View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

REGIONAL ECONOMIC ISSUES
Working Paper Series

Institutional Rigidities as Barriers To Growth:
A Regional Perspective
Michael Kendix

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF CHICAGO



W P - 1990-6

Institutional Rigidities as Barriers To Growth:
A Regional Perspective
MichaelKendix
The term 'institutional sclerosis' has been used to describe the malady
affecting economies suffering from low output growth and an inability to
adapt to shocks brought about, for example, by technological change or oil
price increases. There are two separate issues here: first, the overall
stagnation thathas, at various times, overtaken economies, and second, the
sluggish pace of adapting to change. These two problems appear closely
relatedsinceregionsoreconomies sufferingfrom one tendtosufferfrom the
other.
There has been a wide variation in the economic performance of the
developed western capitalist economies during the past twenty years. A
number ofstudieshave attempted toexplainthis,forexample, by examining
thedifferenceinpoliciesusedby governmentsorthedifferencesinthesizeof
thepublicsector.1 Although thesefactorsmay beimportant,none canexplain
the variation in economic growth or unemployment rates experienced by
different regions within the same political boundaries, since these regions
experience the same macroeconomic policies and exist under the same
politicalandeconomic systems.
This paper concentrates on the industrial Midwest and the role of growth
retarding institutions therein.2 However, a theory of economic stagnation
would be lacking,ifitonly explained events intheone region oftheUnited
States. A more impressivetheoryshouldexplainthepresence,orabsence,of
economic stagnationinawidevarietyofcircumstances. IftheMidwestcould
be shown to be a particular case of a more general pattern of events, this
would add considerable weight tothe argument. Therefore, theapproach of
thispaperwillbetoexaminedifferencesinregionaleconomicperformancein
anumber ofcountries,and thenfocuson theMidwest toseehow itcompares
withsimilarregionsindifferentcountries.

New Classical vs. Keynesian Approaches to Market Efficiency
The most recent mainstream macroeconomic debate has been between the
new classical and Keynesian schools. Although both schools have made
FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6




1

substantialcontributionstoour understanding ofhow economies work, there
are some importantphenomena thatthey have been unable toexplain. This
section will suggest how institutionalconsiderations are able to fillsome of
thesegaps.
The roots of the new classical macroeconomics3 are to be found in the
classical models, beginning with Adam Smith, continuing through into the
TwentiethCentury withAlfredMarshall,and more recentlyMilton Friedman
and the monetarists. These schools ofthought have a single,vital,common
thread;namely,thatmarketsclear.
The logic leading to the market clearingresultissimple butpowerful. The
argument reliesan the incentives facing individual market participants. We
know from basic microeconomic theory that,ifthemarket price issuch that
desiredsalesexceed desiredpurchases, thereisan incentiveforthose sellers
who are unable to sell their output to reduce price until the disparity is
eliminated. On the other hand, ifdesired purchases exceed desired sales,
buyers have an incentivetobidpricesup,again eliminatingthedisparity. In
otherwords, atany pricethatdoes notclearthemarket, thereisthepotential
formutually beneficialtransactionsthat,ifcarriedout,tendtodrivetheprice
towards itsmarket clearing level. Ifthismechanism always operates, there
canneverbeanyprotractedperiodofexcesssupplyordemand.
The new classicalschoolcannot, therefore,offeraconvincingexplanation of
theGreatDepression,orthesecularincreaseintheunemploymentratesofthe
developedwesterneconomiesduringthelatterpostwarperiod. Sincethenew
classical paradigm denies that long-run disparities between supply and
demand can exist, it cannot explain unemployment beyond that due to
frictionalfactorsortemporarystructuraldislocation. Anotheromission ofthe
new classical theory is itcontains no explanation of consistent, significant
differencesineconomic performanceamong regionsofthesame country. For
example, as discussed below, during the past twenty years, the level of
unemploymentinthenorthandeastUnitedStateshasbeenconsistentlyabove
thatofthewestand south. A studyby Hultenand Schwab shows thatwages
in the north and east have been above the west and south, but the general
direction ofpopulation migration has been to thelatter;thatis,the opposite
directiontothatpredictedby thewage differentials.
The Keynesian school offers an explanation of protracted periods of
unemployed resources, based on long-run market disequilibrium. Authors,
such as Barro and Grossman, and Muellbauer and Portes, have laid out
FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6




2

detailed explanations of the macroeconomic effects of slow or non-clearing
markets. The demiseoftheKeynesian schoolinthe1970swas duetoitslack
ofconsistentmicroeconomic foundations. Inparticular,thesedisequilibrium
theories were able to explain the effects of non-clearing markets, but were
unabletoexplainwhy thesemarketsfailedtoclearinthefirstplace. Suppose,
for example, that price is set above the market clearing level. Then as
discussedabove,thereareunrealizedgainsfrom trade. The questionarisesas
towhy suchmutuallybeneficialtradedoesnotoccur.
As itturnsout,both thenew classicaland theKeynesian paradigms can make
valuable contributionstoexplainingwhy markets do notclear,as well asthe
macroeconomic implicationswhen asinglemarketfailstoclear. The former’s
insightistorecognize thatthe individual incentives offirms and consumers
tend toclearmarkets, butitdoes notexplain why markets do notcleargiven
these tendencies. The latter’scontribution isto show how disequilibrium in
one market can spill over into others, but provides no explanation of why
markets do not clear. That is,the Keynesian model assumesmarkets (or a
particularmarket)failtoclear.

The Effects of Cartels
The internallogicofthenew classicalmodel isirrefutable,butitspredictions
arenot always borne out by experience. Therefore, one should examine the
underlyingassumptions ofthismodel tofindthesourceoftheproblem. One
common assumption of these models is that markets are competitive.
However, even if individual firms have monopoly power, this does not
explain either why labor markets do not clear or why unemployment varies
significantlyovertime within thesame economy. Curiouslyenough, thekey
to the answer to these questions lies in the logic of the new classical
economics; namely theincentivesfacingindividuals. Ifmarkets do notclear,
why do individuals forego the benefits of mutually beneficial exchange?
Pursuedtoitsconclusion,thislogicimpliesthatsincethesetransactionsareso
compelling, they must have been blocked by forces beyond the control of
these individuals. One possibility is that there are incentives for another
individual, or group of individuals, to somehow block these transactions.
That is,high levels of excess capacity can be explained by the presence of
coalitions. These organizationscreatemonopolies, restrictoutput, and block
markettransactionsofnon-coalitionmembers.

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6




3

One can argue that these types of cartels contain the seeds of their own
destruction, due totheoverriding incentive forindividualmembers tocheat.
For example, in the case of a cartel of firms, itpays an individual firm to
exceed its output quota, regardless of whether its partners adhere to thenquotas. Ifeach firm reactsthisway, thepriceofoutputisdrivenback toits
pre-cartel level. Although this incentive is present, there may be stronger
forcesbinding cartelmembers together. The theoryofcollectiveaction4 has
explained how itispossible for a group to successfully cartelize a market,
thereby creating excess capacity. This theory also demonstrates how
individual incentives can createprice rigidities, which in turn retardgrowth
and reduce an economy's ability to adjust to shocks. Suppose collusive
behavior is the source of economic stagnation. Why has this affected the
Midwest, and not allregions of the United States? In order to answer this
question,itisnecessarytodescribetheprocessofcartelformation.
The benefitsofa carteland othertypesofcoalitionshave strongpublicgood
characteristics. For example, the members of an industry that lobbies for
import protection all receive the benefit of the protection, regardless of
whether they contribute to the lobbying effort. Ifa labor union improves
writingconditionsinaparticularindustry,allworkersbenefiteven iftheydid
notcontributetothestrike,work-to-rule,orwhatevermeans was necessaryto
achieve theirgoal. Any self-interested individual would, therefore, sitback
and letothersdo thework, then reap therewards themselves. Since no selfinterestedindividualwould evercontributetothistypeofactivity,what isthe
mechanism thatallowsthesegroupstoform?
The general problem of collusion has been fruitfully examined using the
"Prisoners'Dilemma" paradigm.5Inthesituationdescribedabove,forasingle
play ofthe'game',theoptimal strategyforallindividualsisnottocontribute
tothepublic good, whether ornotanyone elsecontributes. If,however, this
game isrepeated many times, that is,itbecomes a 'super-game', the use of
sanctions and incentives may result in the cooperative outcome where
everyone contributes. For example, during the formative years of labor
unions, successful collusion was rarely achieved without actual or threaten
violence. Another example isthe OPEC cartel, where Saudi Arabia has on
occasion,increaseditsown output,thereby driving down thepriceofoiland
punishing other members for previously exceeding their own quotas.
Naturally, the Saudis suffer from implementing these sanctions, but other
OPEC members' economies may be less able to withstand a shortfall in
revenues. The Saudi Arabians might consider these sanctions to be an
investment, since inthe long run, they and allthe othercartelmembers will
FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6




