View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Why are Immigrants’ Incarceration
Rates So Low? Evidence on Selective
Immigration, Deterrence, and
Deportation
Kristin F. Butcher and Anne Morrison Piehl

WP 2005-19

Why are Immigrants' Incarceration Rates So Low?
Evidence on Selective Immigration, Deterrence, and Deportation

Kristin F. Butcher
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
230 South LaSalle Street, Chicago IL 60604
kbutcher@frbchi.org

Anne Morrison Piehl
Rutgers University and NBER
Department of Economics, 75 Hamilton Street
New Brunswick, NJ 08901
apiehl@economics.rutgers.edu

November 2005

We appreciate the excellent research assistance of Yonita Grigorova and Kyung Park. We thank
David Card, Jennifer Hunt, J. Gregory Robinson, Karen Humes, and participants in presentations
at the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Rutgers
University, and the Society of Labor Economists 2005 annual meeting for helpful discussions.
Points of view expressed in this paper do not represent the official view of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago or any other entity. All errors are our own.

Why are Immigrants' Incarceration Rates So Low?
Evidence on Selective Immigration, Deterrence, and Deportation
Much of the concern about immigration adversely affecting crime derives from the fact that
immigrants tend to have characteristics in common with native born populations that are
disproportionately incarcerated. This perception of a link between immigration and crime led to
legislation in the 1990s increasing punishments toward criminal aliens. Despite the widespread
perception of a link between immigration and crime, immigrants have much lower
institutionalization (incarceration) rates than the native born. More recently arrived immigrants
have the lowest comparative incarceration rates, and this difference increased from 1980 to 2000.
We present a model of immigrant self-selection that suggests why, despite poor labor market
outcomes, immigrants may have better incarceration outcomes than the native-born. We examine
whether the improvement in immigrants’ relative incarceration rates over the last three decades
is linked to increased deportation, immigrant self-selection, or deterrence. Our evidence suggests
that deportation and deterrence of immigrants’ crime commission from the threat of deportation
are not driving the results. Rather, immigrants appear to be self-selected to have low criminal
propensities and this has increased over time.

Why are Immigrants' Incarceration Rates So Low?
Evidence on Selective Immigration, Deterrence, and Deportation

I. Introduction
Much of the concern about immigration adversely affecting crime derives from the fact
that immigrants tend to have characteristics in common with native born populations that are
disproportionately incarcerated: they have low average levels of education, very low average
wages, and many are young, male, and Hispanic. For similar reasons, there are general concerns
about immigration adding to the “underclass” in the United States, and thus increasing
dependence on government cash assistance, subsidized medical care, decreasing homeownership,
and generally creating pockets of entrenched poverty with the adverse social outcomes that tends
to imply. During the 1990s, when immigration rates were high and crime rates were high and
rising, observers posited a link between immigration and crime and several significant pieces of
federal legislation were enacted to increase criminal penalties for noncitizens.
Economic theories tend to support the concern about a link between immigration and
crime. The economic model of crime (Becker 1968 ), for example, posits that those who have
poor labor market outcomes, and thus low opportunity costs from giving up activities in the legal
sector, will be more likely to engage in criminal activity. Many studies have documented
immigrants’ poor labor market outcomes (see for example, Borjas (2004)), in part because of the
low skills that many immigrants bring with them and in part because migration forces the loss of
other elements of human capital (e.g., language, social networks) that enable individuals to make
full use of their skills. A unidimensional model of skills would lead one to expect that a
population with poor labor market outcomes would also have poor outcomes in other arenas –
crime, health, family life, etc. – that society values.

In this paper, we examine immigrants’ institutionalization rates as a proxy for their
incarceration and, thus, their involvement in criminal activity. Contrary to what one might
expect from the labor market studies, immigrants have very low rates of institutionalization
compared to the native-born. Their relative rates of institutionalization have fallen over the last
three decades. In addition, more recent cohorts have better criminal justice outcomes than earlier
cohorts, and synthetic cohort analyses show that with time in the country, immigrants’ relative
rates of institutionalization tend to decrease. If one assumed that the “skills” people bring when
they immigrate predict outcomes the same way as they do for natives, this is precisely the
opposite of what one would predict from most synthetic cohort analyses of immigrants’ labor
market outcomes. After documenting immigrants’ low institutionalization rates, the cohort
patterns in institutionalization, and how these have changed over time, we investigate potential
reasons for these changes. Are the much lower relative institutionalization rates of immigrants in
2000 compared to 1990 due to changes in self-selection in immigration? Did the changes in laws
enacted in the 1990s that increased penalties for criminal noncitizens change out-migration
patterns through increased deportation? Or did these increasing penalties simply deter
immigrants from committing crimes in the United States?
We present a variety of tests of these potential explanations. We rule out deportation as
an important factor for the observed differences in institutionalization. Our investigation of
enumeration practices also fails to explain the results. Instead, the evidence suggests that there
are multiple dimensions to who self-selects to immigrate to the United States. Over the 1990s,
those immigrants who chose to come to the United States were less likely to be involved in
criminal activity than earlier immigrants and the native born.

2

II. Immigrant Self-Selection
The scholarly literature on immigration is much more voluminous with regard to wages
and employment than it is with regard to criminal justice outcomes. Borjas (2004) provides a
thorough accounting of the experience of immigrants in the U.S. labor market. Male immigrants
have slightly lower employment rates, but wage rates that are substantially below those of the
native born. While in 1960 immigrants’ wages were 6.5% above those of natives, by 2000 they
were 19% lower. Those who arrived most recently have larger deficits: in 1960 those who
arrived recently earned 9% below natives, a gap that expanded to 38% in 1990. In addition to,
and because of, beginning at lower relative earnings, immigrant cohorts arriving after 1970 are
not expected to fully assimilate to the higher native earnings rates.
Borjas (1987) provides a framework for understanding these changes in immigrants’
labor market outcomes over time. He adapts a version of the Roy model (1951) to the problem
of immigrant self-selection. Suppose in each country, there is a distribution of skill that is
transferable across country boundaries. However, skill is translated into earnings in different
ways in each country, and the distribution of earnings is more unequal in some countries than in
others. Thus, being low skilled may translate into a very different earnings level in one country
than in another. Immigrants will choose to move to a country if their earnings, given their skill
set, will be higher than in their country of origin.
This model gives insight into the change in immigrants’ earnings in the U.S. over the last
four decades. As the sending countries changed from predominantly European countries to
predominantly Latin American and Asian countries there was a shift in the skills of immigrants
coming to the U.S. (because European countries tend to have earnings distributions that are more
compressed than the United States, and Latin American countries tend to have distributions that
are more dispersed). Thus, the model predicts there would be a shift in the rank in the skill

3

distribution of those who immigrate to the U.S. Those from Sweden, for example, who find their
“offer” from the U.S. earnings distribution would be higher than the offer from their own
country’s earnings distribution would tend to be of high skill. On the other hand, immigrants
from Mexico would tend to come from the lower end of the wage distribution, as those with high
levels of skill would prefer the high wages from the relatively unequal wage distribution in
Mexico. This model demonstrates why it might be that in recent years the United States drew
immigrants who where predominantly low-skilled.1
There is recent evidence on the issue of self-selection of Mexican immigrants. Chiquiar
and Hanson (2005) examine the question of immigrant self-selection from Mexico using
Mexican and U.S. Census data from 1990 and 2000. Contrary to what one might expect from the
Borjas-Roy model, they find that Mexican immigrants in the U.S. tend to be selected from the
middle to upper part of the observable skill distribution compared to Mexicans who remain in
Mexico. Ibarraran and Lubotsky (2005), on the other hand, find that households that report
having members who have emigrated to the U.S. tend to be selected from the lower part of the
observable skill distribution.2
The focus in the above papers is on selection along a dimension of observable skills. Our
focus, on the other hand, is on unobservable attributes that determine criminal involvement and
other social outcomes. Perhaps migration decisions depend on returns in other sectors in
addition to the labor market. For example, perhaps people consider their returns to illegal

1

It also suggests that as the U.S. wage distribution became more unequal, we should have seen a change
in the skills of immigrants coming to the United States. Interestingly, the most recent cohort in 2000
appeared to have much higher relative wages than the most recent cohort in 1980 and 1990, a fact that can
be attributed to engineers and computer scientists (Borjas and Friedberg 2004).

2

The difference between these likely arises because Ibarraran and Lubotsky’s methodology should pick
up those individuals who are undercounted in the U.S. Census – young, low-skilled single men. We will
address the undercount issue below. In addition, Ibarraran and Lubotsky suggest that education among
Mexican immigrants in the U.S. is likely to be misreported.

4

activities as well. This might cause those with high illegal earnings to remain in the source
country rather than taking the risk of developing capacities in a new legal environment. Or,
perhaps the migration costs vary across individuals in ways that are correlated with success in
multiple social domains (including criminality), as would be the case if social networks in the
U.S. ease migration and those networks are more stable if the members are successful in one
domain or another.
To see this, consider the Roy model presented in Borjas (1994) in which migration
depends on an index that is a function of wages in the source and host country as well as
migration costs:
(1)

I  ( 1   0   )  ( 1   0 )

where 1 is the mean log earnings (of immigrants) in the host country,  0 is the mean log
earnings of immigrants in the source country,  is the cost of migration divided by the wage in
the source country (which Borjas calls the “time cost” of migration), and  1 and  0 are the
deviations in earnings in the two countries. When I > 0, the individual migrates; when I < 0, the
individual stays.
Borjas analyzes the case where migration costs are constant in the population (and thus
proportional to wages), but if migration costs vary with social networks (Chiquiar and Hanson
2005 and Hanson forthcoming) or other factors related to success in the U.S., this reduces the
cost of emigrating from the source country. In this case, the Roy model implies that those with
productive social networks will require a lower wage premium to reach the migration threshold.
This model of selection implies that the correlation between wages and other outcomes at the
country level may not be as strong as it is in individual-level data for the native born.

5

Finally, consider what happens when policy toward immigrants changes in the U.S., as
happened in the 1990s when criminal penalties for noncitizens were dramatically increased and
eligibility for welfare was reduced. This would reduce the benefits to migration, as the index in
(1) is now a function of these other attributes of the package associated with living in the U.S.:
(2)

I  f ( 1 ,  0 ,  ,  ,  0 ,  )

where I is negatively related to  , the expected policy environment. This deterrent effect will
itself affect the migration decision, reinforcing other mechanisms that select immigrants with
better social outcomes, including lower criminal propensities.
If immigrants with different social networks face different migration costs, then the
process of migration may be one that peels apart different dimensions of skill and selection.
Among immigrants, those with poor wage outcomes may nonetheless have relatively good social
outcomes. As a brief illustration, we show the relationship in the U.S. between mean real wages
and three other outcomes (average institutionalization, welfare receipt, and labor force
participation) for the 20 countries with the largest immigrant populations in the U.S.3 In Figures
1, 2, and 3, the line is a country-level linear regression weighted by the size of the immigrant
population in the United States. We also plot the analogous information for the native-born in the
U.S. While the relationship between real wages and the other outcomes is negative for
institutionalization and welfare receipt and positive for labor force participation, as predicted by
a one dimensional model of skill, there is a great deal of variation. For instance, there are many
countries whose people have very low wages in the United States, but also have very low rates of
institutionalization and welfare receipt, and higher rates of labor force participation than
expected given their wages. Immigrants may have poor real wage outcomes, but relatively good

3

The data are for men aged 18-40 in the 2000 Census. The data are described later in the text. The top
immigrant countries were selected based on the number of men in this age group in the 1990 Census.

6

outcomes in one or another social domain, suggesting selection along more than one dimension
of “skill.”

III. Immigrants’ Non-Labor Market Outcomes
The discussion above gives some insight into why comparisons of natives’ and
immigrants’ labor market and non-labor market outcomes may give a different picture of how
immigrants fare in the United States. The literature on immigration has analyzed many
outcomes, providing a broader picture of how immigration may affect the United States. For
example, research shows that immigrants are less likely to use welfare than similar natives
(Butcher and Hu 2000). Home ownership, often cited as an important feature in American
society both as a stabilizing influence and a generator of wealth, also differs between immigrants
and the native born. Immigrants are less likely to own homes than the native born, and this gap
widened between 1980 and 2000. However, this gap is mainly driven by location choice and
country of origin of immigrants. Increases in immigrant enclaves in the future may be expected
to generate increases in demand for owner-occupied housing (Borjas 2002). Additional research
has examined the participation of immigrants in mainstream financial institutions. Use of banks
and participation in financial markets may be important ways that individuals can improve their
financial wellbeing. If immigrants are reluctant to participate in these markets, then they may
have more difficulty assimilating to U.S. standards of living over time. Recent evidence
suggests that immigrants are less likely to participate in financial markets, that these differences
tend to persist, and may be driven by immigrants’ experience with financial institutions in their
countries of origin (Osili and Paulson 2004a, b).
Research on the crime outcomes of immigrants is limited (Mears 2002). Immigrant
males were much less likely to be institutionalized than native-born males in the United States in

7

1980 and 1990 and the lower observed institutionalization propensities of immigrants are
particularly striking given the demographic characteristics well-known to be highly correlated
with crime (such as education). In addition, more recent immigrants have the lowest
institutionalization rates of all immigrant cohorts, when analyzed relative to the experience of the
native born (Butcher and Piehl 1998a). This evidence is consistent with self-report data on
criminal activity: youth born abroad are statistically significantly less likely than native-born
youth to report being criminally active (Butcher and Piehl 1998b).
Taken together, this research gives a rich picture of how immigrants fare in the United
States, how that has changed over time, and how immigrants are likely to affect the United
States. The literature reveals different patterns depending on the outcome considered. In some
cases, these outcomes are quite different from what one might expect given immigrants’ labor
market outcomes.

IV. Comparison of Immigrant and Native Born Institutionalization Rates across Three Decades
A. Descriptive Statistics
We use data from the 5% Public Use Microsamples of the U.S. Census in 1980, 1990,
and 2000 to examine institutionalization rates for men ages 18-40. 4 Butcher and Piehl (1998b)
shows that for this population, institutionalization closely approximates incarceration.5
Descriptive statistics for native-born citizens and immigrants are reported in Table 1.6

4

We omit those born in outlying areas of the United States and those born abroad to U.S. citizens in order
to simplify the analysis.

