View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Intergenerational Economic Mobility
in the U.S., 1940 to 2000
Daniel Aaronson and Bhashkar Mazumder

REVISED February, 2007
WP 2005-12

Intergenerational Economic Mobility in the U.S., 1940 to 2000

Daniel Aaronson
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
Bhashkar Mazumder
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
February 2007

Abstract: We estimate a time series of intergenerational economic mobility using a two sample
estimation approach that matches individuals in the Census to synthetic parents in the prior
generation based on state of birth and cohort. We find that mobility increased from 1950 to 1980
but has declined sharply since 1980. While our estimator places greater weight on birth location
effects than the standard intergenerational coefficient, evidence suggests that the size of the bias is
small and unlikely to account for the sharp change since 1980. The recent decline in mobility is
only partially explained by education. Our preferred set of results suggest that the rate at which
earnings are regressing to the mean is slower now than at any time in the post World War II period
causing economic differences between families to persist longer than they had mid-century.
However, current rates of positional mobility, as measured by the intergenerational correlation,
appear historically normal.

JEL Codes: J0, D3, J62
Acknowledgements: We thank Merritt Lyon for excellent research assistance. We are especially thankful
to Tom Hertz who offered several very helpful suggestions. We also acknowledge Anders Björklund,
Kristin Butcher, John DiNardo, Greg Duncan, David Levine, Bruce Meyer, Gary Solon, Dan Sullivan,
Chris Taber, the editor, and seminar participants at several conferences and universities. The views
presented here are not necessarily those of the Chicago Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

1. Introduction
Is the United States a less economically mobile society than it was a half century or more ago? Have
economic and policy changes over this period changed the impact of parental influences in determining
one’s future earnings? These questions have a long and notable history in the social sciences, as well as
popular discussion. Recent attention may be partly driven by studies over the past fifteen years (e.g. Solon
1992; Mazumder 2005) demonstrating that income persists across generations at a far higher rate than
previously believed by economists (e.g. Becker and Tomes 1986) and, perhaps, the public.1
Most studies have measured intergenerational income mobility at a point in time and, typically, for a
limited group of cohorts. Therefore, it is unclear whether current estimates of mobility have characterized
the U.S. economy for some time. The few studies that have examined long-term trends in intergenerational
mobility (e.g. Mayer and Lopoo 2005, Hertz 2007, and Lee and Solon 2006)2 suffer from two basic data
shortcomings. Namely, the intergenerational samples that they use do not go very far back in time and are
based on small samples. Given the pronounced changes in inequality and the returns to schooling over the
century, it is important to have reliable estimates of mobility for more than just the most recent decades.
Moreover, small sample sizes make it difficult to identify precise trends in the time-series.
In addition to filling an important void in the literature, greater knowledge of trends in intergenerational
mobility can potentially lead to a deeper understanding of the underlying mechanisms by which income is
transmitted across generations. The development of a time series on intergenerational mobility provides a
source of variation for researchers to exploit to improve our understanding of intergenerational linkages.
For example, Solon (2004) extends the Becker-Tomes model and shows that intergenerational mobility is
1

Both the New York Times and Wall Street Journal printed a series on economic mobility in May and June of 2005.
The New York Times articles can be found at http://www.nytimes.com/pages/national/class/. The initial WSJ article
is at http://www.post-gazette.com/pg/05133/504149.stm (the WSJ site is subscription only). The public’s beliefs are
described in a New York Times poll asking “Is it possible to start out poor, work hard, and become rich?”
(http://www.nytimes.com/packages/html/national/20050515_CLASS_GRAPHIC/index_04.html) The share
answering affirmatively increased from 60% in 1983 to 80% in 2005. The General Social Survey also asks about
social mobility (Questions 1058 and 1059). Although the questions are somewhat ambiguous, they suggest little
change, and perhaps a slight improvement, since the mid-1980s in the belief that upward mobility is possible.
2
Related, there is a large literature, primarily in sociology, on intergenerational occupational mobility. Ferrie and
Long (2005), for example, compares intergenerational occupational mobility during the second half of the 19th and
early 20th centuries to estimates derived from modern datasets, such as the National Longitudinal Surveys.
1

driven by factors that have undergone diverging trends. All else equal, the fact that the returns to human
capital have risen in recent decades (Katz and Autor 1999; Goldin and Katz 1999) implies that
intergenerational mobility should have fallen.3 On the other hand, the emergence of the Great Society
programs in the 1960s (e.g. food stamps, WIC) and the desegregation of schools should have fostered
greater equality of opportunity. How these countervailing trends have impacted changes in
intergenerational mobility is ultimately an empirical question.
In this paper, we take advantage of the large samples available in the decennial Censuses. Because
parents and children cannot be linked across Censuses, we employ an approach analogous to a two sample
instrumental variables (TSIV) estimator to develop a consistent intergenerational mobility series back to
1940.4 Our primary approach uses state of birth to match adult sons’ earnings with the income of synthetic
families, developed from the age of their children and their state of residence, in a previous generation.
This estimator is roughly equivalent to using dummy variables for state of birth as instruments for parental
income. In Appendix A, we show how our estimates compare to traditional OLS and IV estimates by
evaluating both approaches with the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth (NLSY) and Panel Study of
Income Dynamics (PSID).
Our measure of economic mobility is based on the relationship between adult men’s log annual
earnings and log of annual family income in the previous generation. This regression coefficient,
commonly known as the intergenerational elasticity (IGE), describes how much economic differences
between families persist. Since the IGE measures quantitative movements across the income distribution, it
can be used to ask questions such as how quickly families can move from the poverty level to the mean
level of income. Our preferred estimates of the IGE suggest that economic mobility was relatively low in
1940 but increased over the subsequent four decades. However, economic mobility fell sharply during the
1980s and failed to revert, perhaps even continued to decline, in the 1990s.

3

A constant relationship between parent income and children’s schooling would lead to a stronger intergenerational
association in income if the returns to schooling rise.
4
The approach is not exactly equivalent to two sample instrumental variables because we use the log of average
parent income rather than average of log parent income. This is described in footnote 17.
2

We also produce estimates of the IGE that include birth cohort effects and find that mobility has
declined for more recent birth cohorts, especially men born in the late 1950s and the 1960s. These time
patterns may partly reconcile the results from previous studies that have used different birth cohorts
observed in different decades (e.g. Altonji and Dunn, 1991; Solon, 1992; Mazumder, 2005; and Bratsberg
et al, 2006), although we certainly acknowledge that differences across surveys and econometric
methodology play a key role as well (Mazumder 2005).
We explicitly show that trends in the IGE are similar to those in cross-sectional inequality over the 20th
century (e.g. Katz and Autor 1999; Piketty and Saez 2003). As a brief example, wage dispersion, as
measured by the difference in the 90th and 10th percentiles of men’s hourly wages, fell during the great
wage compression of the 1940s and rose sharply between the late 1970s and mid 1990s (Katz and Autor
1999). That this pattern has similarities to our estimates of intergenerational mobility is not wholly
surprising. Cross-sectional measures of inequality provide a “snapshot” of inequality at a moment in time
while measures of intergenerational persistence of inequality provide one version of a “moving picture.” It
could be that the same underlying factors that lead to changes in traditional measures of short-term
inequality, such as changes in the returns to skill, also result in changes to long-term inequality measures.
In fact, the time pattern in the returns to education bears a striking resemblance to our measure of
intergenerational persistence. Nevertheless, years of schooling only partly explains the time pattern in the
IGE. We find for example, that even after accounting for changes in the return to education that the IGE is
significantly higher after 1980.
Some researchers prefer to use the intergenerational correlation (IGC) rather than the IGE as a measure
of intergenerational mobility. In principle, the two measures could show different time patterns. The IGC
is a measure of positional mobility, the likelihood an adult son moves position in the income distribution
relative to his parent’s place a generation prior. An IGC of 1, for example, implies that a child’s position in
the income distribution perfectly replicates that of their parent’s in the prior generation. That is, there is no
intergenerational mobility in rank or position.

3

We find that the IGE’s time-series pattern differs from the IGC, particularly prior to 1980.
Consequently, how we think about the decline in intergenerational mobility exhibited by both the IGE and
IGC during the 1980s depends to a degree on which measure is emphasized. The IGC suggests that the
1980s change is a return to earlier, pre-1970s, norms. By contrast, the high rate of intergenerational income
persistence exhibited by the IGE in the 1980s and 1990s may reflect a more pronounced change from the
rest of the post-WWII period. Accordingly, at the close of the twentieth century, the rate of positional
movement of families across the income distribution appears historically normal, but, at the same time that
cross-sectional inequality has increased, earnings are regressing to the mean at a slower rate, causing
economic differences between families to persist longer than they had several decades ago.
Finally, it is important to highlight that our two sample estimator likely produces an upward biased
estimate of the IGE. This bias may be large if state-specific factors, such as differences in endowments5,
policies, cost-of-living, or local neighborhood, school or peer conditions that are related to state of birth,
are a large part of what the IGE measures.6 Therefore, our estimates may exaggerate the importance of
birth location factors relative to the traditional IGE which places less, although still positive, weight on
these factors. However, for more recent decades, we use a separate identification strategy that purges our
estimate of state-level geographic effects and find very similar trends. This exercise reveals that the effects
of state-specific factors are not large enough to fully account for the decline in mobility we identify in
recent decades and for more recent birth cohorts. This finding should not be taken to mean that there are no
effects on the IGE arising from the public provision of investment in human capital as in Solon (2004).
Rather any variation arising from state differences in public investment have not had meaningful effects on
our estimates of the trend in the IGE. Similarly, our results with the PSID and NLSY, also indicate that the
state-specific effects are relatively small compared to the overall IGE, although these results are less
5

These could include differences in physical capital or agglomeration effects, which may be autocorrelated over time.
Since children tend to stay in their birth state, persistent state differences in factors of production will bring about an
association between parent’s and their adult children’s productivity and hence income. We consider the parent’s
residential choice, which encompasses these factors, to be one aspect of the intergenerational transmission process.

4

conclusive due to the small samples used. We also explicitly show that state cost-of-living differences are
not an important explanatory factor.
Regardless of the size of the bias, our broader descriptive measure is still informative about trends in
the importance of average family income in one’s state of birth on children’s economic success. Although
strictly speaking, this alternative measure should be given a different interpretation than the IGE, our
results still provide one useful gauge of intergenerational mobility.
2. Empirical methods
The standard statistical model of intergenerational income mobility relates a child’s (usually son’s)
permanent log income or earnings, yi, to his parent’s (usually father’s) permanent log income, Xi:
(1)

yi = α +ρXi + f(child’s age) + f(parent’s age) + εi

Since each generation’s income measure is expressed in logs, ρ is the intergenerational elasticity (IGE).
Equation (1) is left intentionally sparse so that ρ captures the full association between the parent’s
economic status and their children’s later outcomes. So, for example, any effect related to birth location
that is correlated with Xi will be included in ρ. The only controls typically included are the age at which
income is measured in each generation in order to control for life-cycle effects. It is now well-established
(e.g. Solon 1992) that a consistent estimate of ρ must account for measurement error in parent permanent
income. In practice, Xi is usually proxied by multi-year averages in order to smooth out the transitory
component of earnings.7 Furthermore, Haider and Solon (2006) show that, as a result of heterogeneous
patterns in life-cycle earnings profiles, OLS and IV estimates may be inconsistent due to the age at which
the child’s earnings are measured. They find that estimates are biased downwards (upwards) when the
income of the children is measured at a young (old) age. The bias is minimized around age 40.

6

It is important to emphasize that the traditional IGE measure is not a causal estimate of the effect of parent income
on children’s earnings but rather captures all factors (including birth location factors), that are correlated with parent
income and children’s future earnings.
7
Mazumder (2005) shows that long time averages are needed to fully solve the problem. Other approaches have used
instrumental variables (e.g. Solon, 1992, Zimmerman, 1992) or method of moments (e.g. Altonji and Dunn, 1991,
Zimmerman, 1992).
5

Our goal is to estimate a time-series of ρ. We begin with a regression equation that is similar in spirit
to Lee and Solon (2006), in that it offers a time-varying estimate of the intergenerational elasticity while
also addressing various statistical issues identified in the literature. Our most complete specification is:
(2)

yibst = α + γ1t(age-40) + γ2t(age-40)2 + γ3t(age-40)3 + γ4t(age-40)4 + ut + vb + δ1(age-40)Xibs +

δ2(age-40)2 Xibs + δ3(age-40)3 Xibs + δ4(age-40)4 Xibs + θ Xibs + βb Xibs + ρt Xibs + ε ibst
where the dependent variable yibst is the log annual earnings of child i, born in birth cohort b (measured in 5
year bands), in state s, at time t. The key independent variable is Xibs, the log of family income for
individual i born in birth cohort b and state s.
Following Lee and Solon (2006), we address the problem of bias stemming from heterogeneous ageearnings profiles by interacting parent income with a quartic in sons’ age minus 40 (δ1 to δ4).8 Other
coefficients on parent income will then reflect effects for 40 year olds. We also control for year effects (ut),
cohort effects (vb), and for a quartic in child’s age (minus 40) that might affect the level of earnings. Unlike
Lee and Solon, we allow for this age profile to vary by year (γ1t to γ4t) since there are likely to be substantial
changes in the age-earnings profile over the time period we are analyzing.9
In order to measure changes in intergenerational mobility over time, we include additional terms
involving parent income. One way to measure time trends in the IGE is to simply include an interaction
between parent’s income and the outcome year. In this specification, the time trend is captured by the
coefficient ρt. Changes in the IGE by outcome year may not only reflect the effects of childhood
investments but will also capture how those payoffs change over time. So, for example, the same
investment in human capital may produce different payoffs in the labor market if the labor market returns
to skill are rising over this period, as has been well documented.