4

benefitifthecooperative solutionisreached. Incentiveshave alsoplayedan
important role in binding coalition members together. Common examples
include special reductions in costs of goods or services, such as health
insurance, vacations and socialactivities. Jointprovisionofthepublic good
is,therefore, more likely ifthisgame can be played many times. The time
element isof tantamount importance because, despite theirpervasiveness in
many economies, exclusive cartels and other rent seeking coalitions do not
formeasily.
In the initial stages of collective action these groups encounter great
difficulties. Aside from theconflictingintereststhatmay ariseamong cartel
members, thecartelmay havetobattle(sometimesliterally)forcesoutsidethe
cartel, whose interests are compromised by the cartel's presence. For
example, thehistoryoftheBritishlabormovement isfilledwith examples of
failure and breakdown of workers' organizations.6 Certain factors may
facilitatecollusion, such as member homogeneity and small group size,but
unusual circumstances may have to occur before a coalition is successful.
One example of unusual circumstances is the emergence of extraordinary
leaders with the ability to organize and motivate their members. Ideal
conditions forcollusion seldom arise,but the longer theperiod ofeconomic
and politicalstability,7 thegreateristheprobability thatthecoincidental set
ofcircumstances requiredforsuccessfulcollusionwilloccur. Consequently,
onewouldexpectmore ofthesetypesofcartelsinregionsthatareolder,since
colluderswould have had more time toorganize,arrange incentives fortheir
members andpunishfree-ridersby metingoutsanctions.
In general, cartels seek to reduce output so their members can acquire
monopoly rents. Therefore, thepresence ofa cartel tends toraisepriceand
reduce output, below that which would have occurred in its absence.
Consequently, ifan economy contains large numbers of these cartels, there
will be a significantlossofoutput. Besides forming cartels,thereare other
ways toacquirerents,forexample, legislationproviding groups with special
tax breaks or government subsidies. Tax breaks and subsidies also tend to
distortprices,resultinginan inefficientallocationofresources. Itispossible
that this type of collective action could move a market closer to its most
efficientoutput. However, thisislikelytooccurmore by chancethandesign,
since the overriding objective of a group is to divert resources toward
themselves.
Usually,collectiveactionofthisnaturebenefitsthemembers ofthegroup,at
the expense of a loss in efficiency for the societyas a whole. The adverse
FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6




5

effectsofasingleinterestgroupupon theentireeconomy mightgo unnoticed,
becausetheburdenissharedby suchalargenumberofpeople. Therefore,the
presence of a few rent seeking groups is unlikely to significantly reduce
output forthe whole economy. However, given time and a stableeconomic
andpoliticalenvironment,thesegroupsmay become ubiquitous,resultingina
substantial loss of output. The benefit to each individual member of the
coalitionmust,ofcourse,exceedthecosttoasingleindividualoutsideofthe
group. Ifthiswere not true,itwould notbe intheinterestofindividuals to
collude, since they would lose more as members of the society as a whole,
than they would gain as members of the interestgroup. In summary, these
types ofexclusive groups directresources toward themselves, but ata cost;
namely,areductioninoutputfortheeconomy asawhole.
The abovedescribeshow exclusiveinterestgroupsreduceoutput. Itturnsout
thatthepresenceofthesegroupscanalsoexplaintheinabilityofeconomies to
adjust to adverse shocks. Collective action, of the kind discussed above,
requires a concerted course ofaction, and the members ofa cartelor lobby
group must arrive at a consensus concerning the means of acquiring and
dividingtheirmonopoly rents. Thisprocessisexpeditedifthegroupissmall
andhomogeneous. Forexample,inBritain,asdiscussedby Olson (1965),the
earliestindustrialunions comprised skilledworkers who were few innumber
and who oftenmet inpubstodiscussunionbusiness. Similarly,intheUnited
States,workers were firstorganizedinsmallcraftindustries. However, even
witharelativelysmallmembership thereisalways theproblemofreachingan
agreementamong thecartelmembers. Thismeans thatan industrycartelora
special interest lobby group must spend some time before they arrive at a
consensus. For example, ifa cartel'smarket conditionschange unexpectedly,
thecartelwillhavetoadjustitspriceandoutputtoachieveitsobjectives.This
requiresthemembershiptoreachanew consensusonpriceandrentdivision.
The cartel must, therefore, decide upon the optimal means to make such a
decision. This problem has been examined by Buchanan and Tullock, who
dividethecostsofcollectivedecisionmaking into'time'or'decisionmaking'
costs,and 'external'or'dictatorial'costs. The timecostsareduetointra-cartel
bargaining; forexample, ifthecartelinsistsupon unanimity,thesecostsmay
be prohibitively high. On the other hand, ifthe cartel uses the method of
majority decision, the majority might impose 'dictatorial' costs upon those
members in the minority. At one extreme, an interestgroup cannot use the
unanimity rule because the cartel may fail to reach a decision within a
reasonabletime,butitmay need more thantheagreementoffifty-onepercent
of itsmembers, otherwise there isthe danger of large number of members
FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6




6




refusingtocooperate. The most likelyoutcome isthatthecartelwillchoose
decisionrules thatfallsomewhere between these two extremes; forexample,
they may require the consent of two-thirds of the membership before any
changescanoccur. Consequently,thereiscertaintobeatimelagbetween the
initialchangeinmarketconditions,andtheeventualchangeincartelpriceand
output.
Aside from various voting rules,thereareotherproceduralrulesdesigned to
reduce time spent on intra-cartel bargaining and decision making. For
example,asdiscussedby Olson (1982),fixingprice,ratherthansettingoutput
quotas, may be used toexpediterentdivision. The ideaisthathaving seta
price,rentdivisionislefttothemarket,which isperceivedasanarbitrary,but
fair,determinantofrentallocation. As aprerequisiteforsuccessfulcollusion,
notonly must each member of the group participateinproviding thepublic
good, but each member has to be assured thateveryone else is doing their
share. Ifnot,thecooperativearrangementmay eithernot emerge inthefirst
place or may break down. Another advantage, therefore, of fixing prices
ratherthanquantities,istheformerfacilitatesmutualobservation.
Even withestablishedproceduresthatshortenthetimespentmakingdecisions
about price and rent division, the need for consensual decision making
requiresthegroup tospend some time making a decision. These intra-cartel
time bargaining costs may discourage a cartel from making any changes in
output price, unless the prospective gains from adjusting theprice outweigh
these bargaining costs. For example, a cartel will adjust its price only if
market conditions have deviated substantially from the cartel’sexpectations,
formedwhen thepricewas previouslynegotiated.
In summary, these types of cartels, not only tend to reduce output for the
economy as a whole, but also tend to fix prices as part of their decision
expediting procedures. In contrast to the Keynesian model, the collective
actionmodel doesnotassume thatpricerigiditiesexist,butdemonstrateshow
they arise from the self-interested behavior of individuals engaged in rentseeking activities,through cartelization ofmarkets. Ifthe proportion of the
economy coveredby thesecartelsand interestgroups isrelativelysmall,their
effect on the ability of the economy to adapt to adverse shocks will be
accordingly diminished. If a country or region has enjoyed a protracted
periodofstability,however, largenumbers ofthese coalitionsmay have had
the opportunity to form. In this case, they may be pervasive and have a
considerableimpactonaneconomy’sadaptabilitytoshocks.

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6

7

Regional Disparities of Growth




The plausibilityofthecollectiveactionmodel canbe increased,ifitisshown
to apply in many different situations. To this end, some preliminary
descriptive datahave been collectedon Britain,Canada and West Germany,
as well as the United States. Although the evidence presented for some
countries isnotas detailedorrigorous as fortheUnited States (presented in
more detail laterin the paper), the results are stillinteresting since they all
point in the same direction; that is,the older regions of economies tend to
exhibitslower growth, and sufferdeeperrecessionsthan lessmature regions.
Ideally,one would liketolook atoutputand growth ratestotesttheinterest
group hypotheses. Unfortunately, thesemeasures arenotreadilyavailablein
allcases. Nevertheless, asidefrom outputdata,thereareotherindicationsof
regional prosperity and growth. Inparticular,thisstudy willconcentrate on
the labor market. Although this is only a single market, itspervasiveness
makes itworthyofinvestigation.
ConsiderTables 1through 4,depictingregionaloutput, employment growth,
and unemployment rates for various time intervals. In the case of West
Germany (Table 1),the older industrialregions tend to be in the north and
west, forexample, Bremen, Hamburg, Niedersachsen, Nordrhein Westfalen,
and Saarland. The areas with more recent industrialdevelopment are in the
southand includeBaden-Wurttemberg andBayern. The dataforGDP growth
in Table 1 show that the newer regions have clearly outstripped the older
regions. The fourthcolumnexplicitlyshows thedecliningrelativeimportance
of the older regions. The population and labor market data show similar
trends. For example, despitean annual increaseofone-thirdpercentinWest
Germany's total population between 1961 and 1986, the populations of
Bremen, Hamburg, and Saarlandhaveactuallyfallen. The otherolderregions
have also had below average population growth. The regions of greatest
population increase have been in the south, for example, in BadenWurttemberg and Bayern. The labor market data also show the most vital
regions tobe in the south. For example, employment growth between 1976
and 1987 inBayern was nearly threetimes thenationalaverage. During the
same period, employment eithercontracted or remained below the national
average in allthe older regions. The unemployment data present a similar
picture,with thehighestratesintheolder,northernregionsand thelowestin
thesouth.

