253***
(0.032)
n=1875
0.264***
(0.029)
n=2191

Father’s Health
60-69
(4)

All Ages
(5)

30-39
(6)

40-49
(7)

0.391***
(0.075)
n=282
0.223***
(0.049)
n=586
0.255***
(0.051)
n=701

0.222***
(0.035)
n=2531
0.202***
(0.024)
n=4207
0.173***
(0.020)
n=5913
0.165***
(0.018)
n=5127
0.204***
(0.019)
n=7606

0.249***
(0.058)
n=1586
0.189***
(0.032)
n=2644
0.123***
(0.016)
n=3795
0.120***
(0.015)
n=3631
0.145***
(0.016)
n=5188

0.297***
(0.115)
n=262
0.195***
(0.049)
n=905
0.145***
(0.023)
n=1900
0.152***
(0.022)
n=2397
0.168***
(0.021)
n=2890

Child’s Age
50-59
(8)

-0.027
(0.082)
n=172
0.125***
(0.035)
n=797
0.200***
(0.033)
n=1271
0.190***
(0.030)
n=1477

60-69
(9)

All ages
(10)

0.180**
(0.078)
n=120
0.350***
(0.061)
n=367
0.388***
(0.066)
n=433

0.249***
(0.057)
n=1588
0.192***
(0.032)
n=2652
0.134***
(0.016)
n=3846
0.146***
(0.017)
n=3774
0.172***
(0.017)
n=5376

Table A.3: Robustness of health mobility estimates to varying parent and child age – Continued
B. Rank-Rank Slopes (Sons Only)

30-39

40-49

50-59
Parent’s Age
60-69
All ages

Mother’s Health

Father’s Health

Child’s Age
50-59
(13)

Child’s Age
50-59
(18)

30-39
(11)

40-49
(12)

0.222***
(0.042)
n=1132
0.212***
(0.033)
n=1888
0.195***
(0.029)
n=2703
0.207***
(0.031)
n=2327
0.209***
(0.025)
n=3360

0.226***
(0.081)
n=254
0.236***
(0.049)
n=696
0.243***
(0.038)
n=1405
0.242***
(0.035)
n=1636
0.235***
(0.029)
n=1909

0.235**
(0.097)
n=206
0.276***
(0.049)
n=650
0.257***
(0.041)
n=887
0.258***
(0.035)
n=998

60-69
(14)

All ages
(15)

30-39
(16)

40-49
(17)

0.359***
(0.104)
n=142
0.288***
(0.060)
n=298
0.268***
(0.051)
n=342

0.217***
(0.040)
n=1135
0.211***
(0.031)
n=1908
0.210***
(0.028)
n=2786
0.242***
(0.031)
n=2488
0.243***
(0.025)
n=3564

0.200***
(0.054)
n=721
0.189***
(0.039)
n=1251
0.197***
(0.032)
n=1833
0.199***
(0.033)
n=1779
0.195***
(0.028)
n=2424

0.268**
(0.114)
n=114
0.239***
(0.063)
n=425
0.201***
(0.044)
n=878
0.230***
(0.041)
n=1133
0.219***
(0.034)
n=1322

0.018
(0.122)
n=85
0.054
(0.062)
n=360
0.166***
(0.056)
n=613
0.123***
(0.044)
n=689

60-69
(19)

All ages
(20)

0.045
(0.152)
n=60
0.347***
(0.089)
n=190
0.300***
(0.070)
n=214

0.196***
(0.052)
n=721
0.189***
(0.039)
n=1256
0.192***
(0.032)
n=1861
0.214***
(0.033)
n=1858
0.212***
(0.028)
n=2520

Table A.3: Robustness of health mobility estimates to varying parent and child age – Continued
C. Rank-Rank Slopes (Daughters Only)

30-39

40-49

50-59
Parent’s Age
60-69
All ages

Mother’s Health

Father’s Health

Child’s Age
50-59
(23)

Child’s Age
50-59
(28)

30-39
(21)

40-49
(22)

0.224***
(0.038)
n=1354
0.282***
(0.028)
n=2266
0.258***
(0.026)
n=3057
0.265***
(0.028)
n=2509
0.271***
(0.023)
n=3792

0.140*
(0.080)
n=326
0.324***
(0.039)
n=937
0.271***
(0.033)
n=1722
0.264***
(0.030)
n=1850
0.269***
(0.026)
n=2246

0.342***
(0.063)
n=301
0.287***
(0.045)
n=797
0.296***
(0.039)
n=984
0.272***
(0.033)
n=1161