8

More recently Böhlmark and Linquist (2006) have found changes over time in the pattern of the life cycle bias in
Sweden. We found that our results are barely affected by including these interaction terms suggesting that lifecycle
bias is not much of an issue in our sample.
9
For example, Altonji and Williams (2005) find that the combined returns to tenure and experience increased
somewhat over time, especially during the 1980s.
6

Alternatively, one may want to think about how intergenerational mobility differs across birth cohorts
that were exposed to different amounts of provision of public investment. For example, cohorts eligible for
the GI Bill had greater access to higher education and may therefore exhibit greater intergenerational
mobility. In this case we would want to focus on trends across birth cohorts viewed in all available
outcome years. We measure the cohort trend βb, by interacting parent’s income with birth cohort. Finally,
in our most flexible specification, we include both cohort and year interactions simultaneously as shown in
(2). In this case we must combine the cohort and year estimates to produce meaningful estimates of the
IGE for a particular cohort observed in a particular year.10 While the most appropriate specification may
depend to some extent on which question is being asked, we view this last specification as generally the
most preferred since it accounts for both types of effects and addresses both of the leading reasons for why
mobility may have changed.11
It is worth noting that while a full specification of cohort, age and year interactions with parent income
is typically unidentified, our strategy assumes that the age interaction with parent income is smooth and can
be parameterized by a polynomial interacted with year.12 We also smooth birth cohort effects by using 5year categories. Nevertheless, we find that excluding any one of the three (age, cohort, or year) sets of
covariates does not change our inferences about the time patterns.

10

To implement (2), we exclude one cohort interaction and one year interaction with parent income for identification.

θ , the coefficient on parent income, measures the IGE for this omitted group. The βb and ρt measure differences in the

IGE relative to this group. Specifically, in order to measure the IGE in year t for a 40 year old born in year b, we must
add the relevant βb and ρt to θ. In specifications that exclude cohort (or year) interactions with family income, we
drop the θ Xibs term and include the full set of year (or cohort) interactions with family income.
11
Hertz (2007) includes a nice discussion of IGE estimates based on cohort or year effects and under what conditions
they produce identical results.
12
This strategy has been used in previous studies in order to identify cohort health effects (e.g. Almond and
Mazumder 2005). In order to implement it, however, the same cohorts must be observed in multiple survey years;
otherwise the linear term in age would be perfectly collinear with the cohort and year dummies. Specifically, we
identify interactions of family income with 5-year birth cohort categories, a quartic in age, and year dummies. We
employ a similar approach (controlling for a smooth function of age interacted with survey year) in order to include
cohort and year dummies as controls on the level of son’s earnings. See Bruguviani and Weber (2003) for a
discussion of alternative strategies to simultaneously identify cohort, age and year effects.
7

Unfortunately, as we discussed earlier, it is not possible to estimate a time varying IGE over very long
periods with existing matched parent-child data sources.13 Instead, we use an IV-based strategy that allows
us to take advantage of the large cross-sectional samples of the decennial Census and use nonlinked parentchild data, to identify the time-varying parameters in equation (2). IV is a common way to deal with the
measurement error problem induced by using short-run earnings of the father. Instruments, typically based
on the status of the father,14 are consistent if the instruments are uncorrelated with the error term in the
son’s income regression. But even if the instruments are correlated with the error term, if the direction of
the bias and its magnitude is constant over time, then IV can be used to measure trends in the IGE.
We use an approach that is analogous to the two sample IV (TSIV) estimator. The innovation behind
TSIV, derived and originally applied in Angrist and Krueger (1992) and Arellano and Meghir (1992), is
that independent datasets can be combined for IV estimation, so long as the instrument is in each. Dearden
et al (1997), Björklund and Jäntti (1997), and Dunn (2003) specifically apply the methodology to IGE
regressions as a way to overcome the lack of data matching parents and children.15 In these studies, an
initial dataset is used to establish the relationship between father’s status (e.g. occupation) and father’s
current income. These estimates are used in a second dataset to predict father’s permanent income based
on his status. Therefore, even though neither dataset includes both son’s and father’s income, ρ is still,
under reasonable assumptions (see Björklund and Jäntti 1997) consistently estimated.
The Census data that we rely on does not contain linked son and parent earnings or potential
instruments like parental education or occupation. However, we make use of the fact that the Census has

13

Individual Census records are released after 72 years. Therefore, by the end of the 21st century, it will be possible to
link children with parents at the end of the 20th century. See Ferrie and Long (2005) and Sacerdote (2005) for
examples of this approach in the 19th and early 20th century. Nonetheless, for studying income mobility, the samples
that will become available in the future will still suffer from the well known problem of attenuation bias due to the
availability of only a single year of parent income (Bowles 1972; Solon 1992).
14
Solon (1992) uses father’s education and Zimmerman (1992) uses father’s socioeconomic status as instruments.
Solon shows that if the instrument has a positive independent effect on son’s earnings (as is presumably the case with
father’s education), IV provides an upper bound estimate of the IGE. Other instruments include father’s occupation
(Björklund and Jäntti 1997), ethnicity (Borjas 1994; Card et al 2000), industry (Shea 2000), union status (Shea 2000),
city of residence (Björklund and Jäntti 1997), and job loss (Shea 2000; Oreopolous et al 2005).
15
A number of other intergenerational mobility studies have used average parent income by group (e.g. occupation) as
a proxy for actual parent income without explicitly giving this strategy a “TSIV” interpretation.
8

always reported state of birth. Therefore, in principle we can use this information from an earlier Census to
run a first stage regression that predicts log parental income:
(3)

Xibs=φbs+υibs

where φbs is a vector containing a complete set of state dummies. The predicted value from this regression,
Xbs, is the average log income of parents with children in birth cohort b, born in state s. In the main
analysis, we calculate average family income by state of birth for the relevant cohort and Census year and
take the log of this as our predicted value of parent income, rather than running TSIV using equations (2)
and (3).16 That is, we use child’s state of birth to associate adult children’s outcomes with the average
parent income from the previous generation. Group averaged income has the additional advantage of
reducing attenuation bias relative to single-year parent income measures.17 To represent the previous
generation in our sample, we restrict the data used to compute Xbs to families with children of a similar
birth year cohort to the adult child.
It is reasonable to conjecture that state of birth is associated with other location-specific factors, such as
school quality or peer effects, which may have causal influences on the unobserved productivity of the
child. The recent literature on neighborhood effects shows weak evidence on children’s outcomes for boys
(the group focused on here), although other work on school and teacher quality suggests otherwise.18 In
addition, since many adults live in their state of birth, if there are differences in state endowments (e.g.
physical capital) that are persistent over time the effects of these differences will also be captured by our
instrument.

16

We prefer this approach because it avoids having to drop families with zero income as a result of the log
specification and also corresponds more closely to the aggregate data on state personal income per-capita, which we
will use to generate a longer (than the Census) time series of the IGE. However, our results do not change appreciably
if we run the first stage regression using bottom coded values for the cases of zero parent income. Furthermore, in the
appendix, we have run the two-stage version and the state average income version on the NLSY and PSID and find it
does not impact our inferences.
17
If measurement error is classical then group averaging of family income in a given year would fully eliminate the
bias. However, given that parents likely face common state shocks in a given year due to business cycles we assume
that our approach only reduces the bias but does not fully eliminate it.
18
See Kling et al (2005) on neighborhood effects. The evidence on neighborhood effects appears stronger for girls.
Recent papers on school and teacher effects include Aaronson et al (2007) and Rivkin et al (2005).
9

It is important to point out that all of these location-specific factors are actually part of what is captured
by the traditional IGE. Recall, the IGE is a descriptive statistic, not a true causal estimate of the effect of
parent income on children’s earnings. However, when state average income is used as a right hand side
regressor instead of actual family income, greater weight is placed on these birth location effects, producing
biased estimates of the IGE. This can be seen in the following example19 where we have omitted age
measures and removed the birth cohort and time subscripts for simplicity. Assume the true model of
children’s earnings is a function not only of family income, Xis, but also a function of average income in
one’s state of birth, Xs:
(4)

yis = α +βXis + γXs+ εi

In this example, a regression of children’s earnings on family income produces the following probability
limit of the traditional IGE:
(5)

β+ γ

Cov( X is , X s )
Var ( X s )
= β+ γ
Var ( X is )
Var ( X is )

In contrast, the regression of children’s earnings on the average family income of parents in one’s state of
birth produces a coefficient with probability limit β +γ which is greater than β + γ

Var ( X s )
when γ>0,
Var ( X is )

since Var(Xis)>Var(Xs). Basically, the averaging of family income puts more weight on the location effects
than does the traditional IGE.
In order to get a rough sense of the amount of bias and to demonstrate our approach on familiar data,
we compare estimates using state averages to OLS and alternative IV estimates with the National
Longitudinal Survey of Youth (NLSY) and Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID). These results are
described in the appendix. We find no clear evidence that there is a large amount of upward bias. We also
show that state of birth compares favorably to other instruments, such as father’s education, that may also
19

This example which borrows heavily from Card et al (2000) is a simple way to capture the idea that state of birth
might matter in a model of children’s earnings. A similar though more complicated formula with the same message
would arise if we specified a vector of state dummies in the model rather than average state income. An alternative
approach to describing the bias in the context of the IV framework is provided in the appendix of Solon (1992). We
thank Tom Hertz for suggesting that we formalize the relationship between the two estimators.
10

have independent effects on children’s earnings, but are used frequently in the literature on
intergenerational mobility. Moreover, in a separate exercise, we link generations by state of birth and
ancestry and include state of birth fixed effects in order to purge our Census-based estimates of statespecific location effects. We find that the implied location effects are small and cannot account for the time
trends. These results strongly suggest that we are primarily capturing trends in income mobility.
Nevertheless, in order to be accurate, when we refer to the IGE, it should be thought of as an
intergenerational measure that is comparable to the IGE but places greater weight on location-specific
effects.
3. Data
To estimate βb and ρt, we use the large cross-sectional samples from the Integrated Public Use
Microdata Series (IPUMS) of the decennial Censuses from 1940 to 2000, the only censuses that contain
information about income. We use the 1 percent samples from 1940 to 1970 and 5 percent samples from
1980 to 2000. Since the Census asks about annual earnings in the prior year, our IGE estimates actually
refer to the years ending in 9’s, e.g. 1999, however, we refer to the Census year in this paper.
We restrict our sample to men born in the United States who had positive annual earnings in a Census
year. To simulate a group of relevant synthetic families, we further restrict our sample to certain birth
cohorts. These are displayed in figure 1. Each cell represents a five year birth cohort’s age range during a
Census year. Reading across rows illustrates how cohorts age across time. In our analysis, we use cohorts
for whom we can measure annual family income20 when they are children (age 0 to 19) and annual earnings
when they are adults (age 25 to 54). This has the effect of restricting our sample to men born between 1921

20

Following several recent studies (e.g. Chadwick and Solon 2002; Mazumder 2005; Mayer and Lopoo 2005), we
chose to use family income to provide a broader measure of the impact of family resources on children’s future
earnings. This allows us to abstract from questions of family structure such as changing divorce rates. In addition, for
some of the earlier Censuses there are many fewer missing observations on family income than father’s income.
Regardless, we have found that the results are not very sensitive to using father’s earnings instead of family income.
We also make sure to remove the son’s own income from the family income measure. This makes our use of family
income for sons over age 15 less of a concern. For the sons, it is more meaningful to focus on earnings since
conceptually, earnings capacity (e.g. skills, effort) cannot be transferred from parents to kids, say, the way a house or a
financial asset can.
11

and 1975. The shaded area in Figure 1 represents the cohort and Census year combinations where we
measure son’s annual log earnings, yibst. Our pooled sample includes over 6 million observations.21
For most cohorts, we measure family income by state of birth at two points in time and use the two
period average as our measure of Xbs.22 Figure 1 bolds cells where family income is available and
illustrates how the lack of income data prior to 1940 constrains our analysis to the 1950 to 2000 Censuses.
This is potentially an important limitation given the sharp drop in inequality that occurred during the 1940s
(Goldin and Margo 1992). Therefore, in order to also identify ρ1940 and to utilize earlier birth cohorts, we
employ an alternative measure of family income by state, personal income per-capita, that is available back
to 1900.23 As before, we continue to use the IPUMS to measure son’s earnings, but figure 2 illustrates the
cohorts and years that are now available to us with this second source of data. Note that per-capita income
includes all forms of income collected by all individuals residing in the state in that year, not just the selfreported income of families for our particular birth cohorts. Nonetheless, the ability to add 1940 and utilize
more cohorts is valuable. In order to gauge the effects of adding data from the earlier time periods and
from older cohorts we also construct a per-capita income measure for families that matches the IPUMS
series by only using cohorts born after 1921 and using income data back to 1940.
As a further sensitivity check, we make use of ancestry to generate an additional source of family
income variation. Since 1980, the Census has asked “What is this person's ancestry?” We match sons,
whose earnings are observed in the 1980 to 2000 Censuses, to parents whose place of birth or whose
parent’s place of birth (grandparent), indicate the same ancestry. The ancestry and place of birth codes are

