View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Global Inflation
Matteo Ciccarelli and Benoît Mojon

WP 2008-05

Global In ation
Matteo Ciccarelliy
European Central Bank

Beno^t Mojon
European Central Bank
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

First draft: March 2005; This draft: April 2008

Abstract
This paper shows that in ation in industrialized countries is largely a global phenomenon. First, the in ation rates of 22 OECD countries have a common factor that alone
accounts for nearly 70 percent of their variance. This large variance share that is associated
with Global In ation is not only due to the trend components of in ation (up from 1960 to
1980 and down thereafter) but also to uctuations at business cycle frequencies. Second,
we show that, in conformity to the prediction of New Keynesian open economy models,
there is little spillover of in ationay shocks across countries. The comovement of in ation
comes largely from common shocks. Global In ation is a function of real developments
at short horizons and monetary developments at longer horizons. Third, there is a robust
\error correction mechanism" that brings national in ation rates back to Global In ation.
A simple model that accounts for this feature consistently beats the previous benchmarks
used to forecast in ation 4 to 8 quarters ahead across samples and countries.
Key Words: Global In ation, common factor, international business cycle, OECD countries
JEL: E31, E37, F42

We would like to thank Julio Rotemberg (the editor) and an anonymous referee whose comments helped
us improve the paper substantially. We are also indebted to Michel Aglietta, Filippo Altissimo, Micheal Bordo,
Gabriel Fagan, Domenico Giannone, Ronald McKinnon, Je rey Frankel, Anil Kashyap, Nobu Kiyotaki, Simone
Manganeli, Cyril Monnet, Philippe Moutot, Lucrezia Reichlin, Frank Smets, Mike Wickens, Micheal Woodford
and seminar participants at the ECB, the OECD, the IMF, the Bank of Canada and the NBER Summer
Institute 2006 for useful comments on several versions of this paper. Finally, we are very grateful to Daniel Levy
for detailed and constructive comments on the draft, and to Sandrine Corvoisier for excellent research assistance.
The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily re ect the views of the European Central
Bank, or the Federal Reserve System. Remaining errors are our own.
y
Corresponding author: European Central Bank, DG Research, Kaiserstrasse 29, D-60311, Frankfurt am
Main. E-mail: matteo.ciccarelli@ecb.int.

1

Introduction

This paper provides a formal analysis of the international comovement of in ation. We document that the international comovement of in ation has been strikingly high. We then investigate the origin of this comovement before we show one of its potential applications, i.e. that
it can improve the forecasting of national in ation rates.
The idea that macroeconomic developments depend on international conditions is not
new. Measures of this depencence, however, were developed only recently. For instance, Kose,
Otrok and Whiteman (2003) (KOW thereafter) nd that the world's common component to
expenditure time series of 60 countries explains between one fourth and one half of the variance
of these series in OECD countries.1 By de nition, the main risk of ignoring international
developments is to overrate the importance of domestic ones. And these include domestic
macroeconomic policies. As KOW put it:
\ Understanding the sources of international economic uctuations is important
both for developing business cycle models and making policy".
Surprisingly, the studies of global macroeconomic developments had, initially, mostly
focused on the real business cycle. However, the uctuations of in ation have been strikingly
similar around the world. All OECD countries have experienced long-term swings in the level
of in ation. In ation has progressively risen in the 1960s and 1970s before it declined in the
1980's. In ation has further declined in the early to mid-1990's and has since then remained
low and stable. A more recent perspective shows that in ation rates are accelerating in most
countries in 2007 and early 2008.
Prominent economists have recently pointed to the common disin ation trend around
the world (Rogo , 2003) or at least OECD countries (Levin and Piger, 2004, and many others).
These studies may overlook two important aspects of the international comovement of in ation.
First, they restrict their analyses to the post-1980 disin ation, hence disregarding the possibility
that the previous phase, i.e. the acceleration of in ation between 1960 and 1980, was also
very much a shared experience of most countries of the world (a point described early on by
McKinnon, 1982 and Darby and Lothian, 1983, among others). Second, they focus strictly on
the downward trend or on downward breaks of the in ation process, while, as we show in this
paper, there is more than su cient evidence of comovements of in ation at the business cycle
frequencies as well.
1

See also Forni and Reichlin (2001), Canova, Ciccarelli and Ortega (2007) and references therein.

1

We proceed in three sequential steps. We rst document the fact with a simple common
factor analysis. We extract the common component to the quarterly in ation series of 22
OECD countries from 1960 to 2007,2 and quantify the extent to which this measure of \Global
In ation" helps explain national in ations. Subsequently, we test alternative explanations
for the international comovement of in ation. Then we study the empirical implications of
our stylised fact for the dynamics and the predictability of national in ation rates and check
whether it is possible to exploit Global In ation to improve in ation forecasts.
Our main results can be summarized as follows. First the intuition that in ation has been
a global phenomenon is decidedly con rmed by the data. We indeed show that a simple average
of 22 OECD countries in ation, which we call \Global In ation," accounts for 70 percent of the
variance of in ation in these countries between 1960 and 2006. The qualitative result is not only
robust to di erent sample periods, but is also valid at low and at business cycle frequencies,
where the variance explained by Global In ation is about 37 percent on average, and much
larger in numerous countries.
Second, consistently with the conclusions of several versions of New Keynesian open
economy models, we reject that in ationary shocks spill over across countries have been important. Hence, the international comovement in in ation seem to come from the high correlation
of in ation determinants in the OECD. At short horizons, in ation has responded to commodity prices and the international business cycle. At longer horizons, changes in the level of
in ation re ect either major changes in the monetary policy regime that have been coincident
across countries or at least changes in the mean level of in ation tolerated by central banks.
These results are important because they support the notion that in ation can be analyzed
directly at the global level, and it con rms that the 70 percent of in ation variance that is
global depends on both real and monetary developments.
Third, Global In ation is an attractor of national in ation, i.e. national deviations from
their projection on this attractor are reverted. The evidence is again uniform and robust
across sample periods and countries. We also document di erences in the long run impact of
Global In ation. Countries that have experienced stronger commitment to price stability (e.g.
Germany) are less a ected than those with weaker in ation discipline (e.g. Italy). However,
this kind of \Error Correction Mechanism" helps predict national in ation of most OECD
countries at various horizons and over several samples. As a result, our forecasting model of
in ation augmented with the Global In ation consistently outperforms standard AR(p) and
2
Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Japan,
Luxembourg, New Zeland, Norway, the Netherland, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom
and the United States.

2

Random Walk models of in ation, as well as augmented Phillips curve models a la Gerlach
(2003). This seems to be true also in the recent period where unpredictability of in ation
has been documented in the recent literature.3 We argue that existing forecasting models
of in ation do not appropriately account for an international perspective which can improve
predictability upon a simple Random Walk benchmark. These results could lead the Global
In ation model to become a new standard for forecasting in ation in OECD countries.
Several papers on the international comovement of in ation have appeared since the rst
circulation of this paper. Mumtaz and Surico (2008) and Monacelli and Sala (2007) use factor
models to decompose sectoral national in ation rates into world and national components.
Wang and Wen (2007) try to replicate the empirical fact that comovement in in ation rates
is higher than the one in output growth in a variety of calibrated New Keynesian two-country
models. Cecchetti et al. (2007) investigate the reasons why most G7 countries went through the
Great In ation in the seventies and provide evidence in favour of similar changes in monetary
regimes. The main conclusions of these papers do usually not contradict our own.
Our work relates only marginally to the literature on \Globalization and in ation" that
analyzes whether the integration of the world economy has changed in ation dynamics.4 We
nd that in ation has been dominated by common shocks ever since the sixties and this has
not changed over time. Arguably, globalization implies similar terms of trade shocks for OECD
countries, an hypothesis that is fully compatible with our model of in ation but one that we
do not analyze in this paper.
As a nal remark, we shall note that the economic and econometric arguments we use
in this paper do not claim to cover all the reasons for why in ation could be driven by global
outcomes, nor does it pretend to be exhaustive on the empirical investigation of our ndings.
We are con dent, however, that our results may provide a good starting point for exploring
the hypothesis that in ation should {to some extent{ be modelled as a global rather than a
local phenomenon.

2

In ation as a global phenomenon

In this section we document the empirical fact that in ation has largely been a global phenomenon over the last 45 years. We rst describe our data and their necessary transformations.
Then, we estimate the Global In ation using simple alternative measures. Finally, we provide
3

See Atkenson and Ohanian (2004), Stock and Watson (2007) and d'Agostino, Giannone and Surico (2006).
See the IMF Spring 2006 World Econmic Outlook, Chen, Imbs and Scott (2004) and the debate on the
global slack which opposes Borio and Filardo (2007) to Ball (2006), Rogo (2006), Woodford (2007) and Ihrig
et al. (2007).
4

3

some descriptive statistics over di erent subsamples and di erent subgroups of countries.

2.1

Data

Sources and transformations of all data are described in more detail in the appendix.
The data used in this section are values of the CPI indices available quarterly from the
OECD main economic indicators database from 1960 onward. Our analysis mainly focuses on
quarterly year-on-year (y-o-y) in ation rates, which, by construction, have no seasonal pattern.
To analyze the uctuations over the business cycle frequency, we consider a transformation of
the data that lter out the lowest and the highest frequencies. We do this using a band-pass
ltered CPI in ation rates with a pass band that removes all frequencies but the periods of 6
to 32 quarters.

2.2

Estimating Global In ation

In what follows, we brie y describe and compare results for three alternative measures of Global
In ation, namely:
1. A cross-country average;
2. The aggregate OECD in ation, published by the OECD; and,
3. A measure based on static factor analysis.5
Results reported in subsequent sections are mainly based on the simplest and most
intuitive measure, the cross-country average.
The \average" measure is the simple average of the year on year in ation rates of the 22
countries that have been members of the OECD for most of the sample period 1961:2{2006:4.6
The aggregate OECD in ation is a weighted average of all OECD countries' in ation, where
the weights are proportional to GDP. Regarding the common factor analysis, we opted for a
parsimonious approximate factor representation (see e.g. Forni et al., 2000; Stock and Watson,
2002) which decomposes in ation rates for the pool of countries as
t
n 1

=

ft
n 11 1

+ "t

(1)

n 1

where the rst term captures the e ect of a common factor (ft ), to which each country responds
di erently through , whereas the last term refers to the idiosyncratic dynamics which captures
5

Results are almost identical when using a dynamic factor model as introduced, e.g., by Forni et al. (2000).
The 8 OECD countries that we do not include in our sample are Mexico, Korea, Turkey, the Czech Republic,
Hungary, Poland, the Slovak Republic and Iceland.
6

4

the components generated by shocks whose e ects remain local. We assume orthogonality
between ft and "t , and normality of the error term, with "t

N (0; R).