60-69
(24)

All ages
(25)

30-39
(26)

40-49
(27)

0.311***
(0.093)
n=140
0.234***
(0.074)
n=285
0.248***
(0.059)
n=339

0.207***
(0.037)
n=1359
0.284***
(0.027)
n=2279
0.279***
(0.026)
n=3125
0.290***
(0.027)
n=2629
0.287***
(0.022)
n=3960

0.201***
(0.047)
n=760
0.223***
(0.039)
n=1323
0.224***
(0.032)
n=1934
0.231***
(0.031)
n=1842
0.229***
(0.027)
n=2606

0.232**
(0.105)
n=124
0.262***
(0.054)
n=459
0.226***
(0.042)
n=1012
0.248***
(0.034)
n=1256
0.238***
(0.029)
n=1514

0.012
(0.102)
n=86
0.225***
(0.058)
n=435
0.248***
(0.046)
n=656
0.237***
(0.038)
n=773

60-69
(29)

All ages
(30)

0.305**
(0.140)
n=60
0.361***
(0.086)
n=176
0.347***
(0.064)
n=211

0.178***
(0.046)
n=762
0.224***
(0.036)
n=1326
0.232***
(0.031)
n=1957
0.261***
(0.030)
n=1905
0.251***
(0.025)
n=2689

Table A.3 reports the intergenerational health association (Panel A) and rank-rank slopes (Panel B) using varying combinations of health measurements at different ages for parent and
child. Each cell of Panel A reports the coefficient and standard error on parent’s health measure, and number of observations from a weighted regression using the most recently available individual sampling weights for the child. Specifications in each row (column) uses parent’s (child’s) health measure constructed by averaging over all available health observations
within the 10-year age bins. All ages refers to the baseline health measure, which averages over all available health observations at age 30 and older. Columns 1 to 5 use mother’s health
as the parent health measure. Columns 6 to 10 use father’s health as the parent health measure. All specifications in Panel A include as controls the quadratic age terms of the parent
(mother or father) and child. Age for both generations is defined as the time-averaged age of the individual at the time of utilized health observations. Panel B reports the rank-rank
slopes using sons and Panel C reports the rank-rank slopes using daughters. Each cell of Panel B and C reports the coefficient and standard error on parent’s health rank and number
of observations from a weighted bivariate regression using the most recently available individual sampling weights for the child. Specifications in each row (column) uses parent’s
(child’s) health percentile ranks constructed using the age-adjusted health measure that averages over all available health observations within the 10-year age bins. Percentile ranking
and age adjustment are done separately for each age bin and gender within each generation. All ages refers to the baseline health percentile ranks, constructed using the age-adjusted
health measure that averages over all available health observations at age 30 and older. Columns 11 to 15 and 21 to 25 use mother’s health rank as the dependent variable. Columns 16
to 20 and 26 to 30 use father’s health rank as the dependent variable. Estimates from regressions with 30 or fewer observations are not reported. Standard errors for the regressions (in
parentheses) are robust to heteroskedasticity and within-family correlation. *10%, **5%, ***1% significance.

Table A.4: Correlation in health and income mobility by parent-child samples
Mother-Son

Father-Son
(2)

MotherDaughter
(3)

FatherDaughter
(4)

(1)
All

0.255

0.253

0.249

0.234

Race
White
Black

0.254
0.251

0.253
0.188

0.258
0.181

0.242
0.159

Education
Less than HS
HS Degree
College Degree

0.28
0.217
0.263

0.149
0.214
0.269

0.207
0.263
0.156

0.147
0.214
0.287

Each cell of Table A.4 reports the correlation in health and income mobility. Health (income) mobility is defined as the difference between child’s health (income) percentile rank and parent’s health (income) percentile rank. Health percentile ranks are
constructed from the age-adjusted health measure and are ranked separately by gender within each generation. Income percentile
ranks are constructed from time-averaged total family income after adjusting for family size and inflation. Education refers to the
parent’s education level. In the sample with mothers, it refers to the mother’s highest level of education in the most recently available survey. In the samples with fathers, it refers to father’s highest level of education in the most recently available survey. All
percentile ranks are constructed for the full sample of mothers, fathers, sons and daughters, not by subpopulations within the race
or education categories. All estimates are weighted using the most recently available individual sampling weight.