21

Summary tables of the sample are available upon request.
For example, for men born in Kentucky between 1946 and 1950, we average the mean income of families with boys
between the ages of 0 and 5 in Kentucky in the 1950 Census with the mean income of families with boys between the
ages of 10 and 14 in Kentucky in the 1960 Census. We also ensure that the boys in these families were born in
Kentucky. This restriction avoids problems associated with interstate migration, as discussed in Card and Krueger
(1992). Family income for the 1921-25 and 1926-30 cohorts are only measured in the 1940 Census. In a robustness
check we also use just a single year of family income measured when the children are between the ages of 0 and 9
alleviating concerns related to using older sons whoa re living at home.
23
No data is available for 1910. The data for 1900 and 1920 is based on Easterlin (1957, Table Y-1, p.753) and was
provided to us by Kris Mitchener of Santa Clara University. Data for 1930 through 1980 comes from Census Bureau
tables (http://www.census.gov/statab/hist/HS-35.pdf) based on national income accounts. We use data for 1929
instead of 1930. Note all other data correspond to years ending in a 0 (i.e. 1980) rather than a 9 (1979), as is the case
for the IPUMS data.
22

12

grouped by geographic similarity to create a set of 47 distinct classifications.24 The interaction of state of
birth and ancestry will be used as an alternative instrument for family income and allow us to include state
fixed effects thereby purging our estimates of any birth location effects.
4. Results
Table 1 reports IPUMS-based results of the IGE. The first column presents a time invariant version (βb
and ρt are set to 0) for the 1950 to 2000 period. That estimate is 0.43 (with a standard error of 0.03).
Column 2 shows how the results vary over time if we do not include cohort interactions (βb=0). The IGE
appears to increase gradually from 0.30 in 1950 to 0.38 in 1980 before sharply rising to 0.52 between 1980
and 1990. The change during the 1980s is highly significant. The IGE further increases to 0.55 by 2000,
but this additional ascent is not statistically significant. In column 3, the IGE is allowed to vary by birth
cohort but not year (ρt=0). The estimates trend upwards for cohorts born between 1921 and 1955 before
spiking up sharply for cohorts born in the late 1950s and early 1960s. For men born between 1961 and
1965 the estimated IGE is 0.7. There is a drop in the IGE for the late 1960s and early 1970s cohorts, but
these cohorts are observed only at very young ages, so these estimates may be biased downward despite our
attempts to model the age bias. Regardless, even these estimates are higher than those for the 1920s to
1940s cohorts.
Finally, in column 4, the IGE is allowed to vary by year and birth cohort. In this specification, the IGE
is the sum of the coefficient on the omitted category (the 1921 to 1925 birth cohort), measured by θ, and
the relevant cohort (βb) and year (ρt) interactions with family income. To compute an overall time trend,
column 5 examines how the IGE changes for 40 year olds by combining all of the relevant coefficients

24

The classifications and the mapping to the Census codes are available upon request. The Census stopped asking
parent’s place of birth after 1970, so we are limited to measuring family income from 1940 to 1970 and to cohorts
born between 1925 and 1970. Although respondents are allowed to answer more than one ancestry, we use only the
first response. Ancestry is not a precisely defined term, so it is not clear how many generations back one should go.
Given data availability, we can only use information about the country of birth of parents or grandparents in the
previous generation. For a variety of reasons, Lieberson and Waters (1988) and Fairlie and Meyer (1996) contend that
the Census ancestry questions are problematic, particularly in 1980. Consequently, Fairlie and Meyer limit their
analysis to those groups that give the most reliable replies -- non-Europeans, Blacks, and Hispanics who provide a
single ancestry response. We find similar results if we restrict our analysis to a similar subsample.
13

from column 4.25 Now we find that there is a decline in the IGE between 1950 and 1980, most of which
occurs between 1950 and 1960, followed by a large rise in the 1980s that continues through the 1990s. For
completeness, column 6 reruns column 2 using only 35 to 44 year-olds in each year. In this specification,
cohort effects are equivalent to time effects by construction. Interestingly, the results are virtually identical
to what we found in column 5, our most flexible specification.
These year and cohort trends may help reconcile previous estimates in the literature that have used
longitudinal data with nationally representative samples to measure the father-son elasticity in earnings.
For example, Altonji and Dunn (1991) use a cohort of National Longitudinal Survey (NLS) men born
between 1942 and 1952 whose earnings were observed primarily in the 1970s. They find an IGE of around
0.25.26 Solon (1992) used a cohort of PSID men born between 1951 and 1959 whose earnings are observed
in 1984 and estimated the IGE to be around 0.4. Bratsberg et al (2006) use the NLSY covering cohorts
born between 1957 and 1964 whose earnings are observed in 1995 and 2001 and estimate the IGE to be
0.54. Mazumder (2005) used the Survey of Income and Program Participation (SIPP), matched to social
security earnings records, for cohorts born between 1963 and 1968 whose earnings are observed between
1995 and 1998. He estimates the IGE to be 0.6 or higher. To be sure there are other important differences
between these studies, most notably the length of the time average used to measure the permanent
economic status of the parents and the age at which the parents’ and children’s earnings are measured, that
have likely driven the differences across studies. However, the results here suggest that the particular
cohorts and the years used are also important factors.27
It is worth noting that the trends described here are not apparent in studies that have attempted to detect
either cohort or year trends using the PSID (e.g. Mayer and Lopoo 2005; Hertz 2007; Lee and Solon 2006).
However, there are notable limitations with using the PSID to study long-term trends in mobility. The
25

For example the IGE for men in 2000 who were born in 1959 is 0.347-0.143+0.375=0.579. For simplicity, we
assume that the cohort effect for individuals born in 1909 and 1919 is equal to the omitted 1921-25 cohort.
26
These are the results reported in Table 4 of Solon (1999). Most other studies using the NLS have found similar
results. An exception is Zimmerman (1992) who uses different selection criteria and reports higher estimates.

14

PSID only began in 1968. Given standard sample selection rules in the literature, it is consequently
difficult to create large enough samples to produce reliable estimates of intergenerational mobility until the
early 1980s or for cohorts born before 1950.28 This is particularly problematic given the large rise in the
return to schooling from the late 1970s into the 1980s. Furthermore, sample sizes in the PSID are
especially small for more recent cohorts and attrition bias remains a concern even if it can be addressed
under certain assumptions (Hertz 2007). In contrast, there appears to be evidence of a trend when
comparing cohorts and outcome years across the NLS and the NLSY as implied by the results in the studies
discussed above. These studies have larger intergenerational samples than the PSID and start with
nationally representative samples of families in each of two time periods (1966 and 1979) rather than rely
on only one initially representative sample in 1968.
To go back farther in time, we next turn to results that use the state-specific per-capita income data.
These are displayed in Table 2 and plotted against the IPUMS estimates in Figure 3. By adding additional
cohorts and an additional year of data, we increase our sample size of adult children by about 380,000 and
can produce an estimate for 1940. That estimate, at 0.67 (column 2), is higher than any subsequent Census
year. Although, the year-specific estimates match up very well with the IPUMS-based estimates beginning
in 1980, including a comparable increase between 1980 and 1990, they diverge prior to that. This is
apparent in Figure 3. We will examine this divergence in more detail below.
Cohort effects (column 3) are highly pronounced very early in the century before falling for cohorts
born between 1915 and 1935. Thereafter, however, the cohort effect gradually rises reaching a peak of
0.68 for those born between 1961 and 1965. The pattern in the cohort effects for those born since 1921 is
very similar to what we found with the IPUMS sample. When we allow for both cohort and year effects,
the implied estimates for the IGE (column 5) show a roughly similar time pattern to the IPUMS-based
results. The IGE is estimated at just under 0.6 in 1940, gradually falls to a low of 0.34 in 1980, then rises
27

Levine and Mazumder (2007) also report a sharp increase in sibling correlation in men’s earnings –an omnibus
measure of family and community influences-- between cohorts born in the 1940s who entered the labor market in the
1970s compared to cohorts born in the 1960s who entered in the 1980s.

15

to 0.50 in 1990 and 0.57 in 2000. As with column 2, the estimates in column 5 line up well with the
IPUMS results from Table 1 beginning in 1980 but diverge a bit in the earlier decades.
There are three possible reasons for this divergence. First, per-capita income measures the income of
all state residents, not just the income of families in our particular cohorts. Second, since income is not
asked in the Census prior to 1940, the IPUMS sample relies heavily on data from 1940 to measure family
income for sons observed in the 1950s and 1960s. Since income inequality appears to be higher in 1940
relative to previous decades (see section 6), this may have the effect of depressing IPUMS-based IGE
estimates relative to per-capita income-based estimates.29 In fact, the estimate of the time-invariant IGE is
a fair bit higher with the per-capita income sample (0.50) than with the IPUMS sample (0.43). Third, the
lack of data prior to 1940 constrains the cohorts used to estimate the IGE in the IPUMS sample. As Figure
3 shows, the cohort-specific IGEs are not very different for cohorts that are in both samples but are
considerably higher for cohorts born prior to 1921 that are only included in the per-capita income sample.
In order to reconcile the estimates, we reran the per-capita income-based regressions using the cohorts
and years available in the IPUMS. With this restricted sample, we exactly match the IPUMS estimate of
0.43 when we impose a common IGE for all cohorts and years. Similarly we used the IPUMS sample but
include the family income of all individuals in the state and find the common IGE to be 0.52, which is
close to the 0.50 estimate we obtained with the per-capita income sample. Furthermore, when we define
the samples similarly by imposing both data limitations, we can largely reconcile differences in the time
patterns as well. Appendix Figure A1 plots the reconciled set of IGE estimates for 40 year olds using the
specification which accounts for cohort and year effects. To be clear, we don’t view the estimates shown in
this figure as representing our view of the best measure of the time trends, rather they are meant to show
that the data are roughly comparable when they are both restricted in the same ways.
Discussion of Results
28

Typically studies exclude children living at home beyond age 17. Ideally we want to measure adult children’s
income when they are at least in their late 20s or early 30s.