An estimation of the factor is obtained using static principal component methods described in Stock and Watson (2002). Data have been previously demeaned and standardized
to have unit variance before estimating ft .
Figure 1 reports the three measures of Global In ation.7 Two observations are in order.
First, the \average" and the factor model measures are almost identical, while the OECD aggregate deviates from the other 2 series, especially in the second half of the eighties, presumably
because of the di erent sample of countries. Second, the uctuations and trends in the Global
In ation re ect the major events of the last 45 years. All measures are characterized by two
trends, up from 1960 until the late-seventies (associated with the two oil shocks and the decline
in OECD productivity) and down thereafter (re ecting tight monetary policies and the debt
crisis), and,

ve or six cycles along the way. Given that both the seventies Great In ation

and the subsequent tight monetary policy have been observed in most countries, the trend
components of Global In ation perhaps should not come as a surprise. As a matter of fact,
Corvoiser and Mojon (2005) show that breaks in the mean of in ation largely coincide through
out the OECD: around 1970, around 1982 and, to a lesser extent, around 1992. Cecchetti et al
(2007) show that the great in ation of the seventies coincide with prolonged periods of overly
accomodative monetary policy, a point we discuss further in section 3.
To gauge the extent to which the in ation in individual countries are related to Global
In ation, Figure 2 reports the in ation series of the G7 and of the euro area with their projections on the common factor. Visual inspection reveals not only that the trend is captured
accurately, but also that the most relevant cyclical movements are indeed common.

2.3

Descriptive statistics

Table 1 reports the share of the variance of national in ation series that is explained Global
In ation for each of the three measures introduced in the previous section: the simple crosscountry average, the OECD aggregate in ation, and the rst static common factor.8 In each
case, the national idiosyncratic variance is the complement to one of the gures reported in
the table. The last column also shows the share of the variance explained by the second static
factor. The table also reports the variance decomposition exercise for the euro area in ation
rate.
7

The OECD aggregate and the \average" have been de-meaned and standardized for the gure.
This share is de ned as 2i var(ft )=var( it ). It is equivalent to the R-square of a regression of the national
in ation rate on Global In ation and a constant.
8

5

First, all measures of Global in ation explain more than two thirds of national in ation
rates

uctuations on average. The comovement of in ation is decidedly large. By way of

comparison, we nd that the global business cycle accounts on average \only" for about one
third of the variance of industrial production growth in OECD countries.9 It is also clear
that the second common factor of the in ation series explains only a very limited share of
the variance of national in ation series, on average. We consider this fraction small enough
that we can model national in ation rates with one common factor only. We also note that
the OECD aggregate in ation under performs the other three measures. We conjecture that
this is because this aggregate includes countries that are not in our sample. Moreover, within
our sample of countries, we also found that averages that are weighted by country size under
perform the factors and the simple unweighted average (not reported).
Table 1 ranks (the column `average' being the reference) the countries by increasing share
of the in ation variance that is explained by the common factor. Only ve countries have less
than 60 percent of this variance explained by Global In ation. Four of these ve countries,
Greece being the exception, are usually seen as low in ation economies. We also note that the
ranking of the countries has little to do with geography nor the nature of the exchange rate
regime.
The fact that non-European countries are spread through out the distribution casts
doubt on the argument that Global In ation among OECD countries is just a re ection that
a majority of these countries are located in Europe. We actually estimated another measure
of Global In ation using a sample of six countries evenly split across time zones: Canada, US,
UK, the euro area, Japan and Australia. We obtain a even higher median (0.75 instead of 0.73)
and mean (0.74 instead of 0.71) share of in ation variance that is explaned by Global In ation
(see the top panel of Table 2). This result reinforces our conjecture that the comovement of
national in ation rates does not necessarily re ect only European economic developments.
Moreover, the high degree of comovement in in ation may be seen as trivial because
(European) countries in our sample have participated to a monetary union since 1999 after
they had pegged their currency to the Deutsche Mark in one way or another since the late
seventies. For these countries, most of our sample period, from 1960 to 1973 and then from
1979 to 2007, would be closer to a xed exchange rate regime than to a one of oating exchange
rate. For the other countries in the sample, the high degree of comovement could also come
from the long periods of the last 45 years when exchange rate were xed, mainly up to the
9

A similar proportion has been found by KOW and used to document the importance of a common world
real factor.

6

mid seventies or under some form of pegs.10 However, the degree of comovement of in ation
remains strikingly high if one looks at countries that did not pursue any sort of xed exchange
rate policies. This can be seen from the second and third panels of Table 2 where we consider
the same sub-set of six countries as in the previous paragraph, though, this time, on the post
1974, as well as on the post 1983 sample. We obtain again a high degree of comovement of
in ation among countries whose exchange rates were not formally tied together.11
Another somewhat easy explanation of the magnitude of in ation comovement is that it
simply re ects common trends in the in ation series. This is why we now explore how much of
the business cycle uctuations in in ation are correlated across countries. In Table 3 we report
(again ranked taking the column `average' as reference) estimates of the share of de-trended
in ation that is associated to a common factor. The national in ation series were detrended
using Baxter and King (1999) band pass

lter, which extracts cycles of length comprised

between 6 and 32 quarters long with a truncation of 12 lags. These cyclical components of
in ation are then used for extracting the common factor at business cycle frequencies (Figure
3). Again, the share of national in ation variance that is common is very large by any standard
with mean and median on the order of 37 percent.12;13
The comovement of in ation is not only due to the trend component associated with the
seventies great in ation and the coincidence of the countries's in ations gradual acceleration
up to 1980 and the gradual disin ation that followed. Global In ation actually explains a
large share of the in ation variance also in countries like Switzerland and Germany, that is
countries where the seventies in ation have been much smaller than in the average of OECD
countries. A comparison of the ranking of countries in Tables 1 and 3 indicates that, in relative
terms, Global In ation seems to matter more at business cycle frequencies for low in ation
countries, where the share of variance explained by Global In ation is among the lowest when
we don't remove the trend (Table 1), and just below the average when we do remove it (Table
3). This should be contrasted with the experience of countries such as Sweden and Portugal
where the common factor of detrended in ation has less explanatory power for local in ation
developments than the non-detrended measure. These results are a rst indication that the
10

For instance, the US and Japan were de facto pegging their currencies between February 1973 and February
1978; Australia had its exchange rate to the US Dollar uctuate within a narrow horizontal band form October
1974 until November 1982, and the UK were shadowing the ECU in the late 1980's (Reinhart and Rogo , 2002).
11
One notable exception is Germany for the post 1983 sample. The divergence of German in ation from the
world evolution around the reuni cation explain this low degree of co-movement.
12
These results hold for other detrending methods such as the HP tler or the rst di erence lter of in ation.
13
An alternative approach, which consists of comparing the coherence of the cross spectra of Global In ation
and national in ation rates at each frequencies, provides very similar results. For most countries, this coherence
is positive and typically superior to 0.5 at both low and business cycle frequencies. The results (not reported)
are available upon request to the authors.

7

low frequency comovement of in ation is likely due to monetary policy, a point we come back
to in section 3.
Finally, we have computed the cross-correlation of Global In ation with national in ation
series at several leads and lags. This exercise is useful to guring out whether in ation tends to
lag or lead Global In ation in some of the countries. Results (not reported, but available upon
request) show that almost no country is markedly leading or lagging global developments. This
is a rst indication against the possibility that in ation in a particular country (e.g. the U.S.)
has been systematically spilling over to the rest of the OECD countries and that our focus on
Global In ation mistakenly picks up that one country sets the OECD in ation trend.

3

Why has in ation been a global phenomenon?

Given the nding that Global In ation explains a substantial proportion of national in ations'
variance, this section analyzes the likely causes of such commonality, provides quantitative
estimates of the sources of the commonality, and investigates the determinants of the global
factor. We make two important steps in the analysis of international in ation comovement.
First, we reject that this comovement is due to spillovers of country speci c shocks, thereby
bringing support to the conclusions of New Keynesian models of monetary policy in open
economies. Second, we describe the nature of the common shocks that explain the comovement
of in ation across countries. At a short horizon, the variance of global in ation is largely
explained by commodity price shocks and the world business cycle. At a longer horizon,
global in ation echoes major changes in the monetary policy regime that have taken place
simultaneously across OECD countries.

3.1

Some theoretical considerations

The comovement of OECD in ation rates can stem from two general sources:
common shocks that spread evenly or at least simultaneously across countries;
country speci c in ationary shocks that spill over from one or a subset of countries.
The rst possibility is somewhat uncontroversial. Commodity price shocks, internationally correlated productivity shocks, cost push shocks or changes in the stance of monetary
policy could have analogous impacts on OECD in ation rates and therefore induce comovement in in ation rates. The common shocks should induce more comovement in in ation if they
have a strong permanent component, or account for a larger share of the variance of in ation

8

determinants, and if the responses of national in ation rates to these shocks are similar across
countries.
The possibility of synchronization stemming from spillovers is more challenging. For
instance, in the context of a stylized two country New Keynesian model, such as the one
derived by Clarida et al. (2002), there is no spillover of in ation across countries when the
central banks implement optimal policy independently from one another { a situation that is
more likely to characterize the oating exchange rate regime that prevailed since 1975. In fact,
in absence of cooperation, domestic in ation and output depend only on domestic cost push
shocks.14 In the case of policy cooperation, cost push shocks in one country can spill over
abroad. E ectively, the domestic central bank would set its output gap as a function of both
home and foreign in ation. But its policy would depend on the sign of the e ects of foreign
output on domectic marginal costs. Clarida et al. (2002) stress that this sign is indeterminate.15
Hence, cross-country in ationary spillovers need not be positive. And negative spillovers would
hardly explain the international comovement of in ation.16
The case against positive spillovers is reinforced by Wang and Wei (2007) and by Woodford (2007). Wang and Wei (2007) explore calibrated New Keynesian models with either sticky
information or sticky prices in order to assess whether monetary shocks could generate the
high degree of international in ation comovement that we see in the data. They show that,
unless the monetary shocks are themselves correlated, there is little international comovement
in the in ation. Woodford (2007) shows that in the context of sticky price two country models,
central banks keep the control of domestic in ation. For instance, stimulative foreign monetary
policy does not a ect domestic in ation directly, and its indirect e ects through the foreign
output gap occurs through depressing the domestic output gap.
These modeling exercises have two important limitations. First, they tend to focus on one
speci c shocks (cost push for Clarida et al. and monetary for Wang and Wei). We cannot rule
out though that, in the data, a particular combination of shocks could boost the comovement
in in ation rates that would be due to spillover.17 One such spillover channels put forth by
14

Note, however, that this solution is compatible with a high correlation between di erent country in ations
also if similar and independent cost-push shocks hit the two economies at the same time. Such coincidence would
be observationally equivalent to common shocks.
15
In the more likely case of intertemporal elasticities of substitution (1/ in Clarida et al's notations) inferior
to one, the elasticity of domestic marginal cost with respect to foreign output is positive and the spillover of a
foreign cost push shock on domestic in ation is negative.
16
Even in the case of a monetary union, the ultimate degree of monetary cooperation, it is di cult to rule out
that negative in ation spill-overs could be important. In particular, as long as the central bank loss function
depends on the average in ation in the two countries, a shock to in ation in one country would lead to a higher
interest rate for both countries and, potentially, a negative response of in ation in the other country.
17
The simulations reported in Wang and Wei (2007) also show that the degree of in ation comovement obtained
in calibrated two-country models can be very sensitive to modeling assumptions. Some of these, such as opting

