View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Do Financial Counseling Mandates
Improve Mortgage Choice and
Performance? Evidence from a
Legislative Experiment
Sumit Agarwal,Gene Amromin,
Itzhak Ben-David, Souphala Chomsisengphet,
and Douglas D. Evanoff

WP 2009-07

Do Financial Counseling Mandates Improve Mortgage Choice
and Performance? Evidence from a Legislative Experiment
Sumit Agarwal#
Gene Amromin#
Itzhak Ben-David*
Souphala Chomsisengphet§
Douglas D. Evanoff#
October 2009
ABSTRACT
We explore the effects of mandatory third-party review of mortgage contracts on the terms, availability,
and performance of mortgage credit. Our study is based on a legislative experiment in which the State of
Illinois required “high-risk” mortgage applicants acquiring or refinancing properties in 10 specific zip
codes to submit loan offers from state-licensed lenders to review by HUD-certified financial counselors.
We document that the legislation led to declines in both the supply of and demand for credit in the treated
areas. Controlling for the salient characteristics of the remaining borrowers and lenders, we find that the
ex post default rates among counseled low-FICO-score borrowers were about 4.5 percentage points lower
than those among similar borrowers in the control group. We attribute this result to actions of lenders
responding to the presence of external review and, to a lesser extent, to counseled borrowers renegotiating
their loan terms. We also find that the legislation pushed some borrowers to choose less risky loan
products in order to avoid counseling.

Keywords: Financial literacy, Counseling, Subprime crisis, Household finance
JEL Classification: D14, D18, L85, R21

We thank Edward Zhong for outstanding research assistance and Dan Aaronson, Henrik Cronqvist, Tom Davidoff, Rüdi
Fahlenbrach, David Laibson, Annamaria Lusardi, Olivia Mitchell, Adair Morse, Anthony Murphy, Jonah Rockoff, Sophie Shive,
Peter Tufano, Annette Vissing-Jorgensen, Paul Willen, Luigi Zingales and seminar participants at the 2009 NBER Summer
Institute, 2009 CEPR/Gerzensee Summer Symposium, 2009 AEA meetings, Bocconi University, Columbia University, the
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC), Federal Reserve Banks of Atlanta and Chicago, Tel-Aviv University, Office of
the Comptroller of the Currency, Ohio State University, University of California Berkeley, University of California San Diego,
University of Illinois at Chicago, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, Vanderbilt University, Financial Intermediation
Research Society Conference, SUERF/Bank of Finland Conference, and the 16th Mitsui Financial Symposium at the University
of Michigan for their comments. The authors thank the FDIC, Paolo Baffi Centre at Bocconi University, and the Dice Center at
the Fisher College of Business, Ohio State University for supporting this research. The views in this paper do not reflect those of
the Federal Reserve System, the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, or of the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency.
Contact author: Itzhak Ben-David, Fisher College of Business, Ohio State University, bendavid@fisher.osu.edu
#

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
Fisher College of Business, The Ohio State University
§
Office of the Comptroller of the Currency
*

1. Introduction
In the wake of the subprime mortgage crisis, policymakers have been urged to increase
their intervention in credit markets (see Sheila Bair’s testimony to the House Financial Services
Committee, 2007). In particular, the leading policy initiatives include tightening the oversight on
lenders (Federal Truth in Lending Act, Regulation Z) and providing mandatory financial
counseling to certain borrowers (President Obama’s Homeownership Affordability and Stability
Plan of 2009). Although it has been shown that these programs may slow down market activity
(Bates and Van Zandt, 2007), their effects on mortgage choice and performance, and their
overall effectiveness are still debated.
In this paper we study the effects of the legislative mandate for third-party review of
mortgage contracts implemented in a pilot program in Cook County, Illinois, between September
2006 and January 2007. The program required “high-risk” mortgage applicants acquiring or
refinancing properties in 10 Chicago zip codes to submit loan offers from state-licensed lenders
to review by loan counselors certified by the Department of Housing and Urban Development
(HUD). The same requirement applied to applicants who chose certain mortgage products
deemed risky by legislators. The empirical setting of this legislative natural experiment allows us
to study the program’s outcomes and isolate the driving forces behind the effects.
In particular, the unorthodox geographic focus of the legislation offers a way to identify
the control and treatment groups for econometric analysis of mandatory counseling. In contrast
to loan-based programs, the geographic mandate makes it nearly impossible for lenders and
households to disguise the terms of the transaction to eschew the regulation. Consequently, we
construct a control group similar to the treatment area in terms of pre-pilot sociodemographic
measures, foreclosure rates, as well as borrower and mortgage characteristics to conduct
difference-in-differences analyses. 1 Since the legislation applied only to a select group of
financial intermediaries and borrowers, we are able to derive further identification from variation
in loan terms and performance within zip codes at given points in time.
1

Our results are robust to alternative control group specifications.

2

Our analysis provides a series of results about the effects of financial advice on behavior
of low- and moderate-income households and on lender response to mandatory loan counseling
programs. In particular, we find that mandatory counseling hampered real estate market activity
in the treated areas. In the 10 pilot zip codes, the legislation caused up to a 73% drop in the
number of mortgage loan applications for the lenders who were subject to the legislation.
Our key result is that the legislation resulted in substantially lower ex post default rates
and somewhat better loan choices among some of the counseled borrowers that remained in the
market. These results hold after controlling for improvements in the credit quality of the
borrower pool and for changes in the composition of the pool of available lenders. Specifically,
the 18-month default rate among low-FICO-score counseled borrowers was about 4.5 percentage
points lower than that among similar borrowers in the control group (the average pre-treatment
default rate of such borrowers in both the treatment and control groups was 17 percent). As we
discuss below, these borrowers could not eschew counseling by modifying their product choice.
Financial counseling mandates are often thought to work by providing better information
to financially unsophisticated households. However, such mandates often have another important
aspect in that they subject financial intermediaries to a certain degree of oversight by an outside
party. In the case studied here, the legislation interjected counselors into the loan application
process. This provided an incentive for lenders to screen out lower-quality borrowers in order to
protect themselves from possible legal and regulatory action. On balance, we find more evidence
in support of the effectiveness of the oversight threat than information per se.
In particular, we obtain mixed support for the direct effect of information received in
counseling sessions. Based on individual counseling records of one agency, we estimate a
stronger propensity to renegotiate loan terms for borrowers who are advised that their loans are
unaffordable, as compared to ones for whom the counselor finds no issues with the loan offer. 2
Yet, we detect almost no aggregate effect of counseling on interest rates, debt leverage, and
2

This analysis is carried out on a small subsample of counseled borrowers that were hand-matched with the Cook
County Deeds data and mortgage servicer records. We are working on obtaining access to the aggregate data on preand post-counseling session mortgage terms.