16

In our view, the key finding is the decline in intergenerational mobility after 1980. Our preferred set of
estimates are those that use both cohort and year interactions estimated with the IPUMS data (column 5 of
Table 1). We prefer the IPUMS-based estimates since it utilizes the microdata where we can clearly
identify synthetic parents. We prefer the model that includes both cohort and year interactions since it
allows for both leading explanations for why mobility may have changed (rising returns to skills, changing
provision of public investment) to be fully reflected in the estimates. These preferred estimates imply that
the IGE is higher now than at any other time in the post World War II period.
Nonetheless we recognize that there is some uncertainty about the trends in the IGE prior to 1980 and
there may be reason to think that the IGE was somewhat higher over the 1950 to 1970 period than our
preferred estimates indicate. We also have some uncertainty about the level of intergenerational mobility
in 1940 and for cohorts born before the 1920s since these can only be estimated using the per-capita
income data. Nonetheless, we suspect that intergenerational mobility likely increased from 1940 to 1950
based on the per-capita results. This matches the trends in cross-sectional inequality that we discuss in
greater detail in section 6.
5. Robustness Checks
Ancestry is an alternative source of variation that can be used to identify the time-varying IGE.
Because ancestry is not strictly tied to geographic location, it may help minimize the confounding effects of
birth location. Given previous research on the potential importance of ethnic capital on wages (e.g. Borjas
1992), we begin with the presumption that averaging income by ancestry group will also produce upward
biased estimates of the IGE. However, unless there have been changes over time in the importance of
ethnic capital, the use of ancestry as an instrument may still be informative about trends in intergenerational
mobility. In our next set of results, we do just that, measuring average family income by state of birth and
ancestry. Unfortunately since ancestry is only asked since 1980 we can only implement this approach for
the last three Censuses.
29

The IGE in a bivariate regression of son’s earnings, yi on parent income, xi is equal to σxy / σx2. If σx2 is particularly
high then this will result in a low estimate of the IGE. We discuss the implications of changing inequality on the IGE

17

In a second specification we also include a full set of state of birth dummies in the regression so that we
can identify the effect of family income on son’s earnings using differences in ethnicity within states.30 In
this specification, birth location effects that operate at the state level are no longer captured by our IGE
estimates, although any ethnic capital effects are. To be clear, this approach also removes any effects that
are due to the mean level of state family income. Any difference between estimates from a statistical
model that includes state fixed effects and one that does not provides a rough indication of the size of the
upward bias arising from the greater weight place on location effects. In a third specification, we also
include a full set of state of birth by Census year interactions. In principle, this should absorb any changes
in the state specific effects that occur over time. However, it is quite demanding on the data given all of the
other controls (e.g. year-specific age profiles, and parent income by age interactions) and the more limited
samples that contain ancestry.
Table 3 presents the results using our most flexible specification that includes both cohort and year
interactions with family income. Recall that this model requires summing up the relevant components of
the IGE by birth cohort and outcome year. As before, we construct the implied IGE for a 40 year old in
each Census year. The first two columns of Table 3 show the baseline results. Column 1 indicates a
statistically significant increase in the year effect of 0.08 for 1990 (relative to 1980) and no further increase
from 1990 to 2000. Much larger trends are picked up by the birth cohort interactions with family income.
Individuals born in the 1930s have an IGE about 0.1 greater than those born between 1926 and 1930.
However, this effect rises dramatically for cohorts born after 1940. Overall, column 2 shows that the IGE
for a 40 year old doubles from 0.34 in 1980 to 0.69 in 1990.
Columns 3 and 4 display results with state fixed effects. We find that adding state fixed effects has
virtually no effect on the year interactions with family income and reduces the cohort interactions with
family income for every single cohort group by about 0.02 to 0.03. It also reduces the coefficient on family
income for the omitted group from 0.26 to 0.23. The overall effects on the IGE for 40 year olds (column 4)
in section 6.

18

is to reduce the size of the coefficients by about 0.05 to 0.07 but has little effect on the trend. Finally in
columns 5 and 6 we include state of birth interacted with year. With this specification, the contributions to
the IGE from the year interactions with family income are close to eliminated but it appears to accentuate
the cohort effects which are now similar to what they were in the baseline specification. Overall, however,
the effects on the trend in the IGE for 40 year olds in each Census year are relatively small. The point
estimates rise from 0.30 in 1980 to 0.56 in 1990. These results are broadly consistent with Card et al
(2000).
That the trend results are so similar across different specifications suggests that the increase in the IGE
during the 1980s is quite robust. While it is likely that differences in ancestry group within state have a
direct impact on son’s earnings, these direct effects would have to have increased sharply over this short
period to account for the observed increase. Finally, we note that comparing the specifications with and
without state fixed effects provides a rough indication of how important birth location effects could be. For
example, if we drop all the year and cohort interactions and simply estimate a common IGE without state
fixed effects, our estimate is 0.55. With state fixed effects, the estimate drops to 0.47 and with state-year
interactions the estimate is 0.48. This suggests that adding state fixed effects tends to lower the level of the
IGE by only about 0.08. This is too small to account for the swing of 0.15 to 0.20 that we estimate for the
1980s.
We also performed a number of other checks on our results. First, we ran “placebo” regressions, which
randomly assign state of birth in place of actual state of birth. In this case, as expected, the IGE was always
around 0 with no discernible time trend. Second, we experimented with adjusting our per-capita income
measures for differences in the costs of living across states, as measured in Mitchener and MacLean (1999),
and found our point estimates were virtually unchanged. Therefore, we can exclude geographic differences
in cost of living as an explanation for these time trends. Third, we reran the regressions on a sample of
only Whites. We find estimates that are uniformly lower than the full sample estimates by about 0.1 in

30

We experimented with average family income by ancestry but found the estimates quite imprecise. However, we
still find the same general time pattern.
19

every period and across all cohorts. This is in accord with Hertz (2005) who finds a similarly sized
difference between whites and the full sample using the PSID. However, as before, we find a large jump in
the IGE between 1980 and 1990 that is statistically significant.31 This suggests that our aggregate results
likely are not driven by race- specific differences in economic mobility that might exist.
Fourth, we find that the results are insensitive to how we handle potential issues stemming from life
cycle bias. We think that this is likely due to the fact that our sample, unlike the PSID for example,
includes all age groups in most Census years. Specifically, our inferences concerning trends are robust to
whether or not we include the age interactions with family income. As we showed in Table 1 the results
are robust to restricting the sample to 35-44 year olds. We also found this to be true if we restrict the
samples to 25-29 or 30-34 year olds.
Finally, we tried three alternative, but reasonable, perturbations, of family income: father’s earnings
rather than family income, using a single Census year rather than averaging family income over two
Censuses32, and including families with zero income by coding them at $1,000 (in 2000 dollars). Although
the point estimates were sometimes lower (as might be expected in the single year Census case), the time
trends were similar in all of these cases.
It is also worth pointing out that our intergenerational model has some similarity to the statistical model
estimated in the growth literature (e.g. Barro and Sala-i-Martin 1992). In Appendix B we explain how the
two models differ, explicitly showing that they produce distinct empirical trends over the last sixty years.
6. Trends in Inequality and the Intergenerational Correlation
It has often been argued that economic mobility is a relevant concept for economists because an
increase in mobility is thought to imply that lifetime income is more equal (Shorrocks 1978). A cross31

In light of the many policies aimed at minority groups over the last half century, it would be natural to estimate how
racial differences in economic mobility have changed over time. However, we must leave to future research the
problem of identifying race-specific effects. Within-group estimates only tell us, say, how economic mobility among
Blacks has changed within the Black population, not the overall population.
32
In this case we used family income at ages 0-9 which also addresses any concerns that our results are driven by
using family income for older sons. A related concern is that there might be differential measurement error in family
income across Census years because the sizes of the samples increase from 1 percent to 5 percent beginning in 1980.
To address this potential problem, we ran the specification using family income at ages 0-9 while also dropping the

20

sectional measure of inequality provides a “snapshot” at a moment in time while generational mobility
provides one version of a “moving picture.”33 It is especially noteworthy then that trends in generational
mobility share similar patterns with cross-sectional inequality trends. For example, in Figure 4 we plot our
IGE time series based on the year estimates (Table 1, column 2) against the 90-10 wage gap as estimated
by Autor and Katz (1999) and the income share of the top 10 percent as calculated by Piketty and Saez
(2003).34 This suggests that both traditional measures of short-term and long-term inequality tend to move
together.
The co-movement between these series is not wholly surprising because a change in the returns to skill
could lead to a change in both the income distribution and intergenerational mobility. The bottom panel of
Figure 4 plots the relationship between our yearly estimates of the IGE from Table 2 column 2 against a
time series of the return to college as estimated by Goldin and Katz (1999). This chart shows a clear
correspondence between these measures.
Fortunately, we can examine this proposition directly because the Census collects information on years
of schooling. In order to gauge whether our IGE trends are fully accounted for by changes in the returns to
schooling, we estimate our models anew with the adult son’s years of schooling as an additional
explanatory variable.35 Figure 5 shows the results of this exercise. We find that, in all cases, the IGE point
estimates significantly decline, typically falling by between 30 and 45 percent. The time trends, however,
remain visible and in some cases are quite large. For example, even when including years of education, the
cohort estimate of the IGE (using the per-capita income sample) for those born between 1950 and 1954 is
0.22 which is less than half of the 0.48 estimate for those born between 1961 and 1965. The 1980s change
in the year-specific IGE is somewhat less pronounced than before, though still statistically significant,
rising from 0.24 to 0.32. Therefore, while it is clear that including education makes the changes somewhat
1971-75 cohort so that we never use a 5 percent sample to calculate family income. We found that this had no effect
on our conclusions.
33
Another measure of economic mobility would be within an individual’s lifetime.
34
We use the year only estimates of the IGE here because they are more directly comparable with the time series
measures in Autor and Katz (1999) and Piketty and Saez (2003) which do not in any way adjust for cohort effects.

21

less dramatic, the time patterns remain striking. This suggests that changes in the return to education
cannot fully account for the observed trends in the IGE.
A related issue is that some researchers prefer to use the intergenerational correlation (IGC) as a
measure of intergenerational mobility because it is sometimes thought to be immune to changes in
inequality. Whether to highlight the IGE or the IGC depends on the question posed. One minus the IGE
measures the degree to which earnings “regress” to the mean and characterizes how earnings differences
between families (in percentage terms) evolve over time. Since the IGE measures quantitative movements
across the income distribution it can be used to ask questions such as how quickly families can move from
the poverty level to the mean level of income. Alternatively, one minus the IGC measures the amount of
rank, or positional, mobility. An IGC of 1, for example, implies that a child’s position in the income
distribution perfectly replicates that of their parent’s in the prior generation.
The relationship between the IGC, labeled r, and the IGE, ρ, is:
(4)

r=ρ

σ parent
σ child

where σ is the standard deviation of log income in the relevant generation. Equation (4) illustrates that if r
were somehow “held constant,” trends in r and ρ could differ during periods in which inequality is
changing sharply. For example, in periods of rising inequality, it might be possible that the rate of
movement of families across the distribution stays the same (IGC) but earnings may regress to the mean at
a slower rate (IGE). In such a scenario, the IGE could be a misleading measure of rank mobility and the
IGC a misleading measure of the rate of regression to the mean. We should caution the reader that there is
no obvious reason to assume that r will stay the same when inequality changes. Further, there is no more
reason to think that r will stay constant than to assume that ρ would stay constant. In our view it is
important to report the empirical trends in both parameters and see how these parameters have actually
changed.
35

Specifically, we start with the three specifications used to produce our column 2, 3 and 4 estimates of the IGE in
Table 2 using the IPUMs sample. We then add years of schooling interacted with either year dummies, cohort

22

In principle, we can use cross-sectional inequality trends to transform our IGE estimates into
correlations. Since our estimates of ρt are based on pooled samples of multiple birth cohorts, family
income is measured in different years, complicating the calculation of the ratio of the σ’s. Consequently,
we estimate the IGC using two approaches. First, we use the sample of 35-44 year olds (i.e. column 6 of
Table 1). Here it is simple to calculate the ratio of the σ’s in each generation for each year. The results are
displayed in the top panel of table 4 and are plotted in figure 6.36 Our second approach uses the yearspecific IGEs computed in column 2 of Table 1. This is shown in the bottom panel of table 4 and is based
on a weighted average of

σ parent
across all cohorts and years. This second approach is more complicated
σ child

but allows us to go back to 1950 and under some assumptions produce an estimate for 1940.37
Because the across-generation inequality adjustments are large prior to 1980, we find that the IGC and
IGE diverge a fair bit in the pre-1980 decades. For the sample of 35-44 year olds, the IGC was essentially
flat from 1960 to 1970, fell sharply between 1970 and 1980, and steadily increased from 1980 to 2000.
With the full sample, the IGC, unlike the IGE, was steady or increasing during the 1940s and 1950s. With
either sample, we find that the 2000 IGC was not at an especially high level by historical standards.
dummies, or both year and cohort dummies. The results are plotted in Figure 5.
The trend in our parent-child inequality ratios is roughly comparable to others that can be imputed in the literature.
For example, from Katz and Autor (1999), we computed the ratio of the full-time male 90/10 wage gap to the same
gap 30 years prior. This generational inequality ratio fell from 1.25 in 1969 to 0.74 in 1989. They do not provide a
long enough time series on the standard deviation of log wages, which is more comparable to what we do, but the
1989 generational inequality ratio is slightly higher --0.81 – using this measure. A longer series can be computed
from Piketty and Saez’s (2003) income share data. The generational ratio of top decile income shares fell from
roughly 1.4 in 1959 (and 1969) to 0.75 in 1999. While the general time pattern is the same for different measures,
there are discrepancies in samples (e.g. full population versus families with young children) and measures (standard
deviation of income, 90/10 wage gaps, or top income shares) that cause variation in magnitudes.
37
The 1940 computation is shown as a dashed line in figure 6 to emphasize that calculating it required several
assumptions. Since we cannot estimate σparent for 1940 (we need microdata from at least 20 years prior), we predict the
1920 σparent using the 1940 to 1990 relationship between σparent and the share of income earned by the top decile of
households, as reported in figure 1 of Piketty-Saez (2003). The latter series, which has a 0.96 correlation with σparent,
dates back to 1920. Specifically, we ran the regression σparent = a + b*INCSH + e , where INCSH is the share of
income earned by the top decile. The constant in this regression is 0.33 (0.09) and the slope is 1.64 (0.25). INCSH in
1920 is 0.395 and σchild, calculated from the 1940 Census, is 0.914. Thus, σparent in 1940 is estimated to be 0.33 + 1.64
* 0.395 = 0.977 and σparent/σchild=0.977/0.914 = 1.069. Based on column 2 of the per-capita income results in Table 2,
we assume the 1940 “IPUMS” IGE is 29 percent larger than the 1950 IPUMS estimate. Consequently, the 1940
IPUMS IGC is 0.31 (1950 IGE) * 1.29 (1940 adjustment) * 1.069 (1940 inequality ratio) = 0.43. This is similar in
magnitude to the 1950 estimate, suggesting that the drop in the IGE during the 1940s is mostly driven by changes in
inequality across generations.
36