9

McKinnon (1983) result from the resistance of central banks to see the dollar either depreciate
too much or appreciate too much. He argues in particular that large scale interventions on
Forex market could have led to over issuance of money when the dollar depreciated in the
seventies and under issuance in the early eighties. For these consideration, in section 3.2 we
assess systematically whether spillovers have been important in the data.
Second, these models describe in ation uctuations around constant steady state in ation rates. Hence, they may not be the best tool to analyze the trend evolution of in ation
and the observed international comovements at low frequencies. Both theoretical and narrative
evidence strongly point to monetary policy as the single determinant of trend in ation. Ball
(2006) argues that even in small open economies, central banks retain the ability to stabilize
in ation at the level of their choice. Moreover, the narrative evidence on shifts in the practise of
monetary policies is compelling. We know for instance that major changes in monetary policies
clustered in two periods of a few years in a majority of OECD countries. First, the early eighties
saw both the US disin ation and the European Monetary System based disin ation in Europe.
Ten years later, most OECD countries were either embarking on the low in ation single currency planned by the Maastrischt treaty or adopting in ation targeting at lower in ation rates
than the one that prevailed in the eighties. Turning to the United States, Goodfriend (2007)
argues that a common understanding that core in ation should be kept near 2 percent arose in
the Federal Open Market Committee in 1995. Hence, the nineties have witnessed all countries
of our sample setting up monetary policy regimes with an in ation objective graviting around
2 percent, and the central banks adopting an explicit or implicit commitment to keep it there.
Ex post, notwithstanding the acceleration of world in ation in 2007 and 2008, in ation has
remained remarkably close to the quanti ed in ation objective or target of the central banks.18
Hence, the common trend in in ation since the late seventies is easily related to the evolution of monetary policies. What about then in ation acceleration in the sixties and seventies?
Cecchetti et al (2007) show that the Great In ation of the seventies relates to continued periods
of loose monetary policies in several G7 countries. The main exception is Germany, where the
low tolerance of the independent Deutsche Bundesbank for in ation in that period is a widely
acknowledged fact. It is precisely the anti-in ation credibility of the German central bank that
led other European countries to anchor domestic in ation expectations through a peg of their
currency to the Deutsche mark from 1979 on within the European Monetary System.
for \cash in advance" rather than \money in the utility function", are however di cult to relate to the evolution
of OECD countries since 1960.
18
Diron and Mojon (2008) show for instance that at one and two-year horizons, in ation targets have been
predictors of in ation.

10

Altogether, theory and narrative evidence suggest that trend in ation have been dominated by changes in the mean level of in ation chosen by monetary authorities. This conclusion
shifts the problem to understanding why major changes in monetary policies with comparable
impacts on trend in ation have coincided across OECD countries. Potential explanations include \peer pressure" between central banks,19 changes in the dominant paradigm in monetary
economics,20 and common changes in preferences due to common demographic trends such
as the baby boom. It however goes beyond the scope of this paper to test these alternative
explanations.
Fluctations of in ation around its trend also have a fair amount of commonality as we
showed in section 2. These uctuations might reasonably have less to do with shifts in monetary
regimes and more with responses to non permanent common shocks.21 The most likely suspects
are shocks to the price of commodities as well as common shocks to output gaps that re ect the
international business cycle (KOW, 2003). In section 3.3, we test these hypotheses by reporting
the ability of various common in ation drivers, be they monetary or real, to forecast global
in ation either in the short run or over a longer horizon.

3.2

Common shocks versus international spillovers

Here we check whether spillovers have been important in the data. Following Stock and Watson
(2005) we extend the speci cation in (1) with an autoregressive component and decompose the
shocks to in ation of G8 countries (G7 and Australia)22 into three sources: common, crosscountry spillovers and domestic shocks.
Using the same notation as before and denoting by

t

the vector of year-on-year in ation

rates, the reduced form VAR is
t

= A (L)

t 1

+

t

where the error terms have a factor structure
t

= ft +

19

t

See for instance Besley and Case (1995) for a model of endogenous in uences of public policies across
geogrpahic areas. It is also stricking that breaks in the mean of in ation in the OECD have clustered around a
few years, a result that reinforce the view that central banks have implemented good and bad monetary policies
together (Corvoisier and Mojon 2005).
20
One could consider (and eventually check) that the Cogley and Sargent (2005) explanation of the Great
In ation is also valid in other countries.
21
The existence of comonalities in the evolution of monetary policy help explain the commonalities in the
trend or long run dynamics of in ation, but could in fact reduce the importance of the global component in
in ation at the business cycle frequencies if, for instance, all central banks following the same reaction function
were perfectly o seting in ation movements due to global forces. We thank the referee for pointing out this
important issue to us.
22
Australia helps rebalance this subset of countries across time zones.

11

As before, ft is the vector of (possibly k) common international factors and, as in Stock and
Watson (2005), we assume the following
E ft ft0

= diag

2
f1 ; :::;

2
fk

0
t t

= diag

2

2

E

1

; :::;

n

The common factors are identi ed as those factors that a ect domestic in ation in all countries
contemporaneously. This is the same speci cation as in (1) with a VAR structure of the
endogenous variable which now, given the assumptions, allows us to decompose the h-step
ahead forecast error variance for in ation into the sum of three sources: common shocks,
idiosyncratic shocks, and spillovers of domestic shocks from the other countries.
In Table 4 we report the variance decomposition at 1, 4 and 16 quarters ahead for
three sub-periods.23 Note rst that given the identi cation assumption, at one-quarter horizon
spillovers do not account for any explained variance. At longer horizon they might account for
a variance between 4 percent and 24 percent for particular countries, and between 9 percent
and 15 percent on average across countries. As expected, most of the variance is explained
by the international factors. Summing up column (1) and (2) the percentage of the variance
explained by the common factors is roughly the one that we have found in Section 2, both at
short and long horizons. Overall, then, these ndings qualify those that have been discussed
before, and show that among the common sources, spillovers { though not entirely ruled out {
account only for a small portion of the common in ation variability.24

3.3

The determinants of global in ation

To determine whether, when and by how much Global In ation may be linked to commodity
prices, real or monetary shock or a combination of these and perhaps other shocks, we evaluate
the predictive power of a set of standard in ation determinants. We proceed with a Bayesian
model selection analysis which is particularly suited to select relevant regressors among a wide
pool of candidate explanatory variables. A detailed description of the methodology is available
in Ciccareli and Mojon (2005).
23
Estimation is done using Maximum Likelihood methods and a factor model approach a la Forni et al (2000)
where the k common factors are generated by q shocks, where q < k. Note that the system is overidentied. Likelihood tests for overidenti cation restrictions reject the null of up to 2 international factors and one
shock against the unrestricted alternative of
having full rank. Results of this part are therefore based on a
speci cation with three international factors generated by one common shock.
24
Because spillovers could in principle depend on the degree of monetary cooperation between countries (Clarida et al 2002) we tested in cross section whether the bilateral spill overs were correlatated with the variance of
bilateral exchange rates. This correlation is based on 42 observations of bilateral spill overs and exchange rate
variability among the G7 countries for either the full sample, 1961 to 1984 and 1985 to 2007. These correlations
are very close to zero.

12

We limit our analysis to a number of variables widely argued to either a ect or help
forecast in ation. Among these, we include two indices of commodity prices, variables that
should be correlated with marginal costs, i.e. real GDP growth, unit labor costs and wages
and asset prices. We also consider the possibility that the U.S. macroeconomic policies trigger
in ationary pressures both at home and abroad. We measure the U.S. scal stance by the
scal de cit. This allow us to test in particular the view that the increase in public deci t
associated to the Vietnam war is correlated with the take o of Global In ation in the rst
part of the sample. The potential spillovers of U.S. monetary policies on Global In ation,
i.e. the McKinnon (1982) hypothesis, is also tested through testing by including the e ective
exchange rate among the explanatory variables.
Finally, we consider the stance of monetary policy. Because there is no consensus on how
one should measure this concept, we investigate two possibilities. For the rst one, we compute
a Taylor rule residual as follows:
Taylor residualt = 1:5
where it is a short-term interest rate,

t

t

0:5(yt

is in ation and yt

yt )

it

yt is the HP lter based output

gap. For the second measure, we use the growth rate of a monetary aggregate (M3).
For each variable, we extract a common factor in a similar way as we had done for
in ation, i.e. taking unweighted averages of the variables of interest. However, because some
of the variables are not available at quarterly frequencies early in the sample, indicators are
obtained by averaging across national variables from the G7 and Australia. These averages
explain usually between 1/3 (e.g. for real GDP growth) and 1/2 (e.g. for monetary aggregates)
of the variance of national time series on average across countries.25 This extraction is not
performed for U.S.

scal de cit, the dollar exchange rate and the in ation of commoditiy

prices for obvious reasons.
We focus the analysis on the 1970-2006 sample because many of our variables were not
available beforehand or since 2007. Within this 35 years sample we further check the stability
of the results across the 1970-1990 sample and 1991-2006 sample. This latter sample should
be particularly interesting with respect to the causality between monetary policies and Global
In ation. In that period, central banks have aimed at stabilizing in ation around a constant
explicit or implicit in ation target. As the common approach to monetary policy has become to
anchor in ation expectations at a constant level, and constants cannot be correlated, indicators
25

Results using the dynamic factor or the existing OECD aggregates to compute the \Global" explanatory
variables of in ation are quite similar to the ones reported here. The exact gures are available from the authors
upon request.

13

of the stance of monetary policies should not help forecast Global In ation in that period.
The results of the Bayesian selection algorithm are shown in Table 5. The prob column
gives the probability that the variable is signi cant, i.e., the probabilty that the variable is
included in the searched model, b gives the elasticity of global in ation vis-a-vis the variable
and the last column gives the standard error of b. Several ndings are worth emphasizing.
Looking rst at the 1970-2006 sample, only a few variables contain forecasting power with
regards to Global In ation. Cost variables, including commodity prices and real GDP have
a positive impact on Global in ation within 4 quarters. At 8 quarters horizon, stock prices,
the dollar and indicators of the world stance of monetary help forecast in ation. In particluar,
fast growth of M3 and smaller interest rates than the Taylor rule norm tend to be followed by
higher in ation. This result strongly support the narrative evidence reported above and the
conclusions of Cecchetti et al (2007) that the trend evolution of in ation in the OECD has
been dominated by commonality in the stance of monetary policy and, possibly, by changes in
the preferences of monetary authorities. We should also stress that the predictive power of the
Dollar, though only over the full sample, comforms to the prediction of McKinnon (1983) that
changes in the stance of monetary policies across countries might have been partially induced
by spillovers of low frequency changes in stance of U.S. monetary policy. A weaker dollar has
been followed, 8 quarters later, by a rise in Global In ation.
The sub-sample results are also quite interesting. In particular, the information contents
of M3 growth and the Taylor rule residuals are much less relevant for Global In ation eight
quarters ahead, as one would expect given the success of central banks in stabilizing in ation.
We even notice that a weaker stance of monetary policies, as de ned by more positive or less
negative Taylor rule residual help forecast a decline in in ation at horizon 4 and 8 quarters.
This may indicate that such deviations from the Taylor rule are much less persistent and more
likely to be reverted in the recent subsample.
The relevance of wages and house prices since 1990 also is worth underlining. A major
shock that could have a ected wages similarly across countries in the last two decades is the
emergence of China. However assessing whether this major labor supply shock has a ected
the impact of OECD wages on in ation would require further research that goes beyond the
scope of this paper. Turning to house prices, we know that there has been a worldwide acceleration of house prices since 1995 in most OECD countries (Germany and Japan being the
notable exceptions). Our results suggest that central banks should monitor house prices, not
only because they may relate to credit fed asset bubble cycles that put banking systems in

14

danger, but also because they carry relevant information for future in ation.26 Finally, both
wages and house prices might surely play a valuable role to overcome the recently noticed
unpredictability inpredictibility (Atkenson and Ohanian, 2001; Stock and Watson, 2007 and
d'Agostino, Giannone and Surico, 2006).
Overall, the ndings reported in this section reveal a robust sensitiveness of Global Ination to real and monetary determinants when measured at the global level. This reinforces
the view that, possibly, economists working on in ation may need to reconsider the relevance
of closed economy models of in ation.27 As a matter of fact, in a majority of OECD countries,
reduced form models of the type we estimated for Global In ation are unable to obtain signi cant coe cients for any variables beyond the own lags of in ation itself (Corvoisier and Mojon,
2005). From this perspective, our results for Global In ation are good news because they show
that there exist one level of aggregation at which leading indicators of in ation indeed contain exploitable information about future in ation. Finally, the response of Global In ation
to both real determinants {at short horizons{ and monetary determinants {at longer horizon{
invite central banks to monitor both categories of in ation determinants. This surveillance,
however, should be done not only at the level of countries, but also more globally to account
for informational content of common international evolutions of in ation.