Table A.5: Health rank mobility by region, race, and education for all parent-child samples
Mother-Son
Rank-Rank
Slope

Region
Northeast
North Central
South
West
Test of Equality P-Value
Race
White
Black
Test of Equality P-Value
Education
Less than HS
HS Degree
College Degree
Test of Equality P-Value

Father-Son
Expected
Rank at 75th
Percentile
(3)

Rank-Rank
Slope

(1)

Expected
Rank at 25th
Percentile
(2)

(4)

Expected
Rank at 25th
Percentile
(5)

Expected
Rank at 75th
Percentile
(6)

0.181
(0.065)
0.236
(0.043)
0.238
(0.044)
0.201
(0.066)
0.861

47.606
(2.310)
44.61
(1.706)
41.755
(1.567)
47.136
(2.926)
0.129

56.64
(2.427)
56.434
(1.621)
53.645
(1.915)
57.164
(2.196)
0.587

0.152
(0.070)
0.233
(0.045)
0.188
(0.051)
0.155
(0.076)
0.711

50.896
(2.696)
46.617
(1.845)
43.822
(1.918)
50.857
(3.531)
0.107

58.482
(2.571)
58.251
(1.721)
53.203
(2.138)
58.601
(2.353)
0.216

0.229
(0.028)
0.082
(0.066)
0.04

46.112
(1.133)
39.274
(1.696)
0.001

57.574
(1.018)
43.359
(3.602)
0

0.202
(0.031)
0.093
(0.107)
0.329

48.234
(1.271)
40.683
(2.442)
0.006

58.318
(1.095)
45.325
(5.736)
0.026

0.272
(0.064)
0.205
(0.031)
0.131
(0.078)
0.371

40.332
(1.662)
45.778
(1.178)
53.433
(3.929)
0.002

53.93
(3.398)
56.025
(1.229)
59.99
(1.864)
0.134

0.12
(0.069)
0.18
(0.040)
0.043
(0.062)
0.171

41.288
(1.696)
48.608
(1.570)
58.711
(2.987)
0

47.274
(3.614)
57.604
(1.451)
60.878
(1.652)
0.003

Table A.5: Health rank mobility by region, race, and education for all parent-child samples– Continued
Mother-Daughter
Rank-Rank
Slope

Region
Northeast
North Central
South
West
Test of Equality P-Value
Race
White
Black
Test of Equality P-Value
Education
Less than HS
HS Degree
College Degree
Test of Equality P-Value

Father-Daughter
Expected
Rank at 75th
Percentile
(9)

Rank-Rank
Slope

(7)

Expected
Rank at 25th
Percentile
(8)

(10)

Expected
Rank at 25th
Percentile
(11)

Expected
Rank at 75th
Percentile
(12)

0.291
(0.054)
0.218
(0.041)
0.349
(0.037)
0.307
(0.051)
0.126

44.154
(2.007)
46.813
(1.722)
41.446
(1.301)
43.303
(2.159)
0.098

58.688
(2.124)
57.693
(1.484)
58.884
(1.681)
58.675
(1.880)
0.951

0.226
(0.061)
0.238
(0.044)
0.239
(0.048)
0.294
(0.055)
0.822

48.322
(2.398)
49.765
(1.871)
45.94
(1.716)
44.816
(2.519)
0.319

59.622
(2.327)
61.648
(1.550)
57.908
(1.998)
59.495
(2.131)
0.511

0.244
(0.027)
0.19
(0.051)
0.349

47.141
(1.070)
35.902
(1.206)
0

59.364
(0.951)
45.42
(2.810)
0

0.226
(0.028)
0.257
(0.065)
0.67

49.476
(1.146)
37.964
(1.615)
0

60.79
(1.038)
50.795
(3.678)
0.009

0.264
(0.054)
0.204
(0.030)
0.317
(0.059)
0.197

37.377
(1.259)
47.768
(1.145)
46.905
(2.965)
0

50.555
(2.968)
57.95
(1.127)
62.735
(1.663)
0.001

0.243
(0.056)
0.175
(0.039)
0.211
(0.050)
0.589

42.276
(1.545)
49.035
(1.443)
53.868
(2.534)
0

54.405
(2.976)
57.769
(1.436)
64.404
(1.486)
0.001

Each row of Table A.5 reports the rank-rank slope, expected ranks at the 25th and 75th health percentile and number of observations for each parentchild sample. Health percentile ranks are constructed from the age-adjusted health measure and are ranked separately by gender within each generation. All percentile ranks are constructed for the full sample of mothers, fathers, sons and daughters, not by subpopulations within the region, race
or education categories. Region refers to the region the child grew up in, defined as the modal region in which the household is surveyed before the
child is 18. Race refers to the reported race of the child. Education refers to the parent’s education level. In the sample with mothers, it refers to the
mother’s highest level of education in the most recently available survey. In the samples with fathers, it refers to father’s highest level of education in
the most recently available survey. All regressions are weighted using the most recently available sampling weight of the child. Standard errors for
the regressions (in parentheses) are robust to heteroskedasticity and within-family correlation. P-values from F-tests on the equality of the rank-rank
slopes, expected ranks at the 25th and 75th percentiles within each category are reported.