23

Consequently, while intergenerational mobility unambiguously fell in the 1980s, how we interpret this
change is dependent on which mobility measure is the focus. Our preferred estimates of the IGE (Table 1,
column 5) that account for both cohort and year effects using the IPUMS suggests that the decline in
mobility after 1980 represented a significant departure from the higher levels of mobility experienced postWWII. But the IGC suggests intergenerational mobility in the 1970s was unusually high; the 1980s and
1990s was a return to a typical post-WWII level.
7. Conclusion
We take advantage of the large samples available in the decennial Censuses and employ a two sample
estimator to develop a consistent time series on intergenerational mobility. Our primary approach uses state
of birth to match adult sons’ earnings with the income of synthetic families from a previous generation. In
our preferred specification we show that the intergenerational elasticity (IGE), a measure of how economic
differences between families persist over time, fell slightly from 1950 to 1980, but rose sharply during the
1980s and may have continued to rise in the 1990s. This implies that intergenerational mobility has fallen
in recent decades. We also find a similar pattern across birth cohorts with mobility especially low for
cohorts born during the 1960s. The cohort and time trends may help to reconcile previous findings in the
literature that used samples of different cohorts observed in different years. Using per-capita aggregate
income data instead of microdata from synthetic families also suggests that there was a decline in the IGE
from 1940 to 1950 that tracks the change in cross-sectional inequality.
A limitation of our strategy is that relative to the traditionally estimated IGE, our measure over-weights
location specific factors such as school quality or factor endowments that are specific to one’s state of birth.
However, we provide several pieces of evidence that birth location effects have little impact on our
measure of trends in intergenerational mobility of economic status. In particular, we find that when we link
individuals to family income in the previous generation by both state of birth and ancestry and include state
fixed effects, the implied state-location effects appear to be small. Accounting for state effects also does
not affect our finding of a large drop in mobility after 1980. In any case, like the traditionally estimated

24

IGE, our measure is still a useful gauge of the intergenerational mobility since residential location is chosen
by parents and is part of the process of the intergenerational transmission of inequality.
Perhaps not surprisingly, the temporal pattern to intergenerational mobility closely tracks crosssectional inequality trends. This is likely due in part to the fact that trends in the intergenerational elasticity
are influenced by changes in the returns to education. In fact, we show that the two series bear a very close
resemblance and share the same inflection points. However, years of education can only explain part of the
pattern in intergenerational mobility; much of the variation remains. Of course, years of education is only a
blunt measure of skill and future research is needed to better understand the extent to which the changing
returns to cognitive and non-cognitive skills may have led to the changing pattern in mobility we observe.
Estimates of rank mobility, the likelihood an adult son moves position in the income distribution
relative to his parent’s place a generation prior, paints a somewhat different picture. Rank mobility did not
vary a great deal from 1940 to 1970 but increased sharply during the 1970s, before falling during the 1980s
and 1990s. While both measures point to a decline in mobility during the last two decades, rank mobility
may have simply returned to more typical historical patterns while the intergenerational elasticity has been
historically high in recent decades according to our preferred estimates. Accordingly, at the close of the
twentieth century, the rate of movement of families across the income distribution appears to be in line with
historically norms, but earnings are regressing to the mean at a slower rate, causing economic differences
between families to persist longer than they had several decades ago.

25

References
Aaronson, Daniel, Lisa Barrow, and William Sander, 2006, “Teachers and Student Achievement in
Chicago,” Journal of Labor Economics 25(1), January 2007, p. 95-136.
Almond, Douglas and Bhashkar Mazumder, 2005, “The Long-Term Health Effects of Fetal Exposure to the
1918 Influenza Pandemic: An Analysis of SIPP Data,” American Economic Review 95(2), p. 258-262.
Altonji, Joseph and Thomas Dunn, 1991, “Relationships among the Family Incomes and Labor Market
Outcomes of Relatives,” Research in labor economics: Volume 12, JAI Press: Greenwich, Conn., p. 269310.
Altonji, Joseph and Nicolas Williams, 2005, “Do Wages Rise with Job Seniority? A Reassessment,”
Industrial and Labor Relations Review 58(3), p. 370-397.
Angrist, Joshua and Alan Krueger, 1992, “The Effect of Age at School Entry on Educational Attainment:
An Application of Instrumental Variables with Moments from Two Samples,” Journal of the American
Statistical Association 87(418), p. 328-36.
Arellano, Manuel and Costas Meghir, 1992, “Female Labour Supply and On-the-Job Search: An Empirical
Model Estimated Using Complementary Data Sets,” Review of Economic Studies 59(3), p. 537-559.
Barro, Robert and Xavier Sala-i-Martin, 1992, “Convergence”, Journal of Political Economy 100(2), p.
223-251.
Becker, Gary and Nigel Tomes, 1986, “Human Capital and the Rise and Fall of Families,”
Journal of Labor Economics 4(3), p. S1-S39.
Björklund, Anders and Markus Jäntti, 1997, “Intergenerational Income Mobility in Sweden Compared to
the United States,” American Economic Review 87(5), p. 1009-1018.
Böhlmark, Anders and Matthew Lindquist, 2006, “Life Cycle Variation in the Association Between
Current and Lifetime Earnings: Replication and extension for Sweden”, Journal of Labor Economics 24(4),
p. 879-896.
Borjas, George , 1992, “Ethnic Capital and Intergenerational Mobility,” Quarterly Journal of Economics
107(1), p. 123-50.
Borjas, George, 1994, “Long-Run Convergence of Ethnic Skill Differentials: The Children and
Grandchildren of the Great Migration,” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 47(4), p. 553-73.
Bound, John, David Jaeger, and Regina Baker, 1995, “Problems with Instrumental Variables Estimation
When the Correlation between the Instruments and the Endogenous Explanatory Variable Is Weak,”
Journal of the American Statistical Association 90(430), p. 443-50.
Bowles, Samuel, 1972, “Schooling and Inequality from Generation to Generation,” Journal of Political
Economy 80(3), p. S219-S251.
Bratsberg, Bernt, Knut Røed, Oddbjørn Raaum, Robin Naylor, Markus Jäntti, Tor Eriksson, Eva
Österbacka, and Anders Björklund, 2006, “Nonlinearities in Intergenerational Earnings Mobility:
Consequences for Cross-Country Comparisons”, working paper.
26

Bruguviani, Agar and Guglielmo Weber, 2003, Household Savings: Concepts and Measurement (2003),
in: Börsch-Supan, A., Life-Cycle Savings and Public Policy, a Cross-National Study of Six Countries, New
York: Academic Press, p. 33-54.
Card, David, John DiNardo and Eugena Estes, 2000, “The More Things Change: Immigrants and the
Children of Immigrants in the 1940s, the 1970s, and the 1990s,” in Issues in the Economics of Immigration,
George J Borjas, Ed. pp.227-69, Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press.
Card, David and Alan Krueger, 1992, “Does School Quality Matter? Returns to Education and the
Characteristics of Public Schools in the United States,” Journal of Political Economy 100(1), p. 1-40.
Chadwick, Laura and Gary Solon, 2002, “Intergenerational Income Mobility among Daughters,” American
Economic Review 92(1), p. 335-344.
Dearden, Lorraine, Stephen Machin, and Howard Reed, 1997, “Intergenerational Mobility in Britain,”
Economic Journal 107(440), p. 47-66.
Dunn, Christopher 2003, “Intergenerational Earnings Mobility in Brazil and its Determinants,” Working
paper, University of Michigan.
Easterlin, Richard A., 1957. "State Income Estimates", in Lee et al, Population Redistribution and
Economic Growth: United States, 1870-1950, vol. 1, The American Philosophical Society, Philadelphia.
Fairlie, Robert and Bruce Meyer, 1996, Ethnic and Racial Self-Employment: Differences and Possible
Explanations,” Journal of Human Resources 31(4), p. 757-793.
Ferrie, Joseph and Jason Long, 2005, “A Tale of Two Labor Markets: Intergenerational Occupational
Mobility in Britain and the U.S. Since 1850,” working paper, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Goldin, Claudia and Lawrence Katz, 1999, “The Returns to Skill in the United States across the Twentieth
Century,” working paper, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Goldin, Claudia and Robert Margo, 1992, “The Great Compression: The Wage Structure in the United
States at Mid-century,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 107(1), p. 1-34.
Haider, Steven J. and Gary Solon, 2006, “Life Cycle Variation in the Association Between Current and
Lifetime Earnings,” American Economic Review 96(4), p. 1308-1320.
Hertz, Tom, 2005, “Rags, Riches and Race: The Intergenerational Economic Mobility of Black and White
Families in the United States,” in Unequal Chances: Family Background and Economic Success. Ed.
Samuel Bowles, Herbert Gintis and Melissa Osborne Groves. Princeton University Press.
Hertz, Tom, 2007, “Trends in the Intergenerational Elasticity of Family Income in the United States,”
Industrial Relations, 46(1), p22-50.
Katz, Lawrence and David Autor, 1999, “Changes in the Wage Structure and Earnings Inequality,” in
Ashenfelter and Card (eds) Handbook of labor economics. Volume 3A, Amsterdam; New York and Oxford:
Elsevier Science, North-Holland, p. 1463-1555.

27

Kling, Jeffrey, Jeffrey Liebman, and Lawrence Katz, 2005, “Experimental Analysis of Neighborhood
Effects,” Econometrica, forthcoming.
Lee, Chul-In, and Gary Solon, 2006, “Trends in Intergenerational Income Mobility”, working paper,
University of Michigan.
Levine, David and Bhashkar Mazumder, 2007, “The Growing Importance of Family: Evidence from
Brothers’ Earnings”, Industrial Relations 46(1), p. 7-21.
Lieberson, Stanley and Mary C. Waters, 1988, From Many Strands: Ethnic and Racial Groups in
Contemporary America, New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Mayer, Susan and Leonard Lopoo, 2005, “Has the Intergenerational Transmission of Economic Status
Changed?” Journal of Human Resources 40(1), p. 169-185.
Mazumder, Bhashkar, 2005, “Fortunate Sons: New Estimates of Intergenerational Mobility In the U.S.
Using Social Security Earnings Data,” Review of Economics and Statistics 87(2), p. 235-55.
Mulligan, Casey, 1997, Parental priorities and economic inequality, Chicago and London: University of
Chicago Press.
Oreopolous, Philip, Marianne Page, and Ann Huff Stevens, 2005, “The Intergenerational Effects of Worker
Displacement,” working paper, University of Toronto.
Piketty, Thomas and Emmanuel Saez, 2003, “Income Inequality in the United States, 1913-1998,“
Quarterly Journal of Economics 118(1), p. 1-39.
Rivkin, Steven, Eric Hanushek, and John Kain, 2005, Teachers, Schools, and Academic Achievement,”
Econometrica 73(2), p. 417-58.
Sacerdote, Bruce, 2005, “Slavery and the Intergenerational Transmission of Human Capital,” The Review
of Economics and Statistics 87(2), p. 217-234.
Shea, John, 2000, “Does Parents' Money Matter,” Journal of Public Economics 77(2), p. 155-84.
Shorrocks, Anthony, 1978, “Income Inequality and Income Mobility,” Journal of Economic Theory 19(2),
p. 376-393.
Solon, Gary, 1992, “Intergenerational Income Mobility in the United States,” American Economic Review
82(3), p. 393-408.
Solon, Gary, 1999, “Intergenerational Mobility in the Labor Market,” in Orley Ashenfelter and David Card
(eds.) Handbook of Labor Economics, Volume 3A, Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Solon, Gary, 2004, “"A Model of Intergenerational Mobility Variation over Time and Place," in Miles
Corak (ed.), Generational Income Mobility in North America and Europe, Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Zimmerman, David, 1992, “Regression toward Mediocrity in Economic Stature,” American Economic
Review 82(3), p. 409-429.