4

Predictive implications of Global In ation

In this section, we describe the impact of Global In ation on national in ation rates. We show
that Global In ation behaves as an attractor of the national in ation rates. This mechanism
is important both to guide our understanding of the in ation process and to pursue practical
policy purposes such as forecasting.

4.1

Global In ation is persistent and \attractive"

Using the simple framework of the factor representation of section 2, it is easy to show that
domestic in ation reverts to the global component { which acts as an \attractor" { and is
characterised by stationary

uctuations around the latter. In the factor representation, an

estimate of national in ation is simply given by

26
27

^ i f^t

"^i;t =

i;t

"^i;t =

^i;t 1
i"

+

i;t

See the discussion in Borio and Lowe (2002).
This point is also made by Borio and Filardo (2007) though for di erent reasons.

15

where ^ i is an estimate of the country-speci c loading and f^t is our preferred measure of global
in ation.
To check whether domestic in ation reverts to the global component it su ces to check
the stationarity of "^i;t . Table 6 reports the estimates of

the rst autoregressive coe cients in
an AR(1) representation for "^i;t , while Table 7 reports the ^ i .28 Estimates of i are on average
i

not higher than 0.5, which implies that, in the available sample of countries, a temporary
shock to in ation is on average absorbed in ve to seven quarters at most. However, the same
estimate for the global in ation is on average much higher than those of countries' in ations,
both on the whole sample and on single subsamples.
On the whole sample, therefore, the global component captures the most persistent and
possibly non-stationary part of in ation.29 This result is in line with the nding that estimated
global factor would capture the non-stationarity of the data used to estimate the factor (see
e.g. Bai and Ng 2002). In this case, then, the global in ation behaves as an attractor and
domestic in ation uctuates around its projection on this attractor.
Incidentally, the importance of the global component of in ation leads us to reconsider
the debate on in ation persistence. Two main conclusions emerge from the recent studies on
in ation persistence. First, empirical estimates of in ation persistence fall when statistically
signi cant shifts or breaks in the mean of in ation are accounted for.30 Second, the question of
what drives the break in the mean has not received a clear answer yet.31 Both evidence on the
importance of the mean of in ation and of common patterns in possible breaks in the mean
are consistent with the view that in ation is a global phenomenon. Therefore, consistently
with our ndings and considering our measure of global in ation as a common long run mean,
we can conclude also that in ation of 22 OECD countries exhibit lower persistence once we
control for the dependence of the national in ation processes on Global In ation. In a previous
version of this work, we have also shown that in ation persistence might have not been stable
over time.32 The question of stability is relevant from an econometric point of view, as any
measure of persistence of a time-varying structure is biased if time variation is not accounted
for. Results here broadly con rm the time-varying ones, where the global factor captures the
28

For this exercise we use annualised quarter-on-quarter trasformations of seasonally adjusted in ation series,
1).
i;t = 400 (Pi;t =Pi;t 1
29
With a year-on-year transformation, the AR(1) coe cient of the global component is not di erent from one,
whereas the average coe cient of country in ations is not higher than 0.85.
30
Robalo Marques (2004), among others, has recently argued that the mean of in ation plays a crucial role
in the de nition of persistence and that any estimate of persistence should be seen conditional on a given
assumption for the mean of in ation.
31
See for instance the discussion by Rogo (2003).
32
See Ciccarelli and Mojon (2005) and Mumtaz and Surico (2008).
i.e.

16

persistent component of in ation on the whole sample, and its persistence declines ove the last
10-15 years.33
It is also worth noting that the estimates of the loadings of in ation rates on Global
In ation are evenly distributed, across countries, around one (see Table 7). These loadings
summarizes the \echo" of Global In ation changes on national in ation rates, on average, since
1960. Countries that have historically been considered as high in ation countries, have, not
surpringly a loading higher than one. Germany, on the contrary, has the lowest loading among
G7 countries. The sub-sample results, with notable exceptions, would also indicate some sort
of convergence to more similar values.

4.2

A new benchmark for forecasting in ation?

A well documented result in the forecasting literature is that reliable leading indicators of
in ation are scarce. For example, Stock and Watson (1999, 2003), Banerjee et al (2003) and
Banerjee and Marcellino (2002) all conclude that, while some leading indicators of in ation
outperform the forecasts based on simple AR(p) models of in ation in some countries and
for some sample periods, none has yet emerged that systematically beat the AR(p) (typically
AR(1) or AR(2) of level in ation), or even the Random walk (RW). It has been also argued
therefore that { especially over the last 10-15 years { in ation has become harder to forecast,
in the sense that it has become much more di cult for an in ation forecaster to provide value
added beyond a univariate model (Stock and Watson, 2005). This nding had already been
documented by Atkeson and Ohanian (2001) { who found that backwards-looking Phillips
curve forecasts were inferior to a RW forecast{ and more recently by D'Agostino et al.(2005)
{ who show that the ability to predict several measures of in ation and real activity declined
remarkably, relative to na•ve forecasts, since the mid-1980s.
All this literature, however, only focuses on the U.S. economy. To the best of our
knowledge, a systematic comparison of similar features for the other industrialised economies
has not been carried out yet. The issue is also partially related to the debate on the Great
Moderation, which has also not attained an international momentum. Both topics are on our
current research agenda. For our purposes here, however, the previous discussion can help shed
new light on the issue of predictability of in ation, particularly by taking into account the
international commonalities of in ation. The question is: Can the international environment
help predict national in ation?
In this section, we sketch an answer by considering a parsimonious speci cation simply
33

For a similar result with disaggregate data see also Angeloni et al. (2006).

17

augmented with the global component of in ation.
Consistently with previous sections, we start from the usual common h-step ahead speci cation (Stock and Watson, 2002)
h
i;t+h

=

h
i;0

+

h
i;1 (L)

+

i;t

h
^
i;2 (L) ft

+ ui;t+h

(2)

where the factor f^t ; instead of summarising hundreds of series, is simply the common component
of the 22 national in ation series:
=

i;t

i ft

+ "i;t

estimated with the average or the static principal component approach.
Notation and strategy are similar to the ones employed by Stock and Watson (2002).
In particular, the multistep forecasts is linear in f^t and t (and lags), and an h-step-ahead
projection is used to construct the forecasts directly. Therefore, after estimating all unknown
up to time T , we use (2) and forecast h
from ^ h + ^ h (L) i;T + ^ h (L) f^T for each unit
i and step h. The dependent variable is de ned

i;0
h
as i;t

annualized in ation in the price level Pt { whereas

i;t

i;T +h

i;1

i;2

= (400=h) ln (Pt =Pt
1
i;t

=

h)

{ the h-period

is the quarter-on-quarter quarterly

in ation rate.
As said, this speci cation is a well known factor-augmented econometric relationship.
Here we simply argue that a very parsimonious search of the factor ft , only based on an average
of in ation series, can outperform or be as competitive as the usual benchmarks, without the
need to choose an optimal number of factors from hundreds of variables. The important issue,
however, is the appropriate consideration of an international ingredient summarised in ft ,
which, as noted previously, works as an attractor for national in ations.
Because we want to keep the discussion limited to the scope of the paper, we check the
forecasting performance of our model only against three natural competitors. The rst one is
an AR(p) of the form
h
i;t+h

=

i;0

+

i;1 (L)

i;t

+ "i;t+h

(3)

where the lag length p is imposed equal to 1 or optimally chosen with a standard BIC.
The second model is a Random Walk (RW)
h
i;t+h

=

i;t

+ "it+h

(4)

We pay particular attention to this naive speci cation { especially on recent samples { to check
the issue of the unpredictability raised e.g. by D'Agostino, Giannone and Surico (2005) and
Stock and Watson (2007).
18

A third benchmark can be considered along the lines of Stock and Watson (1999),
Nicoletti-Altimari (2000) and Gerlach (2003) by setting an augmented Phillips curve model
where the rst di erence of in ation depends on its own lags and on the lags of the growth
rates of industrial production, oil price and M3. Speci cally, it is:
h
i;t+h

=

i;0

+

+

i;1 (L)

i;3 (L)

i;t

+

M 3it +

i;2 (L)
i;4 (L)

IPit
Oilt + "i;t+h

The experiment is conducted in a \pseudo real-time" framework with all models re-estimated
at each step using only information up to time t. We choose the lag length to be one or
two for the AR component of each model, while xing to four the number of lags of ft . The
evaluation and comparison are made over three forecasting periods, 1980-2004, 1980-95 and
post 1995, and for eight forecasting horizons (quarters). We report results only for the last
subsample at the one-year ahead horizon. The choice of the subsamples is motivated by the
issue of unpreditability over the last 15-20 years, and the choice of the horizon by the policy
relevance.34
Tables 8 report the RMSE of our preferred speci cation (2) relative to the RMSE of
the four competing models. Clearly, our speci cation is preferred in a forecasting sense if the
reported statistic is lower than one. A rough comparison across the three benchmarks can also
be made: the bigger the reported statitics for a model the better its performance with respect
to the others. So, for instance, if the reported statistics for RW is greater than the one for AR,
then the former is preferred. The signi cance of these ratios is checked with a simple test on
the di erence between two competing Mean Squared Forecast Errors, adjusting the statistic
when models are nested (Clark and West 2007). Bold entries in the table denote 10 percent
signi cance.
Overall results show that our model can outperform the competing models in forecasting
in ation on average, across forecast horizon and over evaluation periods, and for most countries.
Improvements are of the order of up to 16 percent with respect to the augmented Phillips curve
speci cation, 15 percent with respect to the RW and 20 percent with respect to the standard
AR. Our model seems to perform particularly well on the 4-quarter-ahed horizon, which is
the most relevant one for policymaking, and over the last 10 years, where the unpredictability
related to the Great Moderation should be more evident.
These conclusions are consistent both with the fact that the Global In ation works as
an anchor for national in ations and with a somewhat expected greater commonality among
34

Results for other subsamples and horizons are not reported because qualitatively very similar. A version of
them are available in Ciccarelli and Mojon (2005).

19

in ations from the nineties (e.g. Rogo , 2003). Our interpretation of the results is that the
unpredictability of in ation is related to the use of \local" vs. \global" models, and might not
necessarily be true for all industrialized countries. Our ndings are remarkable, and have the
potential features of a new benchmark for forecasting in ation, based on the incorporation of
global information in the standard models.
Note nally that over the evaluation sample 1995-2004 there is indeed an issue of unpredictability for the average (or median) country, in that the reported statistics for RW are
greater than the one for AR and Phillips curve. However this ratio is lower than 1 (and signi cantly so for many countries), meaning that our preferred speci cation is able to beat on
average the random walk.
Our preliminary conclusion, then, is that a simple parsimonious extension of a standard
AR model, where we consider the attraction role of the Global In ation, outperform robust
predictors of in ation. The results con rm also the importance of exploiting the international
links and commonalities as advocated by the recent empirical Factor-Model literature. What
makes our contribution particularly valuable is the search of the factors in a global rather than
a domestic information set, and the interpretation of the common factor as an attractor of
national in ation. Our parsimonious speci cation, where the global factor is a simple average of
22 national in ation series, seems to forecast well future developments of national in ation. The
latter result, which holds across countries, samples periods and forecasting horizons, is obviously
one of the main contributions of our current research that deserves further investigation.