Table A.6: Robustness of intergenerational health associations by birth cohort using both parents’ health

All Children
At least 30
30-40 Child, 40-70 Parent
30-40 Child, 50-70 Parent

Sons
At least 30
30-40 Child, 40-70 Parent
30-40 Child, 50-70 Parent

Daughters
At least 30
30-40 Child, 40-70 Parent
30-40 Child, 50-70 Parent

1950-1959

1960-1969

1970-1979

(1)

(2)

(3)

Test: 1950-1969
vs. 1970-1979
Slope
(4)

0.230***
(0.031)
0.177***
(0.036)
0.180***
(0.036)

0.173***
(0.031)
0.159***
(0.030)
0.146***
(0.027)

0.287***
(0.038)
0.259***
(0.036)
0.196***
(0.030)

0.079*
(0.042)
0.083**
(0.041)
0.028
(0.036)

0.234***
(0.038)
0.175***
(0.042)
0.179***
(0.042)

0.122***
(0.038)
0.095***
(0.036)
0.084**
(0.033)

0.282***
(0.052)
0.243***
(0.049)
0.197***
(0.040)

0.107*
(0.056)
0.102*
(0.054)
0.059
(0.046)

0.238***
(0.039)
0.190***
(0.045)
0.188***
(0.045)

0.232***
(0.047)
0.242***
(0.044)
0.219***
(0.041)

0.288***
(0.045)
0.273***
(0.041)
0.196***
(0.036)

0.048
(0.052)
0.061
(0.049)
-0.002
(0.046)

Table A.6 reports the intergenerational health association by child’s birth cohort (1950-1959, 1960-1969, 1970-1979) for each sample.
At least 30 refers to using all available health measurements at least 30 years old for both parent and child generations. 30-40 Child,
40-70 (50-70) Parent refers to using all available health measurements that are between age 30 and 40, inclusive, for the child’s health
measure and all available health measurements that are between age 40 (50) and 70 for the parent’s health measure. The dependent
variable for all specifications is the child’s time-averaged continuous health measure. The parent health measure is the average of the
mother’s and father’s health if available. Otherwise, only one parent’s health measure is used. All specifications include as controls the
quadratic age terms of the mother, father and child, and missing indicators for mother and father. Age for both generations is defined as
the time-averaged age of the individual at the time of health observations. In Columns 1 to 3, each cell reports coefficient and standard
error on the both parent health measure from a weighted regression using sampling weights of the most recently available individual
weights for the child. Column 4 reports the estimate and standard error of the difference in the coefficient on parent health measure
for birth cohort 1970-1979 and the coefficient on parent health measure for the pooled birth cohorts 1950-1969. Standard errors for the
regressions (in parentheses) are robust to heteroskedasticity and within-family correlation. *10%, **5%, ***1% significance.

Table A.7: Robustness of rank mobility estimates by birth cohort and parent-child subsamples
1950-1959

Mother-Son
At least 30
30-40 Child, 40-70 Parent
30-40 Child, 50-70 Parent
Mother-Daughter
At least 30
30-40 Child, 40-70 Parent
30-40 Child, 50-70 Parent
Father-Son
At least 30
30-40 Child, 40-70 Parent
30-40 Child, 50-70 Parent
Father-Daughter
At least 30
30-40 Child, 40-70 Parent
30-40 Child, 50-70 Parent
Both Parents-All Children
At least 30
30-40 Child, 40-70 Parent
30-40 Child, 50-70 Parent

1960-1969

1970-1979

Rank-Rank Slope

Exp. Rank at
25th Percentile

Rank-Rank Slope

Exp. Rank at
25th Percentile

Rank-Rank Slope

Exp. Rank at
25th Percentile

Test: 1950-1969
vs. 1970-1979
Slope

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

Test: 1950-1969
vs. 1970-1979
Exp. Rank at the
25th Percentile
(8)

0.258***
(0.045)
0.244***
(0.047)
0.251***
(0.047)