28

Appendix A: Results Using the NLSY and PSID
In order to provide a sense of how our approach compares with the existing literature, we present
results using the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth (NLSY) and the Panel Study of Income Dynamics
(PSID), datasets that can directly compare estimates of ρ derived from our TSIV procedure to traditional
OLS and IV estimates that use matched parent-child samples. The NLSY tracks a cohort of individuals
born between 1957 and 1965, starting in 1979. It contains information on family income while the
respondent is living with their parents, available at the initiation of the survey. State of birth is available
from the geocoded version of the NLSY. The PSID has tracked a nationally representative set of families
since 1968 and followed the children into adulthood. Although the PSID does not provide state of birth it
does contain state of residence during childhood. Although this information does not match the Census
question, we include the PSID because it is the workhorse of IGE studies.
Table A1 reports estimates of ρ from regressions of the form presented in equation (1). The first row
uses a sample of NLSY men who were between the ages of 14 and 18 and living with their parents at the
survey’s inception in 1979. Son’s earnings, yi, is measured as the log of average annual earnings over
1993, 1995 and 1997, when these men were 28 to 36 years of age. Our sample requires both non-missing
and positive measures of family income and son’s earnings in each year. We use a three year average of
son’s earnings to increase the precision of our estimates since the standard errors for TSIV are large in
small samples. Column 1 reports the traditional matched parent-son OLS regression. In this case, family
income, Xi, is defined as the log of average family income between 1978 and 1980, as reported by the
parents. The OLS point estimate for this sample is 0.37 (standard error of 0.05), which is roughly
comparable to previous estimates in the literature that use a short-term average of parent income.
Column 2 reports NLSY results using the TSIV approach. Here, we replace family income from the
NLSY with predicted family income, as measured from the 1970 Census using state of birth instruments.
The TSIV point estimate is 0.51, although the standard error, which is clustered on state of birth, rises to
0.17. While the TSIV point estimate is not statistically different from OLS, it is notably larger. One

29

plausible reason is that averaging parent income across many individuals, as is done with the TSIV
estimate, leads to less attenuation. Mazumder (2005) shows that OLS estimates that use three-year
averages of family income are biased downward by 30 percent or more.
Alternatively, it could be that birth location has an independent impact on son’s earnings and thereby
imparts an upward bias when used as an instrument (Solon 1992). If we start with the assumption that our
coefficient of interest is the OLS estimate of ρ when using family income, and that this coefficient is
consistent by assumption, then we can test the exogeneity of the state of birth instruments by adding them
to the column 1 regression.38 We show the results of this exercise in column 3. We fail to reject that all the
state dummies, jointly, are different from zero. On the other hand, we should point out that this may simply
be due to the small sample available. Also, when we experimented with using individual years of the
NLSY (rather than an average) we fail to reject that the state dummies are different from zero in some
cases. Therefore, we proceed with the more cautious interpretation that our TSIV estimates probably
impart some upward bias.
In the second row, we conduct a similar exercise with the PSID. This sample is constructed using the
1951 to 1959 cohort who were between the ages of 9 and 17 during the initial 1968 interview and is similar
to the cohort used in Solon (1992). Our measure of log family income is averaged over the 1967 to 1969
period and son’s earnings are averaged over 1984 to 1986. The TSIV log family income instrument is
constructed from the 1960 Census. In this case, the OLS matched father-son estimate of 0.40 is actually
slightly higher than the TSIV estimate of 0.37. However, the standard error for the latter is 0.16, and
therefore cannot reject the OLS-TSIV differential uncovered with NLSY data. We also fail to reject that
the state dummies are jointly zero when included with family income.
The difference in the estimates of the IGE when including state dummies versus those without the state
dummies also provide some indication of the importance of state effects in the children’s earnings
38

Recall that we don’t interpret ρ as the true causal effect of family income on son’s earnings but instead view it as a
descriptive parameter that incorporates all of the variety of influences (e.g. ability, school quality) that are correlated
with family income but that are omitted from the regression. Therefore, by assumption, our estimate of ρ when using

30

regression. A comparison of the estimates in column 1 with those in column 3 shows that the state effects
account for about 0.02 of the IGE in the NLSY sample and about 0.08 of the IGE in the PSID sample.
It is worth noting that the point estimates are actually quite similar between the PSID and NLSY
despite the different cohorts and time periods used, which may appear to run counter to the main findings
of the paper. However, we found that this similarity is sensitive to whether or not we include son’s
earnings in 1997 in the NLSY sample. In specifications without 1997 data, the NLSY estimates are
generally around 0.5 or higher. This is also consistent with the results in Bratsberg et al (2006) who also
use the NLSY and produce estimates of the IGE over 0.5. In addition, our main results with the Census
data have little to say about trends in the IGE between the mid 1980s and the mid 1990s, only that there
was a sharp increase between 1980 and 1990 that may or may not have continued through 2000.
Rows (3) and (4) report more standard matched son-parent IV regressions, using father’s education and
occupation as instruments. Despite the same small sample concerns, the tests reported in column 3 reject
the independence of father’s education but not father’s occupation in IGE IV regressions. Differences in
sample sizes, due primarily to missing father’s occupation, have no impact on these results. Therefore, at
least compared to father’s education, which has been widely used as an instrument in prominent studies of
intergenerational mobility, state of birth compares favorably.
Finally, there is no evidence of the common weak instrument problem that can plague IV studies. If
OLS is inconsistent, weak instruments may bias the IV estimates toward OLS (Bound et al 1995). Since
we are primarily interested in measuring trends in mobility rather than estimating the true magnitude of the
IGE, we are less concerned about the consistency of OLS. Nonetheless, the first stage results appear robust
to running a first stage regression predicting family income in the Census using state dummies. For
example, when we use the 1970 Census for the cohorts in the NLSY our F-statistic is 94, well above the
common thresholds that have been used to gauge the weakness of instruments. This also suggests that state
of birth instruments have sound properties for this study.

family income is consistent. This allows us to test whether our instruments are orthogonal to ε (the residuals in the
family income regression) by simply adding them to the regression.
31

Appendix B: Relationship to the Economic Growth Literature
The use of state of birth to create intergenerational links evokes the growth convergence literature, of
which some papers, most famously Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1992), also use U.S. state income data. The
growth convergence model is conceptually very different from the intergenerational model. The former
uses an aggregate model of production to show that convergence in per-capita income across economies is
due to diminishing returns to capital accumulation. In contrast, the theoretical model that underlies the
intergenerational elasticity regressions (e.g. Becker and Tomes 1986) concerns how parents choose to
invest in their children’s human capital. The latter focuses on how inequality evolves among families
within an economy but may also have implications for how inequality evolves across regions.39
Nevertheless, there is some similarity in the statistical implementation of the two models since we
use aggregate state level data for the parent generation. The growth regressions take the following form
(see Barro and Sala-i-Martin 1992 for a derivation):
(5)

 yi ,t + T
1
log 0
 yi ,t
T
0


− βT

 = α − 1− e

 T





 log( yi ,t 0 ) + ε i ,t 0 + T



where yi ,t0 is log of income per-capita in state i in base year t0 . yi ,t0 +T is the analogous measure T years
later. States with lower initial income are hypothesized to grow more quickly. Therefore, β, which
represents the annual rate of convergence, has a negative coefficient.
Under some simplifying assumptions, there is a direct correspondence between the coefficient β
and a simplified version of the IGE regression coefficient ρ. Most importantly, if individuals never leave
their state of birth and if the two time periods are spaced a generation apart (e.g. T=25), β extrapolated over
a generation represents how much income converges across states in percentage terms, which is analogous
to 1- ρ.40 Barro and Sala-i-Martin estimate that over the last century the rate of convergence is roughly 2
percent per year which implies that over a generation, β is 0.64 and the IGE is 0.36.

39

See Mulligan (1997, pages 180-183) for a more detailed discussion.
This assumes an IGE regression that uses aggregate data for both generations and omits the various controls
included in our equation (2) such as cohort effects. If the convergence model is specified as a linear relationship

40

32

However, interstate migration clearly occurs. About 37 percent of our sample of sons does not
reside in their birth state. Furthermore, interstate migration has increased a bit over time. In 1940,
approximately 33 percent of our sample lived away from their state of birth. By 2000, 38 percent did.
Interstate migration is a concern because of the selective nature of who migrates. For obvious reasons, it is
likely that movers are more economically mobile than stayers. Empirical evidence confirms this.41
Therefore, the growth convergence model is likely to produce different estimates of ρ than our
intergenerational regression, which accurately tracks migrants using micro data, and this selection problem
may have worsened over time.
In order to compare the estimates of our approach with the convergence model, we estimate
equation (5) using state per-capita income data thirty years apart and construct a time series for 1930 to
2000.42 Each year represents the convergence rate from 30 years prior (i.e. 2000 is the convergence rate
between 1970 and 2000). Figure A2 presents the implied estimates from the convergence model and
compares these with the IGE estimates using the per-capita income data from Table 2. The convergence
model displays a pronounced V-shaped pattern that reaches a bottom in 1970. In general, the estimates are
highly variable (standard deviation of 0.44) and suggest near perfect mobility in some periods (convergence
between 1940 and 1970) but extreme rigidity in others (convergence between 1970 and 2000). On average,
the implied rate of intergenerational persistence is 0.34.
While the average IGE over the whole period is reasonably similar to ours, the time series is clearly
distinct. Our IGE estimates are much more stable (standard deviation of 0.09) and do not follow the same

between the growth rate over a generation and the initial level of income, so that log (yit) –log(y0i) = α – βlog(y0i) + εit,
and if the intergenerational relationship is modeled as yit = κ + ρy0i + υit then, it follows exactly that ρ = 1- β.
41
For example, among native born men 25 years or older in 1970, 50 percent of those with 4 years of college moved
from their state of birth compared to only 28 percent of those with less than 12 years of completed schooling. We also
find that our point estimates for the IGE are lower for a subsample of movers. Using the IPUMS data for the parent
generation, the IGE falls from 0.358 for the full sample (Table 1) to 0.265 for movers. The time patterns are similar
for our mover sample but the magnitude of the changes are much smaller.
42
We use nonlinear least squares and follow the methodology described by Barro and Sala-i-Martin in the notes
accompanying their table 1. The estimates and the calculations used to transform these into the line shown in Figure
A2 are described in appendix table A2. It should be noted that Barro and Sala-i-Martin produce estimates of β using
data 10 years apart. The implied estimates of ρ from this procedure are extremely variable, ranging from roughly 1.3
in 1930 to –1.0 in 1950, but produce roughly the same pattern. Using their estimates that control for sectoral
reallocation reduces the variability somewhat but it remains an order of magnitude greater than our IGE estimates.
33

V-shaped time pattern. This suggests that our estimates are not simply a restatement of the growth
convergence model but rather reflect the changing patterns of economic mobility among families.

34

Table 1: Estimates of the IGE Using Census IPUMS Data

Full sample
(1)
Family Income

0.433
(0.027)
Family Income*Year
1950
--

(2)

(3)

(4)

--

--

0.347
(0.036)

0.297
(0.041)

--

0.056
(0.023)

Implied IGE
35-44 year
for 40-44 year olds olds only
(5)
(6)
-0.404 *

--

1960

--

0.322
(0.038)

--

--

0.347

0.336
(0.034)

1970

--

0.367
(0.025)

--

-0.039
(0.024)

0.336

0.331
(0.025)

1980

--

0.375
(0.025)

--

-0.121
(0.032)

0.322

0.318
(0.026)

1990

--

0.522
(0.046)

--

-0.076
(0.058)

0.462

0.464
(0.044)

2000

--

0.545
(0.056)

--

-0.143
(0.065)

0.580

0.571
(0.058)

--

0.337
(0.028)

--

--

Family Income*Cohort
1921-25
-1926-30

--

0.298
(0.028)

0.028
(0.014)

--

1931-35

--

--

0.372
(0.031)

0.111
(0.023)

--

1936-40

--

--

0.358
(0.032)

0.095
(0.028)

--

1941-45

--

--

0.453
(0.030)

0.200
(0.032)

--

1946-50

--

--

0.425
(0.036)

0.191
(0.037)

--

1951-55

--

--

0.475
(0.037)

0.251
(0.040)

--

1956-60

--

--

0.604
(0.061)

0.375
(0.048)

--

1961-65

--

--

0.694
(0.082)

0.478
(0.065)

--

1966-70

--

--

0.578
(0.073)

0.398
(0.063)

--

1971-75

N

--

--

--

0.476
(0.090)

0.306
(0.080)

--

6,115,340

6,115,340

6,115,340

6,115,340

2,121,549

Notes : All specifications include cohort dummies, year dummies and a quartic in age-40 interacted with
survey year (1950, 1960 and 1970 have a common age profile). They also include interactions of a quartic in
age-40 with family income. All standard errors are clustered by state of birth.
*Assumes that the cohort effect for 1906-1910 is equal to cohort effect for 1921-25

Table 2: Estimates of the IGE Using Personal Income per Capita Data

Full Sample

Implied IGE
for 40 year olds
(5)

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

0.502
(0.026)

--

--

0.466
(0.030)

--

0.670
(0.027)

--

0.259
(0.037)

0.592

1950

--

0.520
(0.024)

--

0.052
(0.017)

0.579

1960

--

0.509
(0.029)

--

--

0.512

1970

--

0.449
(0.020)

--

-0.101
(0.021)

0.383

1980

--

0.399
(0.030)

--

-0.227
(0.025)

0.342

1990

--

0.569
(0.047)

--

-0.172
(0.052)

0.495

2000

--

0.530
(0.060)

--

-0.297
(0.054)

0.566

--

--

0.617
(0.038)

-0.180
(0.069)

1891-95

--

--

0.595
(0.043)

-0.177
(0.064)

1896-00

--

--

0.573
(0.033)

-0.133
(0.052)

1901-05

--

--

0.688
(0.030)

0.015
(0.039)

1906-10

--

--

0.658
(0.032)

0.061
(0.033)

1911-15

--

--

0.664
(0.030)

0.097
(0.028)

1916-20

--

--

0.506
(0.037)

0.046
(0.020)

1921-25

--

--

0.429
(0.023)

--

1926-30

--

--

0.354
(0.028)

0.018
(0.014)

1931-35

--

--

0.438
(0.033)

0.129
(0.030)

Income per Capita

Income per Capita * Year
1940

Income per Capita * Cohort
1886-90

Table 2: Estimates of the IGE Using Personal Income per Capita Data (cont.)