5

Conclusions

In this paper, we have shown that the in ation of the OECD countries have moved together
over the last 45 years. This comovement accounts for 70 percent of the variability of country
in ation, on average. Moreover, there is a powerful and robust \error correction mechanism"
that brings national in ation rates back toward the level of their long term projection on
Global In ation. As a rst practical application of the idea of Global In ation, we present a
fairly parsimonious model of in ation forecast. The preliminary ndings suggest that the new
speci cation beats standard competitors.
The main open question is to assess whether these results re ect some sort of statistical
\return to the mean" phenomenon or whether some deeper endogenous economic adjustments
are at work. For example, some determinants of in ation are global: the price of commodities
is the same for all countries; KOW have shown that there is a global business cycle; last but not
least, it seems that monetary policy concepts are e ectively spreading among central banks. In
20

some periods, bad monetary policy strategies are dominating for a majority of countries. At
other times, good strategies appear dominant.
We show that Global In ation does not result from countries spillovers but rather from
common shocks. It responds to commodity prices, the global business cycle and the global
trends of liquidity. We further qualify that real developments are more relevant at short horizons
and monetary developments matter at longer horizons.
Our paper has two important policy implications. First, given the importance of Global
In ation for local in ation, the nature of Global In ation brings support to the monetary policy
strategies that give importance both to real and monetary developments in their assessment of
in ationary pressures. Second, there may be a useful informational content in the average of
foreign in ation records, even for countries that, like Switzerland, were on average less a ected
by common developments in in ation.
Future research to which the authors will contribute should follow mainly three directions. The rst one is to extend the sample of countries and regions to emerging markets, and
assess the importance of global, regional and domestic mechanisms that help explain in ation
developments. The second one is to explore more systematically the forecasting performance
of the Global In ation Model, and compare it with the performance of other univariate and
multivariate speci cations, across other samples and cross sections of countries. Finally, we
should try to gain insights on the nature of the shocks that drive Global In ation and their
transmission to country in ations. Our belief is that to a large extent the results reported in
this paper may re ect the importance for central bankers of exchanging views and cooperating
in the design of their monetary policy concepts. Hence, paraphrasing the conclusion of the
1848 Communist Manifesto we would like to invite:
\central bankers of all countries: unite!"

21

References
[1] D'Agostino, A. D. Giannone and P. Surico (2005), (Un)predictability and Macroeconomic
Stability, Mimeo, ECARES.
[2] Andrews, D. and W.K. Chen (1994), Approximately median-unbiased estimation of autoregresive models, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 12, 187-204.
[3] Angeloni, I., L. Aucremanne and M. Ciccarelli (2006), Price setting and in ation persistence: did EMU matter?, Economic Policy 21, 353-387.
[4] Atkenson, A. and L. Ohanian (2001), Are Phillips Curves Useful for forecasting in ation?,
Federal Reserve Bank of Mineapolis Quarterly Review 25, 2-11.
[5] Bai, J. (2003), Inferential theory for factor models of large dimensions, Econometrica 71,
135-171.
[6] Bai, J., and S. Ng (2002), Determine the Number of Factors in Approximate Factor Models,
Econometrica 70, 191-221.
[7] Ball L. (2006), Has Globalization Changed In ation?, NBER Working Paper 12687.
[8] Ball L. and N. Sheridan (2003), Does in ation targeting matter?, NBER Working Paper
9577.
[9] Banerjee A., M. Marcellino and I. Masten (2003), Leading indicators of euro area in ation
and GDP growth, CEPR WP 3893.
[10] Banerjee A. and M. Marcellino (2003), Are there any reliable leading indicators for the
US in ation and GDP growth?, IGIER WP 236.
[11] Baxter, M. and R. King (1999), Measuring Business Cycles: Approximate Band-Pass
Filters for Economic Time Series, Review of Economics and Statistics 81, 575-93.
[12] BIS (2005), Annual Report 2005, Bank of International Settlements, www.bis.org.
[13] Besley T. and A. Case (1995), Incumbent Behavior: Vote-Seeking, Tax-Setting, and Yardstick Competition, American Economic Review 85, 25-45.
[14] Borio, C. and A. Filardo (2007), Globalisation and In ation: New Cross-Country Evidence
on Global Determinants of Domestic In ation, BIS Working Paper 227.

22

[15] Borio, C. and P. Lowe (2002), Asset prices, nancial and monetary stability: exploring
the nexus, BIS Working Papers 114.
[16] Canova F., M. Ciccarelli and E. Ortega (2007), Similarities and convergence in G7 cycles,
Journal of Monetary Economics 54, 850-78 .
[17] Calvo G. and C. Reihnart (2002), Fear of Floating, Quaterly Journal of Economics 117
(2): 379-408.
[18] Cecchetti, S., P. Hooper, B. Kasman, K. Schoenholtz and M. Watson (2007) Understanding
the Evolving In ation Process, Proceedings of the U.S. Monetary Policy Forum 2007.
[19] Chen, N., J. Imbs and A. Scott (2004), Competition, Globalization and the Decline of
In ation, CEPR Discussion paper 4695.
[20] Ciccarelli M. and B. Mojon (2005), Global In ation, ECB WPS no 537.
[21] Cogley T. and T. J. Sargent (2005), The Conquest of US In ation: Learning and Robustness to Model Uncertainty, Review of Economics Dynamics 8, 528-563.
[22] Cristadoro R., M. Forni, L. Reichlin and G. Veronese (2005): A core in ation indicator
for the euro area, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 37, 539-60.
[23] Corvoisier S. and B. Mojon (2005), Breaks in the mean of in ation: How they happen and
what to do with them, ECB Working Paper 451.
[24] Darby, M. and J. Lothian (1983), The International Transmission of In ation, National
Bureau of Economic Research, University of Chicago Press.
[25] Doz, C. D. Giannone and L. Reichlin (2006), A Maximum Likelihood Approach for Large
Approximate Dynamic Factor Models, ECB Working Paper 674.
[26] Forni, M. and L. Reichlin, (2001), Federal policies and local economies: Europe and the
US, European Economic Review 45(1), 109-134
[27] Forni, M., M. Hallin, M. Lippi, and L. Reichlin (2000): The generalized factor model:
identi cation and estimation, The Review of Economics and Statistics 82: 540-554.
[28] Gerlach S. (2003), The ECB's two pillars, CEPR Discussion paper 3689.
[29] Goodfriend, M., (2007), How the world achieved consensus on monetary policy, Journal
of Economic Perspectives 21, 47{68.
23

[30] Kose A,. C. Otrok and C. Whiteman (2003), International business cycles: World, region
and country-speci c factors, The American Economic Review 93, 1216-39.
[31] Ihrig J., S. Kamin, D. Lindner and J. Marquez (2007), Some simple tests of the Globalization and In ation Hypothesis, Federal Reserve Board, International Finance Discussion
Papers 891.
[32] Levin A.T. and J.M. Piger (2004), Is in ation persistence intrinsic in industrial economies?,
ECB Working Paper 334.
[33] McKinnon R. I. (1982), Currency substituion and in instability in the World Dollar Standard, American Economic Review 72, 320-333.
[34] Monacelli T. and L. Sala (2007), The International Dimension of In ation: Evidence from
Disaggregated Consumer Price Data, IGIER mimeo.
[35] Mumtaz H. and P. Surico (2008), Evolving International In ation Dynamics: World and
Country Speci c Factors, CEPR Working Paper 6767.
[36] Nicoletti-Altimari S. (2001), Does money lead in ation in the euro area?, ECB Working
Paper 63.
[37] Reinhart C. and K. Rogo (2002), The Modern History of Exchange Rate Arrangements:
A Reinterpretation , NBER WP 8963.
[38] Robalo Marques C. (2004), In ation persistence: facts or artefacts?, ECB Working Paper
371.
[39] Rogo K. (2003), Globalization and Global Disin ation, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas
City Economic Review, 4th Quarter.
[40] Rogo K. (2006), Impact of Globalization on Monetary Policy, Proceedings of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City Jackson Hole Conference.
[41] Stock J. and M. Watson (1999), Forecasting in ation, Journal of Monetary Economics 44,
293-335.
[42] Stock J. and M. Watson (2002), Macroeconomic Forecasting Using Di usion Indexes,
Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 20, 147-162.
[43] Stock J. and M. Watson (2005), Understanding Changes in International Business Cycle
Dynamics, Journal of the European Economic Association 3, 966-1006.
24

[44] Stock J. and M. Watson (2007), Has in ation become harder to forecast?, Journal of
Money, Banking and Credit 39, 3-33.
[45] Wang P. and Y. Wen (2007), In ation Dynamics: A cross-country investigation, Journal
of Monetary Economics 54, 2004-2031.
[46] Woodford M. (2007), Globalization and Monetary Control, in J. Gali and M. J. Gertler
(editors), International Dimensions of Monetary Policy, University of Chicago Press.

25

APPENDIX. Data source and transformation
Definition
Source

Transformation

Consummer price indices

OECD Main Economic Indicators

y-o-y growth rates

Hourly earnings

OECD Main Economic Indicators

y-o-y growth rates

Industrial production

IMF International Financial Statistics

y-o-y growth rates

Short-term interest rate (3-month) OECD Economic outlook

level

Long-term interest rate (10-year)

OECD Economic outlook

level

GDP

Eurostat and OECD Economic outlook

y-o-y growth rates

Commodity prices

Bridge/Commodity Research Bureau; Spot market price index: All commodities; www.freelunch.com

y-o-y growth rates

Oil price

Fed St Louis Oil price: Domestic West Texas Intermediate

y-o-y growth rates

US government fiscal deficit

Net lending or net borrowing (-); Table 3.2. Federal Government Current Receipts and Expenditures;
Bureau of economic analysis
BIS unpublished data base, Borio and Lowe (2002).

level

Stock prices

Real estate prices, housing indices BIS unpublished data base, Borio and Lowe (2002).
Broad money (M3)

y-o-y growth rates
y-o-y growth rates

euro area countries (Eurostat Balance sheet items); Canada, Denmark, Sweden and United Kingddom y-o-y growth rates
(OECD MEI); Australia, Japan, New Zeland, Norway Switzerland and United States (OECD Economic
Outlook); for Austria, Belgium, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland

Table 1. Share of inflation variance explained by alternative
measures of Global Inflation
Average

OECD

Greece
Switzerland
Japan
Netherlands
Germany
New Zeland
Portugal
United States
Norway
Australia
Denmark
Austria
Spain
Sweden
Luxembourg
United Kindom
Finland
Canada
Belgium
Ireland
Italy
France

0.41
0.46
0.55
0.58
0.60
0.63
0.65
0.69
0.70
0.73
0.73
0.74
0.75
0.76
0.76
0.82
0.83
0.83
0.84
0.85
0.86
0.89

0.65
0.24
0.29
0.25
0.33
0.61
0.65
0.72
0.57
0.70
0.53
0.40
0.58
0.63
0.48
0.66
0.58
0.75
0.56
0.61
0.81
0.73

Static factor
first
second
0.37
0.16
0.41
0.16
0.52
0.15
0.57
0.20
0.57
0.16
0.61
0.14
0.63
0.09
0.67
0.02
0.68
0.03
0.71
0.06
0.71
0.00
0.72
0.12
0.74
0.03
0.71
0.02
0.77
0.02
0.80
0.00
0.81
0.01
0.81
0.04
0.84
0.03
0.86
0.00
0.86
0.03
0.89
0.00

mean
median

0.71
0.73

0.56
0.59

0.69
0.71

0.07
0.03

euro area

0.95

0.76

0.95

0.00

Note: 1961:1-2007:2. The euro area aggregate inflation is not included in the pool of
22 countries used to estimate Global Inflation.