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6

8

Table 1

West Germany: Output, Population and Employment
Annual %
GDP Growth
1960-87
Schleswig-Holstein
Hamburg
Niedersachsen
Bremen
Nordrhein-Westfalen
Hessen
Rhineland-Pfalz
Baden-Wurttenberg
Bayern
Saarland
Berlin
West Germany

3.7
2.8
3.2
2.6
3.0
4.1
3.8
4.0
4.2
2.9
3.3
3.5

Annual
population
growth
1961-86
Schleswig-Holstein
Hamburg
Niedersachsen
Bremen
Nordrhein-Westfalen
Hessen
Rhineland-Pfalz
Baden-Wurttenberg
Bayern
Saarland
Berlin
West Germany

0.49
-0.54
0.32
-0.27
0.18
0.58
0.22
0.76
0.60
-0.10
-0.57
0.33

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6




Annual
employment
growth
1976-87
0.69
-0.54
0.33
-0.71
-0.14
0.58
0.57
0.77
1.18
-0.25
0.01
0.40

% of
Total GDP
1960

% of
Total GDP
1987

3.31
5.36
10.57
1.71
30.10
8.72
5.04
14.20
15.18
1.78
4.04
100.00

3.46
4.50
9.69
1.37
26.24
10.02
5.37
16.11
17.95
1.50
3.78
100.00

Difference
in % of Total
1960-87
0.16
-0.86
-0.88
-0.35
-3.86
1.31
0.33
1.91
2.77
-0.28
-0.26
100.00

Average
unemployment
rate
1971-80

Average
unemployment
rate
1981-88

Average
unemployment
rate
1971-88

3.6
2.7
3.9
3.9
3.5
2.7
3.2
2.0
3.3
4.9
3.0
3.1

9.9
10.4
10.7
12.9
9.9
6.6
7.8
5.0
7.0
11.7
9.4
8.3

6.2
5.8
6.7
7.6
6.1
4.3
5.1
3.2
4.8
7.7
5.7
5.3

9

Table2 showsregionaldataforBritain,thefirstcountrytoindustrialize. The
industrialheartland of lateEighteenth and early Nineteenth Century Britain
was in the North West, which contained the cotton industry, Yorkshire &
Humberside,home ofthewoolindustry,theNorth,Wales and Scotland,allof
which contained large coal deposits. Regional output data are not readily
availableforBritain, however, the labor market trends allshow therelative
economic stagnation of the older regions. Between 1972 and 1987,
employmentinBritaincontractedatan annualrateof0.07percent. The only
regions where employment growth was positive were in the south, the east,
andpartoftheMidlands; namely intheSouth East (which includesLondon),
the South West, East Anglia and the East Midlands. Unemployment rates
between 1965 and 1988 were also significantly greaterin the older regions.
All the older regions had unemployment rates above the national average.
Thiswasthecasebothduringandaftertheoilpricerisesof1973 and 1979.
Table 3 shows labor market data forthe ten Canadian provinces. As isthe
casefortheUnited States,thenewer regionslietothewest and theyare the
regions of highest employment growth. For example, theprairieprovinces
andBritishColumbia. The lowestunemploymentratesarealsotobe foundin
these regions. The older regions, for example, Quebec and the maritime
provinces (exceptPrinceEdward Island) tend tohave higher unemployment
ratesandloweremploymentgrowth.
Table 4 shows similar labor market data for the nine census regions of the
United States. The lowest rates of employment growth are for the MidAtlanticandEast-North-Centralregions. Theseoldindustrialregionsalsohad
unemploymentratesabovethenationalaveragebetween 1964 and 1988. The
East-North-Centralregion also sufferedthe most during the recession ofthe
early nineteen-eighties. In summary, therefore, although the industrial
Midwest oftheUnited Statesdiffersfrom theoldindustrialregions ofWest
Germany, Britain,andCanada inmany ways,itsrelativeeconomic prosperity
matchesthepatternoftheolderregionsintheseothercountries.
In addition to explaining differences in regional performance at particular
pointsintime,thecollectiveactionparadigm isalsoabletoexplaintheslow
growth and slow adaptabilityofolderregionsand countriesacross time. For
example, the relative decline of Britain since the middle of the Nineteenth
Century. In 1800, Britainproduced approximately 90 percentoftheworld's
coal outputand somewhat lessthan halfofthecombined Continentaloutput
of iron. Between 1830 and 1850, Britain'soutput of ironrose from 680 to
2250thousandtons,andheroutputofcoalrosefrom 15to49 milliontons.
FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6




10




Table 2

Britain: Employment and Unemployment
Average annual percent change in employment

North
Yorkshire & Humberside
East Midlands
East Anglia
South East
South West
West Midlands
North West
Wales
Scotland
Great Britain

1972-80

1981-87

1972-87

0.03
0.33
1.00
1.73
0.38
1.29
0.01
-0.10
0.49
0.46
0.41

-1.41
-1.25
-0.07
1.82
-0.02
-0.05
-0.94
-2.08
-2.07
-1.38
-0.69

-0.60
-0.36
0.53
1.77
0.21
0.70
-0.41
-0.97
-0.63
-0.35
-0.07

Average annual unemployment rate
1965-88
North
Yorkshire & Humberside
East Midlands
East Anglia
South East
South West
West Midlands
North West
Wales
Scotland
Great Britain

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6

7.7
5.7
4.6
4.1
3.7
4.9
5.7
6.7
7.0
7.1
5.2

1965-73
4.3
2.5
1.9
2.0
1.5
2.5
1.9
2.7
3.7
4.1
2.1

1974-80
5.5
3.8
3.3
3.2
2.6
4.0
3.8
5.0
5.1
5.2
3.8

1981-88
13.6
11.0
8.9
7.2
7.0
8.2
11.6
12.7
12.4
12.1
9.7

11

Table 3

Canada: Employment and Unemployment
Average annual percent growth in employment

Newfoundland
Prince Edward Island
Nova Scotia
New Brunswick
Quebec
Ontario
Manitoba
Saskatchewan
Alberta
British Columbia
Canada

1976-83

1976-81

1982-83

1.68
3.92
1.13
1.32
1.07
1.73
1.39
3.06
4.47
2.42
1.87

2.98
5.76
1.65
2.22
1.92
2.61
1.85
3.61
6.52
4.19
2.91

-2.33
-1.60
-0.42
-1.35
-1.48
-0.89
0.01
1.41
-1.66
-2.89
-1.25

Average annual unemployment rate

Newfoundland
Prince Edward Island
Nova Scotia
New Brunswick
Quebec
Ontario
Manitoba
Saskatchewan
Alberta
British Columbia
Canada

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6




1966-83

1966-73

1974-83

13.1
8.6
8.4
10.0
8.8
5.5
4.9
3.9
4.3
7.6
6.8

10.4
6.5
6.2
7.8
6.9
3.8
3.6
3.1
3.5
6.2
5.2

15.3
10.2
10.1
11.8
10.3
6.9
5.9
4.5
5.0
8.7
8.1

12

Table 4

United States: Employment and Unemployment
Average annual percent change
in non-agricultural unemployment rate
1965-88
New England
Mid-Atlantic
East-North-Central
West-North-Central
South Atlantic
East-South-Central
West-South Central
Mountain
Pacific
48 contiguous states

1.7
1.1
1.5
2.0
3.3
2.5
2.9
3.8
3.2
2.2

1965-73
2.2
1.4
1.7
2.3
3.8
2.8
3.3
3.9
3.3
2.5

1974-80
2.2
1.8
2.7
3.0
4.9
4.0
4.1
4.7
3.5
3.2

1981-88
2.2
1.1
1.1
1.8
3.1
2.0
2.8
3.4
3.1
2.1

Average annual unemployment rate
1964-88
New England
Mid-Atlantic
East-North-Central
West-North-Central
South Atlantic
East-South-Central
West-South Central
Mountain
Pacific
U.S.

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6




5.7
6.4
6.6
4.7
5.5
6.6
2.9
5.5
7.1
6.2

1964-73
5.0
4.7
4.2
3.5
3.9
4.4
3.3
4.2
6.1
4.6

1974-88

1980-88

6.1
7.5
8.2
5.5
6.5
8.2
4.1
6.5
7.8
7.2

6.0
8.1
10.3
6.7
7.2
2.0
10.0
6.8
8.5
8.1

13

Thatis,averageannual growthrateofover6 percent. Incontrast,during the
post-war era, Britain’sgrowth rate has been the lowest of the industrialized
economies. Britain has enjoyed the longest period of stability, and in this
senseitistheoldesteconomy ofallthewestern developed economies. The
collective action model also explains the economic emergence of 'newer'
economies, such as South Korea and Taiwan. These countries have
experiencedrecentupheavals(duringWorld War Two), thathave sweptaway
growthretardinginstitutions. Consequently, theseeconomies shouldbemore
vibrantsincetheyhavenothadsufficienttimetoacquirerent-seekinggroups.