3

propensity by the counseled borrowers to take out adjustable rate hybrid mortgages or mortgages
with prepayment penalty—the most common areas of concern for counseling agencies.
We find stronger evidence for indirect effects of the counseling requirement on mortgage
origination and mortgage decision making. First, we document a spike in rejection rates of
mortgage applications by lenders who are subject to the legislation during the treatment period,
with rejection rates returning to their normal level as soon as the law is rescinded. This pattern is
partially due to the temporary exit of lenders with loose screening practices from the treated area,
and it is partially due to tighter screening by the remaining lenders. Second, we find a sizable
decline in the prevalence of low-documentation mortgages. We attribute this change to
counselors’ demand that borrowers bring their income documentation to the counseling session.
Both of these responses are consistent with the hypothesis that third-party review of mortgage
offers led to more thorough screening—what we refer to as the oversight effect. Third, we find
that borrowers who could avoid counseling by selecting less risky products did so. Fourth, we
report that counseled borrowers rejected fewer mortgage offers. Since we do not detect an
aggregate improvement in loan terms, it is possible that borrowers give up shopping around for
mortgages to avoid additional counseling sessions. The latter two responses are consistent with
borrowers’ desire to avoid the transaction costs of fulfilling the counseling mandate—that is, the
burden effect.
In general, our results suggest that the threat of oversight and the imposition of
transaction and compliance costs of counseling, rather than the information contained in
counseling sessions, served as the primary catalyst for change in borrower decision making and
in lender behavior, ultimately leading to lower default rates. However, one should be careful not
to interpret these results as a verdict on the general ability of financial counseling to convey
useful information to borrowers. 3 Rather, as discussed in greater detail below, the design of this
particular pilot featured considerable incentives for lenders to shy away from certain borrowers

3

For instance, a recent volume (Lusardi, 2008) offers evidence for effectiveness of targeted, long-term financial
education programs in improving financial literacy and stimulating savings.

4

and products. Further, by designating certain contracts as triggers for counseling, the pilot design
also conveyed information about their desirability outside of counseling sessions themselves.
Our paper contributes to two strands of research on the effect of mortgage choice on
housing market outcomes. The first stresses the role of financial education in enabling more
informed choices by households. 4 For instance, Lusardi (2007, 2008) voices concern that many
consumers who enter into complex financial contracts, such as mortgages, are financially
illiterate. Households may borrow too much at a high rate without realizing future consequences
(Agarwal, Driscoll, Gabaix, and Laibson, 2007) or may have a hard time recalling the terms of
their mortgage contracts (Bucks and Pence, 2008). Moore (2003) and Lusardi and Tufano (2009)
finds that respondents with poor financial literacy are more likely to have costly mortgages. It
has also been argued that insufficient financial sophistication contributed to a growing number of
households in bankruptcy and foreclosure when housing market conditions deteriorated (White,
2007). Stark and Choplin (2009) present survey evidence that borrowers fail to read and
understand contracts. Although there is a shared sense that household financial literacy is
inadequate and the resulting mistakes are consequential, there is less agreement on whether
financial education programs are an effective means of addressing this shortcoming. 5
The second strand focuses on regulatory oversight and corresponding changes in
incentives for various market participants. For instance, Keys, Mukherjee, Seru, and Vig (2009)
show that the incentives associated with the securitization process result in lax screening by
mortgage originators. Ben-David (2008) finds that intermediaries expand the mortgage market
by helping otherwise ineligible borrowers to engage in misrepresentation of asset valuations to
obtain larger mortgages. Rajan, Seru, and Vig (2008) show that soft information about borrowers
4

This literature is motivated by Bernheim (1995, 1998), who was among the first to document low levels of
financial literacy among consumers. One of the starkest illustrations of shortfalls in financial literacy was
demonstrated by Lusardi and Mitchell (2006, 2008) who provided evidence of consumer inability to perform even
simple interest-rate calculations. Lusardi and Tufano (2009) report similar concerns with household debt literacy.

5

For instance, Bernheim, Garrett, and Maki (2001) find that high school financial education mandates have an
appreciable effect on asset accumulation later in life. However, a recent paper by Cole and Shastry (2008) that uses a
larger dataset and a different empirical specification fails to detect any effect of such programs on household
participation in financial markets.

5

is lost as the chain of intermediaries in the origination process becomes longer, leading to a
decline in quality of originated mortgages.
The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2, we describe the mandatory
counseling program in detail. In Section 3, we outline our methodology and the data we used to
test the hypotheses. We present empirical results on the effects of the program on the mortgage
market in Section 4. In Section 5, we evaluate the relative importance of different channels in
attaining these effects. We summarize and discuss policy implications in Section 6.

2. Illinois Predatory Lending Database Pilot Program (HB 4050)
2.1 Description of the Pilot Program
In 2005, the Illinois legislature passed a bill intended to curtail predatory lending.
Although the state had a number of anti-predatory provisions in place, they were based on loan
characteristics, in line with prevailing practices elsewhere in the country. Some political leaders
in Illinois became concerned at the apparent ease with which trigger criteria for anti-predatory
programs could be avoided by creative loan packaging. For instance, balloon mortgages targeted
by regulations were replaced with adjustable rate mortgages (or ARMs) with short fixed rate
periods and steep rate reset slopes (the so-called 2/28 and 3/27 hybrid ARMs). 6 Consequently,
the legislature sought to shift focus from policing loan issuers to educating the borrowers.
To that effect, the legislation sponsored by the Illinois House Speaker Michael Madigan
mandated financial counseling for mortgage loan applicants whose credit scores were
sufficiently low (or product choices were sufficiently risky) to identify them as high-risk
borrowers. The legislation set the FICO score threshold for mandatory counseling at 620, with an
additional provision that borrowers with FICO scores in the 621–650 range be subject for
counseling if they chose certain high-risk mortgage products. Such mortgages were defined to
include interest-only loans, loans with interest rate adjustments within three years, loans

6

For a detailed analysis of the impact of the state anti-predatory lending laws on the type of mortgage products used
in the market, see Bostic, Chomsisengphet, Engel, McCoy, Pennington-Cross, and Wachter (2008).