Table 2: Share of inflation variance explained by average inflation for
a selection of six countries
1961-2007

1975-2007

1984-2007

Australia
Canada
Germany
UK
Japan
US

0.71
0.83
0.63
0.88
0.61
0.78

0.70
0.86
0.63
0.91
0.83
0.81

0.37
0.69
0.26
0.83
0.66
0.67

mean
median

0.74
0.75

0.79
0.82

0.58
0.67

Note: Global inflation is here defined as in column 1 of Table 1, i.e. as the unweighted
average of the inflation rates of the six countries of this table.

Table 3. Share of detrended inflation variance explained
by alternative measures of Global Inflation
Portugal
Spain
New Zeland
Norway
Greece
Sweden
Netherlands
Denmark
Germany
Australia
Canada
Finland
Luxembourg
United Kingdom
United States
Switzerland
Austria
Japan
Ireland
France
Italy
Belgium

Average
0.03
0.10
0.10
0.15
0.27
0.28
0.29
0.30
0.32
0.35
0.36
0.39
0.40
0.40
0.43
0.44
0.47
0.54
0.57
0.61
0.61
0.63

OECD
0.01
0.00
0.01
0.02
0.29
0.08
0.08
0.21
0.08
0.20
0.20
0.15
0.05
0.24
0.57
0.22
0.12
0.49
0.20
0.49
0.41
0.24

Static factor
0.02
0.03
0.05
0.09
0.19
0.17
0.29
0.21
0.26
0.26
0.29
0.34
0.40
0.35
0.42
0.33
0.43
0.46
0.57
0.64
0.60
0.64

mean
median

0.37
0.37

0.20
0.20

0.32
0.31

Euro area

0.83

0.34

0.84

Note: 1961:1-2007:2. The inflation series are detrended by applying the
band pass filter of Baxter and King (1999). The euro area aggregate
inflation is not included in the pool of 22 countries used to estimate Global
Inflation.

Table 4: Decomposition of inflation dynamics into common shocks, international spill overs and countries own shocks
1961-2007

Canada

horizon
0
4
16

(1)
global
shock
0.71
0.69
0.70

(2)

(3)=(1)+(2)

spillovers
0.00
0.14
0.19

common
0.71
0.83
0.89

1984-2007

1961-1983
(4)

(2)

(3)=(1)+(2)

0.29
0.17
0.11

(1)
global
shock
0.34
0.51
0.60

spillovers
0.00
0.09
0.14

common
0.34
0.60
0.74

own shock

(4)

(2)

(3)=(1)+(2)

0.66
0.40
0.26

(1)
global
shock
0.43
0.47
0.47

spillovers
0.00
0.12
0.15

common
0.43
0.59
0.61

own shock

(4)
own shock
0.57
0.41
0.39

France

0
4
16

0.37
0.57
0.64

0.00
0.07
0.11

0.37
0.64
0.75

0.63
0.37
0.25

0.22
0.51
0.60

0.00
0.07
0.11

0.22
0.58
0.71

0.78
0.42
0.29

0.57
0.47
0.45

0.00
0.16
0.24

0.57
0.63
0.70

0.43
0.37
0.30

Germany

0
4
16

0.31
0.41
0.46

0.00
0.04
0.07

0.31
0.45
0.52

0.69
0.55
0.48

0.32
0.38
0.42

0.00
0.04
0.06

0.32
0.42
0.48

0.68
0.58
0.52

0.84
0.66
0.65

0.00
0.22
0.24

0.84
0.88
0.88

0.16
0.12
0.12

Italy

0
4
16

0.51
0.62
0.67

0.00
0.11
0.17

0.51
0.74
0.85

0.49
0.26
0.15

0.91
0.80
0.79

0.00
0.14
0.18

0.91
0.95
0.97

0.09
0.05
0.03

0.39
0.42
0.43

0.00
0.05
0.06

0.39
0.47
0.49

0.62
0.53
0.51

Japan

0
4
16

0.30
0.39
0.43

0.00
0.06
0.08

0.30
0.46
0.51

0.70
0.54
0.49

0.32
0.34
0.35

0.00
0.10
0.10

0.32
0.44
0.46

0.68
0.56
0.54

0.87
0.78
0.76

0.00
0.14
0.16

0.87
0.92
0.92

0.13
0.08
0.08

UK

0
4
16

0.87
0.78
0.76

0.00
0.14
0.18

0.87
0.92
0.95

0.13
0.08
0.05

0.96
0.81
0.79

0.00
0.17
0.19

0.96
0.98
0.98

0.04
0.02
0.02

0.23
0.36
0.37

0.00
0.13
0.16

0.23
0.49
0.54

0.77
0.51
0.46

US

0
4
16

0.42
0.46
0.54

0.00
0.07
0.11

0.42
0.53
0.64

0.58
0.47
0.36

0.67
0.66
0.69

0.00
0.05
0.07

0.67
0.72
0.76

0.33
0.28
0.24

0.61
0.60
0.60

0.00
0.06
0.06

0.61
0.66
0.66

0.39
0.34
0.34

Australia

0
4
16

0.09
0.25
0.39

0.00
0.08
0.13

0.09
0.33
0.52

0.91
0.67
0.48

0.10
0.32
0.45

0.00
0.09
0.13

0.10
0.41
0.58

0.90
0.59
0.42

0.16
0.26
0.27

0.00
0.08
0.11

0.16
0.35
0.37

0.84
0.65
0.63

average

0
4
16

0.45
0.52
0.57

0.00
0.09
0.13

0.45
0.61
0.70

0.55
0.39
0.30

0.48
0.54
0.59

0.00
0.09
0.12

0.48
0.64
0.71

0.52
0.36
0.29

0.51
0.50
0.50

0.00
0.12
0.15

0.51
0.62
0.65

0.49
0.38
0.35

Note: 1961:1-2007:2. Values in the table represent the fraction of forecast error variance due to each shock at the one-, four- and sixteen-quarter horizon. The results are based on a structural FAVAR
model estimated with maximum likelihood methods and a factor model approach a la Stock and Watson (2005) and Forni et al (2000), where the k common factors are generated by q shocks, and
q<k. Likelihood tests for overidentification restrictions reject the null of up to 2 international factors and one shock against the unrestricted alternative full rank. The results are therefore based on a
specification with three international factors generated by one common shock.

Table 5: BMA Posterior probabilities and estimates, dependent variable is Global Inflation
1 step ahead
lag of
own
comm. price
oil price
GDP
ULC
Wages
Stock prices
House prices
U.S. fiscal deficit
Dollar effective x rate
Taylor residual
M3

1970-2006

1970-1990

1990-2006

prob.
1.00
0.98
0.29
0.90
0.11
0.29
0.10
0.09
0.08
0.21
0.08
0.42

b
0.90
0.03
0.00
0.13
0.00
0.02
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.02

std
0.06
0.01
0.01
0.07
0.03
0.04
0.00
0.01
0.02
0.01
0.01
0.03

prob.
1.00
0.95
0.17
0.38
0.15
0.47
0.10
0.10
0.08
0.41
0.13
0.40

b
0.81
0.04
0.00
0.03
0.01
0.09
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.01
0.00
0.02

std
0.13
0.02
0.00
0.05
0.04
0.11
0.00
0.01
0.02
0.01
0.02
0.04

prob.
1.00
0.51
0.11
0.14
0.10
0.17
0.15
0.10
0.19
0.14
0.16
0.08

b
0.86
0.01
0.00
0.01
0.00
0.02
0.00
0.00
0.02
0.00
-0.01
0.00

std
0.08
0.01
0.00
0.03
0.02
0.07
0.00
0.01
0.05
0.00
0.02
0.01

1.00
0.23
1.00
0.85
0.17
0.10
0.09
0.13
0.08
0.19
0.21
1.00

0.61
0.01
0.06
0.23
0.02
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.02
0.26

0.09
0.01
0.01
0.13
0.07
0.04
0.00
0.02
0.04
0.01
0.04
0.05

0.20
0.32
0.39
0.98
0.98
0.70
0.10
0.18
0.16
0.17
0.76
0.50

0.02
0.02
0.01
0.42
0.56
0.23
0.00
-0.01
-0.02
0.00
0.13
0.08

0.12
0.03
0.01
0.14
0.16
0.19
0.00
0.03
0.08
0.01
0.10
0.09

0.13
0.19
0.12
0.14
0.47
1.00
0.26
0.18
0.23
0.98
0.97
0.56

0.01
0.00
0.00
-0.01
-0.10
0.49
0.00
-0.01
0.02
-0.03
-0.21
0.07

0.07
0.01
0.00
0.05
0.13
0.10
0.00
0.02
0.06
0.01
0.07
0.08

0.21
0.36
0.20
0.17
0.13
0.10
0.93
0.22
0.30
0.95
1.00
1.00

-0.03
0.02
0.00
0.02
-0.01
0.00
0.021
-0.02
-0.08
-0.06
0.41
0.58

0.08
0.03
0.01
0.07
0.04
0.04
0.009
0.04
0.14
0.02
0.06
0.06

0.18
0.62
0.10
0.15
0.18
0.19
0.67
0.09
0.09
0.82
1.00
1.00

0.02
0.04
0.00
0.02
0.02
0.03
0.01
0.00
-0.01
-0.04
0.39
0.43

0.08
0.04
0.01
0.08
0.08
0.09
0.01
0.02
0.06
0.03
0.08
0.08

0.98
0.26
0.11
0.90
0.53
0.48
0.25
0.92
0.12
0.24
0.92
0.41

0.58
0.01
0.00
-0.33
-0.13
-0.15
0.00
0.16
-0.01
0.00
-0.33
-0.06

0.26
0.02
0.00
0.17
0.16
0.19
0.00
0.07
0.04
0.01
0.14
0.09

4 steps ahead
own
comm. price
oil price
GDP
ULC
Wages
Stock prices
House prices
U.S. fiscal deficit
Dollar effective x rate
Taylor residual
M3

8 steps ahead
own
comm. price
oil price
GDP
ULC
Wages
Stock prices
House prices
U.S. fiscal deficit
Dollar effective x rate
Taylor residual
M3

Note: The three columns of numbers for each sample-panel report the probability that the corresponding variable help
predict Global Inflation, the estimated coefficient and its standard deviation respectively. Probability higher than 0.5
and significant coefficients are in bold. The dependent variable is Global inflation. Potential explanatory variables
enter with one lag. The estimation and search technique are explained in Ciccarelli and Mojon (2005).