5

The 1980 Census identifies the incarcerated among the institutionalized. For men aged 18-40, at least
70% of the institutionalized are incarcerated. In addition, Butcher and Piehl (1998b) demonstrates that
limiting the 1980 analysis to only those who are incarcerated does not substantively change the results.

6

Throughout the paper we reported estimates using the person weight reported by the Census (there are
no weights in 1980).

8

The educational distributions are very different for immigrants and the native born. In
1980, the proportions with some college and with a college degree were quite similar across the
two groups, while among immigrants the proportion without a high school degree was nearly
twice that of natives. The educational distribution for immigrants is essentially unchanged over
the past twenty years. Over this same period, the native born have greatly increased their
education – in 2000 only 12% had less than a high school degree and there was a 50% increase
in the number with some college education. By the end of the period under study, immigrants
were nearly three times as likely as the native born to have less than a high school education.
The fraction immigrant in the sample nearly tripled over this period – from approximately 6% to
about 17% -- and it is perhaps remarkable that the populations are not even more different.
As has been well-documented elsewhere, the racial and ethnic distributions for
immigrants and natives are quite different, and changing over time. Immigrants are much less
likely than natives to be white, non-Hispanic and much more likely be Asian and Hispanic.
These differences have grown in magnitude over time, with nearly 60% of immigrants in 2000
reporting their ethnicity as Hispanic and over 20% defining their race as Asian or Pacific
Islander.
In our analyses of immigrants over time, we categorize immigrants by their year of
arrival in the United States, generally grouping into five-year cohorts. These cohorts vary by
size both because of immigration and emigration patterns and also due to the age restriction on
the sample. Recent cohorts contain tens of thousands of members, while the earliest cohorts
available in any given Census contain about a thousand members, all at the oldest ages in the
sample. For our analyses we emphasize those who arrived in the U.S. more recently both
because of their relevance to policy discussions and for statistical precision.

9

In these data, “immigrant” is equivalent to “foreign born.” In many contexts, legal
distinctions are made between the foreign born who intend to become permanent residents, and
those who are more transient. For example, permanent resident aliens typically have the right to
work in the U.S., while those on a student visa do not. However, the important distinction in
terms of the legal treatment of criminal aliens is made between immigrants who have naturalized
and those who have not, since the latter are subject to deportation. Thus, it is important to pay
attention to how citizenship status has changed over time for our subsequent analyses of
institutionalization rates.
Overall about 30% of immigrants are naturalized citizens of the United States, and this
number fell somewhat over the past twenty years. The bottom of Table 1 shows that the rate of
citizenship is strongly related to when immigrants arrived. In 1980, for example, 80% of those
who had arrived before 1960 were naturalized. Because of this relationship and because
citizenship determines key dimensions of criminal punishment, this variable will be of particular
interest in the analyses to come.
Table 2 reports descriptive statistics about institutionalization for immigrants and the
native born. The first row reports the proportion in an institution on the day of the census, a
number that has risen from 1.3% of the population of young men in 1980 to 3% in 2000. When
this population statistic is disaggregated, tremendous variation is revealed. For example,
immigrants have substantially lower institutionalization rates, and this ranking holds for all racial
and ethnic groups. Immigrants had an institutionalization rate 30% that of natives in 1980, 49%
in 1990, and 20% in 2000. In 1980 immigrants who were citizens had a higher
institutionalization rate than those who were not, but in 1990 and 2000 the situation was
reversed. There are several potential explanations for this shift, some having to do with

10

incentives for citizenship and others having to do with the detention and deportation of
noncitizens. We explore these explanations later in the paper.
The middle part of the table shows the variation in institutionalization rates with
education and race/ethnicity. While the rates for immigrants are in all cases much lower than for
natives, the strong correlation with education is observed in both groups. The cross-racial group
pattern too shows the same features for both groups.
The bottom part of Table 2 shows that more recent immigrants have lower
institutionalization rates than immigrants who arrived earlier. This pattern is consistent with the
idea that immigrants are positively selected on the crime commission dimension and assimilate
toward the higher native rate with time in the country. We will examine evidence on this point
in greater detail later in the paper.
Figure 4 shows the fraction immigrant inside and outside of institutions in each Census.
Although the fraction immigrant in the nation as a whole increased dramatically between each of
these Censuses, the fraction immigrant in institutions actually fell from 1990 to 2000. In the
most recent Census, nearly four percent of young men in institutions were immigrant while 17
percent of the general population (of young men) was immigrant.
Figure 5 shows the relationship between age and institutionalization for the native born
and for the most recent immigrants for each of the three Census years. For the native-born
Americans, the age-institutionalization curve peaks in the early twenties and gradually falls off in
a pattern well-known to criminologists. The institutionalization rates increased each decade for
each age group. The most dramatic feature of the graph is the relatively low rates for recent
immigrants. One possible explanation for the low rates is that it takes several years of exposure
to the U.S. criminal justice system before one is likely to be institutionalized and recent
immigrants have not accumulated enough experience (either to begin criminal enterprises, to be

11

caught by law enforcement, or to have cases processed through the system). This may also be
behind the relatively linear relationship between age and institutionalization among immigrants.
Setting aside this “exposure time” hypothesis (which we explore in a subsequent section),
there are several other features to note. Recent immigrants have not had increases in
institutionalization comparable to natives and, in fact, it appears that the line for 2000 is shifted
down from 1990. The estimates bounce around somewhat and no big changes appear in the
basic shape of the relationship between age and institutionalization.
Although immigrants have lower institutionalization rates than natives, they share
characteristics with native-born Americans who have high institutionalization rates. These
characteristics include education and race, but also age, as immigrants are under-represented
(relative to natives) in the youngest ages in this analysis (ages 18-21), when native
institutionalization rates are lowest. Figure 6 reports the institutionalization rates we expect to
see among various groups of immigrants based on the institutionalization propensities of the
native born.7 This exercise reveals just how low the observed rates are, considering the lower
educational attainment and other characteristics of immigrants.
Simply predicting institutionalization for immigrants based on their ages and the nativeborn institutionalization propensities in 1980 gives an average predicted institutionalization rate
of 0.013 for immigrants, up from their observed rate of 0.004 and equal to the rate of the native
born. The effect for 1990 and 2000 is similar: predictions based on age-institutionalization
relationship give immigrants institutionalization rates similar to those of natives. Thus, the
simple comparison of means in Table 2 shows that institutionalization of immigrants is greatly

7

These calculations come from running logits on a sample of the native born only and then using the
estimated coefficients to predict institutionalization for immigrants.

12

affected by the ages under consideration. Predicted institutionalization rates for citizen and
noncitizen immigrants (not shown) based on age and are very similar.
The second bar in Figure 6 for each year represents predictions based on age, education,
race, and ethnicity. This model predicts and institutionalization rate for immigrants of 0.073, ten
times the observed rate in the data. Furthermore, for this specification, in all years the predicted
institutionalization rate is about 50% higher for noncitizens than it is for citizens (not shown).
Clearly, immigrants have characteristics that in the native born population are highly correlated
with institutionalization.
B. Data Considerations and Corroborating Evidence
The basic result from the tables and figures described above is that immigrants, despite
having characteristics that in the native population are highly correlated with institutionalization,
have very low institutionalization rates, and their institutionalization rates relative to the native
born fell between 1990 and 2000. In this section, we discuss whether these results can be
reliably used to estimate how institutionalization and criminal propensities changed over time.
i.

Enumeration Issues

These institutionalization rates are measures of the number of individuals in institutions
divided by the number of individuals overall. Mismeasurement of either the numerator or the
denominator would result in poor estimates of institutionalization rates.
a. The Numerator
In our context we are concerned with whether the total number of institutionalized
individuals are counted correctly, and particularly concerned that any mismeasurement does not
differ systematically between the native-born and immigrant populations. For our detailed
analysis of changes over time (below) we are also concerned with whether mismeasurement in
the institutionalized population changes over time.

13

The institutionalized population is a subset of the “special populations” category in the
U.S. Census. The Census has separate questionnaires and procedures for those housed in group
quarters, including institutions. Many of those living in institutions, including prisons and jails,
are deemed unable to fill out their own questionnaires. Thus, Census enumerators fill out these
forms over several weeks using administrative data. (See the data appendix for a more detailed
description of Census enumeration procedures in special populations.) Thus, the Census records
for the incarcerated population should be as good as the administrative data on which they are
based.
There very large incentives for the administrators of prisons and jails to accurately count
their inmates. Thus, we would expect this population to be accurately counted relative to the rest
of the population.
The next question is whether there are systematic differences in the counting of
immigrants and the native born, and whether the differences in counting changed over time.
While it is plausible that not all the foreign born are properly identified, there are incentives for
criminal justice administrators to identify the foreign born, particularly those who are not
citizens. The incentives to identify noncitizen aliens increased over this time period. Thus, if
anything, we would expect any undercount of institutionalized immigrants to decrease relative to
the native born over the time period. These changes in mismeasurement would be expected to
increase the measured institutionalization rate of immigrants relative to the native born.
b. The Denominator
A second source of mismeasurement comes from the undercount of the overall
population. The “undercount” arises when the Census does not enumerate some individuals, and
this is thought to be more likely in certain populations, particularly those that are more likely to
be transient. The 2000 Census is widely reputed to have improved the undercount problem

14

relative to the 1990 Census. In our case then, if the denominator in the calculation of
institutionalization rates got larger, not because the population actually grew, but because more
of the individuals who were here were enumerated, then we would find a spurious decrease in
the institutionalization rate between 1990 and 2000. Again, we are not necessarily concerned if
the undercount improved for all populations in the same way, but if immigrants are more likely
to be undercounted than the general population and the undercount improved for them then we
could find a spurious decrease in the relative institutionalization rates of immigrants to the native
born.
The data appendix provides more details on the potential impact of changes in the
undercount on our estimates of immigrant institutionalization rates in 1990 and 2000. Our
simulations demonstrate that it is unlikely our estimates are purely driven by changes in the
undercount. Suppose that the institutionalization rate for immigrants in 1990 and 2000 were
actually the same. In order for changes in the undercount to generate the estimates of
institutionalization in Table 2, the relative undercount of immigrants to the native born would
have to be 37:1 (e.g., the Census missed 37 immigrants for every 1 missed native).
ii. Incarceration and its relationship to Crime Commission
A second important question is whether we can use the information on institutionalization
rates to make inferences about immigrants’ commission of crime in the United States. If Census
measures of institutionalization were poor measures of the true incarceration rates, then these
measures would not tell us much about how immigration affects public safety. Alternatively, if
immigrants are less likely than the native born to be caught for a given criminal act, then the
institutionalization rates may change without crime rates being affected.
We can use information on Metropolitan Area (MA) crime rates and immigrant density to
provide some corroborating evidence on the relationship between immigration and crime. Figure

15

7 shows the change in MA crime rates graphed against the change in fraction immigrant for 1990
to 2000 for the 24 largest MAs (with reliable data). Here we see that those areas that had the
largest increases in their fraction immigrant had the largest decreases in their crime rates. This
confirms earlier results in Butcher and Piehl (1998a) that presents a thorough analysis of changes
in metropolitan crime rates and immigration patterns between 1980 and 1990. This analysis at
the Metropolitan Area level also confirms the results from the individual level Census data
reported here: immigrants’ criminality improved relative to the native born between 1990 and
2000.

V. Institutionalization by Immigrant Cohort
Table 3a reports the marginal effects, evaluated at the sample mean, for logit models for
institutionalization in the 1980, 1990, and 2000 Censuses. Here we examine the differences in
institutionalization rates for different cohorts of immigrants, controlling for differences in
characteristics. The first column shows the overall difference in institutionalization for
immigrants and the native born, controlling for a full set of age indicators. In 1980, immigrant
institutionalization rates are about one percentage point below natives; in 1990, they are a little
more than one percentage point lower; and in 2000, they are nearly three percentage points
lower.
Columns 2-5 in Table 3a break out the differences between institutionalization rates for
immigrants and the native born by cohort. Column 2 controls only for the age distribution.
Column 3 includes controls for education.8 Column 4 adds controls for race and ethnicity.9

8

College degree and above is the omitted category.

9

White non-Hispanic is the omitted category.

16

Finally, column 5 includes controls for whether or not the individual is a U.S. citizen. This
variable is equal to one for the native born and for naturalized immigrants.
We can see several patterns in the estimated effects of immigrant cohorts in each of the
three samples. First, nearly all the estimated effects for immigrant cohorts are negative. No
matter in which year immigrants came to the U.S., they are less likely to be institutionalized than
are the native born with similar characteristics.
Second, although the estimated cohort effects are negative, there are larger negative
effects for more recent cohorts. More recent immigrants in each of the three Census samples are
relatively less likely to be institutionalized, compared to immigrants who arrived earlier. With a
few exceptions, relative institutionalization rates rise as we move from more recent to earlier
cohorts, regardless of the control variables included.
The cohort pattern in these estimates is open to several interpretations (see, for example,
Borjas 1985). Immigrants who have been in the country for longer periods of time may be
“assimilating” toward the higher institutionalization rates of the native-born. This could come
through two effects. Immigrants may be increasing their participation in criminal activities with
time in the country, or, they may have had more chances to get caught for a given level of
criminal activity. The first of these would suggest that immigrants are changing their criminal
activity as they learn more about opportunities in the illegal sector. The second we refer to as the
“exposure time” hypothesis: it may take a while before an individual has a serious enough
offense record to receive an incarcerative punishment. Alternatively, the people who came to the
U.S. between 1970 and 1974 may be very different from the people who came between 1980 and
1985, for example. There are several mechanisms by which such shifts could occur, including
selective immigration.