6

underwritten on the basis of stated income (low-doc loans), and repeat refinancings within the
last 12 months. Borrowers were subject to counseling regardless of their FICO score if they took
out loans with prepayment penalties, loans that allowed negative amortization, or loans that had
closing costs in excess of five percent. The proposal was modeled on a successful FHA program
run in the 1970’s (Merrick, 2007), and it generated a lot of excitement among Illinois lawmakers.
The program was meant to run as a four-year pilot in select parts of Cook County that
covers the metropolitan Chicago area, after which its coverage could be expanded. In spite of
vocal opposition from community-based groups and affected lenders, Illinois politicians
clamored to have their districts included in the pilot (Merrick, 2007). This choice looked
particularly ironic in retrospect, given the eventual response of the population in the pilot areas.
In the end, the bill (titled HB 4050) was passed on the last day of the 2005 legislative session.
HB 4050 mandated that each of the high-risk borrowers attend a counseling session with
one of the HUD-certified loan counseling agencies. The determination of the need for such a
session was made on the day of the application, and the borrower had 10 days to fulfill the
requirement. The goal of these sessions, lasting one to two hours, was to discuss the terms of the
specific loan offer for a home purchase or refinancing and to explain their meaning and
consequences to the prospective borrower. The counselors were not supposed to advise
borrowers about their optimal mortgage choice in the sense of Campbell and Cocco (2003);
rather, they were to warn them against common pitfalls. The counselor was also expected to
verify the loan application information about the borrower (e.g., income and expenses). At the
end of the session the counselor was required to record a number of findings about the loan, such
as whether the lender charged excessive fees, whether the loan interest rate was in excess of the
market rate, whether the borrower understood the transaction and/or could afford the loan.
Both the interview and the independent collection of data on borrower income and
expenses allowed counselors to form an assessment of borrower creditworthiness that potentially
went beyond what was conveyed by the lender. Effectively, the counselors were able to elicit
private information that was not necessarily used by lenders to make approval and/or pricing
7

decisions and make it a matter of public record by entering their recommendations in the statemaintained database. This may well have induced the lenders to screen better prior to referring
approved applications to counseling for the fear of a regulatory (e.g., license revocation) or legal
(e.g., class action lawsuits) response. It should be noted that none of the recommendations was
binding in the sense that borrowers could always choose to proceed with the loan offer at hand.
HB 4050 stipulated that the $300 cost of the session be borne by the mortgage originator,
and not the borrower. 7 However, even if this were to be the case, HB 4050 imposed other time
and psychic costs on borrowers. Finally, by lengthening the expected amount of time until
closing, HB 4050 could force borrowers to pay for longer credit lock periods, raising loan costs.
As mentioned earlier, only loans offered by state-licensed mortgage lenders were subject
to this requirement, as the State lacks legal authority to regulate any federally-chartered
institutions and generally exempts such institutions and state-chartered banks from mortgage
licensing. However, lending in disadvantaged neighborhoods has been done primarily through
the state-licensed mortgage bankers that presented themselves as a local and nimble alternative
to the more traditional bank lenders. 8 Consequently, the legislation was likely to increase the
regulatory burden on the very entities providing credit in the selected pilot areas. The possibility
that this could result in credit rationing prompted many observers to voice concern on the
potential effect of HB 4050 on housing values in the selected zip codes.
HB 4050 imposed a substantial compliance burden on lenders as well. In addition to the
cost of counseling (assuming it was not recovered through other loan charges), lenders had to
make sure that the certification requirements of HB 4050 were implemented fully. 9 Otherwise,
7

There is substantial anecdotal evidence that brokers attempted to pass the $300 counseling fee to the borrowers in
the form of higher closing costs or administrative charges (Bates and VanZandt, 2007, and personal communication
with a number of mortgage counselors.)

8

Using the HMDA data described in greater detail in section 3, we estimate that state-licensed mortgage bankers
accounted for 56% of mortgage loans originations in the HB 4050 zip codes during 2005.

9

Under HB 4050, title companies did not receive a "safe harbor" provision for “good faith compliance with the
law.” As a result, any clerical errors at any point in the loan application process could potentially invalidate the title,
resulting in loss of the lender’s right to foreclose on a nonperforming loan. According to the Cook County Recorder
of Deeds, even federally regulated lenders had to procure a certificate of exemption from HB 4050 to obtain a clean
title. Consequently, all lenders were affected to at least some degree by the legislation.

8

lenders could potentially lose the right to foreclose on the property. Finally, lenders reportedly
feared losing some of their ability to steer borrowers toward high margin products.
A report by the non-profit Housing Action Illinois (2007) summarized the counselors’
assessment of HB 4050. Over the course of the pilot, about 1,200 borrowers had their loan offers
reviewed by 41 HUD-certified counselors. In 9% of the cases, mortgages were deemed to have
indications of fraud. About half of the borrowers were advised that they could not afford the loan
or were close to not being able to do so. For 22% of the borrowers, loan rates were determined to
be more than 300 basis points above the market rate. For 9% of the borrowers, the counselors
found a discrepancy between the loan documents and the verbal description of the mortgage.
Perhaps most alarmingly, an overwhelming majority of borrowers who were receiving adjustable
rate loans did not understand that their mortgage payment was not fixed over the life of the loan.
The geographic focus of the legislation differed substantially from typical regulatory
approaches that required counseling for certain loan types and did not apply uniformly to a
particular area (Bates and Van Zandt, 2007). This feature of the legislation generated
considerable opposition from community activists and residents and prompted several lawsuits.
Since the selected pilot areas were overwhelmingly (82%) populated by Hispanic and AfricanAmerican residents, the selection prompted heated accusations of discriminatory intent on the
part of lawmakers. As mortgage bankers threatened to withdraw from the pilot zip codes en
masse, and as the rising tide of concerns about subprime mortgages began to have both demand
and supply effects in the real estate market, the opposition to HB 4050 reached a fever pitch. 10
The pilot program was suspended indefinitely in January 2007, after only 20 weeks of operation.

2.2 How Was the Pilot Program Area Selected?
The HB 4050 bill instructed the state regulatory body (Department of Financial and
Professional Regulation, IDFPR) to designate a pilot area on the basis of “the high rate of

10

The record of a public hearing held on November 27, 2006, provides a good illustration of the acrimony
surrounding HB 4050 (it is available at http://www.idfpr.com/newsrls/032107HB4050PublicMeeting112706.pdf).

9

foreclosure on residential home mortgages that is primarily the result of predatory lending
practices.” The pilot area announced by the Department in February 2006 encompassed ten
contiguous zip codes on the southwest side of Chicago (the solid areas in Figure 1). 11 Four of
these ten zip codes were located in Speaker Madigan’s district.
Table 1 summarizes some of the key demographic and mortgage characteristics for the
pilot area and the rest of the City of Chicago. The mortgage data come from the First American
CoreLogic LoanPerformance dataset on securitized non-prime mortgages (henceforth, the LP
data described in greater detail below). As can be seen in panel B of the table, at the time of
IDFPR decision the selected zips indeed had substantially higher delinquency and default rates
than the rest of the city (columns (1) and (3)). The pilot zip codes are also predominantly
minority-populated and have much higher rates of unemployment and poverty (Panel A). A
simple comparison of population counts and the total number of loans in the LoanPerformance
data (Panel A) and FICO scores (Panel B) strongly suggests that the HB 4050 area has a
disproportional share of subprime and Alt-A mortgages.