Labor Unions as Special Interest Groups
There aremany examples ofrent-seeking interestgroups, some ofwhom are
more obvious thanothers. Forexample, organizationsthatrepresentspecific
industries, such as agriculture, railroads, steel, and various manufacturing
industries,lobby legislaturesforspecialtaxconcessions,importprotectionor
subsidies. There arealso lessobvious groups, forexample, tradeguilds and
professional organizations thatoversee standards ofproduction and monitor
(orrestrict)industryentrants,suchasthevariousprofessionalorganizationsof
physicians,lawyers,and accountants. Many oftheseorganizationsoperateto
improve the quality of production and services, but their activities
(intentionallyor not)often limitindustryoutputand restricttheflow ofnew
entrantsintotheindustry.
A more obvious rent-seeking type oforganization isthe labor union. Since
thecollectiveactionhypothesispredictsthatolderregionscontain more rentseeking groups ingeneral, thisimplies inparticulartolaborunions. Indeed,
thedatainTables 1through4 suggestthatadetailedexaminationofthelabor
market would provide a useful testofthe collective action hypothesis. The
hypothesis predicts first,thatcartelized markets tend to have greater excess
capacity. This implies thatthe most heavily unionized regions are likely to
have low employment growth and higher unemployment. The second
predictionofdie model, namely thatcartelsare slow toadjusttochanges in
market conditions,hasramificationsfortheway recessionsandbooms affect
cartelized labor markets. This latterhypothesis isworthy of more detailed
explanation.
First, it is necessary to characterize the kind of labor union under
consideration. A laborunionisassumed tocompriseagroup ofworkers that
colludewith theobjectiveofraisingtheirwages; thatis,theymonopolize the

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6




14

labormarket The union’sdecisionsaremade according toa utilityfunction
containing theunionwage and thequantityofemployment asgoods’. In this
’monopoly union’paradigm, theunion must choose itsmost favoredpointon
the l
abordemand curve, just as a monopoly firm chooses the profit
maximizing pointon itsmarket demand curve. The union, ineffect,facesa
trade-off between wages and employment, in a similar way to consumers
choosing between two or more goods; that is, a union can choose higher
wagesorhigheremployment,butnotboth.
Consideraunionizedlabormarket thatfacesa sudden change inthedemand
forlabor. In a competitive labormarket, (under the most usual assumptions
abouttheslopesofthedemand and supply oflaborschedules)both thewage
and employment willadjustuntiltheexcess demand or supply iseliminated.
Ina unionizedlabormarket, however, theunion must decideon a new wage
andemploymentlevel,giventhechangeinlabormarketconditions.
As discussed above, considerable time may elapse before a cartel isable to
reach an agreement about the wage and rent division. In the case of labor
unions, rents only accrue to those remaining in employment. Therefore, if
there has been a decrease in labor demand, the rent division decision is
equivalent to deciding which members, ifany, should become unemployed.
A number ofoptionsareavailabletotheunioninthisrespect. Forexample,it
ispossiblefortheunion toreduce every member's hours ofemployment by
thesame amount; thatis,puteveryone on short-time. Usually, however, the
totalhours ofemployment are reduced (atleastpartially) by allowing some
members to be made unemployed.8 For example, the seniority criterion is
often used as a determinant of which members remain in full-time
employment. According to Oswald (1984), "...this rule is apparently
ubiquitous in the U.S. industrial union sector;...". This rule is another
example of a predetermined procedure, designed to reduce intra-cartel
bargaining costs and speed up the cartel's decision-making process.9
However, even with these time-reducing procedures, there may be a
significant lag between the change in labor market conditions and wage
adjustment. Given thatcartels,including laborunions, tend tosetprices (or
wages), theburdenofadjustmentincartelizedmarkets willbe on quantity,or
inthecaseofthelabormarket,employment.
Considernexttheeffectofan unanticipateddecreaseinthedemand forlabor.
Inacompetitivelabormarket,thewage isbiddown andemploymentfalls. In
a unionized setting, slow decision making allows the wage to change only
after a time lag, and employment bears the whole burden of adjustment.
FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6




15




Thus, slow decision making in cartelized labor markets tends to exacerbate
the unemployment that generally accompanies a recession. Conversely,
following an increase in labor demand, an inflexible-wage leads to a larger
rise in employment than under competitive labor market conditions.
Therefore, slow moving cartelstendtocreatelessexcess capacity ina boom
periodbecause slow wage adjustment exaggerates the beneficial effectsof a
boom onemployment.
Models withincompletepriceadjustment,thatgeneratechanges inoutputand
employment, havebeenapartoftheeconomic literatureforsome time. Price
rigiditiescan arisefrom sources other than cartels,forexample, incomplete
information about markets,10 the costs of gathering information11 or
imperfect competition.12 However, unlike the collective action model, these
theories do not explain why price rigidities should be pervasive in mature
regionsandeconomies.
Recently, there have been contributions that have built upon the collective
action hypothesis and provided a more detailed examination of cartelized
labormarkets. One ofthe most important, forthepurposes ofthispaper, is
the work done an 'insider-outsider' and 'hysteresis'13 theories of
unemployment.14 These theories concentrate an therole oflabor unions as
monopoly cartels,and show how unionscangenerateexacerbatedfluctuations
in employment (and hence unemployment) without assuming wage
inflexibility. The term 'insider-outsider' conveys the idea of one group
excludinganother,which isespeciallyappropriateinthepresentcontext. The
'insiders'are the group of labor union members and the 'outsiders'are those
workers seekingemployment. The insider-outsidermodel assumes first,that
the union leadership only considers the welfare oftheirown members when
making a decision about wages and employment. Second, a worker's
membershipdependsupon theirbeingcurrentlyemployed (oratleastrecently
employed). These two assumptions are fairly standard and are part of
previous contributions to the monopoly union literature.15 The key extra
assumption of the insider-outsider model emanates from the idea that the
union onlycaresaboutitsown members. Given this,they assume thatwhen
there are fewer members, the union sets employment lower than otherwise.
The corollaryofthis,isthatsincetheunionisconstrainedtothelabormarket
demand curve,itwillchooseahigherwage when thereisasmallernumber of
unionmembers.
Given these assumptions, suppose there isan unexpected reduction in labor
demand. Ifthe union considers the 'wage' and 'employment' to be normal
FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6

16

goods,bothofthesewilldecreasefollowingthisdeteriorationinlabormarket
conditions. However, since membership is contingent upon recent
employment, and employment has fallen, the union has fewer members to
worry about. Therefore, in future periods, when membership islower, the
union will negotiate a higher wage and lower level of employment than
otherwise. In brief, any decrease in labor demand that leads to a fall in
employment (and a riseinunemployment) isexacerbated due tothe inverse
relationbetween theunion’schoiceofwage andthequantityofmembers. On
theotherhand, ifthereisan increaseinlabordemand, thereisno reason for
the union to allow employment to rise by letting outsiders enter the labor
market. In themonopoly union model, iftheunion increasesemployment, it
would have totemper thewage increasesofexistingmembers. Therefore,in
an insider-outsidermodel withoutwage stickiness,employment eitherfallsor
remainsunchanged.14
Sincethecollectiveactionmodel hasaconvincingexplanationofwhy cartels'
prices (or wages) should be sticky, and we do observe increases in
employment in unionized industries,thenext step should be tocombine the
insider-outsiderand collectiveaction models. Let us assume, therefore, that
first, there is an inverse relation between the union’s wage choice and the
number ofmembers and second,thatunions adjustwages onlyafteralag. In
describing a union's reaction to a change in labor demand, itis helpful to
dividethesequence ofeventsintothreetimeperiods. Inthefirstperiod,the
union isininitialequilibrium. Inthesecond period,theimmediate effectsof
the change in labor demand take place. In the third period, the new
equilibrium levels of wages and employment are established. In order to
simplify matters, we will assume that membership in the current period is
contingentuponemploymentintheprecedingperiod.
Suppose there is an unexpected decrease in labor demand. In the second
period,sincetheunionisaslowdecisionmaker,thewage isstuckatitsinitial
leveland employment bears the totalburden ofadjustment. Inperiod three,
membership declinesbecauseemployment hasfalleninperiodtwo. Although
thedeteriorationinlabormarketconditionstendstodecreasetheunion'swage
choice, the decrease will be mitigated because the number of members has
fallen, which tends to raise the union’s wage. The sequence of events
following an unexpected increase in labor demand are the reverse of the
above. Inthiscase,thewage isstuckinperiodtwo andemploymentrises. In
thethirdperiod,thenumber ofmembers risessinceemployment hasrisenin
period two. Although the union tends to choose a higher wage due to the
increase in labor demand, this increase is offset, at least in part, by the
FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6




17

increaseinmembers, which tendstoreducetheunion'schoiceofwage. Thus,
combiningtheslowdecisionmakingresultofthecollectiveactionmodel with
thetypeof'selfish'behavioroftheinsider-outsidermodel,leadstoevenwider
swingsinemploymentandhenceunemployment.