17

If immigrants who came to the United States in different waves of immigration were
identical in all respects, and institutionalization rates overall were stable over time, then within a
Census sample, we could use earlier immigrants’ institutionalization rates as a predictor of the
eventual institutionalization rates of later immigrants. We refer to this estimate as the “within
Census” prediction. On the other hand, since we have several Census samples, we can examine
how the institutionalization rates for a given cohort change over time across Census samples.
We refer to this estimate as the “between-Census” prediction.
Table 3b calculates the within- and between-Census estimates of changes in
institutionalization for a number of immigrant cohorts.10 If there had been no change in overall
institutionalization probabilities and no change in immigrant institutionalization propensities
over time, we would expect the within and between Census estimates to yield similar results.
Here we see that they are quite different. In all three years, the within-Census estimates are
positive, implying that we should expect immigrant institutionalization rates to rise relative to the
native born with time in the country.
In contrast, following a given cohort across Census years generally shows the opposite
result. Between 1980 and 1990, the 1975-1979 and 1970-1974 cohorts decreased their relative
institutionalization rates once education is included in the controls. Between 1990 and 2000, all
of the cohorts examined decreased their relative institutionalization rates, regardless of which
controls are included. These estimates suggest, for example, between a 0.36 to a 0.86 percentage
point decline in relative institutionalization for the 1985-1990 and 1980-1984 cohorts between
1990 and 2000 while the within estimates suggest that relative institutionalization rates should
have increased by 0.1 to 0.5 percentage points.

10

Standard errors are calculated as for the difference between two independent means.

18

These results strongly suggest that something changed across these decades. We will
spend the remainder of the paper weighing the evidence for what that something might be.
Before we do that, however, it is worth examining how relative institutionalization rates changed
for the most recent two cohorts in each Census year. Table 3c computes the relative
institutionalization rates for the two most recent cohorts for the three combinations of Censuses.
This comparison holds constant exposure to the criminal justice system, as discussed above, and
also limits the bias resulting from any return migration.11 Each of the cohorts had been in the
country for less than five or between five and ten years. In every case, the recent arrivals have
lower relative institutionalization rates in the later Census years. Once again, this suggests that
immigrants who have arrived in the U.S. in the last two decades are less prone to criminal acts
than previous immigrants, or that something else has changed. And once again, these effects are
large, especially in 2000.
Lubotsky (2000) points out that the Census may misclassify immigrants as recent arrivals
who are actually re-entrants.12 Indeed, he finds that many of the studies focusing on immigrant
wage assimilation overstate the secular decline in the level of earnings across immigrant cohort
due to the misclassification of these mostly low-wage multiple entrants as “recent immigrants.”
It is less clear how this misclassification may affect our results. If some in the “recent

11

One of the potential problems with both the within and between comparisons is that cohorts that have
been in the U.S. for longer periods of time may have changed their composition significantly from when
they arrived. For example, suppose that those immigrants who fared worst in the U.S. were those most
likely to return to their country of origin. Both the within and between comparisons could be affected by
this selection process (although presumably they would be affected in the same direction, so this is not an
explanation for why the within and between above are of opposite sign).

12

Another source of misclassification may come from the allocation codes. If immigrants are more likely
to be allocated incorrect data than the native born, then that might affect our results. There is evidence
that immigrants are more likely to have allocated education data than are the native born, for example
(Ibarraran and Lubotsky 2005). In our case, the problem would be most serious if immigration or
institutionalization status were disproportionately misallocated. However, very few observations have
allocated data for the key pieces of information in this study.

19

immigrant” category are these re-entrants with very low skills, then we might expect, as a
corollary to the wage studies, to find this group relatively more likely to be incarcerated. On the
other hand, the fact that they are re-entrants may suggest a certain fluidity of movement that
allows them to escape detection, and thus to have lower institutionalization rates for a given level
of criminal activity.
Before turning to a discussion of the potential explanations for our estimates, we examine
how sensitive our results are to the choice of where to evaluate the marginal effects. Appendix
Tables 1a and 1b present estimates analogous to those in Tables 3b and 3c evaluated at a
constant set of characteristics. Immigrant and native-born characteristics change across the
decades in uneven ways. In addition, the non-linear nature of the logit means that the marginal
effects may differ depending on where they are calculated. Here we have chosen to evaluate the
marginal effects for a 25-year old Hispanic with a high school degree. The estimates are
qualitatively similar to those in Tables 3b and 3c – namely the within-Census estimates predict
an increase in institutionalization while the between-Census estimates and the estimates holding
constant exposure time show a decrease. However, the between-Census estimates of the relative
decline in institutionalization are much larger here – from 1.5 to 6 percentage points, depending
on the specification.
Next we consider the potential role of age-at-arrival. As pointed out by Friedberg (1992)
age-at-arrival will vary systematically across cohorts, especially when the data are limited to a
restrictive set of ages. Those who arrived earlier, must have arrived at an earlier age in order to
still be under 40 years old and be in our sample. It is likely that those who arrive at earlier ages
have a greater potential to assimilate to U.S. norms than those who arrive at older ages. If there
are systematic changes in age-at-arrival across Censuses, that could affect our cohort patterns.
Thus, Appendix Tables 2a and 2b contain a final robustness check on our main results. Here we

20

restrict the sample to those immigrants who arrived in the U.S. as children (younger than age
13). This serves to test whether our earlier results were driven by the changing age distribution
within cohort. Comparing the results in these tables to those in Tables 3b and 3c we find quite
comparable findings, in magnitude as well as sign. Thus we conclude that changing age at
arrival is not an important driver of our finding that immigrants have improved relative to the
native born over time.

VI. Deportation, Selection and Deterrence
Clearly immigrants are less likely to be institutionalized than the native born, and this
difference is larger in 2000 than in earlier years. Further, the immigrants appear to improve
relative to natives with time in the country, and this improvement is greater from 1990 to 2000
than it was from 1980 to 1990. There are several potential explanations for the time patterns in
relative institutionalization rates discussed above. Changes in policies toward criminal aliens in
the 1990s may have increased deportation, reducing the population of institutionalized
immigrants relative to other immigrants and the native born. Alternatively, changes in the legal
environment and the economic environment in the United States may have changed the types of
immigrants who self-select to immigrate and to return to their countries of origin. Or, selection
of the types of immigrants who come to the U.S. may have remained stable, but the increased
criminal penalties may have had a deterrent effect, changing their behavior once here.
If institutionalization mapped directly to underlying criminal behavior in the same way
for all immigrant cohorts and for the native born, differences between institutionalization rates
for immigrants and the native born could be interpreted as differences in criminality, and we
could directly infer immigrants’ criminality. There are several reasons to worry that criminality
does not map to institutionalization in the same way for all immigrant cohorts and the native

21

born. In particular, immigrants who are not citizens and who have committed crimes may be
subject to deportation (for details see Legomsky 1999). Deportation may be thought of as a
special case of “out-migration.” Lubotsky (2000) notes that selective out-migration of less
successful immigrants in the labor market may have overstated immigrant earnings growth with
time in the country. If immigrants who are less successful in the labor market are more likely, all
else equal, to commit crimes and more likely to emigrate (such that they emigrate prior to
committing those crimes), then both our within and between estimates of changes in
institutionalization rates will lead us to infer too little criminality among immigrants (but will be
accurate as to the commission of crime in the U.S.).
The implications of deportation, as opposed to self-selected out-migration, for
institutionalization rates are somewhat more complicated as they depend on the speed with
which immigrants are removed from the country. Immigrants who have committed crimes
generally are required to serve their sentences before being removed. So, deportation does not
reduce institutionalization for the current offense, but may reduce institutionalization because
removed immigrants are no longer in the U.S. to be institutionalized for subsequent violations.
This effect would serve to reduce immigrant institutionalization rates relative to the native born.
On the other hand, if immigrant removal is slow, perhaps because of backlogs in the system,
immigrants may serve longer for a given sentence than do the native born, as was shown in
Butcher and Piehl (2000). This would tend to inflate immigrant institutionalization rates relative
to the native born.
In addition, if the probability that an immigrant is deported is changing over time, then
deportation will also affect the comparisons of relative immigrant-native born institutionalization
rates over time. The Violent Crime Law of 1994 and then the Anti-Terrorism and Effective
Death Penalty Act of 1996 expanded the list of crimes for which noncitizen immigrants can be

22

deported. Thus, one might expect that increased deportation over the 1990s would bias our
estimates toward finding lower institutionalization rates among immigrants.
There are few definitive estimates in the literature of these key parameters. Noncitizens
may also be institutionalized while awaiting deportation, or while the process for deportation
evolves (included waiting for hearings). Legomsky (1999) reports that following the 1996 Antiterrorism and Effective Death Penalty Act, “mandatory detention now applies to almost all
noncitizens who are inadmissible or deportable on crime-related grounds – not just to those
convicted of aggravated felonies (p.532).” Thus there are several reasons that noncitizens may
have higher probabilities than natives of being observed in an institutional setting.13
The INS has been surprisingly ineffective at removing criminal aliens. Shuck and
Williams (1999) note that there is tremendous political support for removing criminal aliens, and
large fiscal incentives for doing so. Nonetheless, their best estimate is that the INS has removed
“fewer than twenty percent of the nearly 300,000 criminal aliens estimated to be already under
law enforcement supervision.” In their assessment of the political economy around the removal
of criminal aliens, Shuck and Williams find that the federal government focused on procedural
reforms rather than identifying criminal aliens and information management, which should have
been first order concerns. They attribute the policy failure to a misalignment of incentives
between federal and state (and local) agencies. A recent New York Times investigation reported
that city sanctuary policies, such as the one in Los Angeles that prohibits police from inquiring
about immigration status unless there is a formal charge of a crime, mean that those who have
been deported can frequently return to the United States and resume their lives (LeDuff 2005).
Regardless of the reasons behind the implementation problems, the existence of these
13

Of course there are other factors at work. Immigrants may be less likely to report crimes, so
perpetrators of these crimes may have lower rates of detection (see Butcher and Piehl 1998a for some
discussion). Also, bail decisions may be influenced by citizenship status.

23

inefficiencies is central to interpretation of the results of any analysis of criminal justice
outcomes for immigrants.
Indeed, the numbers of immigrants deported (both voluntary departures and formal
removals) increased over the three decades we examine. From 1971 to 1980, about 7.5 million
immigrants were expelled;14 from 1981 to 1990, about 10.2 million immigrants were expelled;
and from 1991 to 2000, about 14.5 million immigrants were expelled.15 Among those deported,
not simply excluded, the most common administrative reasons given during the 1990s were
“attempted entry without proper documents” (35%) and “criminal activity” (31%).16 It is
difficult to use these aggregate numbers to gain traction for the issue at hand: the extent of the
bias in our estimates across synthetic cohorts. So for now we turn to a different approach to
checking for the robustness of the estimates reported earlier: restricting our attention to U.S.
citizens, for whom detention and deportation are not relevant considerations. In addition,
immigrants who have become citizens are less likely to emigrate, so this should also mitigate
problems due to selective voluntary out-migration.
Before we report on our analyses for citizens only, we consider the possibility of changes
in the nature of citizenship over time. In addition to increasing the list of criminal offenses for
which one could be deported if one was not a citizen, the Anti-Terrorism and Effective Death
Penalty Act made this change in law retroactive. That is, if a noncitizen had committed one of
these deportable offenses before the law was enacted, he or she was now subject to deportation.
Thus, this law increased the punishment associated with a particular conviction for non14

Fiscal Year 2002 Yearbook of Immigration Statistics
http://uscis.gov/graphics/shared/aboutus/statitstics/ENF2002list.htm

15

The vast majority of these expulsions are voluntary departures. For example, from 1991-2000, only
939,749 of the expulsions were formal removals.

16

The INS Immigration Statistics Reports
http://uscis.gov/graphics/shared/aboutus/statistics/ENF2002tables.pdf.

24

naturalized immigrants relative to citizens. One might expect this to have two effects. First, it
might act as a deterrent such that noncitizens, knowing they could be subject to banishment in
addition to a term of incarceration, are now less likely to commit crimes than they were in the
past. Secondly, it might have given immigrants an incentive to become naturalized citizens.
Indeed, the Personal Responsibility and Work Opportunity Reconciliation Act of 1996,
better known as “welfare reform,” may also have given immigrants an incentive to become
citizens. As originally passed, the welfare reform bill barred non-naturalized immigrants from
receipt of most forms of welfare; as revised, only immigrants who arrived after the law are
subject to the ban.17 Anecdotes at the time suggested that immigrants were lining up to apply for
citizenship as the atmosphere in the mid-1990s gave immigrants new incentives to naturalize.
Table 4 reports our inquiry into changes in citizenship status by immigrant cohort across
the three Censuses. Here, we estimate a logit for citizenship among immigrants only. We
evaluated the marginal effects at the sample means. As in table 3a, we control for a full set of
age dummies in all regressions; the second set of results adds controls for education; the third set
adds controls for race and ethnicity. In this case, the omitted category is the most recent cohort
in each Census year, so the baseline varies across samples. The first column for each year shows
the raw statistic for fraction citizen for each of the cohorts.
Table 4 shows the extent to which different immigrant cohorts “take up” citizenship over
this time period. Perhaps unsurprisingly, those who have just arrived have low rates of
citizenship – under 10% -- and those who have been in the country over 20 years hover around
70%. This general pattern is relatively stable over time. Note that the estimates in Table 4 are
relative to the most recent arrival cohort, which in 2000 has the lowest citizenship rates of all

17

States had the option to use state funds to extend benefits to immigrants left out of the federal statute.
Many, especially many with large immigrant populations chose to do so.

25

cohorts in all years. These results give us no reason to believe that immigrants in great numbers
sought protection from the increased penalties for criminal activity by naturalizing as citizens.
Fix et al. (2003) reports that those immigrants with the least English language proficiency, those
with lower education, and those with lower incomes are less likely to become naturalized
citizens. The direction of these correlations is the opposite direction implied by the hypothesis
that, over time, criminally active immigrants increased their citizenship propensity.
We use the sample of citizens (native born and naturalized) to examine how
institutionalization patterns changed over time for immigrants who are not subject to the
increased threat of deportation due to legislation enacted in the 1990s. Tables 5a and 5b show
that restricting our attention to citizens, immigrant and native, does not appreciably alter our
conclusions from Tables 3b and 3c. Here we do see some negative within-Census predictions,
but in all cases the between-Census predictions are larger in absolute value. Among citizens,
immigrants are much less likely than natives to be institutionalized, and the magnitude of the
difference with the native born has grown substantially over time. The fact that citizens continue
to show the same patterns, even when the incentive for criminally active immigrants to become
citizens increased, substantially moderates concerns that the estimation strategy is biased in favor
immigrants due to deportation of criminal immigrants. It also suggests that the shift is not due to
a deterrent effect from the threat of deportation, since citizens are not subject to deportation.
Next, we consider whether immigrants may be self-selected from among those with
lower criminal propensities. If individuals who move are positively selected in some regard
compared to those who stay put near where they were born,18 then this may explain the better

18

Butcher (1994) compares labor market outcomes for immigrant and native-born blacks and finds that
immigrant blacks have better labor market outcomes than the native born. However, when the native born
who have moved from their state of birth are used as the comparison group, outcomes are very similar.
Suggesting that movers, whether native born or immigrant, are similar.