2.3 Constructing a Control Group
However, this set of pilot zip codes is far from unique in satisfying HB 4050 selection
guidelines. We use this fact in constructing our control group that is meant to resemble the HB
4050 zip codes in terms of their pre-treatment socioeconomic characteristics and housing market
conditions. Such areas could plausibly be expected to experience the same changes in outcome
variables as HB 4050 zip codes in the absence of intervention. To fulfill this goal, we move
beyond the univariate metric of foreclosure rates to a set of measures identifying economically
disadvantaged, inner-city neighborhoods.
In particular, we use 2005 Internal Revenue Service (IRS) zip-code-level income
statistics, as well as the 2000 Census shares of minority population, of those living below the
poverty level, and the unemployment rate to identify zip codes within the City of Chicago limits
11

The HB 4050 zip codes are: 60620, 60621, 60623, 60628, 60629, 60632, 60636, 60638, 60643, and 60652.

10

that have the smallest geometric distance from the HB 4050 zips. The resulting 12-zip-code area
is summarized in column (2) of Panel A of Table 1. The statistics in Panel B of Table 1
corroborate our prior that the control zip codes are similar to the treated area in terms of their
high default and delinquency rates, low borrower FICO scores, and disproportionate reliance on
subprime mortgage products. 12
This set of comparable zip codes (shown by the striped area in Figure 1) is used as one of
the control samples in our empirical analysis. Judging by the spirit and the letter of stated
legislative guidelines, these areas could have plausibly been selected for HB 4050 treatment. 13
To further establish the empirical robustness of our analysis, we construct a synthetic
HB4050-like area in the spirit of Abadie and Gardeazabal (2003). Instead of identifying a similar
but untreated set of loans at the zip code level, we build up a comparison sample loan-by-loan by
matching on observable loan characteristics. Specifically, for each of the loans issued in the 10zip HB 4050 area we look for a loan most similar to it that was issued elsewhere within the City
of Chicago in the same month. The metric for similarity here is the geometric distance in terms
of standardized values of the borrower’s FICO score, the loan’s debt-service-to-income (DTI),
the loan-to-value (LTV) ratios, the log of home value, and the loan’s intended purpose (purchase
or refinancing). Once a loan is matched to an HB 4050-area loan, it is removed from the set of
potential matches and the process is repeated for the next HB 4050-area loan. The resulting
synthetic HB 4050-like area is made up of observations from 42 out of 45 non-HB 4050 Chicago
zip codes. Not surprisingly, more than half of the observations in this synthetic area come from
the 12 comparable zip codes identified above on the basis of their socioeconomic characteristics.
In subsequent analysis we will refer to the comparable zip codes and the synthetic area
counterfactuals as the Control and the Matched samples, respectively.
12

In an earlier version of the paper, we used the reverse sequence for constructing the control sample. That is, we
built up the set of control zip codes by minimizing the distance in observed mortgage characteristics in the pre-HB
4050 LP data. Afterward we checked for similarity on socioeconomic characteristics of treatment and control areas.
All of the results reported below are robust to the definition of the control area and are available upon request.
13

The control area includes the following zip codes: 60609, 60617, 60619, 60624, 60633, 60637, 60639, 60644,
60649, 60651, 60655, and 60827.

11

3. Data and Empirical Setup
3.1 Data Used in the Study
Our study relies on several complementary sources of data that cover the calendar years
2005–2007. First, we use data collected under the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act (HMDA) to
assess elements of supply and demand for credit. Ideally, we would rely on the loan application
and counseling data collected under the statutory authority of HB 4050 to analyze credit demand.
In its absence, however, we turn to HMDA as the next best source of information on loan
application volume, rejection rates, etc. Using information from HUD as well as hand-collected
data, we are able to distinguish between lenders who specialize in prime and subprime loans, as
well as between lenders that are licensed by Illinois and those who are exempt from licensing.
Since the effects of the legislation were likely to be felt most acutely by state-licensed subprime
lenders, we use this list to refine our analysis. Furthermore, the HMDA data allows us to
examine how the HB 4050 affected the credit supply along the extensive margin, i.e., to identify
lenders that left the market altogether. In addition, we use Census data and IRS data to control
for zip-code-level characteristics of income and population composition.
Next we employ the Cook County Recorder of Deeds database to obtain information on
all actual transactions (mediated by agents or sold by owners) that took place in Cook County,
including basic information about the associated mortgages.
We also use the LoanPerformance (LP) database to assess the effect of HB 4050 on the
composition and performance of mortgages originated in the treated zip codes. This dataset is the
main source of loan-level information available for subprime mortgages. According to
LoanPerformance, its database covered over 90% of securitized subprime mortgages as of 2006.
The database includes detailed borrower and loan information, such as FICO scores, debtservice-to-income (DTI) and loan-to-value ratios, zip codes, and home characteristics; it also
features mortgage terms, including maturity, product type (e.g., fixed or adjustable rate
mortgage), interest rate, and interest rate spread. In addition, it contains information on whether a
12

given loan has a prepayment penalty, whether negative amortization was allowed, and whether it
required full documentation in underwriting. These and other characteristics of LP data are
summarized in Table 1, Panel C. FICO scores are used extensively by lenders to assess borrower
creditworthiness and set appropriate loan terms. For the purposes of our study, the FICO scores
also allow us to determine which borrowers in the treated zip codes were automatically or
conditionally subject to loan counseling (see the discussion in Section 2 for details). 14
Finally, we received a sample of counseling data from one of the agencies that provided
counseling services during the HB 4050. The data includes information on original mortgage
offers reviewed in 191 counseling sessions. We matched these data to the Recorder of Deeds and
LoanPerformance datasets to identify which mortgages were originated and on what terms. We
use this dataset to gauge the extent to which counseling had a direct effect on mortgage choice.

3.2. Design of Tests: Difference-in-Differences Micro-Level Analysis
Our empirical analysis is designed to exploit cross-sectional and temporal variation in a
difference-in-differences framework. Specifically, our tests measure the difference in response of
various variables (e.g., default status, loan terms, etc.) as a function of whether the loan was
originated in a zip code subject to the mandatory counseling program. Our regressions include
both time controls and cross-sectional controls, as in classic difference-in-differences analysis.
Our basic specification regressions have the following form:
(1)

Responseijt = α + β Treatmentjt + γ Time dummiest + δ Zip dummiesj +θ Controlsijt + εijt,

where Responseijt is the loan level response variable, such as default status of loan i originated at
time t in zip j; Treatmentjt is a dummy variable that receives the value of 1 if zip code j is subject
14

We replicate our results using the loan-level data from LPS Applied Analytics (formerly known as McDash
Analytics). The LPS data contain information similar to that in LoanPerformance with the important distinction that
it is not limited to subprime securitized loans. Since the majority of loans in HB 4050 zip codes were made to
subprime borrowers and the vast majority of those were securitized, both databases cover substantially similar
transactions. However, using LoanPerformance forces us to focus on the subset of loans directly affected by
legislation by default. This allows for a sharper test of the effects of the counseling mandate and limits concerns
about selection described more fully in Section 3.2.