45.3***
(1.6)
45.1***
(1.7)
44.8***
(1.7)

0.171***
(0.050)
0.148***
(0.051)
0.125**
(0.053)

46.3***
(1.8)
46.8***
(1.8)
47.0***
(1.8)

0.248***
(0.044)
0.247***
(0.043)
0.230***
(0.045)

44.1***
(1.9)
43.8***
(1.8)
43.8***
(1.9)

0.035
(0.055)
0.053
(0.055)
0.042
(0.057)

-1.7
(2.195)
-2.111
(2.196)
-2.075
(2.254)

0.260***
(0.042)
0.230***
(0.045)
0.241***
(0.046)

44.9***
(1.7)
45.5***
(1.8)
45.6***
(1.8)

0.291***
(0.044)
0.317***
(0.042)
0.305***
(0.044)

44.1***
(1.6)
43.2***
(1.6)
43.4***
(1.6)

0.276***
(0.042)
0.282***
(0.042)
0.284***
(0.045)

43.4***
(1.5)
43.0***
(1.5)
43.3***
(1.6)

0
(0.052)
0.004
(0.052)
0.008
(0.055)

-1.032
(1.937)
-1.273
(1.903)
-1.122
(1.974)

0.149***
(0.055)
0.187***
(0.056)
0.190***
(0.056)

49.4***
(2.1)
48.0***
(2.1)
47.9***
(2.1)

0.166***
(0.054)
0.166***
(0.054)
0.184***
(0.054)

48.4***
(2.1)
48.2***
(2.0)
48.2***
(2.1)

0.287***
(0.046)
0.253***
(0.048)
0.294***
(0.047)

44.1***
(2.0)
44.6***
(1.9)
44.2***
(2.0)

0.128**
(0.059)
0.078
(0.061)
0.108*
(0.061)

-4.755*
(2.450)
-3.477
(2.420)
-3.858
(2.485)

0.258***
(0.046)
0.278***
(0.047)
0.279***
(0.047)

48.5***
(1.9)
48.8***
(1.9)
48.8***
(1.9)

0.196***
(0.050)
0.220***
(0.053)
0.236***
(0.055)

47.6***
(2.0)
47.5***
(2.0)
47.3***
(2.1)

0.236***
(0.048)
0.202***
(0.051)
0.208***
(0.055)

46.2***
(1.9)
47.1***
(1.9)
47.7***
(2.0)

0.011
(0.059)
-0.041
(0.061)
-0.046
(0.066)

-1.731
(2.309)
-0.971
(2.320)
-0.268
(2.401)

0.257***
(0.033)
0.230***
(0.035)
0.240***
(0.034)

44.7***
(1.3)
45.3***
(1.3)
45.2***
(1.3)

0.203***
(0.034)
0.206***
(0.033)
0.214***
(0.034)

45.8***
(1.2)
45.8***
(1.2)
45.5***
(1.2)

0.278***
(0.030)
0.269***
(0.030)
0.250***
(0.031)

43.6***
(1.2)
43.7***
(1.2)
44.0***
(1.2)

0.049
(0.038)
0.052
(0.039)
0.023
(0.040)

-1.633
(1.491)
-1.924
(1.476)
-1.383
(1.517)

Table A.7 reports the rank-rank slope and expected rank at the 25th health percentile by child’s birth cohort (1950-1959, 1960-1969, 1970-1979) for each sample. At least 30 refers to using all available health measurements at least 30 years old for both parent and child generations. 30-40 Child, 40-70 (50-70) Parent refers to using all available health measurements that are between age 30 and 40, inclusive, for the child’s health measure and all available health measurements that are between age 40 (50) and
70 for the parent’s health measure. Column 4 reports the estimate and standard error of the difference in the rank-rank slope for birth cohort 1970-1979 and the coefficient on parent health measure for the pooled birth cohorts 1950-1969. Column 5 reports
the estimate and standard error of the difference in the expected rank at the 25th health percentile for birth cohort 1970-1979 and that for the pooled cohort 1950-1969. Standard errors for the regressions (in parentheses) are robust to heteroskedasticity and
within-family correlation. *10%, **5%, ***1% significance.