Table 6: Persistence of the Global and the National Components of Inflation
1960-2007
ρ
stderr
Euro area

1960-1980
ρ
stderr

1980-1990
ρ
stderr

1990-2007
ρ
stderr

0.48

0.06

0.23

0.11

0.36

0.14

0.55

0.10

United States
Canada
United Kingdom
Japan
Germany
France
Italy

0.63
0.35
0.45
0.54
0.54
0.55
0.44

0.06
0.07
0.07
0.06
0.06
0.06
0.07

0.68
0.30
0.34
0.37
0.47
0.50
0.43

0.09
0.11
0.11
0.11
0.10
0.10
0.10

0.47
0.61
0.52
0.33
0.40
0.24
0.03

0.12
0.12
0.11
0.14
0.14
0.15
0.15

0.15
0.28
0.17
0.03
0.42
0.19
0.52

0.12
0.12
0.12
0.12
0.11
0.12
0.11

median
mean

0.54
0.50

0.06
0.06

0.43
0.44

0.10
0.10

0.40
0.37

0.14
0.13

0.19
0.25

0.12
0.12

Other Euro/EU
Austria
Belgium
Denmark
Finland
Greece
Ireland
Luxembourg
Portugal
Spain
Sweden
The Netherlands

0.18
0.42
0.10
0.44
0.73
0.19
0.48
0.05
0.37
0.18
0.41

0.07
0.07
0.07
0.07
0.05
0.07
0.06
0.07
0.07
0.07
0.07

0.10
0.42
-0.05
0.42
0.41
0.02
0.44
-0.14
0.39
0.02
0.16

0.11
0.10
0.11
0.10
0.10
0.11
0.10
0.11
0.10
0.12
0.11

0.32
0.52
-0.03
0.37
0.39
-0.34
0.48
0.61
0.16
0.23
0.07

0.15
0.13
0.16
0.15
0.14
0.14
0.13
0.11
0.15
0.14
0.16

0.17
-0.04
0.30
0.37
0.44
0.61
0.03
0.22
-0.13
0.10
0.42

0.12
0.12
0.11
0.11
0.11
0.10
0.12
0.12
0.12
0.12
0.11

median
mean

0.37
0.32

0.07
0.07

0.16
0.20

0.11
0.11

0.32
0.25

0.14
0.14

0.22
0.23

0.12
0.11

0.28
0.59
0.17
0.61

0.07
0.06
0.07
0.06

-0.09
0.57
0.09
0.63

0.11
0.09
0.11
0.09

0.32
0.51
0.44
0.33

0.15
0.13
0.14
0.15

0.20
0.45
-0.16
0.29

0.12
0.11
0.13
0.12

0.43
0.41

0.07
0.07

0.33
0.30

0.11
0.11

0.38
0.40

0.14
0.14

0.24
0.20

0.12
0.12

0.94

0.02

0.92

0.04

0.88

0.05

0.69

0.08

G7

Others
Australia
New Zeland
Norway
Switzerland
median
mean
Global Inflation

Note: The table reports the estimates of the first autoregressive coefficient of national inflations (defined as πit-λift) and their
standard errors over four samples. An AR(1) is asssumed. Estimation technique is OLS. The factor is estimated with a simple
average.

Table 7: Loadings of National Inflation Rates on Global Inflation
λ
Euro area

1960-2007
stderr

λ

1960-1980
stderr

λ

1980-1990
stderr

λ

1990-2007
stderr

0.76

0.02

0.73

0.03

1.01

0.03

0.85

0.05

United States
Canada
United Kingdom
Japan
Germany
France
Italy

0.71
0.84
1.34
0.91
0.42
1.04
1.48

0.04
0.04
0.06
0.08
0.03
0.03
0.05

0.85
0.84
1.54
0.81
0.37
0.93
1.62

0.07
0.07
0.11
0.14
0.05
0.06
0.10

0.90
1.00
1.10
0.61
0.70
1.44
1.78

0.13
0.08
0.14
0.10
0.07
0.09
0.12

0.80
0.91
1.24
0.65
0.86
0.60
1.03

0.10
0.16
0.14
0.15
0.12
0.06
0.09

median
mean

0.91
0.96

0.04
0.05

0.85
0.99

0.07
0.08

1.00
1.07

0.10
0.10

0.86
0.87

0.12
0.12

0.54
0.77
0.91
1.12
1.53
1.44
0.70
2.02
1.35
0.96
0.57

0.04
0.04
0.07
0.06
0.14
0.07
0.04
0.15
0.07
0.06
0.05

0.49
0.79
0.74
1.04
1.99
1.46
0.70
2.06
1.30
0.83
0.52

0.08
0.07
0.14
0.11
0.18
0.13
0.06
0.29
0.15
0.10
0.09

0.67
0.93
0.98
0.92
0.87
2.25
1.03
1.24
1.20
0.86
0.90

0.08
0.09
0.14
0.10
0.23
0.18
0.13
0.35
0.11
0.15
0.06

0.67
0.61
0.15
0.92
3.68
0.28
0.62
2.10
1.03
2.09
0.35

0.09
0.09
0.08
0.11
0.32
0.16
0.10
0.16
0.10
0.20
0.09

0.96
1.08

0.07
0.08

0.83
1.08

0.13
0.14

0.93
1.08

0.15
0.17

0.67
1.14

0.16
0.16

1.04
1.26
0.83
0.47

0.06
0.08
0.06
0.05

1.24
1.22
0.67
0.26

0.08
0.10
0.11
0.09

0.39
0.88
0.81
0.52

0.15
0.33
0.14
0.12

0.87
0.59
0.80
1.29

0.21
0.15
0.18
0.08

0.94
0.90

0.06
0.07

0.94
0.85

0.10
0.10

0.81
0.65

0.15
0.18

0.80
0.89

0.16
0.15

G7

Other Euro/EU
Austria
Belgium
Denmark
Finland
Greece
Ireland
Luxembourg
Portugal
Spain
Sweden
The Netherlands
median
mean
Others
Australia
New Zeland
Norway
Switzerland
median
mean

Note: The table reports the estimates of the factor loading in the equation πit = λift+εit and its standard errors for all countries and over
four samples. Estimation technique is OLS. The factor is estimated with a simple average.

Table 8: RMSE of the Global Inflation model relative to standard benchmarks (1995-2006)

Euro area total

RW
0.77

1-step ahead
AR
PHIL
0.76
0.76

RW
0.87

4-step ahead
AR
PHIL
0.83
0.84

RW
0.86

8-step ahead
AR
PHIL
0.79
0.78

G7
United States
Canada
United Kingdom
Japan
Germany
France
Italy

0.90
0.81
0.96
1.17
0.78
0.86
1.36

0.96
0.87
0.76
1.06
0.84
0.86
0.95

0.93
0.89
0.81
1.34
0.84
0.87
1.13

0.92
0.77
1.01
1.14
0.81
0.86
1.02

0.97
0.84
0.65
0.96
0.86
0.81
0.64

0.96
0.85
0.69
1.37
0.87
0.85
0.75

0.85
0.76
1.02
1.18
0.82
0.80
0.92

0.89
0.83
0.58
0.89
0.87
0.75
0.52

0.91
0.84
0.61
1.57
0.91
0.82
0.59

median
mean

0.90
0.98

0.87
0.90

0.89
0.97

0.92
0.93

0.84
0.82

0.85
0.90

0.85
0.91

0.83
0.76

0.84
0.89

Other Euro/EU
Austria
Belgium
Denmark
Finland
Greece
Ireland
Luxembourg
Portugal
Spain
Sweden
The Netherlands

0.88
0.69
1.35
0.97
1.06
1.37
0.84
1.30
0.76
1.03
0.87

0.75
0.75
0.62
0.90
0.95
1.25
0.90
0.39
0.66
0.76
0.81

0.76
0.74
0.81
0.91
1.02
1.16
0.91
0.44
0.68
0.73
0.82

0.80
0.77
1.36
0.94
1.03
1.02
0.86
0.98
0.85
0.96
0.78

0.69
0.82
0.59
0.83
0.76
1.07
0.92
0.39
0.66
0.71
0.73

0.73
0.83
0.86
0.82
0.79
0.87
0.91
0.41
0.70
0.70
0.78

0.69
0.64
1.12
0.96
0.98
0.97
0.84
1.11
0.82
1.05
0.88

0.63
0.69
0.53
0.80
0.69
1.05
0.93
0.36
0.59
0.72
0.82

0.66
0.68
0.81
0.82
0.71
0.88
0.92
0.39
0.65
0.71
0.83

median
mean

0.97
1.01

0.76
0.79

0.81
0.82

0.94
0.94

0.73
0.74

0.79
0.76

0.96
0.91

0.69
0.71

0.71
0.73

Australia
New Zeland
Norway
Switzerland

0.79
0.85
0.75
1.06

0.85
0.80
0.82
0.94

0.84
0.75
0.81
0.95

0.83
0.83
0.74
1.25

0.88
0.73
0.79
1.01

0.89
0.71
0.78
0.96

0.74
0.83
0.74
1.31

0.81
0.67
0.77
0.98

0.80
0.61
0.77
0.99

0.82
0.86

0.84
0.85

0.83
0.84

0.83
0.91

0.83
0.85

0.83
0.83

0.79
0.91

0.79
0.81

0.79
0.79

0.90
0.96

0.84
0.83

0.84
0.87

0.92
0.93

0.81
0.79

0.83
0.82

0.88
0.91

0.76
0.75

0.80
0.79

Others

median
mean
Overall median
Overall mean

Note: entries are the ratios of root mean squared errors of the Global inflation forecast model to the one obtained with a
random walk (RW), an AR(1) (AR), and a Phillips Curve augmented with industrial production, commodity prices and money
(PHIL). Evaluation period: 1995-2006.

Figure 1: Measures of Global Inflation
United States, Japan, Canada and United Kingdom (1965-2004)

3.5
3
First static factor
average
OECD aggregate

2.5
2
1.5
1
0.5
0
-0.5
-1
-1.5

6
-0

3
Ju
n

-0

0
Ju
n

-0

7
Ju
n

-9

4
Ju
n

-9

1
Ju
n

-9

8
Ju
n

-8

5
Ju
n

-8

2
Ju
n

-8

9
Ju
n

-7

6
Ju
n

-7

3
Ju
n

-7

0
Ju
n

-7

7
Ju
n

-6

4
Ju
n

-6
Ju
n

Ju
n

-6

1

-2

Note: Three measure of Global Inflation: a simple cross-country average, the accregate OECD measure and a static factor.

Figure 2a : G7 and euro area inflation and their projection on Global Inflation
United States, Japan, Canada and United Kingdom (1961-2007)

US

Canada

16

14

14

12

12

10

10

8

8

6

6

4

4

2

2

0

0

-2

-2

-4
1960

1964

1968

1972

1976

1980

1984

1988

1992

1996

2000

2004

1960

1964

1968

1972

1976

Japan

1980

1984

1988

1992

1996

2000

2004

1988

1992

1996

2000

2004

UK

40

35

35

30

30

25

25

20

20
15
15
10

10

5

5
0

0

-5

-5
1960

1964

1968

1972

1976

1980

1984

1988

1992

1996

2000

2004

1960

1964

1968

1972

1976

1980

1984

Note: Domestic inflations and their projections on the Global Inflation (measured by simple average). Estimation technique: OLS. Dependent variable
is a deseasonalized quarter-on-quarter inflation rate.