13

to mandatory counseling in month t and 0 otherwise; and Time and Zip code dummies capture
fixed time and location effects. In all regressions, we cluster errors at the zip code level.15 For
each loan, the response is evaluated at only one point in time (e.g., interest rate at origination or
default status 18 months hence). Consequently, out dataset is made up of the series of monthly
cross-sections. The set of controls varies with the underlying data source, but it includes
variables such as loan-to-value ratios at origination, borrower FICO score, loan interest rate, etc.
As is always the case with program evaluation studies, we are concerned about properly
accounting for selection and matching effects. In particular, the set of HB 4050 zip codes is
patently non-random, as it concentrates on low-income neighborhoods in which foreclosure rates
were high at the outset. The problem with selecting such zip codes is that there is a possibility
that they have different resilience to economic shocks unrelated to treatment. For example, it is
possible that prices in low-income areas were more sensitive to the general price decline
following the housing market peak around November 2006.
We offer two solutions for the treatment zip code selection. First, we use the design of the
pilot project and separate the effect of treatment across low-, mid-, and high-FICO score groups.
Recall that all of the low-FICO borrowers (FICO score < 620) were subject to counseling, while
the mid-FICO (scores in the 621–650 range) and the high-FICO (scores above 650) borrowers
were counseled conditional on their mortgage contract choice. This approach retains the structure
of standard difference-in-differences analysis while also exploiting the within-zip-code
heterogeneity in treatment. 16
We further interact time dummies with the log of the average zip code income, as
reported by the IRS at an annual frequency. This allows the effects of unobservable shocks to
15

Clustering allows for an arbitrary covariance structure of error terms over time within each zip code and thus
adjusts standard error estimates for serial correlation, potentially correcting a serious inference problem (Bertrand,
Duflo, and Mullainathan, 2004). Depending on the sample, there are 22 or 53 zip codes in our regressions.

16

The FICO-score-only partitioning of borrowers in treated zip codes has the advantage of being based on a
characteristic that is exogenous to the treatment regime. As shown in section 5.4, the mandate caused a sizable move
away from mortgage contracts that trigger counseling for mid- and high-FICO-score borrowers. We also evaluated
an alternative specification that evaluates the effects on ex-post counseled borrowers by partitioning on both FICO
score and observed contract choice. The results of this approach are shown in Appendix A.

14

vary with the level of economic resources available to households in a particular zip code, further
alleviating some of the selection concerns. 17 The regression specification that we therefore run
is:
(2)

Responseijt = α + β1 (Treatmentjt × Low-FICOijt) + β2 (Treatmentjt ×Mid-FICOijt)
+ β3 (Treatmentjt × High-FICOijt)+
+ γ (Time dummiest) + δ (Zip code dummiesj) +
+ η (Time dummiest × log IRS incomejt) +θ Controlsijt + εijt.
As a second solution to non-random sample selection and matching a counterfactual

control area on only a limited set of observables, we conduct our tests using several alternative
control groups. We first compare transactions in the treated zip codes with transactions in a 12zip-code control group described in section 2.3 (the Control sample). 18 We also use a synthetic
HB 4050-like area that is constructed loan by loan, using a different set of observables for
identification (the Matched sample also described in section 2.3). Finally, to account for selfselection of lenders out of the treated zip codes, both the Control and the Matched samples are
restricted to a set of lenders that remained active in the HB 4050 zip codes during treatment (the
Control Active and Matched Active samples). 19 This part of the analysis holds the population of
lenders constant; that is, we are identifying treatment effects unrelated to the change in lender
composition. In each of these cases, we are evaluating the performance and characteristics of
securitized subprime and alt-A mortgages contained in the LoanPerformance data.

3.3. Summary of Testable Hypotheses

17

For robustness, we also evaluate a specification with a full set of time and zip code interactions. In this case,
identification derives strictly from within-zip-code variation across borrower categories at a point in time. The main
results remain qualitatively the same with this approach.
18

It would be ideal to look at transactions that lie on either side of the border between HB 4050 and control zip
codes to tease out the effect of the counseling mandate. Unfortunately, the LP data do not contain street addresses.
19

The exact definition of an active lender is provided in section 4.1.

15

We use the setup described in the previous section to test a number of hypotheses. As
discussed earlier, HB 4050 increased the costs of engaging in mortgage transactions and
providing lending services. For example, the program added legal uncertainty for mortgage
lenders about their future ability to foreclose on properties in the treated area (Bates and Van
Zandt, 2007). Consequently, we expect the legislation to restrict both the demand for and supply

of lending, particularly in the directly affected market segments—subprime borrowers and stateregulated mortgage bankers. These effects may be simultaneous and mutually reinforcing and
may occur along both extensive and intensive margins (e.g., lender exit and loan rejection rates).
Since the stated goal of the pilot program was to reduce foreclosures, we next evaluate
the performance of transactions carried out under the new regime. If the intervention was at all
effective, we would expect to find improvements in ex post mortgage performance among the
counseled population, particularly low-FICO households. We subject the findings to a number of
robustness checks on identification approach, functional form, and choice of control sample.
The documented change in performance could come from a number of sources—e.g., exit
of predatory lenders, removal of less creditworthy borrowers, or borrower ability to negotiate
better loan terms or make better product choices. We evaluate each of these possibilities in turn.
Each of the above actions could come about through a number of channels associated
with the counseling mandate. We identify three such channels: the direct information effect of
counseling, the burden effect of transaction costs of fulfilling the counseling requirement, and
the oversight effect of the threat of regulatory or legal action (e.g., license revocation or class
action lawsuits). The data and the design of the legislation allow us to test the relative
importance of these channels.
In particular, if HB 4050 succeeded in furnishing better information through counseling
sessions, its effects should be most pronounced in mortgage characteristics (e.g., lower LTV and
loan spreads) of the counseled borrowers. Absent the evidence of successful loan offer
renegotiations, we would expect to see an increase in rejections of loan offers by the counseled

16

borrowers. In contrast, we would not expect better information to have any effect on levels of
loan applications, since they are filed prior to any counseling.
Information can be furnished not only through counseling sessions, but also by mere
designation of certain products as risky in the sense that their selection triggers counseling.
These designations are publicly known and may constitute a credible signal to avoid such
mortgage products. If this signaling effect is at work, we would expect the incidence of risky
product choices to decline for all FICO groups in the treated zip codes.
In contrast, product selection can also be driven by the desire to avoid counseling and its
associated costs. In this case, members of a given FICO group would avoid products that trigger
counseling for their group. That is, one would expect a reduction in low-documentation loans
among mid-FICO households, but not high-FICO ones. Similarly, both mid- and high-FICO
households (but not low-FICO ones) would be expected to choose fewer negative amortization
loans and mortgages with prepayment penalty.
Turning to lenders, one possibility for their decision to exit the market is inability to
make a profit in the presence of the $300 counseling fee. If this were the case, we would expect
to see greater lender rejection rates for low-value loans, since lender compensation is typically
proportional to the value of originated loans.
Another possibility that was discussed earlier is that lenders are fearful of the
consequences of the oversight of their actions by counselors and, implicitly, by the state. In this
case, we would expect the lenders to tighten their screening of prospective borrowers, allowing
fewer doubtful cases to enter the counseling process. This would be reflected in a temporary
spike in rejection rates among the affected lenders during the HB 4050 period. Our final test of
the oversight channel focuses on availability of low-documentation loans. Under HB 4050,
lenders have little reason to offer low-documentation loans to any but high-FICO borrowers,
since counseling would elicit income and expenses information and furnish it to the state-run
database.
These hypotheses form the backbone of the analysis in Sections 4 and 5 below.
17