26

outcomes of immigrants with regard to criminal justice outcomes. To partially control for this
unobserved quality, we compare immigrants to natives who have moved from their state of birth,
rather than to the whole native-born population.19 We recognize that this is a partial control for
what it takes to immigrate across national boundaries, likely requiring living in a new culture
with a new language. But we hope it goes some way to controlling for this important form of
selection.
Tables 6a and 6b report the results of this exercise. Here we find that selection matters a
great deal to the estimates for various immigrant cohorts. The between-Census estimates are
about one-third to one-half the magnitude when the comparison group is native movers rather
than all natives. In fact, some of the between census estimates come very close to zero when
controls for education are included. (Note that among natives, education is positively correlated
with the likelihood of residing outside one’s home state.) Holding exposure time constant in
Table 6b, we similarly find that recently arrived immigrants have lower institutionalization rates
than native-born movers. However, in contrast to results in Table 3c, the results for 2000-1990
compared to 1990-1980 do not show that the recently arrived in the later time period have lower
relative institutionalization rates. Now the results are more similar across the decades, suggesting
that native-born movers and immigrants responded to increased penalties for criminal activity in
similar ways. These results suggest that migration, whether across national or state boundaries,
tends to select individuals with lower criminal propensities.

19

This measure is somewhat problematic since one reason a person may live outside his state of birth is if
he is sent to a federal prison in another state. This would tend to increase the institutionalization rates of
native born movers. This bias is likely to be small, however, as federal prisoners are a small fraction of all
prisoners.

27

VII. Conclusion
The institutionalization experience of immigrants raises questions that have bearing on
our basic understandings of criminal behavior, immigrant selection and assimilation, and, by
extension, public policies related to crime and to immigration. We have shown that immigrants
have substantially lower institutionalization than natives, and that this differential has grown
over the time period that institutionalization expanded. In 2000, male young adult immigrants
are institutionalized at one-fifth the rate of comparable native-born Americans. Although
immigrants continue to be much more likely than natives to have low levels of education, this
has not caused institutionalization rates to rise. In fact, when we predict the institutionalization
rate for immigrants based on the experiences of natives, we find that the observed rate is onetenth of the predicted one.
Analyses across immigrant cohorts suggest that more recent immigrant cohorts have
lower institutionalization rates than earlier cohorts. Further, immigrants reduce their relative
incarceration rates with time in the country. The fact that our results for immigrant citizens are
similar to those for immigrants overall, convince us that increased deportation of criminal aliens
in the 1990s is not driving these findings. In addition, one might expect a dramatic increase in
the rate at which citizenship is taken up if crime-prone immigrants were taking up citizenship as
protection against deportation. We do not observe such a shift. We do, however, find that
immigrants do not look nearly as good when evaluated relative to natives who move. We read
this as evidence that both internal and international migrants are self-selected from among those
with lower criminal propensities. Together, this evidence suggests that selection of immigrants
occurs over more than one dimension of skill.

28

References

Becker, Gary (1968). “Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach,” Journal of Political
Economy vol. 76, p.169-.
Borjas, George J. (2004). “Immigration and the Labor Market 1960-2000,” unpublished paper,
Harvard University.
Borjas, George J. (2003). “The Labor Demand Curve is Downward Sloping: Reexamining the
Impact of Immigration on the Labor Market,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics,
November: 1335-74.
Borjas, George (2002). “Home Ownership in the Immigrant Population,” NBER working paper
8495, May.
Borjas, George (1994). “The Economics of Immigration,” Journal of Economic Literature, vol.
XXXII, pp. 1667-1717.
Borjas, George J. (1987) “Self-Selection and the Earnings of Immigrants,” American Economic
Review, pp. 531-553.
Borjas, George J. (1985). “Assimilation, Changes in Cohort Quality, and the Earnings of
Immigrants,” Journal of Labor Economics, vol.3 no. 4, October, pp. 463-489.
Borjas, George and Rachel M. Friedberg (2004). “What Happened to Immigrant Earnings in the
1990s,” unpublished paper, Harvard University, March.
Butcher, Kristin and Luojia Hu (2000). “Use of Means-Tested Transfer Programs by Immigrants,
Their Children, and Their Children’s Children,” in Finding Jobs: Work and Welfare
Reform, Rebecca Blank and David Card, eds., Russell Sage: New York.
Butcher, Kristin F. (1994). "Black Immigrants in the United States: A Comparison with Native
Blacks and Other Immigrants," Industrial and Labor Relations Review, vol. 47, no. 2, pp.
265-284.
Butcher, Kristin F. and Anne Morrison Piehl (2000). “The Role of Deportation in the
Incarceration of Immigrants,” in George Borjas, ed., Issues in the Economics of
Immigration, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp.351-385.
Butcher, Kristin F. and Anne Morrison Piehl (1998a). “Recent Immigrants: Unexpected
Implications for Crime and Incarceration,” Industrial and Labor Relations Review, vol.
51, no. 4, July, pp.654-679.

29

Butcher, Kristin F. and Anne Morrison Piehl (1998b). “Cross-City Evidence on the Relationship
between Immigration and Crime,” Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, vol. 17,
no. 3, Summer, pp.457-493.
Card, David (2001). “Immigrant Inflows, Native Outflows, and the Local Labor Market Impacts
of Higher Immigration,” Journal of Labor Economics 19, no. 1: 22-64;
Chiquiar, Daniel and Gordon Hanson (2005),”International Migration, Self-Selection, and the
Distribution of Wages: Evidence from Mexico and the United States, Journal of Political
Economy, 113(2): 239-281.
Fix, Michael, Jeffrey S. Passel, and Kenneth Sucher (2003). “Trends in Naturalization,”
Immigrant Families and Workers, Brief no. 3, Urban Institute, September.
Friedberg, Rachel M. (1992) "The Labor Market Assimilation of Immigrants in the United
States: The Role of Age at Arrival," Unpublished paper, Brown University, 1992.
Hanson, Gordon (forthcoming), "Emigration, Labor Supply and Earnings in Mexico," in George
Borjas, ed., Mexican Immigration, Chicago: University of Chicago Press and the
National Bureau of Economic Research.
Ibarraran, Pablo and Darren Lubotsky (forthcoming). “Mexican Immigration and Self-selection:
New Evidence from the 2000 Mexican Census,” in George Borjas, ed., Mexican
Immigration, Chicago: University of Chicago Press and the National Bureau of
Economic Research.
LeDuff, Charlie (2005). “Police Say Immigrant Policy is Hindrance” New York Times, April 7.
Legomsky, Stephen H. (1999). “Symposium: Immigration Reform Article: The Detention Of
Aliens: Theories, Rules, and Discretion” University of Miami Inter-American Law
Review, vol. 30: 531.
Lubotsky, Darren, “Chutes or Ladders? A Longitudinal Analysis of Immigrant Earnings,”
Working Paper #445, Industrial Relations Section, Princeton University, August 2000.
Mears, Daniel P. (2002). “Immigration and Crime: What’s the Connection?” Federal
Sentencing Reporter, vol. 14, no. 5: 284-88.
Osili, Una and Anna Paulson (2004a). “Institutional Quality and Financial Market Development:
Evidence from International Migrants in the U.S.,” Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
working paper number 2004-19.
Osili, Una and Anna Paulson (2004b). “Prospects for Immigrant-Native Wealth Assimilation:
Evidence from Financial Market Participation,” Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
working paper number 2004-18.

30

Robinson, J. Gregory, Arjun Adlakha, and Kristen K. West (2002). “Coverage of Population in
Census 2000: Results from Demographic Analysis,” mimeo, prepared for the 2002
Annual Meeting of the Population Association of America.
Roy, A. (1951). “Some Thoughts on the Distribution of Earnings,” Oxford Economic Papers,
Vol 3., pp.135-146.
Schuck, Peter A. (1997). “INS Detention and Removal: A White Paper,” Georgetown
Immigration Law Journal, vol. 11: 667.
Schuck, Peter A. and John Williams (1999). “Removing Criminal Aliens: The Pitfalls and
Promises o Federalism” Harvard Journal of Law & Public Policy, vol. 22: 367-.
Smith, James P. and Barry Edmonston, eds. (1997). The New Americans: Economics,
Demographic, and Fiscal Effects of Immigration, Washington, DC: National Research
Council.

31

Data Appendix
There are two potential problems with Census data that could affect our results. The first
is the “undercount” – the problem of failing to enumerate individuals, typically thought to be
more serious in poor and minority communities. The second potential problem has to do with
how special populations, such as those in institutions are counted by the Census. For example, if
a high fraction of those under correctional supervision are in transition (being transferred from
one place to another) they may be missed in the population count. Thus, it is worth
understanding how Census collects data for special populations.
1) Data Collection in Special Populations
Data collection in special populations, like the institutionalized population, may present
particular challenges. For example, many of those in institutions may not be able to or may be
unwilling to fill out Census forms. Additionally, in the case of prisoners, for example, people
may frequently be moved between institutions, creating a difficulty in counting them on Census
day.
There is a different Census form for those living in group quarters, and additional forms
for those in military quarters and on-board ships. As mentioned in the data section, among those
living in group quarters, some types of group quarters are designated as “institutions.” Jails and
prisons fall into this category, and although they are not separately identifiable in the PUMS
data, by limiting our sample to men aged 18-40, a very high fraction of the institutionalized
populations is in correctional facilities (based on comparisons to the 1980 Census where type of
institution is identifiable).

32

In the 2000 Census, about half of those living in group quarters were unable to fill out
Census forms.20 A disproportionate share of those unable to fill out their own Census forms is in
an institution (jail, prison, mental institution, for example). In this case, Census enumerators fill
out the forms using the institutions’ administrative records.
The enumeration procedure for group quarters takes place over several weeks. The
Census enumerators ask where an inmate was on April 1. For those inmates who are in transit on
April 1, if they reach their final destination on that day, then they are counted at the final
destination. If they are in transit, then they are counted at their originating location.
Under these circumstances then, the institutionalized population is likely to be well-counted,
since the institutions themselves are likely to keep accurate administrative records that document
the number of inmates. Thus, the “undercount” of the institutionalized population is likely much
less severe than of the overall population. In addition, the demographic information on inmates
of correctional institutions is likely to be about as good as the administrative records themselves.
Since there was more pressure and more incentive for correctional institutions to identify (nonnaturalized) immigrants in their inmate populations in 2000 than in 1990, we would expect that a
higher fraction of immigrants would be identified in 2000 than in 1990. Thus, any “undercount”
of institutionalized immigrants would be likely higher in 1990 than in 2000.
2) The Undercount
The 1990 Census is widely viewed to have missed a substantial number of people. This
problem is thought to be particularly severe in the case of poor and minority communities. The
undercount does not present a problem for our analysis per se, if all populations are mis-counted
to the same degree in all years. There may be a problem for our analysis of changes in

20

Personal correspondence with Karen Humes, Special Populations Division, U.S. Census Bureau.

33

institutionalization between years, however, if the undercount changes across the years, or is
different for different populations.
Consider, for example, the change in the institutionalization rates of immigrants between
1990 and 2000. Table 2 shows that the fraction institutionalized for immigrants in 1990 was
0.0107 and fell to 0.0068 in 2000. Our interpretation is that immigrants were less likely to be
institutionalized in 2000 than in 1990. However, this change could happen mechanically if the
undercount of minority communities was less severe in 2000 than in 1990. Our interpretation of
this decline in institutionalization as signaling something about the behavior of immigrants in the
U.S. would be flawed, if the decline really occurs not because the numerator (the
institutionalized population) changed, but because the denominator (the total population)
changed due to better data collection methodology.
Robinson et al. (2002) uses demographic analysis methodology to estimate the
undercount in 1990 and 2000. They estimate that the net undercount in 1990 was 1.65% and in
2000 was a much smaller 0.12%. We can use these estimates to do some “back of the envelope”
calculations as to how the undercount of the immigrant population might affect our estimate of
the fraction of immigrants who are institutionalized. Appendix Table 1 shows how our estimate
of the fraction of immigrants institutionalized would change under different assumptions about
the undercount of immigrants in 1990 and 2000.

34

Data Appendix Table 1: Estimates of How the
Undercount Might affect Fraction of Immigrants Institutionalized
Fraction Institutionalized

Undercount Ratio
Immigrants:Native-born
1990

2000

1:1

0.0105

0.00679

2:1

0.0104

0.00678

3:1

0.0102

0.006776

37:1

0.0067

0.0065

These calculations are based on the numbers reported in Tables 1 and 2. For example, in 1990,
there were 209,878 immigrants in our sample. The fraction institutionalized was 0.0107,
implying 2245.7 institutionalized immigrants in 1990. If we assume the undercount estimate
applies to the non-institutionalized population, then we need to subtract the number of
institutionalized immigrants from the full sample, multiply this number by the fraction “missing”
and then add this number back onto the estimate of the total number of immigrants:
(209878-2245.7) * 0.0165 = 3425.9
Thus, the fraction institutionalized among the immigrants, assuming a 1.65% undercount would
be:
2245.7 / (209878 + 3425.9) = 0.0105.
Using this formulation, we can examine what the effect on the estimate of the fraction of
immigrants institutionalized would be given different assumptions about the severity of the
undercount in the non-institutionalized immigrant population.

35

Assuming that the undercount is three times larger for immigrants than for the overall
population (e.g., there are three “missing” immigrants for every “missing” person overall), we
would still find that the fraction institutionalized among immigrants was over 1.5 times higher in
1990 than in 2000. In order for the undercount to be the only reason that the fraction
institutionalized among immigrants declined between 1990 and 2000, we would have to think
that the undercount was about 37 times bigger for immigrants than for the population overall.
In sum, neither the improvement in the undercount of the overall population between
1990 and 2000, nor specialized undercount problems that pertain to the institutionalized
population would be likely to mechanically generate our finding that there was a substantial
decline in the fraction of immigrants institutionalized between 1990 and 2000.