Evidence of Unions' Effects on Unemployment
Therearetwo hypothesespresentedinthepreceding discussionregardingthe
regional effectsoflaborcartels. First,thatlaborcartelstend toraisewages,
reduceemploymentandraiseunemployment. Second,thattheunemployment
generatingeffectsoflaborcartelsareincreasedduring nationwide recessions
and mitigatedduringnationwidebooms. That is,laborunionsexacerbatethe
swings in unemployment over the course of the business cycle. The first
hypothesiscan be testedby simply looking attherelationshipbetween union
presence and unemployment rates. Below are presented the results of an
ordinaryleastsquaresestimation,usingdataforthe48 contiguousstates. The
measure used to approximate union presence isunion density (UD), thatis,
the percent of non-agricultural employees that are union members. The
collective action hypothesis, that cartels create excess capacity, would be
supported if the coefficient on the union density variable is large and
significant.
Intheseregressions,an effortwas made toaccountforthepossibilitythatthe
apparent relation between union density and unemployment was caused
indirectlyby athird,more importantvariable. First,ithasbeen suggestedthat
unions tend to be prevalent in industries with a high degree of industryspecific human capital. Ifthis istrue,following a deterioration in business
conditions,therewould be atendency tohave more temporary lay-offsrather
than redundancies. This would benefit firms who would be able to recall
more productive workers when conditionsimproved. Workers would be less
willingtoseek employment elsewhere because oftheincentive towait fora
recall and realize the benefits of their specific human capital. The extra
unemployment generated by this arrangement would not be due to the
monopoly effectsofunions,butmightbe theoutcome ofan efficientimplicit
(or explicit) contract between a firm and its employees. It is possible,
therefore, that the observed relationship between unemployment and union
densityisdue tohuman capitaleffects,ratherthanthemonopoly unioneffects
discussed earlier. Second, according to the collective action hypothesis, the
oldestindustriesaremore likelytobeunionized. Itispossiblethattheseolder
industriesareinthefinalstageoftheirproductcycle. Theiremploymentmay

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6




18

be declining and their unemployment rate higher than other industries, for
example, due totechnological change. The expected rateofunemployment,
giventheindustrialstructureofaregion,isequalto
1)

IMrt= ZEMjrtUNjt .
j

IMjtistheindustrialmix ofregionrattimet. EMjrt isthepercentofworkers
employed in the j-th industry, in the r-th region at time t. UNjt is the
unemploymentrateforthej-thindustryattimet.
A secondcontrolvariableinthemodelwas thelevelofeducationalattainment
(ED),measuredasthepercentofthelaborforceovertwenty-fivewithatleast
twelve years of formal education. This was used to control forlabor force
quality,sinceaworkerwithsome educationwouldhavelessdifficultyshould
hebecome unemployedandwouldbemore likelytofindajobmatch.
Third, an oilemployment variable (OIL) was used tocontrol forthe special
labormarketconditionsinsomeregionsoftheUnitedStates,createdby world
oilprice movements. This variable isthe percentofemployment in the oil
industrymultipliedby thepercentchangeintherealpriceofoil.
Fourth, a measure of states'unemployment insurance benefitgenerosity was
included intheregressions. The measure used here was theaverage weekly
benefitdividedby theaverageweekly wage inmanufacturing(RR). Thiswas
used to account forthe possibility thathigh benefits encourage unemployed
workers to remain idle. Higher benefits may also encourage unemployed
workers to search longer for a new job, rather than take the firstjob that
comes their way. This raises the average duration of unemployment and
hencetheunemploymentrate. The datausedwerefrom 1964 to 1985,pooled
overthe48 contiguousstates. Theresultsofordinaryleastsquaresestimation
were:
2) UN = -1.37 + .054UD + .754IM + .008ED - 4.05RR + .0010IL, R2 =.43
(2.44) (8.24)
(23.4) (1.30)
(3.30)
(1.05)

The numbers in parentheses are the absolute value of the t-statistics. The
union density variable is highly significant and its coefficient suggests an
increaseinuniondensity,sayfrom 10to20 percent,raisestheunemployment
rate by about half a percentage point. This number may not appear
particularlylarge,butinthestateofIllinoisthiswouldhave amounted toover
FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6




19

31,000 jobsin 1988. However, thisequationestimatesan averageeffectover
aperiodof22 years. The secondresultofthecollectiveactionmodel predicts
thatthiseffectvariesaccordingtothenationalconditionofthelabormarket.
As a simple testofthissecond hypothesis, the same equation was estimated
for each of the 22 years in the sample, again using data from the 48
contiguousstates. Fortunately,forthepurpose ofthisanalysis,thetime span
contains spells ofboth, very high and fairlymodest national unemployment
rates. Itis,therefore,possibletoexamine theeffectsofunionpresenceon the
unemployment rate over a broad spectrum of labor market conditions. For
example,thisperiodincludesthemiddleand late1960s,when unemployment
was extremely low. Italso includes the recessionsbrought about by the oil
price rises of 1973 and 1979. The theory predicts that the coefficient
estimateson uniondensityshouldbeespeciallylargeandsignificantwhen the
national unemployment rate is high, and conversely when national
unemploymentislow.
The resultsoftheseestimationsaresummarized inFigure 1,and arestrongly
supportive of the hypothesis that unions have a far greater tendency to
generate excess capacity in the labor market when national labor market
conditionsarepoor. Figure 1plotstheestimatedcoefficienton uniondensity,
againsttheUnited States unemployment rate,between 1964 and 1985. The
collinearityoftheseseriesisstartling. The coefficientpicksup theperiodsof
highunemploymentduringtheearlyseventies,themid-seventiesandtheearly
eighties. Italsofollowsthelow unemploymentperiodsofthelatesixtiesand
late seventies. When the national unemployment rate is low, there isvery
little,ifany effectofunions on unemployment. For example, in 1968 when
the United States' unemployment was below 4 percent, the estimated
coefficienton union densitywas only .03,implyingthata 10percentincrease
inuniondensity,raisesastate'sunemploymentrateby lessthanone thirdofa
percent. However, in 1983 when thenationalunemploymentratewas almost
10 percent, the estimated coefficient is .25. This implies thata 10 percent
increaseinuniondensityraisestheunemployment rateby 2.5percent,which
inthestateofIllinoiswouldhaveamountedtoabout 150,000jobsin1983.
Data on laborunionsintheUnited Statesstronglysupportthehypothesisthat
rent-seeking organizations worsen the effect of a recession. On average,
between 1964 and 1980, the statescomprising theindustrialMidwest region
allrank in the top ten most heavily unionized states.17 Itisnot surprising,
therefore,thatthisregionwas thehardesthit,interms ofunemployment (see
Table4),duringtherecessionoftheearly 1980s.
FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6




20

Figure 1

UD coefficient and % US unemployment rate
percent

In summary, both the hypotheses of the collective action model are well
supported by regional United States data. More exhaustive and detailed
analyses has been completed using other sets of regional data. Standard
Metropolitan StatisticalArea (SMSA) datafor 34 citiesin theUnited States
has yielded strong results in favor of the collective action model. Similar
robustresults have been found, using regional dataforBritain.18As can be
seen inTable 2,theolderregions sufferedconsiderably during therecession
oftheearly 1980s,and theseareby farthemost heavilyunionizedregionsin
Britain. The overallevidence suggests,therefore,thatthepatternsofrelative
prosperity and excess capacity in the industrial Midwest have also been
observedinothercountries1olderregions.

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6




21

Implications for the Future
What are the prospects for the older regions and countries? Are they
perpetuallyconfinedtoapathofslow growth? Willtheyalwaysbe subjectto
severe recessions, brought on by supply and demand shocks? In particular,
whataretheprospectsfortheindustrialMidwest inthiscontext?Thereareno
straightforwardanswerstothesequestions. The finalpartofthispapertriesto
evaluatefirst,whether theMidwest has improved itsgrowth potentialand its
economic resilience. Second, whether the position of the Midwest in this
respecthasimprovedrelativetotheotherregionsoftheUnitedStates.
The recessionsofthe 1970sandearly 1980shave ledtoashake-outincertain
industriesand,accordingtothecollectiveactiontheory,theheavilyunionized
industries are the most vulnerable to downturns in economic activity.
Consequently, a region's labor force should comprise proportionately fewer
laborunion members aftera severe recession. This hasbeen thecase in the
United States as a whole, where union density fell from 26 to 17 percent
between 1973 and 1988.19 Unfortunately, it is not possible to say with
certaintyhow theseeffectshave been distributedregionally,because data on
regionaluniondensityarenotavailableafter1982. Itispossible,however, to
gathersome information on thedirectionofunion densityintheMidwest by
lookingattheregion'sindustrialstructure.
The data in Table 5 show the annual percent change in employment by
industry forthenine Census regions of theUnited Statesbetween 1973 and
1988. The formeryearwas chosenbecauseitprecedestherecessionresulting
from the first oil price shock. During this period, employment in the
industrialMidwest regiongrew by abouthalfthenationalaverage. The most
heavily unionized sectors, namely, mining, construction, manufacturing and
transportation,20grew atamuch slowerrateintheMidwest regioncompared
with thenationaltrend. Inparticular,manufacturing employment contracted
atfive times the national average rate, falling from one third to less than a
quarter of the region's total employment. The biggest growth sector in the
region was services, where union density is typically low. These trends
suggest that union density in the Midwest region has fallen. The shifts in
Midwest employment by sectorand theirrelativeimportancearedisplayedin
Figure 2, which shows the number of jobs that were lost relative to the
national trend. For example, ifmanufacturing employment in the Midwest
region had only contracted at the same rate as the remainder of the United
States,therewould havebeenover 1.1millionmore manufacturingjobsinthe