Full Sample
(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

--

--

0.409
(0.026)

0.103
(0.029)

1941-45

--

--

0.518
(0.034)

0.241
(0.039)

1946-50

--

--

0.442
(0.034)

0.202
(0.038)

1951-55

--

--

0.508
(0.042)

0.296
(0.038)

1956-60

--

--

0.607
(0.057)

0.397
(0.045)

1961-65

--

--

0.675
(0.090)

0.497
(0.066)

1966-70

--

--

0.491
(0.090)

0.380
(0.066)

1971-75

--

--

0.437
(0.083)

0.353
(0.058)

6,501,257

6,501,257

6,501,257

6,501,257

Income per Capita * Cohort
1936-40

N

Table 3: Estimates of the IGE Using State of Birth and Ancestry as Instruments

Baseline Model

(1)
0.262
(0.024)

Family Income
Family Income*Year
1980

State Fixed Effects

IGE
at age 40
(2)

(3)
0.234
(0.022)

IGE
at age 40
(4)

State Fixed Effects
with State-Yr Interactions
IGE
at age 40
(5)
(6)
0.209
(0.022)

--

0.343

--

0.293

--

0.301

1990

0.085
(0.024)

0.696

0.085
(0.023)

0.629

0.005
(0.002)

0.564

2000

0.008
(0.036)

0.689

0.002
(0.036)

0.615

0.009
(0.001)

0.658

Family Income*Cohort
1926-30

--

--

--

1931-35

0.087
(0.019)

0.096
(0.019)

1936-40

0.080
(0.023)

0.059
(0.021)

0.092
(0.021)

1941-45

0.372
(0.038)

0.333
(0.035)

0.372
(0.035)

1946-50

0.348
(0.038)

0.310
(0.036)

0.350
(0.036)

1951-55

0.350
(0.045)

0.313
(0.042)

0.360
(0.042)

1956-60

0.419
(0.050)

0.379
(0.046)

0.440
(0.046)

1961-65

0.328
(0.059)

0.303
(0.055)

0.369
(0.055)

1966-70

N

0.107
(0.021)

0.321
(0.061)

0.297
(0.057)

0.347
(0.057)

4,621,092

4,621,092

4,621,092

Notes : All specifications include cohort dummies and year dummies and a quartic in age-40 interacted with
survey year. They also include interactions of a quartic in age-40 with family income. All standard errors are
clustered by the combination of ancestry and state of birth.

Table 4: Estimates of the Intergenerational Correlation
Using 35-44 year olds only

IGE

σ parent
σ child

Implied
IGC

1950

--

--

--

1960

0.336

1.500

0.505

1970

0.331

1.452

0.481

1980

0.318

1.114

0.354

1990

0.464

0.945

0.438

2000

0.571

0.903

0.515

IGE

σ parent
σ child

Implied
IGC

1950

0.297

1.304

0.387

1960

0.322

1.437

0.462

1970

0.367

1.395

0.512

1980

0.375

1.082

0.406

1990

0.522

0.948

0.495

2000

0.545

0.949

0.517

Year

Using full sample weighted by cohorts

Year

Note: The 1950 IGE for 35-44 year olds cannot be calculated with available IPUMS data.

Figure 1: Layout of Census IPUMS Data by Birth Cohort and Year
Census has income data starting in 1940

Cohort
1921 1925
1926 1930
1931 1935
1936 1940
1941 1945
1946 1950
1951 1955
1956 1960
1961 1965
1966 1970
1971 1975

1940
19 15
14 10
9
5
4
0

1950
29 25
24 20
19 15
14 10
9
5
4
0

1960
39 35
34 30
29 25
24 20
19 15
14 10
9
5
4
0

Bold: Indicates cells used
to calculate family income
for each cohort

1970
49 45
44 40
39 35
34 30
29 25
24 20
19 15
14 10
9
5
4
0

Shaded Area: Indicates cells
used to calculate son's earnings

1980

1990

54
49
44
39
34
29
24
19
14
9

54
49
44
39
34
29
24
19

50
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5

50
45
40
35
30
25
20
15

2000

54
49
44
39
34
29

50
45
40
35
30
25

Figure 2: Layout of Personal Income Per Capita (PIPC) Data by Birth Cohort and Year

AGE IN…

1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18

Cohort
1886 1890
1891 1895
1896 1900
1901 1905
1906 1910
1911 1915
1916 1920
1921 1925
1926 1930
1931 1935
1936 1940
1941 1945
1946 1950
1951 1955
1956 1960
1961 1965
1966 1970
1971 1975

1900
1900 only
1900 only
1900 only

1920

1930

1940
54 50
49 45
44 40
39 35
34 30
29 25

1920 only
1920 only
1920 and 1930
1920 and 1930
1930 and 1940
1930 and 1940
40 and 50
40 and 50
Bold: Indicates year used
for state PIPC for
parent generation

1950

54
49
44
39
34
29

50
45
40
35
30
25

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

Shaded Area: Indicates data
used to calculate son's earnings

54
49
44
39
34
29

50
45
40
35
30
25

50 and 60
50 and 60

54
49
44
39
34
29

50
45
40
35
30
25

60 and 70
60 and 70

54
49
44
39
34
29

50
45
40
35
30
25

70 and 80
70 and 80
80 and 90

54
49
44
39
34
29

50
45
40
35
30
25

54
49
44
39
34
29

50
45
40
35
30
25

Figure 3: Comparisons of IGE Computed From the IPUMS and Income Per Capita Data
Year Effects Only (column 2)
0.9
0.8
0.7
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3

Income per capita
IPUMS

0.2
0.1
0
1940

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

Cohort Effects Only (column 3)
0.8
0.7
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3

Income per capita
IPUMS

0.2
0.1
0

1895 1900 1905 1910 1915 1920 1925 1930 1935 1940 1945 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975

Combined Cohort and Year Effects (column 4)
0.9
0.8
0.7
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2

Income per capita
IPUMS

0.1
0
1940

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

Figure 4: Comparison of Trends in Inequality and the IGE

The 90-10 Wage Gap and IGE
0.600

2.00

0.500

1.50

0.400

1.00

0.300
0.200

0.50

0.100

0.00

0.000
1940

1950

1960

1970

1980

90-10 Wage Gap

1990

2000

IGE

Income Share of Top 10% and IGE
0.31
0.29
0.27
0.25
0.23
0.21
0.19
0.17
0.15

0.600
0.500
0.400
0.300
0.200
0.100
0.000
1940

1950

1960

1970

1980

Income Share Top 10%

1990

2000

IGE

The Return to College and IGE
0.14
0.12
0.1
0.08
0.06
0.04
0.02
0

0.600
0.500
0.400
0.300
0.200
0.100
0.000
1940

1950

1960

1970

Return to College

1980

1990
IGE

2000

Figure 5: Estimates of the IGE With and Without Education
Year Effects Only (column 2)
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3

w/o educ
with educ

0.2
0.1
0
1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

Cohort Effects Only (column 3)
0.8
0.7
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2

w/o educ
with educ

0.1
0
1925

1930

1935

1940

1945

1950

1955

1960

1965

1970

1975

Combined Cohort and Year Effects (column 4)
0.7
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2

w/o educ
with educ

0.1
0
1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

Figure 6: Comparisons of the Intergenerational Elasticity and Intergenerational Correlation

Based on Sample of 35-44 Year Olds
0.6

IGC

IGE or IGC

0.5
0.4
0.3

IGE

0.2
0.1
0.0
1940

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

1980

1990

2000

Based on Full Sample
0.6
IGC

IGE or IGC

0.5
0.4
0.3

IGE

0.2
0.1
0
1940

1950

1960

1970

Table A1: Comparison of OLS, TSIV and IV Estimates of the IGE using the NLSY and PSID
IGE
(s.e.)
N
Panel A: Estimates of OLS and SSIV
OLS
NLSY
(avg 1993, 1995, 1997)

TSIV

0.367
(0.054)
443

0.507
(0.167)
443

OLS including
Birth State Dummies
0.346
(0.061)
443
Joint test of State Dummies
F-stat p-value
0.27

PSID
(avg 1984 to 1986)

0.402
(0.062)
356

0.372
(0.159)
356

0.315
(0.073)
356
Joint test of State Dummies
F-stat p-value
0.14

Panel B: Estimates of OLS and IV
OLS
NLSY
IV with
father's education

IV

OLS including
Instrument

0.382
(0.052)
446

0.621
(0.106)
446

0.299
(0.060)
446
Test of Father's Education
T-stat p-value
0.01

NLSY
IV with
father's occupation

0.378
(0.055)
419

0.367
(0.072)
419

0.392
(0.081)
419
Joint test of Occupation dummies
F-stat p-value
0.23

Notes: The NLSY sample includes men born between 1961 and 1965 who lived with their father and for
whom family income is available in 1978, 1979 and 1980. Son's earnings and state of birth must be
nonmissing in the relevant years. The PSID sample include men born between 1951 and 1959 who were
the son of a household head in 1968 and who report positive and nonmissing earnings in 1984 to 1986.
Family income is averaged over 1967 to 1969. The PSID sample uses state of residence in 1968 rather
than state of birth.

Table A2: Estimates from Growth Convergence Model

Ten year estimates of β

Time Period
1920-30
1930-40
1940-50
1950-60
1960-70
1970-80
1980-88/90
1990-2000

Reported in
Barro and
Sala-I-Martin

Replication of
Barro and
Sala-I-Martin

-0.0122
(0.007)
0.0127
(0.005)
0.0373
(0.005)
0.0202
(0.005)
0.0135
(0.004)
0.0119
(0.007)
-0.005
(0.011)
--

-0.0618
(0.005)
-0.0009
(0.004)
0.0507
(0.005)
0.0180
(0.004)
0.0229
(0.004)
0.0135
(0.005)
0.0030
(0.007)
0.0020
(0.004)

Thirty year estimates of β and implied IGE

Time Period

β

1900-30

0.0135
(0.003)
0.0070
(0.003)
0.0143
(0.002)
0.0220
(0.002)
0.0297
(0.002)
0.0223
(0.003)
0.0151
(0.003)
0.0050
(0.003)

1910-40
1920-50
1930-60
1940-70
1950-80
1960-90
1970-00

β Extrapolated
over 30 years
β30= ((1 + β)^30)-1

Implied
estimate of ρ
ρ = 1 - β30

0.4971

0.5029

0.2312

0.7688

0.5312

0.4688

0.9226

0.0774

1.4095

-0.4095

0.9354

0.0646

0.5663

0.4337

0.1600

0.8400

Notes: The first column presents estimates from Table 1, rows 4 to 10 of Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1992). Column (2) presents our attempt to
replicate their estimates following the description of their methodology in their notes. We use more recently revised data and our data does not
adjust for transfers. In column 4 we use equation (5) to estimate annual convergence over thirty year periods. Column 5 extrapolates this annual
rate over thirty years and column 6 shows the implied estimate for ρ presented in Figure 6.