4. Effects of HB 4050 on Mortgage Market Composition and Mortgage Performance
4.1 Exit of Borrowers and Lenders
We measure mortgage market activity in the wake of HB 4050 as the volume of loan
applications captured in the HMDA database. 20 Figure 2a depicts the total number of loan
applications in the treated zip codes (the solid line) and in the control set of zip codes (the dashed
line). This information is reported in two panels that further subdivide application volumes by
state-licensed lenders that specialize in subprime loans and all other lenders (labeled exempt
lenders in the figure). These panels capture a number of key trends related to the legislation. In
both panels there is a substantial and statistically significant drop in the number of applications
in the treated area around the time the regulation became effective (September 1, 2006). In
contrast, the volumes in the control area remained relatively flat for much of the HB 4050 period,
before beginning a rapid market-wide decline in subprime mortgage originations early in 2007. 21
The decline in loan application volume is much more pronounced among state-licensed
mortgage bankers specializing in subprime loans. For such lenders, the application volume
dropped from nearly 4,000 in August 2006 to 2,341 in September. Although this decline may
potentially be exaggerated by the run-up of applications in anticipation of the regulation, it is
clearly not present in the control sample. Following the repeal of HB 4050, activity levels in both
geographic areas converged nearly instantaneously; then they proceeded to plummet jointly to
less than one-sixth of those in the market heyday.
Although not shown in Figure 2a, HMDA data provide additional insight into lender
specialization. While the vast majority of subprime lending was done by state-licensed mortgage

20

We count all HMDA records associated with owner-occupied properties that have one of the following action
codes: originated, denied, approved but not taken, withdrawn, and incomplete. Purchase loans are excluded because
of uncertainty about the timing of the initial loan application. When purchase loans are added to the set of
applications, the time patterns are effectively unchanged.
21

In an earlier version of the paper we examined whether house prices changed during the legislation period. Using
a variety of home price measures, we did not detect any statistically significant change in prices. Price measures
included logged prices, changes of market-adjusted (or unadjusted) prices since last transaction in the same property,
and transaction prices relative to the asking prices. The results are available upon request.

18

lenders, most prime lending was done by entities exempt from the state licensing requirement,
and thus from HB 4050. This specialization, and the lack of any appreciable upward trend in the
number of applications filed by lenders exempt from HB 4050 (the right-hand panel) are
consistent with the scenario in which low FICO borrowers were the ones most adversely affected
by the treatment and were not able to switch to the non-treated lenders.
Similar results are presented in regression form in Table 2, Panel A. These regressions
are run at the zip-code-month level. Column (1) shows a nearly 73% decline in loan application
volume in treated zip codes among lenders most affected by the regulation. The declines are
much smaller among other lenders, some of whom were also subject to regulation, e.g., statelicensed lenders that originated negative amortization mortgages to prime borrowers (column 2).
Panels B and C further differentiate between applications for mortgage refinancing and
home purchases. Among subprime lenders, the decline in applications for refinancing is much
greater; we attribute this to the voluntary nature of refinancing decisions versus home purchase
financing. Home buyers who need to relocate are bound to take a mortgage; conversely, for
existing homeowners, refinancing is an optional stand-alone action. The disparity between the
declines in origination rates of purchase- and refinancing-related transactions is indicative of the
extent of the burden that counseling places on borrowers.
Some of the dramatic drop in loan applications could be traced to much publicized lender
withdrawals. We can tackle the question of market exit by counting the number of unique lenders
filing HMDA reports before, during, and after the treatment period in both the treated and the
control geographic areas. To be counted as an active lender in a given geographic area, a
HMDA reporting institution must originate an average of at least 1 loan per week over a given
five-month period, with at least 1 origination in every given month. 22 The results of this simple
exercise are reported in Panel A of Table 3. The table shows a substantial decline in the number

22

The five-month period is chosen to match the duration of HB 4050. None of the patterns depend on the choice of
the threshold level or geographic area. The “every month” condition is intended to eliminate lenders that withdraw
from HB 4050 zip codes during the fall of 2006 after working off their backlog of earlier applications. We thank
Adair Morse for this suggestion.

19

of lenders in treated zip codes. The magnitude of this decline is much greater and strongly
statistically different from the pattern observed in the control area. The table also confirms that
lender exit was disproportionately concentrated among state-licensed lenders specializing in
subprime mortgages. These results corroborate the hypothesis that the mandatory counseling
requirement resulted not just in the reduction of demand for credit, but also in the abrupt exit of
relatively large lenders from the affected zip codes.
It is worth noting that some of the subprime lenders that exited the pilot areas appear to
have returned as soon as HB 4050 was rescinded. Figure 2b illustrates the rapid run-up in loan
applications filed by those lenders. As noted in footnote 9, the legislation created some legal
uncertainty about enforceability of mortgage contracts in treated zips. This by itself may have
accounted for the strong lender response along the extensive margin.
This identification of active lenders allows us to check whether the drop off in loan
applications in Table 2 is due entirely to lender exit. Column (3) of Table 2 shows that restricting
the sample to lenders that remained active in the HB 4050 area still generates a substantial (albeit
smaller) drop in volume. In other words, fewer applications were filed even with the subprime
lenders that did not shut down their operations in HB 4050 zip codes. Applications for
refinancing declined more, suggesting a shift to purchase loans among the remaining lenders. 23
We further assess whether the lenders who stayed in the market have different
characteristics than the ones that exited following implementation of HB 4050. Panel B of Table
3 compares those two types of lenders, based on characteristics of their mortgage applications
and originations prior to HB 4050. Two of the characteristics jump out. Lenders who remained in
the market are much larger than those who exited. They also have much higher rejection rates
prior to the HB 4050 period, indicating more stringent screening practices. We will return to this
point in Section 5.5.

23

We count 9 state-licensed subprime lenders that satisfy this definition of active in the HB 4050 zip codes. This
number refers to the number of lenders funding loans and filing HMDA reports. According to the Housing Action
Illinois (2007) report, these lenders were represented by more than 300 mortgage brokers. This correspondence
looks less surprising given the large size of entities in the active lender subset.