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6




22

region. The graph indicates that the biggest effect in private sector
employment was in the manufacturing sector. However, thegrowth ratesof
thewholesaleandretailtradeand servicesectors,bothofwhich contain very
low proportions of union members, were below the national average. In
contrasttotheeffectfrom themanufacturingsector,thiseffectwould tendto
increase union density in the Midwest region relative to other regions.
Therefore, while the Midwest has probably losta large percentage of union
workers, there is some doubt as to whether the loss has been above the
nationaltrend.
T a b le 5

Percent change in em ploym ent by sector, 1973-1988
min
New England
Mid-Atlantic
East-North-Central
West-North-Central
South Atlantic
East-South-Central
West-South-Central
Mountain
Pacific
U.S.

10.0
-2.0
-0.7
-1.2
-1.3
0.8
2.5
0.0
2.1
0.7

con______man

tran

W&R

-0.3
-2.0
-1.5
0.3
0.6
0.1
0.9
2.5
1.7
-0.3

1.0
-0.1
0.3
0.9
2.1
1.9
1.8
2.8
1.6
1.1

2.9
1.6
1.9
2.1
4.0
2.9
3.0
3.6
3.5
2.7

2.5
1.3
0.5
0.5
1.7
0.4
0.4
0.8
3.5
1.4

fin
3.8
2.4
2.7
2.9
4.1
2.9
3.8
4.3
4.2
3.3

ser
4.5
3.6
3.7
3.9
5.8
4.2
4.9
5.7
5.2
4.5

QOV

total

1.3
0.9
0.9
1.2
2.6
1.9
2.6
2.4
1.7
1.7

2.1
1.1
1.0
1.8
3.0
2.0
2.7
3.4
3.1
2.1

As averyrough estimateofregionalunion density,thevalueofuniondensity
was calculated, given the industrial structure of each region for 1972-1 and
1988. Thatis,theexpected union densitywas calculated,assuming thateach
sectorisunionizedtothesame extentineveryregion.21The resultsaregiven
inTable6. Interms ofitsrankingineachoftheseyears,theMidwestregion
hasgone from thirdtofifth. Over thelong term,one would expectfootloose
industries to locate away from high labor cost areas, and that the greatest
contractions would occur in the least competitive (high input cost) sectors.
These two effects would tend to equalize the rates of union density across
regions. In other words, one would anticipate thatas the ’younger' regions
(the south and west) mature, they will eventually catch up with their older
counterparts,intermsoftheirinstitutionalstructure.

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6




23

Figure 2

Changes in employment in Midwest, 1973-86
(relative to national trend)
millions

Table 6

Estimated Union Density Using Industrial Structure
___________________________________ 1972______________ 1988
New England
Mid-Atlantic
East-North-Central
West-North-Central
South Atlantic
East-South-Central
West-South-Central
Mountain
Pacific
U.S.

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6




30.4
30.5
32.0
29.9
32.2
33.1
31.2
29.9
29.5
31.1

15.2
15.7
16.3
16.5
16.4
17.7
16.8
16.4
16.0
16.2

24




In summary, union density appears to have fallen in the Midwest, but the
evidencesuggeststhatthisreductionhasonlybeen slightlyabovethenational
trend. The collective action hypothesis implies that,so faras the effects of
laborunionsareconcerned,theMidwestregionhascorrespondinglyincreased
itsprospects for growth, but that is true for the United States as a whole.
However, as discussed above, labor unions are one of many interestgroups
thatreduce growth potentialand economic resilience. Iftheolderregions of
the United States contain the highest concentration of labor unions, they
probably contain other growth-retarding groups. Unlike labor unions, these
othergroups may nothavebeen diminishedby therecentrecessions. Indeed,
itisoftenthecasethatonceformed,thesetypesoforganizationsdo noteasily
break apart.22 This implies that the Midwest's economy will continue to
encounter difficultiesadjustingtoeconomic shocks. On theotherhand, one
might reasonably ask why unions would engage in rent-seekingbehavior, if
they are aware that eventually their members are likely to become
unemployed? Thatis,thesimplefactthateconomic participantsareaware of
the damage caused by exclusive, rent-seeking coalitions might change the
behavior ofthese coalitions. Such awareness may alsoextendtopoliticians,
who may enactlegislationtoreducetheeffectivenessofthesegroups.^

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6

25

Footnotes
^See Sachs, and Bruno and Sachs.
^This paper defines the industrial Midwest as the East-North Central Census region o f the United
States or the states of Ohio, Michigan, Illinois, Indiana, and Wisconsin.
'i

The new classical school includes among its most prominent members, Robert Lucas, Thomas
Sargent, and more recently, Robert Barro.
4 See Olson (1965).
^Hardin makes extensive use o f this paradigm in his analysis o f collective action.
6 See G.D.H. Cole.

7'The

term 'political and economic stability' requires elaboration. In many cases successful
collusion has occurred after or during destabilizing events, for example, the formation o f the
teamsters union during the Great Depression. By 'stable' I mean absence o f revolution or wars
that fundamentally alter the political and economic regimes.
^See Gersuny.
^Beside reducing intraunion bargaining costs, the seniority criterion has other advantages. First,
using seniority restricts management from arbitrarily dismissing or promoting employees and is,
therefore, considered to be a 'fair' procedure. Second, rewarding seniority gives an incentive for
workers to provide firms with a reliable source of labor, reducing quits and thereby lowering
training costs. Third, the seniority rule can be justified on utilitarian grounds, since an older
worker who is made redundant would have less chance o f finding alternative employment than a
younger counterpart. Fourth, more senior workers will have acquired more firm specific human
capital, so it may benefit both the firm and the worker to retain more experienced workers.
^ F o r example, see Lucas (1975) and Gertler (1982).
1 1See Alchian (1970).

12

AZ,For example, see Fitousse and Phelps, who describe a model where firms are reluctant to adjust
their output price for fear o f losing market share.
l^T his term is drawn from physics to describe a phenomenon where the strength o f the magnetic
field in a ferromagnetic material depends on its 'magnetic history', as well as the magnetizing
current presently applied to it. Thus, in the hysteresis theory o f unemployment, the present rate o f
unemployment depends on past rates.
^ F o r example, see Blanchard and Summers and Lindbeck and Snower (1986 and 1987).
•^ S ee Oswald (1984).
^ I t should be noted that Lindbeck and Snower (1987) implicitly incorporate wage stickiness in
their model. The sequence of events in their model is first, the union sets a wage, given the
expected labor demand schedule which contains a random component. Second, the random
component is realized and the firm sets employment according to the now known' labor demand
schedule. Once this occurs, the union must wait until the next period to adjust its wage.
^ M ich igan , Illinois, Ohio, Indiana and Wisconsin, are ranked, 3 , 6 , 7 , 8 and 10, respectively.
l^T he results presented in this paper and those mentioned here are in Kendix, and Kendix and
Olson.

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6




26

1Q

Private sector non-agricultural union density was only 12.9 percent in 1988.

2^1 have ignored the government sector because theoretical evidence suggests that public sector
unions operate quite differently from those in the private sector. For example, see Oswald, Grout
and Ulph.

21

The expected union density in region r at time t, given its industrial structure is
where j denotes the industry.

EMjrtUDjt,

2 2 See Olson (1982), page 40
^ A recent example is in Britain, where there is proposed legislation to break down barriers
within the legal profession by eliminating the distinction between solicitors and barristers.