Figure A1: Reconciling Estimates of the IGE (column 4 specification) by
Imposing Common Data Limitaions
0.7

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.3

0.2
per-capita income
IPUMS
0.1

0
1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

Figure A2: Comparison of Intergenerational Model with Convergence Model
1

Convergence
model
0.8

0.6

Intergenerational
model

0.4

0.2

0
1930
-0.2

-0.4

-0.6

1940

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

Working Paper Series
A series of research studies on regional economic issues relating to the Seventh Federal
Reserve District, and on financial and economic topics.
Outsourcing Business Services and the Role of Central Administrative Offices
Yukako Ono

WP-02-01

Strategic Responses to Regulatory Threat in the Credit Card Market*
Victor Stango

WP-02-02

The Optimal Mix of Taxes on Money, Consumption and Income
Fiorella De Fiore and Pedro Teles

WP-02-03

Expectation Traps and Monetary Policy
Stefania Albanesi, V. V. Chari and Lawrence J. Christiano

WP-02-04

Monetary Policy in a Financial Crisis
Lawrence J. Christiano, Christopher Gust and Jorge Roldos

WP-02-05

Regulatory Incentives and Consolidation: The Case of Commercial Bank Mergers
and the Community Reinvestment Act
Raphael Bostic, Hamid Mehran, Anna Paulson and Marc Saidenberg

WP-02-06

Technological Progress and the Geographic Expansion of the Banking Industry
Allen N. Berger and Robert DeYoung

WP-02-07

Choosing the Right Parents: Changes in the Intergenerational Transmission
of Inequality  Between 1980 and the Early 1990s
David I. Levine and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-02-08

The Immediacy Implications of Exchange Organization
James T. Moser

WP-02-09

Maternal Employment and Overweight Children
Patricia M. Anderson, Kristin F. Butcher and Phillip B. Levine

WP-02-10

The Costs and Benefits of Moral Suasion: Evidence from the Rescue of
Long-Term Capital Management
Craig Furfine

WP-02-11

On the Cyclical Behavior of Employment, Unemployment and Labor Force Participation
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-02-12

Do Safeguard Tariffs and Antidumping Duties Open or Close Technology Gaps?
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-02-13

Technology Shocks Matter
Jonas D. M. Fisher

WP-02-14

Money as a Mechanism in a Bewley Economy
Edward J. Green and Ruilin Zhou

WP-02-15

1

Working Paper Series (continued)
Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy: Equivalence Results
Isabel Correia, Juan Pablo Nicolini and Pedro Teles

WP-02-16

Real Exchange Rate Fluctuations and the Dynamics of Retail Trade Industries
on the U.S.-Canada Border
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Beverly Lapham

WP-02-17

Bank Procyclicality, Credit Crunches, and Asymmetric Monetary Policy Effects:
A Unifying Model
Robert R. Bliss and George G. Kaufman

WP-02-18

Location of Headquarter Growth During the 90s
Thomas H. Klier

WP-02-19

The Value of Banking Relationships During a Financial Crisis:
Evidence from Failures of Japanese Banks
Elijah Brewer III, Hesna Genay, William Curt Hunter and George G. Kaufman

WP-02-20

On the Distribution and Dynamics of Health Costs
Eric French and John Bailey Jones

WP-02-21

The Effects of Progressive Taxation on Labor Supply when Hours and Wages are
Jointly Determined
Daniel Aaronson and Eric French

WP-02-22

Inter-industry Contagion and the Competitive Effects of Financial Distress Announcements:
Evidence from Commercial Banks and Life Insurance Companies
Elijah Brewer III and William E. Jackson III

WP-02-23

State-Contingent Bank Regulation With Unobserved Action and
Unobserved Characteristics
David A. Marshall and Edward Simpson Prescott

WP-02-24

Local Market Consolidation and Bank Productive Efficiency
Douglas D. Evanoff and Evren Örs

WP-02-25

Life-Cycle Dynamics in Industrial Sectors. The Role of Banking Market Structure
Nicola Cetorelli

WP-02-26

Private School Location and Neighborhood Characteristics
Lisa Barrow

WP-02-27

Teachers and Student Achievement in the Chicago Public High Schools
Daniel Aaronson, Lisa Barrow and William Sander

WP-02-28

The Crime of 1873: Back to the Scene
François R. Velde

WP-02-29

Trade Structure, Industrial Structure, and International Business Cycles
Marianne Baxter and Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-02-30

Estimating the Returns to Community College Schooling for Displaced Workers
Louis Jacobson, Robert LaLonde and Daniel G. Sullivan

WP-02-31

2

Working Paper Series (continued)
A Proposal for Efficiently Resolving Out-of-the-Money Swap Positions
at Large Insolvent Banks
George G. Kaufman

WP-03-01

Depositor Liquidity and Loss-Sharing in Bank Failure Resolutions
George G. Kaufman

WP-03-02

Subordinated Debt and Prompt Corrective Regulatory Action
Douglas D. Evanoff and Larry D. Wall

WP-03-03

When is Inter-Transaction Time Informative?
Craig Furfine

WP-03-04

Tenure Choice with Location Selection: The Case of Hispanic Neighborhoods
in Chicago
Maude Toussaint-Comeau and Sherrie L.W. Rhine

WP-03-05

Distinguishing Limited Commitment from Moral Hazard in Models of
Growth with Inequality*
Anna L. Paulson and Robert Townsend

WP-03-06

Resolving Large Complex Financial Organizations
Robert R. Bliss

WP-03-07

The Case of the Missing Productivity Growth:
Or, Does information technology explain why productivity accelerated in the United States
but not the United Kingdom?
Susanto Basu, John G. Fernald, Nicholas Oulton and Sylaja Srinivasan

WP-03-08

Inside-Outside Money Competition
Ramon Marimon, Juan Pablo Nicolini and Pedro Teles

WP-03-09

The Importance of Check-Cashing Businesses to the Unbanked: Racial/Ethnic Differences
William H. Greene, Sherrie L.W. Rhine and Maude Toussaint-Comeau

WP-03-10

A Firm’s First Year
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-03-11

Market Size Matters
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Hugo A. Hopenhayn

WP-03-12

The Cost of Business Cycles under Endogenous Growth
Gadi Barlevy

WP-03-13

The Past, Present, and Probable Future for Community Banks
Robert DeYoung, William C. Hunter and Gregory F. Udell

WP-03-14

Measuring Productivity Growth in Asia: Do Market Imperfections Matter?
John Fernald and Brent Neiman

WP-03-15

Revised Estimates of Intergenerational Income Mobility in the United States
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-03-16

3

Working Paper Series (continued)
Product Market Evidence on the Employment Effects of the Minimum Wage
Daniel Aaronson and Eric French

WP-03-17

Estimating Models of On-the-Job Search using Record Statistics
Gadi Barlevy

WP-03-18

Banking Market Conditions and Deposit Interest Rates
Richard J. Rosen

WP-03-19

Creating a National State Rainy Day Fund: A Modest Proposal to Improve Future
State Fiscal Performance
Richard Mattoon

WP-03-20

Managerial Incentive and Financial Contagion
Sujit Chakravorti, Anna Llyina and Subir Lall

WP-03-21

Women and the Phillips Curve: Do Women’s and Men’s Labor Market Outcomes
Differentially Affect Real Wage Growth and Inflation?
Katharine Anderson, Lisa Barrow and Kristin F. Butcher

WP-03-22

Evaluating the Calvo Model of Sticky Prices
Martin Eichenbaum and Jonas D.M. Fisher

WP-03-23

The Growing Importance of Family and Community: An Analysis of Changes in the
Sibling Correlation in Earnings
Bhashkar Mazumder and David I. Levine

WP-03-24

Should We Teach Old Dogs New Tricks? The Impact of Community College Retraining
on Older Displaced Workers
Louis Jacobson, Robert J. LaLonde and Daniel Sullivan

WP-03-25

Trade Deflection and Trade Depression
Chad P. Brown and Meredith A. Crowley

WP-03-26

China and Emerging Asia: Comrades or Competitors?
Alan G. Ahearne, John G. Fernald, Prakash Loungani and John W. Schindler

WP-03-27

International Business Cycles Under Fixed and Flexible Exchange Rate Regimes
Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-03-28

Firing Costs and Business Cycle Fluctuations
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-03-29

Spatial Organization of Firms
Yukako Ono

WP-03-30

Government Equity and Money: John Law’s System in 1720 France
François R. Velde

WP-03-31

Deregulation and the Relationship Between Bank CEO
Compensation and Risk-Taking
Elijah Brewer III, William Curt Hunter and William E. Jackson III

WP-03-32

4

Working Paper Series (continued)
Compatibility and Pricing with Indirect Network Effects: Evidence from ATMs
Christopher R. Knittel and Victor Stango

WP-03-33

Self-Employment as an Alternative to Unemployment
Ellen R. Rissman

WP-03-34

Where the Headquarters are – Evidence from Large Public Companies 1990-2000
Tyler Diacon and Thomas H. Klier

WP-03-35

Standing Facilities and Interbank Borrowing: Evidence from the Federal Reserve’s
New Discount Window
Craig Furfine

WP-04-01

Netting, Financial Contracts, and Banks: The Economic Implications
William J. Bergman, Robert R. Bliss, Christian A. Johnson and George G. Kaufman

WP-04-02

Real Effects of Bank Competition
Nicola Cetorelli

WP-04-03

Finance as a Barrier To Entry: Bank Competition and Industry Structure in
Local U.S. Markets?
Nicola Cetorelli and Philip E. Strahan

WP-04-04

The Dynamics of Work and Debt
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-04-05

Fiscal Policy in the Aftermath of 9/11
Jonas Fisher and Martin Eichenbaum

WP-04-06

Merger Momentum and Investor Sentiment: The Stock Market Reaction
To Merger Announcements
Richard J. Rosen

WP-04-07

Earnings Inequality and the Business Cycle
Gadi Barlevy and Daniel Tsiddon

WP-04-08

Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets: The Case of Payment Networks
Sujit Chakravorti and Roberto Roson

WP-04-09

Nominal Debt as a Burden on Monetary Policy
Javier Díaz-Giménez, Giorgia Giovannetti, Ramon Marimon, and Pedro Teles

WP-04-10

On the Timing of Innovation in Stochastic Schumpeterian Growth Models
Gadi Barlevy

WP-04-11

Policy Externalities: How US Antidumping Affects Japanese Exports to the EU
Chad P. Bown and Meredith A. Crowley

WP-04-12

Sibling Similarities, Differences and Economic Inequality
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-04-13

Determinants of Business Cycle Comovement: A Robust Analysis
Marianne Baxter and Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-04-14

5

Working Paper Series (continued)
The Occupational Assimilation of Hispanics in the U.S.: Evidence from Panel Data
Maude Toussaint-Comeau

WP-04-15

Reading, Writing, and Raisinets1: Are School Finances Contributing to Children’s Obesity?
Patricia M. Anderson and Kristin F. Butcher

WP-04-16

Learning by Observing: Information Spillovers in the Execution and Valuation
of Commercial Bank M&As
Gayle DeLong and Robert DeYoung

WP-04-17

Prospects for Immigrant-Native Wealth Assimilation:
Evidence from Financial Market Participation
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-04-18

Individuals and Institutions: Evidence from International Migrants in the U.S.
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-04-19

Are Technology Improvements Contractionary?
Susanto Basu, John Fernald and Miles Kimball

WP-04-20

The Minimum Wage, Restaurant Prices and Labor Market Structure
Daniel Aaronson, Eric French and James MacDonald

WP-04-21

Betcha can’t acquire just one: merger programs and compensation
Richard J. Rosen

WP-04-22

Not Working: Demographic Changes, Policy Changes,
and the Distribution of Weeks (Not) Worked
Lisa Barrow and Kristin F. Butcher

WP-04-23

The Role of Collateralized Household Debt in Macroeconomic Stabilization
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-04-24

Advertising and Pricing at Multiple-Output Firms: Evidence from U.S. Thrift Institutions
Robert DeYoung and Evren Örs

WP-04-25

Monetary Policy with State Contingent Interest Rates
Bernardino Adão, Isabel Correia and Pedro Teles

WP-04-26

Comparing location decisions of domestic and foreign auto supplier plants
Thomas Klier, Paul Ma and Daniel P. McMillen

WP-04-27

China’s export growth and US trade policy
Chad P. Bown and Meredith A. Crowley

WP-04-28

Where do manufacturing firms locate their Headquarters?
J. Vernon Henderson and Yukako Ono

WP-04-29

Monetary Policy with Single Instrument Feedback Rules
Bernardino Adão, Isabel Correia and Pedro Teles

WP-04-30

6

Working Paper Series (continued)
Firm-Specific Capital, Nominal Rigidities and the Business Cycle
David Altig, Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum and Jesper Linde

WP-05-01

Do Returns to Schooling Differ by Race and Ethnicity?
Lisa Barrow and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP-05-02

Derivatives and Systemic Risk: Netting, Collateral, and Closeout
Robert R. Bliss and George G. Kaufman

WP-05-03

Risk Overhang and Loan Portfolio Decisions
Robert DeYoung, Anne Gron and Andrew Winton

WP-05-04

Characterizations in a random record model with a non-identically distributed initial record
Gadi Barlevy and H. N. Nagaraja

WP-05-05

Price discovery in a market under stress: the U.S. Treasury market in fall 1998
Craig H. Furfine and Eli M. Remolona

WP-05-06

Politics and Efficiency of Separating Capital and Ordinary Government Budgets
Marco Bassetto with Thomas J. Sargent

WP-05-07

Rigid Prices: Evidence from U.S. Scanner Data
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Benjamin Eden

WP-05-08

Entrepreneurship, Frictions, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-05-09

Wealth inequality: data and models
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-05-10

What Determines Bilateral Trade Flows?
Marianne Baxter and Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-05-11

Intergenerational Economic Mobility in the U.S., 1940 to 2000
Daniel Aaronson and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-05-12

7