20

Finally, we examine whether borrowers that were subject to counseling were more likely
to be rationed from the market. In Figures 3a and 3b we compare the distribution of borrowers
that originated their loans before and during the HB 4050 period across FICO ranges. There is a
pronounced shift to the right in the FICO score distribution during the treatment period in the HB
4050 zip codes. The share of loans originated for borrowers with sub-620 FICO scores in treated
areas shrank by 10 percentage points relative to the pre-HB 4050 period. In contrast, the FICO
score distribution in the comparable (untreated) sample remains virtually unchanged.
In unreported analysis, we evaluate these changes in borrower credit quality in a
regression framework, with one of the specifications limiting the sample to financial institutions
that remained active in the HB 4050 zip codes during the treatment period. The restricted sample
also shows a sizable improvement in borrower credit quality in HB 4050 zip codes, indicating
that the change was not entirely due to the exit of lenders that catered to low-FICO borrowers.

4.2 Default Rates
Perhaps the main goal of HB 4050 was to reduce the extent to which borrowers defaulted
and had their properties foreclosed on. To measure loan performance, we flag borrowers that
default within 18 months of origination. 24 We then estimate a series of ordinary least squares
(OLS) regressions defined in (2), where the set of controls includes measures of borrower
characteristics (FICO score and flags for being an investor or second-home owner), contract
terms (LTV, loan spread, and logged property valuation), contract type (low-doc, negative
amortization, interest only, prepayment penalty, or refinancing loans), and property
characteristics (indicators of whether a property is a single-family home, condo, or townhouse).
The results of difference-in-differences tests are reported in Table 4. Columns (1)–(4)
display the results of specification (2) that differentiates between borrowers on the basis of their
FICO scores. As discussed in Section 3.2, each difference-in-differences specification is

24

A loan is considered defaulted if it is 90+ days past due, in bankruptcy, or in foreclosure or if it has real-estate
owned (REO) status in the first 18 months since the first mortgage payment date.

21

estimated for four samples: the control sample, the matched sample, and the control sample and
the matched sample restricted to lenders that remained active during the HB 4050 period.
The results in columns (1)–(4) suggest that the treatment had a strong effect on lowFICO-borrowers, each of whom had to attend a counseling session. For such borrowers, the ex
post default rates are substantially lower than those among similar borrowers in the control
group. The difference ranges from 4.1 to 5.4 percentage points across the four samples, but is
uniformly economically and statistically significant in each of the samples. 25 In contrast, there is
no statistically measurable effect of HB 4050 for borrowers with high or mid FICO scores. The
results are qualitatively the same if contract type controls (which determine counseling
requirements for mid- and high-FICO borrowers) are added as regressors—columns (5)–(8).
The specifications in table 4 allow us to account for the possibility that the superior
performance of counseled borrowers is due to factors other than counseling, such as changes in
the composition of borrowers or of lenders. For instance, limiting the sample to lenders that
remained active during the HB 4050 period (columns (3)–(4), tests whether better post-treatment
default rates owe to the fact that predatory lenders that previously accepted unqualified
borrowers simply exited the market after HB 4050, thereby eliminating some bad loans. The
results indicate that our conclusions remain fully robust to this restriction. Even among loans
made by this static group of lenders, there is a marked improvement in ex post defaults for HB
4050 originations among low-FICO-score borrowers relative to those in either control group.
Another potential interpretation of the results is that risky borrowers self-selected out of
the market or were rejected by lenders (as shown in Figures 3a and 3b). However, all of Table 4
specifications control for borrower credit scores, implying that the improvement in performance
is not due solely to higher FICO scores of the remaining borrowers. They also include a control
for the loan spread paid by borrowers as an additional measure of borrower riskiness not

25

The weakest statistical result— for the matched active sample— has a t-statistic of 1.94.

22

captured by the credit score. 26 The validity of these variables as risk measures is corroborated by
the consistent association of lower FICO scores and higher loan spreads with higher defaults.
As a test of our identification strategy, we estimate a specification with a full set of
interactions between zip code and time dummies. This setting allows us to identify the effects of
HB 4050 by exploiting within-zip-code heterogeneity in applicability of the counseling
requirement. This specification represents a triple difference-in-differences estimator, with the
additional set of differences taken with respect to performance of the omitted (high-FICO-score)
group. The results shown in columns (1)–(4) of Panel B once again indicate a statistically and
economically significant effect of HB 4050. To test the importance of the functional form
assumptions, we rerun the regressions in a probit framework despite the critique of Ai and
Norton (2003). The estimated marginal effects presented in columns (5)–(8) indicate a consistent
treatment effect of 3–4 percentage points on defaults.
In sum, we find that the financial counseling requirement improved ex post default rates
for the low-FICO-score counseled borrowers relative to similar borrowers outside the treatment
area. The effect on default is impressive in its economic magnitude and does not seem to be
driven solely by documented changes in the borrower and lender pools.

5. Disentangling the Effects of Information, Costs, and Oversight
Our results in the previous section show that the HB 4050 program had a strong
contractionary effect on the mortgage market in affected zip codes. Still, the pilot program
appears to have accomplished one of its stated goals—sharply lower default rates among some of
the vulnerable (low-FICO-score) borrowers. In this section we analyze the factors that could
have led to the improvement in performance. In particular, we consider changes in borrower
ability to make better product choices or negotiate better loan terms, as well as changes in lender
underwriting practices. We will use each of these actions to try to differentiate between the direct

26

For ARMs, LoanPerformance provides the relevant data item. For fixed-rate mortgages (FRMs), Loan Spread is
calculated as the difference between the contract interest rate and the matching-maturity Treasury.

23

information effect of counseling, the transaction costs of fulfilling the counseling requirement,
and the threat of regulatory or legal action.

5.1 Mortgage Terms
According to Housing Action Illinois (2007), counselors commonly observed that
mortgage applicants took on too much debt at excessive interest rates. As a result, one would
expect that treated borrowers would try to reduce their leverage and negotiate better loan terms.
If the pilot program worked by providing better information through counseling sessions, its
effects should be most pronounced in mortgage terms of the counseled borrowers.
The top panel of Table 5 presents evidence of changes in some of the key contract terms
of loans originated during the treatment period. For each dependent variable, we estimate
difference-in-differences specifications for the four samples described earlier. We find a
marginally significant decrease in LTV for the low-FICO-score borrowers (columns (1)–(2)). 27
These relative improvements translate to a decrease in debt levels of about $1,500 for an average
borrower. We further investigate whether interest rate spreads improved for counseled
borrowers. Regression results show no material effect of HB 4050 on loan spreads once the
sample is restricted to lenders that remained active during the treatment period (columns (5)–
(6)). For the broader sample, it is the mid- and high-FICO groups show statistically significant, if
small, improvements in spreads.
The lower panel of Table 5 explores measures of loan affordability by looking at the
debt-service-to-income (DTI) ratio that captures borrowers’ ability to service existing loan
obligation (columns (1)–(2)) and the dollar amount of the annual mortgage payment relative to
the original loan size (columns (3)–(6)). For either of these measures we fail to detect any effect
of the treatment on the low-FICO-score population. Somewhat surprisingly, we find slightly

27

Note that for LTV and Debt-Service-to-Income (DTI) regressions we do not present matched sample results since
they were constructed by matching on characteristics which include LTV and DTI.