36

Table 1. Summary Statistics:
Characteristics of Immigrants and Natives in 1980, 1990 and 2000
(Standard Errors in Parentheses)
Characteristic
Age
< H.S.Degree
H.S.Degree
Some College
College Degree
Black
White non-Hispanic
Asian or Pacific
Other Race
Hispanic
U.S. Citizen

1980
Native-Born
Immigrants
28.793
27.834
( 0.0178)
(0.0047)
0.3449
0.1925
(0.0013)
(0.0003)
0.2365
0.3909
(0.0012)
(0.0004)
0.2029
0.2285
(0.0011)
(0.0003)
0.2157
0.1880
(0.0011)
(0.0003)
0.0682
0.1143
(0.0007)
(0.0002)
0.3421
0.8330
(0.0013)
(0.0003)
0.1957
0.0060
(0.0011)
(0.0001)
0.0270
0.0024
(0.0005)
(0.0000)
0.3975
0.0405
(0.0014)
(0.0001)
1
0.3306
(0.0013)

1990
Native-Born
Immigrants
29.280
29.085
( 0.0137)
(0.0046)
0.3258
0.1268
( 0.0010)
(0.0002)
0.2470
0.3545
(0.0009)
(0.0003)
0.2228
0.3222
(0.0009)
(0.0003)
0.2043
0.1964
(0.0009)
(0.0003)
0.0807
0.1243
(0.0006)
(0.0002)
0.1994
0.8084
(0.0009)
(0.0003)
0.2347
0.0082
(0.0009)
(0.0001)
0.0034
0.0005
(0.0001)
(0.0000)
0.4977
0.0519
(0.0011)
(0.0002)
1
0.2903
(0.0010)

Citizen: 96-00
Citizen: 91-95
Citizen: 85-90
Citizen: 80-84
Citizen: 75-79

0.0674
(0.0010)
0.2388
(0.0018)
0.3973
(0.0025)
0.4771
(0.0032)
0.5839
(0.0044)
0.6809
(0.0054)
0.7699
(0.0057)

2000
Native-Born Immigrants
29.671
29.321
(0.0107)
(0.0050)
0.3396
0.1241
(0.0008)
(0.0002)
0.2693
0.3506
(0.0007)
(0.0003)
0.1889
0.3256
(0.0007)
(0.0003)
0.2023
0.1997
(0.0007)
(0.0003)
0.0719
0.1401
(0.0004)
(0.0003)
0.1547
0.7631
(0.0006)
(0.0003)
0.2198
0.0169
(0.0007)
(0.0001)
0.3400
0.0405
(0.0008)
(0.0001)
0.5671
0.0784
(0.0008)
(0.0002)
1
0.2667
(0.0007)
0.0445
(0.0007)
0.1392
(0.0012)
0.2991
(0.0015)
0.4863
(0.0022)
0.5874
(0.0031)
0.6671
(0.0043)
0.7292
(0.0057)
0.7667
(0.0100)

0.0730
(0.0012)
Citizen: 70-74
0.2604
(0.0025)
Citizen: 65-69
0.4345
(0.0034)
Citizen: 60-64
0.5875
(0.0041)
Citizen: 50-59
0.7890
(0.0034)
Citizen: 40-49
0.8965
(0.0057)
No. Obs
1,900,112
127,392
1,984,069
209,878
1,875,961
352,534
Notes: These data are from the 1980, 1990 and 2000 Integrated Public Use Microdata Series (IPUMS) of the U.S.
Census. The data include men aged 18-40 inclusive. Those born in U.S. outlying areas, born abroad of American
parents, or born at sea are excluded from the sample. All means are weighted to reflect sampling.

37

Table 2. Fraction of the Population Institutionalized in 1980, 1990 and 2000
(Standard Errors in Parentheses; Sample Size in Square Brackets)
Group

1980

1990

2000

All
Full Sample

All

< H.S Degree
H.S. Degree
Some College
Black
White Non-Hispanic
Asian or Pacific
Hispanic
U.S. Citizen

0.0206
(0.00010)
[2,193,947]
By Immigrant Status
1980
1990
Native-Born
Immigrants
Native-Born
Immigrants
0.0107
0.0217
0.0042
0.0135
(0.00022)
(0.00010)
(0.00018)
(0.00008)
[209,878]
[1,984,069]
[127,392]
[1,900,111]
0.0167
0.0673
0.0076
0.0389
(0.0048)
(0.00049)
(0.0041)
(0.00032)
0.0119
0.0229
0.0041
0.0101
(0.00048)
(0.00018)
(0.00037)
(0.00011)
0.0082
0.0143
0.0024
0.0069
(0.00042)
(0.00015)
(0.00030)
(0.00013)
0.0289
0.0811
0.0078
0.0445
(0.00142)
(0.00060)
(0.00095)
(0.0004)
0.0052
0.0116
0.0040
0.0088
(0.00035)
(0.00008)
(0.00030)
(0.00007)
0.0024
0.0130
0.0011
0.0086
(0.00022)
(0.00090)
(0.00021)
(0.00087)
0.0152
0.0396
0.0054
0.0210
(0.00037)
(0.00062)
(0.00032)
(0.00052)
0.0097
0.0055
(0.00040)
(0.00036)
0.0129
(0.00008)
[2,027,504]

Immigrant Cohorts
1996-2000
1991-1995
1985-1990
1980-1984
1975-1979

0.0068
(0.00032)
0.0117
(0.00046)
0.0117
(0.00055)
0.0128
(0.00072)
0.0172
(0.00115)
0.0163
(0.00147)
0.0090
(0.00128)

0.0299
(0.00011)
[2,228,495]
2000
Native-Born Immigrants
0.0068
0.0345
(0.00014)
(0.00013)
[352,534]
[1,875,961]
0.0101
0.1104
(0.0028)
(0.00064)
0.0082
0.0412
(0.00024)
(0.00024)
0.0047
0.0171
(0.00027)
(0.00017)
0.0179
0.1132
(0.00087)
(0.00065)
0.0039
0.0170
(0.00027)
(0.00011)
0.0037
0.0253
(0.00022)
(0.00090)
0.0079
0.0659
(0.00020)
(0.00066)
0.0051
(0.00023)
0.0037
(0.00020)
0.0050
(0.00025)
0.0072
(0.00028)
0.0106
(0.00046)
0.0096
(0.00061)
0.0141
(0.00108)
0.0098
(0.00127)
0.0183
(0.00309)

0.0029
(0.00025)
1970-1974
0.0036
(0.00034)
1965-1969
0.0039
(0.00043)
1960-1964
0.0067
(0.00068)
1950-1959
0.0065
(0.00068)
1940-1949
0.0089
(0.0018)
Notes: These data are from the 1980, 1990 and 2000 Integrated Public Use Microdata Series (IPUMS) of the U.S. Census. The
data include men aged 18-40 inclusive. All means are weighted to reflect sampling.

38

Immigrant
1996-2000
1991-1995
1985-1990
1980-1984
1975-1979
1970-1974
1965-1969
1960-1964
1950-1959
1940-1950
Less than H.S.
H.S. Degree
Some College

Table 3a. Marginal Effects for Logit Estimates of Institutionalization – Evaluated at Sample Mean
(Robust Standard Errors in Parentheses)
1980
1990
2000
-0.0090
-0.0110
-0.0276
(0.0002)
(0.0003)
(0.0002)
-0.0254 -0.0166 -0.0142 -0.0146
(0.0002) (0.0002) (0.0001) (0.0002)
-0.0239 -0.0160 -0.0137 -0.0141
(0.0003) (0.0002) (0.0001) (0.0001)
-0.0144 -0.0112 -0.0095 -0.0095
-0.0219 -0.0155 -0.0134 -0.0138
(0.0004) (0.0002) (0.0002) (0.0002)
(0.0003) (0.0002) (0.0001) (0.0002)
-0.0097 -0.0094 -0.0083 -0.0083
-0.0183 -0.0136 -0.0119 -0.0123
(0.0006) (0.0003) (0.0002) (0.0003)
(0.0004) (0.0002) (0.0002) (0.0002)
-0.0100 -0.0073 -0.0066 -0.0061
-0.0091 -0.0090 -0.0079 -0.0079
-0.0189 -0.0131 -0.0115 -0.0118
(0.0002) (0.0001) (0.0001) (0.0002)
(0.0007) (0.0003) (0.0002) (0.0003)
(0.0005) (0.0002) (0.0002) (0.0002)
-0.0090 -0.0070 -0.0064 -0.0059
-0.0076 -0.0081 -0.0073 -0.0073
-0.0151 -0.0106 -0.0098 -0.0104
(0.0003) (0.0002) (0.0001) (0.0002)
(0.0011) (0.0005) (0.0003) (0.0004)
(0.0009) (0.0004) (0.0003) (0.0003)
-0.0084 -0.0065 -0.0058 -0.0054
-0.0043 -0.0049 -0.0049 -0.0049
-0.0180 -0.0111 -0.0100 -0.0104
(0.0004) (0.0002) (0.0002) (0.0003)
(0.0014) (0.0008) (0.0006) (0.0006)
(0.0011) (0.0007) (0.0005) (0.0004)
-0.0059 -0.0045 -0.0038 -0.0030
-0.0044 -0.0031 -0.0031 -0.0031
-0.0097 -0.0045 -0.0048 -0.0058
(0.0007) (0.0004) (0.0004) (0.0005)
(0.0019) (0.0013) (0.0010) (0.0010)
(0.0027) (0.0019) (0.0014) (0.0013)
-0.0060 -0.0038 -0.0029 -0.0023
-0.0096 -0.0060 -0.0041 -0.0041
(0.0007) (0.0005) (0.0005) (0.0006)
(0.0017) (0.0012) (0.0012) (0.0012)
-0.0015 -0.0007 0.0002 0.0007
(0.0021) (0.0015) (0.0015) (0.0016)
0.0735 0.0519 0.0519
0.1920 0.1153 0.1153
0.2468 0.1630 0.1621
(0.0017) (0.0013) (0.0013)
(0.0054) (0.0038) (0.0038)
(0.0046) (0.0035) (0.0035)
0.0150 0.0117 0.0117
0.0491 0.0315 0.0315
0.0689 0.0469 0.0466
(0.0004) (0.0004) (0.0004)
(0.0014) (0.0010) (0.0010)
(0.0014) (0.0010) (0.0010)
0.0110 0.0085 0.0085
0.0356 0.0243 0.0243
0.0349 0.0243 0.0242
(0.0005) (0.0005) (0.0005)
(0.0013) (0.0010) (0.0010)
(0.0011) (0.0008) (0.0008)

1980
Black
American Indian
Asian or Pacific
Other Race
Hispanic
U.S. Citizen
Age Dummies
Psuedo R-square

Yes
0.0085

1991

0.0162 0.0162
(0.0003) (0.0003)
0.0094 0.0094
(0.0008) (0.0008)
0.0007 0.0006
(0.0007) (0.0007)
0.0074 0.0074
(0.0012) (0.0012)
0.0027 0.0027
(0.0003) (0.0003)
0.0025
(0.0005)
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
0.0089 0.0838 0.1122 0.1122 0.0072 0.0077 0.0779

2000
0.0393 0.0393
(0.0007) (0.0007)
0.0173 0.0173
(0.0013) (0.0013)
0.0013 0.0013
(0.0009) (0.0009)
0.0314 0.0314
(0.0071) (0.0071)
0.0119 0.0119
(0.0005) (0.0005)
0.0000
(0.0008)
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
0.1379 0.1379 0.0213 0.0221 0.1166

0.0432 0.0430
(0.0006) (0.0006)
0.0043 0.0043
(0.0006) (0.0006)
0.0081 0.0083
(0.0008) (0.0008)
-0.0010 -0.0010
(0.0003) (0.0003)
0.0165 0.0164
(0.0005) (0.0005)
-0.0053
(0.0010)
Yes
Yes
0.1739 0.1739

Notes: The marginal effects are calculated at the sample means. Number of observations for 1980 is 2,027,504. Number of observations for 1990 is 2,193,947. Number of
observations for 2000 is 2,228,495. All specifications include a full set of age dummies. Controls are: (1) age dummies; (2) age, education; (3) age, education,
race/ethnicity; (4) age, race, ethnicity, education, and u.s. citizen.

40

Table 3b. Institutionalization and Immigrant Arrival Cohorts Compared to the Native-Born in 1980, 1990 and 2000
(Standard Errors in Parentheses)
1980
1990
2000
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(1)
(2)
(3)
1996-2000 Cohort
Within Census a
1991-1995 Cohort
Within Census a
1985-1990 Cohort
Within Census a
Between Census b
1980-1984 Cohort
Within Census a
Between Census b
1975-1979 Cohort
Within Census a
Between Census b
1970-1974 Cohort
Within Census a
Between Census b

(4)

0.0035
(0.0003)

0.0011
(0.0002)

0.0008
(0.0002)

0.0008
(0.0002)

0.0056
(0.0005)

0.0024
(0.0002)

0.0018
(0.0002)

0.0017
(0.0002)

0.0053
(0.0008)
-0.0074
(0.0005)

0.0022
(0.0004)
-0.0043
(0.0003)

0.0016
(0.0003)
-0.0039
(0.0002)

0.0016
(0.0004)
-0.0043
(0.0003)

0.0030
(0.0006)

0.0024
(0.0003)

0.0019
(0.0002)

0.0019
(0.0002)

0.0020
(0.0012)
-0.0086
(0.0006)

0.0013
(0.0005)
-0.0042
(0.0003)

0.0010
(0.0004)
-0.0036
(0.0002)

0.0010
(0.0005)
-0.0041
(0.0003)

0.0032
(0.0010)

0.0030
(0.0005)

0.0021
(0.0003)

0.0020
(0.0003)

0.0016
(0.0005)
0.0009
(0.0008)

0.0008
(0.0002)
-0.0016
(0.0003)

0.0008
(0.0002)
-0.0012
(0.0003)

0.0007
(0.0003)
-0.0018
(0.0004)

0.0048
(0.0016)
-0.0098
(0.0009)

0.0041
(0.0008)
-0.0042
(0.0004)

0.0029
(0.0006)
-0.0036
(0.0003)

0.0030
(0.0007)
-0.0040
(0.0003)

0.0009
(0.0013)

0.0020
(0.0007)

0.0015
(0.0005)

0.0014
(0.0004)

0.0032
(0.0007)
0.0014
(0.0011)

0.0025
(0.0004)
-0.0011
(0.0005)

0.0026
(0.0004)
-0.0009
(0.0004)

0.0029
(0.0005)
-0.0014
(0.0004)

0.0032
(0.0022)
-0.0075
(0.0014)

0.0050
(0.0014)
-0.0025
(0.0006)

0.0041
(0.0010)
-0.0025
(0.0004)

0.0041
(0.0011)
-0.0031
(0.0005)

0.0054
(0.0028)

0.0061
(0.0020)

0.0051
(0.0015)

0.0045
(0.0013)

Notes: These numbers are calculated using the marginal effects calculated from logit estimates reported in Table 3a; column (1) here corresponds to the specification in column (2)
in (2) in Table 3a etc. Standard errors are calculated as for the difference between two means.
a
Within Census differences are calculated by subtracting the given cohort’s probability from the probability for the cohort that arrived 10 years earlier.
a
Between Census differences are calculated by subtracting the probability for a given cohort in the two different Censuses (Probability in later census – probability in earlier
census).