Figure 2b : G7 and euro area inflation and their projection on Global Inflation
United States, Japan, Canada and United Kingdom (1961-2007)

Germany

Italy

9.6

25

8.0

20

6.4
15
4.8
10
3.2
5
1.6
0

0.0
-1.6

-5
1960

1964

1968

1972

1976

1980

1984

1988

1992

1996

2000

2004

1960

1964

1968

1972

1976

France

1980

1984

1988

1992

1996

2000

2004

1988

1992

1996

2000

2004

Euro area

16

12

14
10
12
10

8

8
6
6
4

4

2
2
0
-2

0
1960

1964

1968

1972

1976

1980

1984

1988

1992

1996

2000

2004

1960

1964

1968

1972

1976

1980

1984

Note: Domestic inflations and their projections on the Global Inflation (measured by simple average). Estimation technique: OLS. Dependent variable
is a deseasonalized quarter-on-quarter inflation rate.

Figure 3: Measures of Global de-trended Inflation
United States, Japan, Canada and United Kingdom (1965-2004)

5
First static factor
Average
OECD aggregate

4
3
2
1
0
-1
-2
-3

ar
-0
5

M

ar
-0
2

M

ar
-9
9

M

ar
-9
6

M

ar
-9
3

M

ar
-9
0

M

ar
-8
7

M

ar
-8
4

M

ar
-8
1

M

ar
-7
8

M

ar
-7
5

M

ar
-7
2

M

ar
-6
9

M

ar
-6
6

M

M

ar
-6
3

-4

Note: Three measures of detrended Global Inflation. The inflation series are detrended with Baxter and King (1999).

Working Paper Series
A series of research studies on regional economic issues relating to the Seventh Federal
Reserve District, and on financial and economic topics.
Firm-Specific Capital, Nominal Rigidities and the Business Cycle
David Altig, Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum and Jesper Linde

WP-05-01

Do Returns to Schooling Differ by Race and Ethnicity?
Lisa Barrow and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP-05-02

Derivatives and Systemic Risk: Netting, Collateral, and Closeout
Robert R. Bliss and George G. Kaufman

WP-05-03

Risk Overhang and Loan Portfolio Decisions
Robert DeYoung, Anne Gron and Andrew Winton

WP-05-04

Characterizations in a random record model with a non-identically distributed initial record
Gadi Barlevy and H. N. Nagaraja

WP-05-05

Price discovery in a market under stress: the U.S. Treasury market in fall 1998
Craig H. Furfine and Eli M. Remolona

WP-05-06

Politics and Efficiency of Separating Capital and Ordinary Government Budgets
Marco Bassetto with Thomas J. Sargent

WP-05-07

Rigid Prices: Evidence from U.S. Scanner Data
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Benjamin Eden

WP-05-08

Entrepreneurship, Frictions, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-05-09

Wealth inequality: data and models
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-05-10

What Determines Bilateral Trade Flows?
Marianne Baxter and Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-05-11

Intergenerational Economic Mobility in the U.S., 1940 to 2000
Daniel Aaronson and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-05-12

Differential Mortality, Uncertain Medical Expenses, and the Saving of Elderly Singles
Mariacristina De Nardi, Eric French, and John Bailey Jones

WP-05-13

Fixed Term Employment Contracts in an Equilibrium Search Model
Fernando Alvarez and Marcelo Veracierto

WP-05-14

1

Working Paper Series (continued)
Causality, Causality, Causality: The View of Education Inputs and Outputs from Economics
Lisa Barrow and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP-05-15

Competition in Large Markets
Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-05-16

Why Do Firms Go Public? Evidence from the Banking Industry
Richard J. Rosen, Scott B. Smart and Chad J. Zutter

WP-05-17

Clustering of Auto Supplier Plants in the U.S.: GMM Spatial Logit for Large Samples
Thomas Klier and Daniel P. McMillen

WP-05-18

Why are Immigrants’ Incarceration Rates So Low?
Evidence on Selective Immigration, Deterrence, and Deportation
Kristin F. Butcher and Anne Morrison Piehl

WP-05-19

Constructing the Chicago Fed Income Based Economic Index – Consumer Price Index:
Inflation Experiences by Demographic Group: 1983-2005
Leslie McGranahan and Anna Paulson

WP-05-20

Universal Access, Cost Recovery, and Payment Services
Sujit Chakravorti, Jeffery W. Gunther, and Robert R. Moore

WP-05-21

Supplier Switching and Outsourcing
Yukako Ono and Victor Stango

WP-05-22

Do Enclaves Matter in Immigrants’ Self-Employment Decision?
Maude Toussaint-Comeau

WP-05-23

The Changing Pattern of Wage Growth for Low Skilled Workers
Eric French, Bhashkar Mazumder and Christopher Taber

WP-05-24

U.S. Corporate and Bank Insolvency Regimes: An Economic Comparison and Evaluation
Robert R. Bliss and George G. Kaufman

WP-06-01

Redistribution, Taxes, and the Median Voter
Marco Bassetto and Jess Benhabib

WP-06-02

Identification of Search Models with Initial Condition Problems
Gadi Barlevy and H. N. Nagaraja

WP-06-03

Tax Riots
Marco Bassetto and Christopher Phelan

WP-06-04

The Tradeoff between Mortgage Prepayments and Tax-Deferred Retirement Savings
Gene Amromin, Jennifer Huang,and Clemens Sialm

WP-06-05

2

Working Paper Series (continued)
Why are safeguards needed in a trade agreement?
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-06-06

Taxation, Entrepreneurship, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-06-07

A New Social Compact: How University Engagement Can Fuel Innovation
Laura Melle, Larry Isaak, and Richard Mattoon

WP-06-08

Mergers and Risk
Craig H. Furfine and Richard J. Rosen

WP-06-09

Two Flaws in Business Cycle Accounting
Lawrence J. Christiano and Joshua M. Davis

WP-06-10

Do Consumers Choose the Right Credit Contracts?
Sumit Agarwal, Souphala Chomsisengphet, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles

WP-06-11

Chronicles of a Deflation Unforetold
François R. Velde

WP-06-12

Female Offenders Use of Social Welfare Programs Before and After Jail and Prison:
Does Prison Cause Welfare Dependency?
Kristin F. Butcher and Robert J. LaLonde
Eat or Be Eaten: A Theory of Mergers and Firm Size
Gary Gorton, Matthias Kahl, and Richard Rosen
Do Bonds Span Volatility Risk in the U.S. Treasury Market?
A Specification Test for Affine Term Structure Models
Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

WP-06-13

WP-06-14

WP-06-15

Transforming Payment Choices by Doubling Fees on the Illinois Tollway
Gene Amromin, Carrie Jankowski, and Richard D. Porter

WP-06-16

How Did the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut Affect Stock Prices?
Gene Amromin, Paul Harrison, and Steven Sharpe

WP-06-17

Will Writing and Bequest Motives: Early 20th Century Irish Evidence
Leslie McGranahan

WP-06-18

How Professional Forecasters View Shocks to GDP
Spencer D. Krane

WP-06-19

Evolving Agglomeration in the U.S. auto supplier industry
Thomas Klier and Daniel P. McMillen

WP-06-20

3

Working Paper Series (continued)
Mortality, Mass-Layoffs, and Career Outcomes: An Analysis using Administrative Data
Daniel Sullivan and Till von Wachter
The Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures:
Tying One’s Hand through the WTO.
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-06-21

WP-06-22

How Did Schooling Laws Improve Long-Term Health and Lower Mortality?
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-06-23

Manufacturing Plants’ Use of Temporary Workers: An Analysis Using Census Micro Data
Yukako Ono and Daniel Sullivan

WP-06-24

What Can We Learn about Financial Access from U.S. Immigrants?
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-06-25

Bank Imputed Interest Rates: Unbiased Estimates of Offered Rates?
Evren Ors and Tara Rice

WP-06-26

Welfare Implications of the Transition to High Household Debt
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-06-27

Last-In First-Out Oligopoly Dynamics
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-06-28

Oligopoly Dynamics with Barriers to Entry
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-06-29

Risk Taking and the Quality of Informal Insurance: Gambling and Remittances in Thailand
Douglas L. Miller and Anna L. Paulson

WP-07-01

Fast Micro and Slow Macro: Can Aggregation Explain the Persistence of Inflation?
Filippo Altissimo, Benoît Mojon, and Paolo Zaffaroni

WP-07-02

Assessing a Decade of Interstate Bank Branching
Christian Johnson and Tara Rice

WP-07-03

Debit Card and Cash Usage: A Cross-Country Analysis
Gene Amromin and Sujit Chakravorti

WP-07-04

The Age of Reason: Financial Decisions Over the Lifecycle
Sumit Agarwal, John C. Driscoll, Xavier Gabaix, and David Laibson

WP-07-05

Information Acquisition in Financial Markets: a Correction
Gadi Barlevy and Pietro Veronesi

WP-07-06

Monetary Policy, Output Composition and the Great Moderation
Benoît Mojon

WP-07-07

4

Working Paper Series (continued)
Estate Taxation, Entrepreneurship, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-07-08

Conflict of Interest and Certification in the U.S. IPO Market
Luca Benzoni and Carola Schenone

WP-07-09

The Reaction of Consumer Spending and Debt to Tax Rebates –
Evidence from Consumer Credit Data
Sumit Agarwal, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles

WP-07-10

Portfolio Choice over the Life-Cycle when the Stock and Labor Markets are Cointegrated
Luca Benzoni, Pierre Collin-Dufresne, and Robert S. Goldstein

WP-07-11

Nonparametric Analysis of Intergenerational Income Mobility
with Application to the United States
Debopam Bhattacharya and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-07-12

How the Credit Channel Works: Differentiating the Bank Lending Channel
and the Balance Sheet Channel
Lamont K. Black and Richard J. Rosen

WP-07-13

Labor Market Transitions and Self-Employment
Ellen R. Rissman

WP-07-14

First-Time Home Buyers and Residential Investment Volatility
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Martin Gervais

WP-07-15

Establishments Dynamics and Matching Frictions in Classical Competitive Equilibrium
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-07-16

Technology’s Edge: The Educational Benefits of Computer-Aided Instruction
Lisa Barrow, Lisa Markman, and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP-07-17

The Widow’s Offering: Inheritance, Family Structure, and the Charitable Gifts of Women
Leslie McGranahan

WP-07-18

Demand Volatility and the Lag between the Growth of Temporary
and Permanent Employment
Sainan Jin, Yukako Ono, and Qinghua Zhang

WP-07-19

A Conversation with 590 Nascent Entrepreneurs
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-07-20

Cyclical Dumping and US Antidumping Protection: 1980-2001
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-07-21

The Effects of Maternal Fasting During Ramadan on Birth and Adult Outcomes
Douglas Almond and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-07-22

5

Working Paper Series (continued)
The Consumption Response to Minimum Wage Increases
Daniel Aaronson, Sumit Agarwal, and Eric French

WP-07-23

The Impact of Mexican Immigrants on U.S. Wage Structure
Maude Toussaint-Comeau

WP-07-24

A Leverage-based Model of Speculative Bubbles
Gadi Barlevy

WP-08-01

Displacement, Asymmetric Information and Heterogeneous Human Capital
Luojia Hu and Christopher Taber

WP-08-02

BankCaR (Bank Capital-at-Risk): A credit risk model for US commercial bank charge-offs
Jon Frye and Eduard Pelz

WP-08-03

Bank Lending, Financing Constraints and SME Investment
Santiago Carbó-Valverde, Francisco Rodríguez-Fernández, and Gregory F. Udell

WP-08-04

Global Inflation
Matteo Ciccarelli and Benoît Mojon

WP-08-05

6