Table A.8: Upward and downward health mobility by region, race, and education
Mother-Son
Escape
Bottom
Quintile
(1)

Father-Son

Bottom
to
Top
Quintile
(2)

Escape Top
Quintile
(3)

Top
to
Bottom
Quintile
(4)

Escape
Bottom
Quintile
(5)

Bottom
to
Top
Quintile
(6)

Escape Top
Quintile
(7)

Top
to
Bottom
Quintile
(8)

Overall

65.8%

11.4%

70.3%

10.4%

68.0%

12.1%

70.3%

8.8%

Region
Northeast
North Central
South
West

76.1%
62.9%
62.6%
68.8%

10.5%
13.7%
9.5%
19.9%

67.1%
74.7%
75.1%
76.6%

12.0%
9.5%
11.1%
13.5%

73.3%
71.5%
63.6%
73.1%

16.6%
14.5%
7.6%
20.9%

68.8%
68.3%
78.5%
69.6%

6.1%
7.3%
11.2%
11.2%

Race
White
Black

67.7%
62.0%

11.7%
11.5%

69.2%
88.3%

9.5%
23.5%

69.6%
60.2%

13.0%
8.3%

70.5%
57.9%

8.0%
10.1%

Education
Less than HS
HS Degree
College Degree

62.5%
67.8%
73.1%

7.1%
12.4%
34.4%

61.2%
75.4%
63.0%

16.5%
10.6%
8.9%

64.6%
71.3%
84.9%

10.2%
12.3%
28.9%

77.9%
75.0%
66.0%

19.3%
8.7%
8.0%

Table A.8: Upward and downward health mobility by region, race, and education – Continued
Mother-Daughter
Escape
Bottom
Quintile
(9)

Father-Daughter

Bottom
to
Top
Quintile
(10)

Escape Top
Quintile
(11)

Top
to
Bottom
Quintile
(12)

Escape
Bottom
Quintile
(13)

Bottom
to
Top
Quintile
(14)

Escape Top
Quintile
(15)

Top
to
Bottom
Quintile
(16)

Overall

64.4%

10.7%

69.0%

8.7%

72.1%

14.8%

67.4%

8.0%

Region
Northeast
North Central
South
West

60.9%
71.5%
59.1%
63.8%

10.5%
12.7%
7.0%
10.9%

63.6%
73.0%
69.5%
75.0%

7.5%
9.9%
3.0%
12.4%

75.0%
73.4%
69.8%
72.2%

17.5%
17.9%
12.6%
5.7%

66.3%
68.2%
74.8%
67.1%

11.4%
4.0%
8.8%
8.9%

Race
White
Black

70.2%
54.0%

13.5%
6.3%

68.3%
82.9%

8.3%
22.3%

75.5%
61.3%

17.9%
5.6%

66.9%
90.2%

7.3%
15.1%

Education
Less than HS
HS Degree
College Degree

53.5%
73.5%
72.9%

5.7%
14.2%
18.3%

74.0%
69.9%
66.3%

16.1%
9.4%
5.9%

62.3%
80.2%
92.1%

9.6%
17.8%
29.2%

88.2%
74.3%
56.0%

21.0%
9.6%
3.7%

Each row of Table A.8 reports the percentage of the specified subsample that escapes the bottom health quintile, moves from bottom to top health quintile, escapes the top
health quintile and moves from top to bottom health quintile. Escape Bottom (Top) Quintile refers to the percentage of the specified subsample with parent in the bottom
(top) parent health quintile who is not in the bottom (top) health quintile of the child health distribution. Bottom (top) to Top (bottom) refers to the percentage of the specified
subsample with parent in the bottom (top) parent health quintile who is in the top (bottom) quintile of the child health distribution. Health quintiles are constructed from the
age-adjusted baseline health measure and are created separately by gender within each generation. All quintile ranks are constructed for the full sample of mothers, fathers,
sons and daughters, not by subpopulations within the region, race or education categories. Region refers to the region the child grew up in, defined as the modal region in
which the household is surveyed before the child is 18. Race refers to the reported race of the child. Education refers to the parent’s education level. In the sample with mothers, it refers to the mother’s highest level of education in the most recently available survey. In the samples with fathers, it refers to father’s highest level of education in the
most recently available survey. All estimates are weighted using the most recently available sampling weights of the child.