41

Table 3c. Differences in Institutionalization Rates Across Immigrant Arrival Cohorts
(Standard Errors in Parentheses)
1980 versus 1990

1990 versus 2000

Years Since
Arrival
Fewer than 5
Between 5 and 10

Fewer than 5
Between 5 and 10

(1)
-0.0044
(0.0005)
-0.0007
(0.0007)
-0.0154
(0.0003)
-0.0148
(0.0004)

(2)
(3)
-0.0039
-0.0029
(0.0002)
(0.0002)
-0.0024
-0.0019
(0.0003)
(0.0002)
1980 versus 2000
-0.0093
-0.0076
(0.0002)
(0.0002)
-0.0090
-0.0074
(0.0002)
(0.0002)

(4)
-0.0034
(0.0003)
-0.0024
(0.0003)

(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
-0.0110 -0.0054 -0.0047 -0.0051
(0.0005) (0.0003) (0.0002) (0.0003)
-0.0142 -0.0067 -0.0054 -0.0058
(0.0006) (0.0003) (0.0002) (0.0003)

-0.0085
(0.0003)
-0.0082
(0.0003)

Notes: These numbers are calculated from Table 3a, subtracting the relative institutionalization rate for a cohort in 1980 (1990 respectively)
from the relative institutionalization rate of the cohort in 1990 (2000 respectively) that had been in the U.S. for a comparable length of time. The
bottom panel subtracts 1980 values from 2000 values. Column numbers refer to the specification from which the institutionalization rates were
estimated, as in the previous two tables. See Table 3a for list of controls. Standard errors are calculated as for difference between two means.

42

Raw
Mean

Table 4. Marginal Effects for Logit Estimates of Citizenship
Immigrants Only
(Standard Errors in Parentheses)
1980
1990
Raw
Raw
Mean
Mean
(1)
(2)
(3)
(1)
(2)
(3)

1996-2000
1991-1995
1985-1990
1980-1984
1975-1979
1970-1974
1965-1969
1960-1964
1950-1959
1940-1950
Psuedo Rsquare

0.0730
(0.0012)
0.2604
(0.0025)
0.4345
(0.0034)
0.5875
(0.0041)
0.7890
(0.0034)
0.8965
(0.0057)

0.3309
(0.0049)
0.5059
(0.0044)
0.6132
(0.0037)
0.7212
(0.0026)
0.7163
(0.0025)

0.3398
(0.0050)
0.5113
(0.0045)
0.6116
(0.0038)
0.7180
(0.0027)
0.7174
(0.0026)

0.2444 0.2534

0.3550
(0.0051)
0.5270
(0.0046)
0.6293
(0.0039)
0.7223
(0.0028)
0.7220
(0.0025)
0.2615

0.0674
(0.0010)
0.2388
(0.0018)
0.3973
(0.0025)
0.4771
(0.0032)
0.5839
(0.0044)
0.6809
(0.0054)
0.7699
(0.0057)

0.3079 0.3140 0.3140
(0.0043) (0.0043)(0.0044)
0.4876 0.4948 0.5012
(0.0042) (0.0042)(0.0043)
0.5588 0.5679 0.5869
(0.0041) (0.0041)(0.0041)
0.6287 0.6275 0.6475
(0.0037) (0.0038)(0.0037)
0.6761 0.6699 0.6894
(0.0034) (0.0036)(0.0034)
0.7070 0.7020 0.7139
(0.0031) (0.0033)(0.0032)

0.1656 0.1849 0.1980

0.0445
(0.0007)
0.1392
(0.0012)
0.2991
(0.0015)
0.4863
(0.0022)
0.5874
(0.0031)
0.6671
(0.0043)
0.7292
(0.0057)
0.7667
(0.0100)

2000
(1)

(2)

(3)

0.2413 0.2433 0.2381
(0.0045)(0.0045) (0.0045)
0.4432 0.4559 0.4628
(0.0039)(0.0039) (0.0039)
0.6222 0.6378 0.6433
(0.0035)(0.0035) (0.0035)
0.6868 0.6940 0.7017
(0.0030)(0.0030) (0.0030)
0.7178 0.7179 0.7293
(0.0028)(0.0030) (0.0029)
0.7312 0.7284 0.7408
(0.0029)(0.0032) (0.0031)
0.7347 0.7308 0.7432
(0.0039)(0.0047) (0.0044)

0.1911 0.2277 0.2455

Notes: The marginal effects are calculated at the sample means. The first column is just the raw fraction citizen for each Census year. The second set of results
is for a logit controlling for a full set of age dummies; the third set of results adds controls for education. The fourth set adds controls for race and ethnicity. In
all cases, the most recent arrival cohort is the excluded immigrant category. The marginal effects are evaluated at the sample means. Number of observations
for 1980 is 127,392. Number of observations for 1990 is 209,878. Number of observations for 2000 is 352,534.

43

Table 5a. Institutionalization and Immigrant Arrival Cohorts Compared to the Native-Born in 1980, 1990 and 2000
Naturalized U.S. Citizens and Native-Born Only
(Standard Errors in Parentheses)
1980
1990
2000
(1)
(2)
(3)
(1)
(2)
(3)
(1)
(2)
1996-2000 Cohort
Within Census a
1991-1995 Cohort
Within Census a
1985-1990 Cohort
Within Census a
Between Census b
1980-1984 Cohort
Within Census a
Between Census b
1975-1979 Cohort
Within Census a
Between Census b
1970-1974 Cohort
Within Census a
Between Census b

(3)

-0.0013
(0.0010)

-0.0006
(0.0005)

-0.0005
(0.0003)

0.0023
(0.0008)

0.0010
(0.0004)

0.0005
(0.0003)

0.0011
(0.0017)
-0.0137
(0.0014)

0.0018
(0.0008)
-0.0065
(0.0006)

0.0015
(0.0005)
-0.0054
(0.0004)

0.0011
(0.0008)

0.0011
(0.0005)

0.0008
(0.0003)

0.0019
(0.0018)
-0.0140
(0.0012)

0.0019
(0.0010)
-0.0072
(0.0006)

0.0014
(0.0007)
-0.0060
(0.0004)

0.0014
(0.0010)

0.0020
(0.0006)

0.0013
(0.0004)

-0.0025
(0.0014)
-0.0055
(0.0016)

-0.0005
(0.0006)
-0.0030
(0.0008)

-0.0003
(0.0005)
-0.0022
(0.0006)

0.0046
(0.0019)
-0.0137
(0.0012)

0.0042
(0.0012)
-0.0072
(0.0007)

0.0029
(0.0009)
-0.0060
(0.0005)

-0.0007
(0.0011)

0.0004
(0.0008)

0.0004
(0.0005)

0.0024
(0.0012)
-0.0021
(0.0017)

0.0028
(0.0007)
-0.0015
(0.0009)

0.0029
(0.0007)
-0.0012
(0.0007)

0.0021
(0.0025)
-0.0144
(0.0017)

0.0042
(0.0019)
-0.0072
(0.0010)

0.0036
(0.0014)
-0.0061
(0.0007)

0.0090
(0.0034)

0.0086
(0.0028)

0.0069
(0.0021)

Notes: These numbers are calculated using marginal effects calculated from logit estimates, not shown. Controls are: (1) age dummies; (2) age, education; (3) age, education,
race/ethnicity; (4) age, race, ethnicity, education. Standard errors are calculated as for the difference between two means. The sample is limited to native-born and naturalized
citizens.
a
Within Census differences are calculated by subtracting the given cohort’s probability from the probability for the cohort that arrived 10 years earlier.
a
Between Census differences are calculated by subtracting the probability for a given cohort in the two different Censuses (Probability in later census – probability in earlier
census).

44

Table 5b. Differences in Institutionalization Rates Across Immigrant Arrival Cohorts
Naturalized U.S. Citizens and Native-Born Only
(Standard Errors in Parentheses)
1980 versus 1990

1990 versus 2000

Years since
Arrival
Fewer than 5
Between 5 and 10

Fewer than 5
Between 5 and 10

(1)
-0.0066
(0.0018)
-0.0040
(0.0013)
-0.0190
(0.0015)
-0.0203
(0.0009)

(2)
-0.0048
(0.0007)
-0.0034
(0.0006)
1980 versus 2000
-0.0107
(0.0006)
-0.0116
(0.0005)

(3)
-0.0037
(0.0005)
-0.0027
(0.0005)

(1)
-0.0124
(0.0016)
-0.0163
(0.0011)

(2)
-0.0059
(0.0007)
-0.0082
(0.0006)

(3)
-0.0049
(0.0004)
-0.0065
(0.0004)

-0.0085
(0.0005)
-0.0092
(0.0004)

Notes: These numbers are calculated from marginal effects for logit estimates -- subtracting the relative institutionalization rate for
a cohort in 1980 (1990 respectively) from the relative institutionalization rate of the cohort in 1990 (2000 respectively) that had
been in the U.S. for a comparable length of time. The bottom panel subtracts 1980 values from 2000 values. Column numbers refer
to the specification from which the institutionalization rates were estimated

45

Table 6a. Institutionalization and Immigrant Arrival Cohorts Compared to the Native-Born in 1980, 1990 and 2000
All Immigrants and Native-Born who have Moved across States
(Standard Errors in Parentheses)
1980
1990
2000
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(1)
(2)
(3)
1996-2000 Cohort
Within Census a
1991-1995 Cohort
Within Census a
1985-1990 Cohort
Within Census a
Between Census b
1980-1984 Cohort
Within Census a
Between Census b
1975-1979 Cohort
Within Census a
Between Census b
1970-1974 Cohort
Within Census a
Between Census b

(4)

0.0036
(0.0003)

0.0012
(0.0003)

0.0010
(0.0002)

0.0010
(0.0003)

0.0051
(0.0025)

-0.0080
(0.0002)

0.0020
(0.0002)

0.0021
(0.0002)

0.0053
(0.0008)
-0.0030
(0.0005)

0.0022
(0.0004)
-0.0013
(0.0003)

0.0018
(0.0003)
-0.0015
(0.0003)

0.0018
(0.0004)
-0.0019
(0.0003)

0.0031
(0.0005)

0.0025
(0.0003)

0.0023
(0.0002)

0.0024
(0.0002)

0.0018
(0.0012)
-0.0044
(0.0006)

0.0011
(0.0005)
-0.0011
(0.0003)

0.0010
(0.0004)
-0.0011
(0.0002)

0.0010
(0.0042)
-0.0014
(0.0003)

0.0028
(0.0008)

0.0022
(0.0003)

0.0018
(0.0003)

0.0018
(0.0003)

0.0017
(0.0005)
0.0017
(0.0007)

0.0009
(0.0002)
-0.0010
(0.0003)

0.0009
(0.0002)
-0.0008
(0.0003)

0.0008
(0.0003)
-0.0013
(0.0004)

0.0046
(0.0015)
-0.0051
(0.0008)

0.0032
(0.0007)
-0.0010
(0.0003)

0.0025
(0.0005)
-0.0010
(0.0003)

0.0038
(0.0009)
-0.0012
(0.0003)

0.0009
(0.0010)

0.0014
(0.0005)

0.0012
(0.0004)

0.0011
(0.0003)

0.0030
(0.0007)
0.0019
(0.0011)

0.0021
(0.0003)
-0.0007
(0.0004)

0.0023
(0.0004)
-0.0006
(0.0004)

0.0025
(0.0005)
-0.0010
(0.0042)

0.0029
(0.0020)
-0.0034
(0.0012)

0.0036
(0.0010)
0.0000
(0.0005)

0.0033
(0.0009)
-0.0003
(0.0004)

0.0024
(0.0043)
-0.0007
(0.0042)

0.0046
(0.0022)

0.0038
(0.0012)

0.0035
(0.0010)

0.0031
(0.0009)

Notes: These numbers are calculated using marginal effects calculated from logit estimates, not shown. All specifications include a full set of age dummies. Controls are: (1) age dummies; (2) age,
education; (3) age, education, race/ethnicity; (4) age, race, ethnicity, education, and U.S. citizen. Standard errors are calculated as for the difference between two means.
a
Within Census differences are calculated by subtracting the given cohort’s probability from the probability for the cohort that arrived 10 years earlier.
a
Between Census differences are calculated by subtracting the probability for a given cohort in the two different Censuses (Probability in later census – probability in earlier census).