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6




27




Bibliography
Alchian, A. "Information Costs, Pricing and Resource Unemployment."
Chapter 1 in Phelps etal,Microeconomic Foundations of Employment and
Inflation Theory. W. W. Norton& Company, Inc.,1970.
Barro, R. J. and H. I. Grossman, Money, Employment and Inflation.
CambridgeUniversityPress,1976.
Blanchard, 0. J. and L. H. Summers. "Hysteresis and the European
Unemployment Problem." NBER Working Paper Series No. 1950 (June
1986).
Bruno, M. and J. D. Sachs, Economics of Worldwide Stagflation. Oxford,
1985.
Buchanan, J. M. and G. Tullock, The Calculus of Consent: Logical
Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. The UniversityofMichiganPress,
1962;reprint1983.
Coe, D. T. "Nominal Wages, The NAIRU and Wage Flexibility." DECD
Economic Studies (Autumn 1985):87-126.
Coe, D. T. and F. Bagliardi. "Nominal Wage Determination in Ten DECD
Countries." OECD Working Paper Series No. 19(1985).
Cole,B.D. H.,A Short History of the British Working Class Movement, 17891947. London,B.Allen & Unwin, 1948.
Fitoussi, J. P. and E. S. Phelps. "Causes of the 1980s Slump in Europe."
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (2:1986):487-513.
Gersuny, C. "Origins of Seniority Provisions in Collective Bargaining."
Labor Law Journal (August 1982).
Gertler,M. "ImperfectInformationand Wage InertiaintheBusinessCycle."
Journal of Political Economy (October 1982).
Hardin,R. Collective Action. Published forResources fortheFuture by the
JohnHopkinsUniversityPress,1982.
Hulten,C. R. and R. M. Schwab. "RegionalProductivityGrowth intheU.S.
Manufacturing: 1951-78." The American Economic Review 74 (1:1984): 152162.
Kendix, M. "An Investigation Into the Effects of Labor Unions on
Unemployment With Decentralized Union-Firm Bargaining Structures:
FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6

28

Empirical Evidence for Britain, Canada and the United States." Ph.D.
dissertation,UniversityofMaryland, 1988.
Kendix, M. and M. Olson. "Changing Unemployment Rates in Europe and
the U.S.: Institutional Structure and Regional Variation" paper presented at
theI
nternationalEconomicAssociation,meetingsinVenice,Italy(September
1988).
Lindbeck, A. and D. J.Snower. "Union Activity,Unemployment Persistence
and Wage-Employment Ratchets." EuropeanEconomicReview21 (1987):
157-167.
Lucas Jr.,R. E. "An Equilibrium Model oftheBusiness Cycle." Journalof
PoliticalEconomy83 (December 1975).
Muellbauer, J. and R. Portes. "Macroeconomic Models with Quantity
Rationing." TheEconomicJournal(December 1987).
Olson, M. TheLogicofC
ollectiveAction:PublicGoodsandtheTheoryof
Groups. Cambridge, Massachusetts and London, England: Harvard
UniversityPress, 1965;reprint,1982.
Olson, M. TheRiseandDeclineofNations:EconomicGrowth,S
tagflation
andSocialRigidities.New Haven andLondon: YaleUniversityPress,1982.
Olson, M. "Maintaining a Healthy Business Climate: A Broader Perspective
on the Rates ofEconomic Growth and Unemployment in the Southern and
Southwestern States."I
nEnergyandtheSouthwestEconomy:Proceedingsof

the1985ConferenceonEnergyandtheSouthwestEconomyinDallas,Texas,

by theFederalReserve Bank ofDallas. Dallas Texas: Federal Reserve Bank
ofDallas,1906.
Oswald, A. J. "EfficientContracts are on theLabor Demand Curve: Theory
andFacts."I
ndustrialRelationsSector.PrincetonUniversity,WorkingPaper
SeriesNo.178(July 1984).
Oswald, A. J. ’’The Economic Theory of Trade Unions: An Introductory
Survey." ScandinavianJournalofEconomics87 (2: 1985): 160-193.
Oswald, A. J.,P. A. Grout and D. T. Ulph. "Uncertainty, Unions and the
Theory of Public Sector Labor Markets." I
ndustrialRelationsSection,
PrincetonUniversity,WorkingPaperSeriesNo. 176(July1984).
Sachs, J. D. "High Unemployment in Europe: Diagnosis and Policy
Implications."NBERWorkingPaperS
eriesNo. 1830(1986).

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6




29

Summers, L. H. "Why is the Unemployment Rate So Very High Near Full
Employment?” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (2:1986): 339-383.

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
June 1990, WP-1990-6




30

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
RESEARCH STAFF MEMORANDA, WORKING PAPERS AND STAFF STUDIES
The following lists papers developed in recent years by the Bank’s research staff. Copies of those
materials that are currently available can be obtained by contacting the Public Information Center
(312) 322-5111.
Working Paper Series—A series of research studies on regional economic issues relating to the Sev­
enth Federal Reserve District, and on financial and economic topics.
Regional Economic Issues
♦WP-82-1

Donna Craig Vandenbrink

“The Effects of Usury Ceilings:
the Economic Evidence,” 1982

David R. Allardice

“Small Issue Industrial Revenue Bond
Financing in the Seventh Federal
Reserve District,” 1982

WP-83-1

William A. Testa

“Natural Gas Policy and the Midwest
Region,” 1983

WP-86-1

Diane F. Siegel
William A. Testa

“Taxation of Public Utilities Sales:
State Practices and the Illinois Experience”

WP-87-1

Alenka S. Giese
William A. Testa

“Measuring Regional High Tech
Activity with Occupational Data”

WP-87-2

Robert H. Schnorbus
Philip R. Israilevich

“Alternative Approaches to Analysis of
Total Factor Productivity at the
Plant Level”

WP-87-3

Alenka S. Giese
William A. Testa

“Industrial R&D An Analysis of the
Chicago Area”

WP-89-1

William A. Testa

“Metro Area Growth from 1976 to 1985:
Theory and Evidence”

WP-89-2

William A. Testa
Natalie A. Davila

“Unemployment Insurance: A State
Economic Development Perspective”

WP-89-3

Alenka S. Giese

“A Window of Opportunity Opens for
Regional Economic Analysis: BEA Release
Gross State Product Data”

WP-89-4

Philip R. Israilevich
William A. Testa

“Determining Manufacturing Output
for States and Regions”

WP-89-5

Alenka S.Geise

“The Opening of Midwest Manufacturing
to Foreign Companies: The Influx of
Foreign Direct Investment”

WP-89-6

Alenka S. Giese
Robert H. Schnorbus

“A New Approach to Regional Capital Stock
Estimation: Measurement and
Performance”

**WP-82-2

♦Limited quantity available.
**Out of print.






Working Paper Series (cont'd)

WP-89-7

William A. Testa

“Why has Illinois Manufacturing Fallen
Behind the Region?”

WP-89-8

Alenka S. Giese
William A. Testa

“Regional Specialization and Technology
in Manufacturing”

WP-89-9

Christopher Erceg
Philip R. Israilevich
Robert H. Schnorbus

“Theory and Evidence of Two Competitive
Price Mechanisms for Steel”

WP-89-10

David R. Allardice
William A. Testa

“Regional Energy Costs and Business
Siting Decisions: An Illinois Perspective”

WP-89-21

William A. Testa

“Manufacturing’s Changeover to Services
in the Great Lakes Economy”

WP-90-1

P.R. Israilevich

“Construction of Input-Output Coefficients
with Flexible Functional Forms”

WP-90-4

Douglas D. Evanoff
Philip R. Israilevich

“Regional Regulatory Effects on
Bank Efficiency”

WP-90-5

Geoffrey J.D. Hewings

“Regional Growth and Development Theory:
Summary and Evaluation”

WP-90-6

Michael Kendix

“Institutional Rigidities as Barriers to Regional
Growth: A Midwest Perspective”

Issues in Financial Regulation
WP-89-11

Douglas D. Evanoff
Philip R. Israilevich
Randall C. Merris

“Technical Change, Regulation, and Economies
of Scale for Large Commercial Banks:
An Application of a Modified Version
of Shepard’s Lemma”

WP-89-12

Douglas D. Evanoff

“Reserve Account Management Behavior:
Impact of the Reserve Accounting Scheme
and Carry Forward Provision”

WP-89-14

George G. Kaufman

“Are Some Banks too Large to Fail?
Myth and Reality”

WP-89-16

Ramon P. De Gennaro
James T. Moser

“Variability and Stationarity of Term
Premia”

WP-89-17

Thomas Mondschean

“A Model of Borrowing and Lending
with Fixed and Variable Interest Rates”

WP-89-18

Charles W. Calomiris

“Do "Vulnerable" Economies Need Deposit
Insurance?: Lessons from the U.S.
Agricultural Boom and Bust of the 1920s”

♦Limited quantity available.
♦♦Out of print.

Working Paper Series (cont'd)

WP-89-23

George G. Kaufman

“The Savings and Loan Rescue of 1989:
Causes and Perspective”

WP-89-24

Elijah Brewer III

“The Impact of Deposit Insurance on S&L
Shareholders’ Risk/Return Trade-offs”

Macro Economic Issues
WP-89-13

David A. Aschauer

“Back of the G-7 Pack: Public Investment and
Productivity Growth in the Group of Seven”

WP-89-15

Kenneth N. Kuttner

“Monetary and Non-Monetary Sources
of Inflation: An Error Correction Analysis”

WP-89-19

Ellen R. Rissman

“Trade Policy and Union Wage Dynamics”

WP-89-20

Bruce C. Petersen
William A. Strauss

“Investment Cyclicality in Manufacturing
Industries”

WP-89-22

Prakash Loungani
Richard Rogerson
Yang-Hoon Sonn

“Labor Mobility, Unemployment and
Sectoral Shifts: Evidence from
Micro Data”

WP-90-2

Lawrence J. Christiano
Martin Eichenbaum

“Unit Roots in Real GNP: Do We Know,
and Do We Care?”