Table A.9: Income rank mobility by region, race, and education for all parent-child samples
Mother-Son
Rank-Rank
Slope

Region
Northeast
North Central
South
West
Test of Equality P-Value
Race
White
Black
Test of Equality P-Value
Education
Less than HS
HS Degree
College Degree
Test of Equality P-Value

Father-Son
Expected
Rank at 75th
Percentile
(3)

Rank-Rank
Slope

(1)

Expected
Rank at 25th
Percentile
(2)

(4)

Expected
Rank at 25th
Percentile
(5)

Expected
Rank at 75th
Percentile
(6)

0.403
(0.066)
0.45
(0.045)
0.433
(0.037)
0.453
(0.061)
0.937

44.802
(2.745)
39.7
(1.569)
36.156
(1.441)
37.936
(2.247)
0.035

64.975
(2.095)
62.178
(1.840)
57.819
(1.745)
60.604
(2.335)
0.06

0.414
(0.072)
0.395
(0.050)
0.363
(0.052)
0.358
(0.070)
0.916

47.045
(2.814)
44.999
(1.775)
40.25
(2.035)
43.691
(2.706)
0.182

67.725
(2.394)
64.727
(2.002)
58.396
(1.965)
61.586
(2.619)
0.015

0.4
(0.028)
0.425
(0.070)
0.745

42.086
(1.123)
31.471
(1.694)
0

62.087
(0.993)
52.698
(3.856)
0.018

0.39
(0.032)
0.278
(0.127)
0.392

44.407
(1.230)
37.681
(3.009)
0.039

63.928
(1.142)
51.585
(5.836)
0.038

0.409
(0.059)
0.406
(0.033)
0.303
(0.084)
0.501

34.676
(1.379)
41.094
(1.234)
50.026
(4.452)
0

55.113
(3.266)
61.383
(1.213)
65.158
(1.799)
0.02

0.353
(0.070)
0.259
(0.047)
0.372
(0.067)
0.3

37.948
(1.629)
47.776
(1.629)
48.188
(3.436)
0

55.611
(3.968)
60.732
(1.583)
66.763
(1.620)
0.004

Table A.9: Income rank mobility by region, race, and education for all parent-child samples – Continued
Mother-Daughter
Rank-Rank
Slope

Region
Northeast
North Central
South
West
Test of Equality P-Value
Race
White
Black
Test of Equality P-Value
Education
Less than HS
HS Degree
College Degree
Test of Equality P-Value

Father-Daughter
Expected
Rank at 75th
Percentile
(9)

Rank-Rank
Slope

(7)

Expected
Rank at 25th
Percentile
(8)

(10)

Expected
Rank at 25th
Percentile
(11)

Expected
Rank at 75th
Percentile
(12)

0.5
(0.047)
0.48
(0.035)
0.495
(0.037)
0.411
(0.050)
0.527

44.564
(2.005)
39.226
(1.370)
37.059
(1.300)
41.605
(1.818)
0.011

69.556
(1.702)
63.219
(1.464)
61.829
(1.722)
62.142
(2.218)
0.004

0.339
(0.053)
0.409
(0.045)
0.473
(0.041)
0.295
(0.061)
0.056

53.188
(2.343)
44.057
(1.758)
40.62
(1.534)
45.869
(2.276)
0

70.147
(1.843)
64.501
(1.772)
64.292
(1.770)
60.625
(2.621)
0.014

0.413
(0.025)
0.422
(0.058)
0.885

43.712
(1.018)
30.363
(1.179)
0

64.385
(0.917)
51.488
(3.381)
0

0.365
(0.028)
0.332
(0.087)
0.712

47.341
(1.133)
31.416
(1.690)
0

65.613
(1.019)
48.009
(5.192)
0.001

0.38
(0.058)
0.396
(0.029)
0.382
(0.055)
0.957

33.121
(1.249)
43.266
(1.115)
48.711
(2.847)
0

52.114
(3.472)
63.042
(1.108)
67.805
(1.511)
0

0.51
(0.064)
0.248
(0.040)
0.27
(0.053)
0.002

37.916
(1.484)
47.903
(1.351)
56.653
(2.852)
0

63.395
(3.736)
60.285
(1.553)
70.168
(1.327)
0

Each row of Table A.9 reports the rank-rank slope, expected ranks at the 25th and 75th health percentile and number of observations for each parentchild sample. The corresponding regression for each row only uses observations in that category. Income percentile ranks are constructed from
time-averaged total family income after adjusting for family size and inflation and are ranked separately by gender within each generation. Ranks
are constructed from the full sample, not separately for each subpopulation. Region refers to the region the child grew up in, defined as the modal
region in which the household is surveyed before the child is 18. Race refers to the reported race of the child. Education refers to the parent’s education level. In the sample with mothers, it refers to the mother’s highest level of education in the most recently available survey. In the samples with
fathers, it refers to father’s highest level of education in the most recently available survey. See notes to Table ?? for additional details on rank-rank
specifications. All regressions are weighted using the most recently available sampling weight of the child. Standard errors for the regressions (in
parentheses) are robust to heteroskedasticity and within-family correlation. P-values from F-tests on the equality of the rank-rank slopes, expected
ranks at the 25th and 75th percentiles within each category are reported.