46

Table 6b. Differences in Institutionalization Rates Across Immigrant Arrival Cohorts
All Immigrants and Native-Born who have Moved across States
(Standard Errors in Parentheses)
1980 versus 1990

1990 versus 2000

Years since
Arrival
Fewer than 5
Between 5 and 10

Fewer than 5
Between 5 and 10

(1)
-0.0036
(0.0005)
0.0001
(0.0006)
-0.0101
(0.0003)
-0.0094
(0.0025)

(2)
(3)
-0.0032
-0.0026
(0.0003)
(0.0003)
-0.0019
-0.0016
(0.0003)
(0.0003)
1980 versus 2000
-0.0057
-0.0051
(0.0002)
(0.0002)
0.0050
-0.0047
(0.0002)
(0.0002)

(4)
-0.0031
(0.0003)
-0.0021
(0.0004)

(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
-0.0065 -0.0025 -0.0025 -0.0029
(0.0005) (0.0003) (0.0003) (0.0003)
-0.0095 0.0069 -0.0031 -0.0034
(0.0026) (0.0003) (0.0003) (0.0003)

0.0043
(0.0003)
-0.0055
(0.0003)

Notes: These numbers are calculated from marginal effects for logit estimates -- subtracting the relative institutionalization rate for a cohort in
1980 (1990 respectively) from the relative institutionalization rate of the cohort in 1990 (2000 respectively) that had been in the U.S. for a
comparable length of time. The bottom panel subtracts 1980 values from 2000 values. Column numbers refer to the specification from which
the institutionalization rates were estimated. See notes to Table 8a for list of controls. Standard errors are calculated as for difference between
two means.

47

Figure 1: Institutionalization and Real Hourly Wages, 2000, by Country
0.04

0.035

U.S.

Fraction Institutionalized

0.03
Dom Rep

Jamaica

0.025
Cuba
0.02
Colombia

Germany

0.015
Haiti
0.01

Italy
Mexico

Canada
El Salvador

0.005 Guatemala

Vietnam
Phil.

England
China

Korea
10

12

14

16

Iran

Japan

Taiwan

0
18

20

weighted regression
line w/o U.S.

India
22

24

26

Real Hourly Wage

48

Figure 2: Real Hourly Wages vs.Welfare Receipt, 2000, by country
0.018
Cuba
0.016

Iran

Vietnam

Fraction Receiving Welfare

0.014

Dom. Rep.

0.012

U.S.

0.01

Mexico

0.008
Guatemala

Jamaica
El Salvador
Haiti
Germany

Phil

0.006

England

Colombia
China

0.004

Italy

Canada
Taiwan

Korea
0.002

weighted regression
line w/o U.S.
Japan
India

0
10

12

14

16

18

20

22

24

26

Real Wages

49

Figure 3: Real Hourly Wages vs. Labor Force Participation, 2000, by country
0.9
England
Canada

0.85

Italy
U.S.

Germany
Iran

0.8

Fraction Participating

India

weighted regression
line w/o U.S.

Phil.

Jamaica

China
Mexico
El Salvador

0.75

Vietnam

Guate.

Cuba
Colombia

Haiti

Korea
0.7

Taiwan

Japan

Dom. Rep.
0.65

0.6
10

12

14

16

18

20

22

24

26

Real Hourly Wage

50

Figure 4. Fraction Immigrant Inside and Outside Institutions
0.18

0.16

0.14

Fraction Immigrant

0.12

0.1
Fraction Immigrant Non-Institution
Fraction Immigrant Institution
0.08

0.06

0.04

0.02

0
1980

1990

2000

Year

51

Figure 5. Institutionalization by Age
Native-born and Most Recent Immigrant Cohort
1980, 1990,and 2000 Census

0.045

0.04

Fraction Institutionalized

0.035

0.03
Native-born 2000
Native-born 1990

0.025

Native-born 1980
Recent Immig 2000
Recent Immigs 1990

0.02

Recent Immigs 1980
0.015

0.01

0.005

0
18

19

20

21

22

23

24

25

26

27

28

29

30

31

32

33

34

35

36

37

38

39

40

Age

52

Figure 6. Predicted Institutionalization Rates For Immigrants
0.08

0.07

Predicted Fraction Institutionalized

0.06

0.05
Prediction based on age
0.04

Prediction based on age, race/ethnicity, and
education

0.03

0.02

0.01

0
1980

1990

2000

Year

Notes: These numbers are calculated from logit regressions using the 5% Public Use Microdata Samples of the U.S. Census. Predictions are created by running the logits for
natives alone and predicting immigrant institutionalization rates using these coefficients and the characteristics of immigrants. Controls include a full set of age dummies and
dichotomous variables for black, Asian, other race, Hispanic origin, high school dropout, high school degree, and some college.

53

Figure 7. Changes in Metropolitan Area (MA) Crime Rates
by Changes in Fraction Immigrant
1990 to 2000
1,000

Change in overall crime rate

0

-1,000

-2,000

regression line w eighted by MA population
t=-1.82

-3,000

-4,000
-0.02

0.00

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.10

Change in fraction im migrant

54

Appendix Table 1a. Institutionalization and Immigrant Arrival Cohorts Compared to the Native-Born in 1980, 1990 and 2000
Evaluated at a constant set of characteristics across Censuses
(Standard Errors in Parentheses)
1980
1990
2000
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(1)
(2)
(3)
1996-2000 Cohort
Within Census a
0.0041
0.0023
0.0023
(0.0012) (0.0000) (0.0000)
1991-1995 Cohort
Within Census a
0.0070
0.0051
0.0052
(0.0012) (0.0000) (0.0000)
1985-1990 Cohort
Within Census a
0.0063
0.0038
0.0040
0.0040
0.0030
0.0042
0.0045
(2.0000) (3.0000) (4.0000) (5.0000) (0.0014) (0.0000) (0.0000)
Between Census b
-0.0146
-0.0248
-0.0345
-0.0605
(0.0011) (0.0008) (0.0012) (0.0063)
1980-1984 Cohort
Within Census a
0.0025
0.0022
0.0025
0.0025
0.0044
0.0084
0.0087
(0.0016) (0.0013) (0.0018) (0.0034) (0.0017) (0.0000) (0.0000
Between Census b
-0.0160
-0.0245
-0.0339
-0.0592
(0.0012) (0.0008) (0.0011) (0.0061)
1975-1979 Cohort
Within Census a
0.0018
0.0009
0.0010
0.0007
0.0061
0.0080
0.0085
0.0085
0.0011
0.0060
0.0068
(0.0008) (0.0005) (0.0007)
0.0012
(0.0021) (0.0018) (0.0022) (0.0034) (0.0022) (0.0000) (0.0000)
Between Census b
0.0012
-0.0069
-0.0121
-0.0162
-0.0179
-0.0245
-0.0340
-0.0589
(0.0011) (0.0009) (0.0013)
(0.0026)
(0.0015) (0.0008) (0.0012) (0.0061)
1970-1974 Cohort
Within Census a
0.0040
0.0037
0.0043
0.0033
0.0041
0.0101
0.0124
0.0123
0.0085
0.0201
0.0258
(0.0010) (0.0007) (0.0009)
0.0012
(0.0029) (0.0029) (0.0033) (0.0041) (0.0045) (0.0000) (0.0000)
Between Census b
0.0019
-0.0056
-0.0108
-0.0149
-0.0140
-0.0183
-0.0276
-0.0509
(0.0015) (0.0011) (0.0015)
(0.0026)
(0.0020) (0.0011) (0.0014) (0.0059)

(4)
0.0026
(0.0082)
0.0062
(0.0081)
0.0056
(0.0081)

0.0108
(0.0078)

0.0089
(0.0080)

0.0327
(0.0110)

Notes: These numbers are calculated using marginal effects calculated from logit estimates, not shown. Here, we evaluate the marginal effects at the same values across all censuses: 25 year old
Hispanics with a high school degree. All specifications include a full set of age dummies. Controls are: (1) age dummies; (2) age, education; (3) age, education, race/ethnicity; (4) age, race, ethnicity,
education, and u.s. citizen. Standard errors are calculated as for the difference between two means.
a
Within Census differences are calculated by subtracting the given cohort’s probability from the probability for the cohort that arrived 10 years earlier.
a
Between Census differences are calculated by subtracting the probability for a given cohort in the two different Censuses (Probability in later census – probability in earlier census).

55

Appendix Table 1b. Differences in Institutionalization Rates Across Immigrant Arrival Cohorts
Evaluated at a constant set of characteristics across Censuses
(Standard Errors in Parentheses)
1980 versus 1990

1990 versus 2000

Years since
Arrival
Fewer than 5
Between 5 and 10

Fewer than 5
Between 5 and 10

(1)
-0.0051
(0.0009)
-0.0006
(0.0010)
-0.0239
(0.0010)
-0.0236
(0.0010)

(2)
(3)
-0.0107
-0.0161
(0.0008)
(0.0012)
-0.0078
-0.0133
(0.0008)
(0.0012)
1980 versus 2000
-0.0378
-0.0528
(0.0003)
(0.0005)
-0.0374
-0.0524
(0.0004)
(0.0005)

(4)
-0.0202
(0.0027)
-0.0173
(0.0026)

(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
-0.0188 -0.0271 -0.0368 -0.0632
(0.0011) (0.0008) (0.0012) (0.0064)
-0.0230 -0.0296 -0.0392 -0.0655
(0.0012) (0.0008) (0.0011) (0.0063)

-0.0834
(0.0059)
-0.0828
(0.0059)

Notes: These numbers are calculated from marginal effects for logit estimates -- subtracting the relative institutionalization rate for a cohort in
1980 (1990 respectively) from the relative institutionalization rate of the cohort in 1990 (2000 respectively) that had been in the U.S. for a
comparable length of time. The bottom panel subtracts 1980 values from 2000 values. Column numbers refer to the specification from which
the institutionalization rates were estimated. See notes to Table 4a for list of controls. Marginal effects were calculated for 25 year old
Hispanics with a high school degree. Standard errors are calculated as for difference between two means.

56

Appendix Table 2a. Institutionalization and Immigrant Arrival Cohorts Compared to the Native-Born in 1980, 1990 and 2000
Immigrants who Arrived as Children and Native-Born
(Standard Errors in Parentheses)
1980
1990
2000
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(1)
(2)
(3)
1996-2000 Cohort
Within Census a
0.0032
0.0011
0.0008
(0.0004) (0.0002) (0.0002)
1991-1995 Cohort
Within Census a
0.0041
0.0017
0.0013
(0.0006) (0.0002) (0.0002)
1985-1990 Cohort
Within Census a
0.0002
0.0015
0.0011
0.0011
0.0030
0.0017
0.0015
(0.0009) (0.0004) (0.0016) (0.0004) (0.0008) (0.0003) (0.0002)
Between Census b
-0.0124
-0.0048
-0.0042
-0.0041
(0.0005) (0.0003) (0.0016) (0.0003)
1980-1984 Cohort
Within Census a
0.0017
-0.0005
-0.0002
0.0000
0.0021
0.0016
0.0012
(0.0014) (0.0005) (0.0004) (0.0004) (0.0029) (0.0011) (0.0007)
Between Census b
-0.0085
-0.0051
-0.0042
-0.0040
(0.0006) (0.0003) (0.0002) (0.0003)
1975-1979 Cohort
Within Census a
0.0005
0.0002
0.0002
0.0001
0.0060
0.0023
0.0016
0.0015
0.0198
0.0143
0.0122
(0.0005) (0.0002) (0.0002)
(0.0003)
(0.0029) (0.0011) (0.0008) (0.0007) (0.0008) (0.0003) (0.0002)
Between Census b -0.0002 -0.0023
-0.0018
-0.0026
-0.0096
-0.0046
-0.0038
-0.0037
(0.0008) (0.0003) (0.0003)
(0.0004)
(0.0011) (0.0004) (0.0003) (0.0003)
1970-1974 Cohort
Within Census a
0.0010
0.0008
0.0009
0.0009
0.0103
0.0101
0.0087
0.0090
0.0184
0.0131
0.0115
(0.0009) (0.0004) (0.0004)
(0.0005)
(0.0012) (0.0004) (0.0003) (0.0003) (0.0029) (0.0011) (0.0007)
Between Census b -0.0008 -0.0029
-0.0021
-0.0027
-0.0080
-0.0030
-0.0029
-0.0029
(0.0013) (0.0005) (0.0003)
(0.0004)
(0.0031) (0.0012) (0.0007) (0.0006)

(4)
0.0009
(0.0002)
0.0014
(0.0002)
0.0016
(0.0002)

0.0011
(0.0006)

0.0125
(0.0002)

0.0119
(0.0005)

Notes: These numbers are calculated using marginal effects calculated from logit estimates, not shown. All specifications include a full set of age dummies. Controls are: (1) age dummies; (2) age,
education; (3) age, education, race/ethnicity; (4) age, race, ethnicity, education, and u.s. citizen. Standard errors are calculated as for the difference between two means.
a
Within Census differences are calculated by subtracting the given cohort’s probability from the probability for the cohort that arrived 10 years earlier.
a
Between Census differences are calculated by subtracting the probability for a given cohort in the two different Censuses (Probability in later census – probability in earlier census).

57

Appendix Table 2b. Differences in Institutionalization Rates Across Immigrant Arrival Cohorts
Immigrants who Arrived as Children and Native-Born
(Standard Errors in Parentheses)
1980 versus 1990

1990 versus 2000

Years since
Arrival
Fewer than 5
Between 5 and 10

Fewer than 5
Between 5 and 10

(1)
-0.0004
(0.0005)
-0.0025
(0.0007)
-0.0160
(0.0003)
-0.0151
(0.0004)

(2)
(3)
-0.0039
-0.0029
(0.0002)
(0.0016)
-0.0024
-0.0020
(0.0003)
(0.0002)
1980 versus 2000
-0.0097
-0.0079
(0.0002)
(0.0002)
-0.0093
-0.0075
(0.0002)
(0.0002)

(4)
-0.0037
(0.0003)
-0.0027
(0.0003)

(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
-0.0156 -0.0058 -0.0050 -0.0050
(0.0005) (0.0003) (0.0016) (0.0003)
-0.0126 -0.0068 -0.0055 -0.0054
(0.0006) (0.0003) (0.0002) (0.0003)

-0.0087
(0.0003)
-0.0081
(0.0003)

Notes: These numbers are calculated from marginal effects for logit estimates -- subtracting the relative institutionalization rate for a cohort in
1980 (1990 respectively) from the relative institutionalization rate of the cohort in 1990 (2000 respectively) that had been in the U.S. for a
comparable length of time. The bottom panel subtracts 1980 values from 2000 values. Column numbers refer to the specification from which
the institutionalization rates were estimated. See notes to Table 7a for list of controls. Standard errors are calculated as for difference between
two means.