WP-90-3

Steven Strongin
Vefa Tarhan

“Money Supply Announcements and the Market’s
Perception of Federal Reserve Policy”

WP-90-7

Prakash Loungani
Mark Rush

“Sectoral Shifts in Interwar Britain”

WP-90-8

Kenneth N. Kuttner

“Money, Output, and Inflation: Testing
The P-Star Restrictions”

WP-90-9

Lawrence J. Christiano
Martin Eichenbaum

“Current Real Business Cycle Theories
and Aggregate Labor Market Fluctuations”

WP-90-10

S. Rao Aiyagari
Lawrence J. Christiano
Martin Eichenbaum

“The Output, Employment, And Interest Rate
Effects of Government Consumption”

*Limited quantity available.
**Out of print.



Staff Memoranda—A series of research papers in draft form prepared by members of the Research
Department and distributed to the academic community for review and comment. (Series discon­
tinued in December, 1988. Later works appear in working paper series).
**SM-81-2

George G. Kaufman

“Impact of Deregulation on the Mortgage
Market,” 1981

**SM-81-3

Alan K. Reichert

“An Examination of the Conceptual Issues
Involved in Developing Credit Scoring Models
in the Consumer Lending Field,” 1981

Robert D. Laurent

“A Critique of the Federal Reserve’s New
Operating Procedure,” 1981

George G. Kaufman

“Banking as a Line of Commerce: The Changing
Competitive Environment,” 1981

SM-82-1

Harvey Rosenblum

“Deposit Strategies of Minimizing the Interest
Rate Risk Exposure of S&Ls,” 1982

♦SM-82-2

George Kaufman
Larry Mote
Harvey Rosenblum

“Implications of Deregulation for Product
Lines and Geographical Markets of Financial
Instititions,” 1982

•SM-82-3

George G. Kaufman

“The Fed’s Post-October 1979 Technical
Operating Procedures: Reduced Ability
to Control Money,” 1982

SM-83-1

John J. Di Clemente

“The Meeting of Passion and Intellect:
A History of the term ‘Bank’ in the
Bank Holding Company Act,” 1983

SM-83-2

Robert D. Laurent

“Comparing Alternative Replacements for
Lagged Reserves: Why Settle for a Poor
Third Best?” 1983

**SM-83-3

G. O. Bierwag
George G. Kaufman

“A Proposal for Federal Deposit Insurance
with Risk Sensitive Premiums,” 1983

♦SM-83-4

Henry N. Goldstein
Stephen E. Haynes

“A Critical Appraisal of McKinnon’s
World Money Supply Hypothesis,” 1983

SM-83-5

George Kaufman
Larry Mote
Harvey Rosenblum

“The Future of Commercial Banks in the
Financial Services Industry,” 1983

SM-83-6

Vefa Tarhan

“Bank Reserve Adjustment Process and the
Use of Reserve Carryover Provision and
the Implications of the Proposed
Accounting Regime,” 1983

SM-83-7

John J. Di Clemente

“The Inclusion of Thrifts in Bank
Merger Analysis,” 1983

SM-84-1

Harvey Rosenblum
Christine Pavel

“Financial Services in Transition: The
Effects of Nonbank Competitors,” 1984

SM-81-4
**SM-81-5




♦Limited quantity available.
**Out of print.

Staff Memoranda (cont'd)

SM-84-2

George G. Kaufman

“The Securities Activities of Commercial
Banks,” 1984

SM-84-3

George G. Kaufman
Larry Mote
Harvey Rosenblum

“Consequences of Deregulation for
Commercial Banking”

SM-84-4

George G. Kaufman

“The Role of Traditional Mortgage Lenders
in Future Mortgage Lending: Problems
and Prospects”

SM-84-5

Robert D. Laurent

“The Problems of Monetary Control Under
Quasi-Contemporaneous Reserves”

SM-85-1

Harvey Rosenblum
M. Kathleen O’Brien
John J. Di Clemente

“On Banks, Nonbanks, and Overlapping
Markets: A Reassessment of Commercial
Banking as a Line of Commerce”

SM-85-2

Thomas G. Fischer
William H. Gram
George G. Kaufman
Larry R. Mote

“The Securities Activities of Commercial
Banks: A Legal and Economic Analysis”

SM-85-3

George G. Kaufman

“Implications of Large Bank Problems and
Insolvencies for the Banking System and
Economic Policy”

SM-85-4

Elijah Brewer, III

“The Impact of Deregulation on The True
Cost of Savings Deposits: Evidence
From Illinois and Wisconsin Savings &
Loan Association”

SM-85-5

Christine Pavel
Harvey Rosenblum

“Financial Darwinism: Nonbanks—
and Banks—Are Surviving”

SM-85-6

G. D. Koppenhaver

“Variable-Rate Loan Commitments,
Deposit Withdrawal Risk, and
Anticipatory Hedging”

SM-85-7

G. D. Koppenhaver

“A Note on Managing Deposit Flows
With Cash and Futures Market
Decisions”

SM-85-8

G. D. Koppenhaver

“Regulating Financial Intermediary
Use of Futures and Option Contracts:
Policies and Issues”

SM-85-9

Douglas D. Evanoff

“The Impact of Branch Banking
on Service Accessibility”

SM-86-1

George J. Benston
George G. Kaufman

“Risks and Failures in Banking:
Overview, History, and Evaluation”

SM-86-2

David Alan Aschauer

“The Equilibrium Approach to Fiscal
Policy”

’•'Limited quantity available.
**Out of print.



Staff Memoranda (cont'd)

SM-86-3

George G. Kaufman

“Banking Risk in Historical Perspective”

SM-86-4

Elijah Brewer III
Cheng Few Lee

“The Impact of Market, Industry, and
Interest Rate Risks on Bank Stock Returns”

SM-87-1

Ellen R. Rissman

“Wage Growth and Sectoral Shifts:
New Evidence on the Stability of
the Phillips Curve”

SM-87-2

Randall C. Merris

“Testing Stock-Adjustment Specifications
and Other Restrictions on Money
Demand Equations”

SM-87-3

George G. Kaufman

“The Truth About Bank Runs”

SM-87-4

Gary D. Koppenhaver
Roger Stover

“On The Relationship Between Standby
Letters of Credit and Bank Capital”

SM-87-5

Gary D. Koppenhaver
Cheng F. Lee

“Alternative Instruments for Hedging
Inflation Risk in the Banking Industry”

SM-87-6

Gary D. Koppenhaver

“The Effects of Regulation on Bank
Participation in the Market”

SM-87-7

Vefa Tarhan

“Bank Stock Valuation: Does
Maturity Gap Matter?”

SM-87-8

David Alan Aschauer

“Finite Horizons, Intertemporal
Substitution and Fiscal Policy”

SM-87-9

Douglas D. Evanoff
Diana L. Fortier

“Reevaluation of the Structure-ConductPerformance Paradigm in Banking”

SM-87-10

David Alan Aschauer

“Net Private Investment and Public Expenditure
in the United States 1953-1984”

SM-88-1

George G. Kaufman

“Risk and Solvency Regulation of
Depository Institutions: Past Policies
and Current Options”

SM-88-2

David Aschauer

“Public Spending and the Return to Capital”

SM-88-3

David Aschauer

“Is Government Spending Stimulative?”

SM-88-4

George G. Kaufman
Larry R. Mote

“Securities Activities of Commercial Banks:
The Current Economic and Legal Environment

SM-88-5

Elijah Brewer, III

“A Note on the Relationship Between
Bank Holding Company Risks and Nonbank
Activity”

SM-88-6

G. O. Bierwag
George G. Kaufman
Cynthia M. Latta

“Duration Models: A Taxonomy”

G. O. Bierwag
George G. Kaufman

“Durations of Nondefault-Free Securities”

♦Limited quantity available.
♦♦Out of print.



Staff Memoranda (cont'd)

SM-88-7

David Aschauer

“Is Public Expenditure Productive?”

SM-88-8

Elijah Brewer, III
Thomas H. Mondschean

“Commercial Bank Capacity to Pay
Interest on Demand Deposits:
Evidence from Large Weekly
Reporting Banks”

SM-88-9

Abhijit V. Banerjee
Kenneth N. Kuttner

“Imperfect Information and the
Permanent Income Hypothesis”

SM-88-10

David Aschauer

“Does Public Capital Crowd out
Private Capital?”

SM-88-11

Ellen Rissman

“Imports, Trade Policy, and
Union Wage Dynamics”

Staff Studies A series of research studies dealing with various economic policy issues on a national
level.
SS-83-1
**SS-83-2

Harvey Rosenblum
Diane Siegel

“Competition in Financial Services:
the Impact of Nonbank Entry,” 1983

Gillian Garcia

“Financial Deregulation: Historical
Perspective and Impact of the Garn-St
Germain Depository Institutions Act
of 1982,” 1983

♦Limited quantity available.
**Out of print.