Table A.10: Upward and downward income mobility by region, race, and education
Mother-Son
Escape
Bottom
Quintile
(1)

Father-Son

Bottom
to
Top
Quintile
(2)

Escape Top
Quintile
(3)

Top
to
Bottom
Quintile
(4)

Escape
Bottom
Quintile
(5)

Bottom
to
Top
Quintile
(6)

Escape Top
Quintile
(7)

Top
to
Bottom
Quintile
(8)

Overall

54.7%

5.3%

55.0%

6.1%

64.9%

7.4%

56.1%

6.5%

Region
Northeast
North Central
South
West

69.4%
54.4%
52.8%
42.4%

18.2%
4.5%
2.6%
0.1%

46.5%
51.7%
69.2%
57.7%

4.1%
6.7%
6.6%
8.0%

76.4%
66.0%
60.0%
69.6%

12.6%
5.9%
7.9%
4.0%

44.7%
56.7%
67.9%
61.2%

5.8%
3.4%
8.3%
9.9%

Race
White
Black

58.5%
46.9%

6.7%
3.0%

56.1%
74.6%

6.2%
13.7%

65.2%
62.5%

7.5%
8.7%

56.9%
81.6%

6.2%
48.3%

Education
Less than HS
HS Degree
College Degree

49.6%
58.1%
86.9%

3.1%
6.2%
35.6%

63.2%
57.9%
51.1%

11.8%
4.7%
6.9%

57.6%
76.3%
87.5%

5.5%
11.1%
0.0%

54.5%
69.0%
51.5%

13.5%
3.8%
7.1%

Table A.10: Upward and downward income mobility by region, race, and education – Continued
Mother-Daughter
Escape
Bottom
Quintile
(9)

Father-Daughter

Bottom
to
Top
Quintile
(10)

Escape Top
Quintile
(11)

Top
to
Bottom
Quintile
(12)

Escape
Bottom
Quintile
(13)

Bottom
to
Top
Quintile
(14)

Escape Top
Quintile
(15)

Top
to
Bottom
Quintile
(16)

Overall

55.4%

4.8%

56.2%

4.3%

66.0%

6.7%

56.5%

5.1%

Region
Northeast
North Central
South
West

54.2%
56.2%
50.0%
67.1%

6.7%
2.1%
5.6%
6.1%

52.5%
54.3%
67.0%
49.1%

3.1%
3.3%
6.1%
3.6%

90.0%
64.6%
52.8%
77.8%

13.2%
6.5%
5.2%
8.3%

49.5%
60.4%
61.6%
57.9%

3.6%
5.9%
4.1%
8.2%

Race
White
Black

64.3%
42.3%

6.1%
3.4%

55.4%
73.6%

3.9%
22.0%

70.8%
51.4%

8.8%
1.7%

56.9%
99.6%

5.2%
4.0%

Education
Less than HS
HS Degree
College Degree

48.3%
63.4%
80.0%

3.0%
7.7%
0.0%

86.2%
59.5%
49.6%

3.9%
3.3%
5.9%

55.4%
76.9%
90.7%

3.7%
8.4%
28.0%

67.9%
67.8%
50.1%

3.5%
6.9%
4.2%

Each row of Table A.10 reports the percentage of the specified subsample that escapes the bottom income quintile, moves from bottom to top income quintile, escapes the top
income quintile and moves from top to bottom income quintile. Escape Bottom (Top) Quintile refers to the percentage of the specified subsample with parent in the bottom
(top) parent income quintile who is not in the bottom (top) income quintile of the child income distribution. Bottom (top) to Top (bottom) refers to the percentage of the specified subsample with parent in the bottom (top) parent income quintile who is in the top (bottom) quintile of the child income distribution. Income quintiles are constructed
from the age-adjusted baseline income measure and are created separately by gender within each generation. All quintile ranks are constructed for the full sample of mothers,
fathers, sons and daughters, not by subpopulations within the region, race or education categories. Region refers to the region the child grew up in, defined as the modal region
in which the household is surveyed before the child is 18. Race refers to the reported race of the child. Education refers to the parent’s education level. In the sample with
mothers, it refers to the mother’s highest level of education in the most recently available survey. In the samples with fathers, it refers to father’s highest level of education in
the most recently available survey. All estimates are weighted using the most recently available sampling weights for the child.