58

Working Paper Series
A series of research studies on regional economic issues relating to the Seventh Federal
Reserve District, and on financial and economic topics.
Outsourcing Business Services and the Role of Central Administrative Offices
Yukako Ono

WP-02-01

Strategic Responses to Regulatory Threat in the Credit Card Market*
Victor Stango

WP-02-02

The Optimal Mix of Taxes on Money, Consumption and Income
Fiorella De Fiore and Pedro Teles

WP-02-03

Expectation Traps and Monetary Policy
Stefania Albanesi, V. V. Chari and Lawrence J. Christiano

WP-02-04

Monetary Policy in a Financial Crisis
Lawrence J. Christiano, Christopher Gust and Jorge Roldos

WP-02-05

Regulatory Incentives and Consolidation: The Case of Commercial Bank Mergers
and the Community Reinvestment Act
Raphael Bostic, Hamid Mehran, Anna Paulson and Marc Saidenberg

WP-02-06

Technological Progress and the Geographic Expansion of the Banking Industry
Allen N. Berger and Robert DeYoung

WP-02-07

Choosing the Right Parents: Changes in the Intergenerational Transmission
of Inequality  Between 1980 and the Early 1990s
David I. Levine and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-02-08

The Immediacy Implications of Exchange Organization
James T. Moser

WP-02-09

Maternal Employment and Overweight Children
Patricia M. Anderson, Kristin F. Butcher and Phillip B. Levine

WP-02-10

The Costs and Benefits of Moral Suasion: Evidence from the Rescue of
Long-Term Capital Management
Craig Furfine

WP-02-11

On the Cyclical Behavior of Employment, Unemployment and Labor Force Participation
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-02-12

Do Safeguard Tariffs and Antidumping Duties Open or Close Technology Gaps?
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-02-13

Technology Shocks Matter
Jonas D. M. Fisher

WP-02-14

Money as a Mechanism in a Bewley Economy
Edward J. Green and Ruilin Zhou

WP-02-15

1

Working Paper Series (continued)
Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy: Equivalence Results
Isabel Correia, Juan Pablo Nicolini and Pedro Teles

WP-02-16

Real Exchange Rate Fluctuations and the Dynamics of Retail Trade Industries
on the U.S.-Canada Border
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Beverly Lapham

WP-02-17

Bank Procyclicality, Credit Crunches, and Asymmetric Monetary Policy Effects:
A Unifying Model
Robert R. Bliss and George G. Kaufman

WP-02-18

Location of Headquarter Growth During the 90s
Thomas H. Klier

WP-02-19

The Value of Banking Relationships During a Financial Crisis:
Evidence from Failures of Japanese Banks
Elijah Brewer III, Hesna Genay, William Curt Hunter and George G. Kaufman

WP-02-20

On the Distribution and Dynamics of Health Costs
Eric French and John Bailey Jones

WP-02-21

The Effects of Progressive Taxation on Labor Supply when Hours and Wages are
Jointly Determined
Daniel Aaronson and Eric French

WP-02-22

Inter-industry Contagion and the Competitive Effects of Financial Distress Announcements:
Evidence from Commercial Banks and Life Insurance Companies
Elijah Brewer III and William E. Jackson III

WP-02-23

State-Contingent Bank Regulation With Unobserved Action and
Unobserved Characteristics
David A. Marshall and Edward Simpson Prescott

WP-02-24

Local Market Consolidation and Bank Productive Efficiency
Douglas D. Evanoff and Evren Örs

WP-02-25

Life-Cycle Dynamics in Industrial Sectors. The Role of Banking Market Structure
Nicola Cetorelli

WP-02-26

Private School Location and Neighborhood Characteristics
Lisa Barrow

WP-02-27

Teachers and Student Achievement in the Chicago Public High Schools
Daniel Aaronson, Lisa Barrow and William Sander

WP-02-28

The Crime of 1873: Back to the Scene
François R. Velde

WP-02-29

Trade Structure, Industrial Structure, and International Business Cycles
Marianne Baxter and Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-02-30

Estimating the Returns to Community College Schooling for Displaced Workers
Louis Jacobson, Robert LaLonde and Daniel G. Sullivan

WP-02-31

2

Working Paper Series (continued)
A Proposal for Efficiently Resolving Out-of-the-Money Swap Positions
at Large Insolvent Banks
George G. Kaufman

WP-03-01

Depositor Liquidity and Loss-Sharing in Bank Failure Resolutions
George G. Kaufman

WP-03-02

Subordinated Debt and Prompt Corrective Regulatory Action
Douglas D. Evanoff and Larry D. Wall

WP-03-03

When is Inter-Transaction Time Informative?
Craig Furfine

WP-03-04

Tenure Choice with Location Selection: The Case of Hispanic Neighborhoods
in Chicago
Maude Toussaint-Comeau and Sherrie L.W. Rhine

WP-03-05

Distinguishing Limited Commitment from Moral Hazard in Models of
Growth with Inequality*
Anna L. Paulson and Robert Townsend

WP-03-06

Resolving Large Complex Financial Organizations
Robert R. Bliss

WP-03-07

The Case of the Missing Productivity Growth:
Or, Does information technology explain why productivity accelerated in the United States
but not the United Kingdom?
Susanto Basu, John G. Fernald, Nicholas Oulton and Sylaja Srinivasan

WP-03-08

Inside-Outside Money Competition
Ramon Marimon, Juan Pablo Nicolini and Pedro Teles

WP-03-09

The Importance of Check-Cashing Businesses to the Unbanked: Racial/Ethnic Differences
William H. Greene, Sherrie L.W. Rhine and Maude Toussaint-Comeau

WP-03-10

A Firm’s First Year
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-03-11

Market Size Matters
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Hugo A. Hopenhayn

WP-03-12

The Cost of Business Cycles under Endogenous Growth
Gadi Barlevy

WP-03-13

The Past, Present, and Probable Future for Community Banks
Robert DeYoung, William C. Hunter and Gregory F. Udell

WP-03-14

Measuring Productivity Growth in Asia: Do Market Imperfections Matter?
John Fernald and Brent Neiman

WP-03-15

Revised Estimates of Intergenerational Income Mobility in the United States
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-03-16

3

Working Paper Series (continued)
Product Market Evidence on the Employment Effects of the Minimum Wage
Daniel Aaronson and Eric French

WP-03-17

Estimating Models of On-the-Job Search using Record Statistics
Gadi Barlevy

WP-03-18

Banking Market Conditions and Deposit Interest Rates
Richard J. Rosen

WP-03-19

Creating a National State Rainy Day Fund: A Modest Proposal to Improve Future
State Fiscal Performance
Richard Mattoon

WP-03-20

Managerial Incentive and Financial Contagion
Sujit Chakravorti, Anna Llyina and Subir Lall

WP-03-21

Women and the Phillips Curve: Do Women’s and Men’s Labor Market Outcomes
Differentially Affect Real Wage Growth and Inflation?
Katharine Anderson, Lisa Barrow and Kristin F. Butcher

WP-03-22

Evaluating the Calvo Model of Sticky Prices
Martin Eichenbaum and Jonas D.M. Fisher

WP-03-23

The Growing Importance of Family and Community: An Analysis of Changes in the
Sibling Correlation in Earnings
Bhashkar Mazumder and David I. Levine

WP-03-24

Should We Teach Old Dogs New Tricks? The Impact of Community College Retraining
on Older Displaced Workers
Louis Jacobson, Robert J. LaLonde and Daniel Sullivan

WP-03-25

Trade Deflection and Trade Depression
Chad P. Brown and Meredith A. Crowley

WP-03-26

China and Emerging Asia: Comrades or Competitors?
Alan G. Ahearne, John G. Fernald, Prakash Loungani and John W. Schindler

WP-03-27

International Business Cycles Under Fixed and Flexible Exchange Rate Regimes
Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-03-28

Firing Costs and Business Cycle Fluctuations
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-03-29

Spatial Organization of Firms
Yukako Ono

WP-03-30

Government Equity and Money: John Law’s System in 1720 France
François R. Velde

WP-03-31

Deregulation and the Relationship Between Bank CEO
Compensation and Risk-Taking
Elijah Brewer III, William Curt Hunter and William E. Jackson III

WP-03-32

4

Working Paper Series (continued)
Compatibility and Pricing with Indirect Network Effects: Evidence from ATMs
Christopher R. Knittel and Victor Stango

WP-03-33

Self-Employment as an Alternative to Unemployment
Ellen R. Rissman

WP-03-34

Where the Headquarters are – Evidence from Large Public Companies 1990-2000
Tyler Diacon and Thomas H. Klier

WP-03-35

Standing Facilities and Interbank Borrowing: Evidence from the Federal Reserve’s
New Discount Window
Craig Furfine

WP-04-01

Netting, Financial Contracts, and Banks: The Economic Implications
William J. Bergman, Robert R. Bliss, Christian A. Johnson and George G. Kaufman

WP-04-02

Real Effects of Bank Competition
Nicola Cetorelli

WP-04-03

Finance as a Barrier To Entry: Bank Competition and Industry Structure in
Local U.S. Markets?
Nicola Cetorelli and Philip E. Strahan

WP-04-04

The Dynamics of Work and Debt
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-04-05

Fiscal Policy in the Aftermath of 9/11
Jonas Fisher and Martin Eichenbaum

WP-04-06

Merger Momentum and Investor Sentiment: The Stock Market Reaction
To Merger Announcements
Richard J. Rosen

WP-04-07

Earnings Inequality and the Business Cycle
Gadi Barlevy and Daniel Tsiddon

WP-04-08

Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets: The Case of Payment Networks
Sujit Chakravorti and Roberto Roson

WP-04-09

Nominal Debt as a Burden on Monetary Policy
Javier Díaz-Giménez, Giorgia Giovannetti, Ramon Marimon, and Pedro Teles

WP-04-10

On the Timing of Innovation in Stochastic Schumpeterian Growth Models
Gadi Barlevy

WP-04-11

Policy Externalities: How US Antidumping Affects Japanese Exports to the EU
Chad P. Bown and Meredith A. Crowley

WP-04-12

Sibling Similarities, Differences and Economic Inequality
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-04-13

Determinants of Business Cycle Comovement: A Robust Analysis
Marianne Baxter and Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-04-14

5

Working Paper Series (continued)
The Occupational Assimilation of Hispanics in the U.S.: Evidence from Panel Data
Maude Toussaint-Comeau

WP-04-15

Reading, Writing, and Raisinets1: Are School Finances Contributing to Children’s Obesity?
Patricia M. Anderson and Kristin F. Butcher

WP-04-16

Learning by Observing: Information Spillovers in the Execution and Valuation
of Commercial Bank M&As
Gayle DeLong and Robert DeYoung

WP-04-17

Prospects for Immigrant-Native Wealth Assimilation:
Evidence from Financial Market Participation
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-04-18

Individuals and Institutions: Evidence from International Migrants in the U.S.
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-04-19

Are Technology Improvements Contractionary?
Susanto Basu, John Fernald and Miles Kimball

WP-04-20

The Minimum Wage, Restaurant Prices and Labor Market Structure
Daniel Aaronson, Eric French and James MacDonald

WP-04-21

Betcha can’t acquire just one: merger programs and compensation
Richard J. Rosen

WP-04-22

Not Working: Demographic Changes, Policy Changes,
and the Distribution of Weeks (Not) Worked
Lisa Barrow and Kristin F. Butcher

WP-04-23

The Role of Collateralized Household Debt in Macroeconomic Stabilization
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-04-24

Advertising and Pricing at Multiple-Output Firms: Evidence from U.S. Thrift Institutions
Robert DeYoung and Evren Örs

WP-04-25

Monetary Policy with State Contingent Interest Rates
Bernardino Adão, Isabel Correia and Pedro Teles

WP-04-26

Comparing location decisions of domestic and foreign auto supplier plants
Thomas Klier, Paul Ma and Daniel P. McMillen

WP-04-27

China’s export growth and US trade policy
Chad P. Bown and Meredith A. Crowley

WP-04-28

Where do manufacturing firms locate their Headquarters?
J. Vernon Henderson and Yukako Ono

WP-04-29

Monetary Policy with Single Instrument Feedback Rules
Bernardino Adão, Isabel Correia and Pedro Teles

WP-04-30

6

Working Paper Series (continued)
Firm-Specific Capital, Nominal Rigidities and the Business Cycle
David Altig, Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum and Jesper Linde

WP-05-01

Do Returns to Schooling Differ by Race and Ethnicity?
Lisa Barrow and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP-05-02

Derivatives and Systemic Risk: Netting, Collateral, and Closeout
Robert R. Bliss and George G. Kaufman

WP-05-03

Risk Overhang and Loan Portfolio Decisions
Robert DeYoung, Anne Gron and Andrew Winton

WP-05-04

Characterizations in a random record model with a non-identically distributed initial record
Gadi Barlevy and H. N. Nagaraja

WP-05-05

Price discovery in a market under stress: the U.S. Treasury market in fall 1998
Craig H. Furfine and Eli M. Remolona

WP-05-06

Politics and Efficiency of Separating Capital and Ordinary Government Budgets
Marco Bassetto with Thomas J. Sargent

WP-05-07

Rigid Prices: Evidence from U.S. Scanner Data
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Benjamin Eden

WP-05-08

Entrepreneurship, Frictions, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-05-09

Wealth inequality: data and models
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-05-10

What Determines Bilateral Trade Flows?
Marianne Baxter and Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-05-11

Intergenerational Economic Mobility in the U.S., 1940 to 2000
Daniel Aaronson and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-05-12

Differential Mortality, Uncertain Medical Expenses, and the Saving of Elderly Singles
Mariacristina De Nardi, Eric French, and John Bailey Jones

WP-05-13

Fixed Term Employment Contracts in an Equilibrium Search Model
Fernando Alvarez and Marcelo Veracierto

WP-05-14

Causality, Causality, Causality: The View of Education Inputs and Outputs from Economics
Lisa Barrow and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP-05-15

7

Working Paper Series (continued)
Competition in Large Markets
Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-05-16

Why Do Firms Go Public? Evidence from the Banking Industry
Richard J. Rosen, Scott B. Smart and Chad J. Zutter

WP-05-17

Clustering of Auto Supplier Plants in the U.S.: GMM Spatial Logit for Large Samples
Thomas Klier and Daniel P. McMillen

WP-05-18

Why are Immigrants’ Incarceration Rates So Low?
Evidence on Selective Immigration, Deterrence, and Deportation

WP-05-19

Kristin F. Butcher and Anne Morrison Piehl

8