24

higher mortgage payments for mid- and high-FICO-score borrowers in HB 4050 areas. However,
the magnitude of the estimated effect is very small, never exceeding 20 basis points.
In sum, the analysis of loan terms contains only some evidence of the beneficial effects of
information obtained in counseling sessions. Although debt burdens improve somewhat for
counseled borrowers, the economic magnitude of these effects is fairly small. We find no
evidence that counseled borrowers were able to negotiate lower loan spreads. Instead, it is the
borrowers exempt from counseling that are able to obtain (slightly) better loan rates.

5.2 Direct Evidence of Loan Renegotiations
The results in the preceding section suggest that HB 4050 did not improve the bargaining
power of low- and mid-FICO-score borrowers. However, we can learn more about the actions of
counseled borrowers by comparing the initial loan offers reviewed by counselors and the final
originated loan. In particular, we assess whether counseled borrowers walked away from the
original offer or tried to renegotiate it following the counseling session.
To do so, we obtain detailed counseling session information from one of the agencies
providing services under HB 4050. For each of the 191 sessions we compared the original terms
(as recorded by the agency) to mortgage details in LoanPerformance data set.28 Panel A of Table
6 presents a breakdown of these mortgage offers organized by counselor recommendation.
About 19% of the initial mortgage offers were abandoned by the borrowers, with the
rejection rates substantially higher among borrowers that were told that their loans were either
“unaffordable” or “fraudulent”. The majority of the reviewed offers that proceeded to closing
(101 out of 155) received a “no issues” entry, indicating that the counselor had no concerns
about the loan’s affordability, the borrower’s understanding of the terms, or the original offer’s
disclosures. Yet, about a half of these “no issues” loans did become modified after counseling,
28

To match counseling records with those in the LoanPerformance database, we first use the property address and
counseling date to obtain the amount of originated loan in the Recorder of Deeds database. If there is no record of a
mortgage transaction in the month following the counseling session, the loan offer is considered to have been
abandoned. For matched properties we use the Deeds dataset values on loan amount and loan recording dates, and
the agency’s data on the counseling date and applicant’s FICO score to find a matching loan in the LP data.

25

with slightly over 40% of renegotiated loans resulting in lower monthly payments. Although the
share of renegotiated “unaffordable” or “fraudulent” loans is similar to that of the “no issue”
loans, substantially more of them result in lower monthly payments.
Looking more closely into the specifics of renegotiated problem loans highlights some of
the complexities in establishing a direct mapping between counseling recommendations and the
eventual loan choice. Some contract changes appear incongruous with the recommendation. For
example, some unaffordable loans were renegotiated to loans with shorter amortization periods
or longer resets. This may have made such choices less risky, but also less affordable at the time
of origination. Although counselors commonly recommended fixed rate mortgages as the best
means to lessen the risk of mortgage obligations, few borrowers switched away from their
original ARM offers. In fact, as many borrowers went from fixed rate mortgages to ARMs as the
other way around. Among those renegotiating their ARM deals, extending reset periods (by
switching from, say, 2/28 to 3/27 loans) was also nearly as common as shortening them. Thus, it
may not be surprising that, on average, counseling did not appear to change debt burden and
interest costs of originated mortgages substantially (Table 5).
An open question then is whether the evidence in this small sample of treated borrowers
is consistent with direct information effects of counseling. On the one hand, higher rejection
rates of fraudulent loans and a high prevalence of lower payments for renegotiated unaffordable
loans is suggestive of a strong effect of counseling. On the other, about a half of all problematic
loans that went to origination did so without any changes. Moreover, if we assume that recorded
recommendations reflect relevant information provided by counselors, the fact that many loan
changes do not seem to line up with such recommendations weakens the hypothesis of direct
information effects.

5.3 Borrower Rejection of Loan Offers
HB 4050 also required further sessions for each mortgage offer from a new lender or a
renegotiated offer from the original lender that worsened the initial terms. Hence, if counseling is
26

regarded as a burden instead of a source of valuable information, we would anticipate fewer
rejections of loan offers by treated population. Conversely, we would expect to see a spike in
loan rejections by better informed borrowers if they cannot renegotiate their loan terms.
Table 6, Panel B presents a test of these hypotheses using aggregate HMDA applications
data. The regressions are run at the loan level, with borrower rejection of a loan offer as the
dependent variable. The table shows that rejection of mortgages by borrowers actually declined
during the HB 4050 period by about 5 percentage points among subprime lenders. Note,
however, that the borrower rejection rate appears to be unchanged among subprime lenders that
remained in the HB 4050 zip codes (columns (3)–(4)). This suggests that such lenders were
somewhat different than the ones who exited the market.
This finding is remarkable because the majority of the counseled were advised that they
could not afford the loan and/or that they should seek alternative mortgage offers (see discussion
in Section 2.1). Since we find little evidence of significant improvement in loan terms following
counseling (e.g., loan spread), a likely explanation for the decrease in the rejection rate is that
borrowers preferred to accept the offer at hand and not to return for further counseling with
offers from different lenders.
This result is consistent with the idea that decisions of low-FICO-score borrowers were
not influenced as much by information presented in counseling sessions as they were by the costs
of obtaining an alternative loan offer. For such borrowers, the costs of compliance likely
outweighed the expected benefits of new offers. This finding also appears to reflect the limits of
bargaining power and ability to act on new information by this subset of borrowers. Finally, this
result also removes concerns that the incentives of counselors led them to convince borrowers to
reject loans, ultimately leading to low origination volume.

5.4 Product Choice
From our interviews with a number of counselors involved in HB 4050 we know that
borrowers were typically warned about risks associated with hybrid ARM loans or loans carrying
27

prepayment penalties. However, the information pertaining to broad product choices was
provided not only through counseling sessions, but also by the fact that the legislation signaled
certain products were risky because their selection triggered counseling. Hence, analyzing
changes in product selection in HB 4050 zips can help us differentiate between the effects of
counselor information, signaling, and borrowers’ desire to avoid compliance costs of counseling.
To do this, we again estimate difference-in-differences regressions of borrower choice of
a particular mortgage contract, omitting the set of contract controls. If the information effect is at
work, we would expect the low-FICO-score borrowers to shift away from products highlighted
by counselors. In the case of signaling, we would expect the incidence of risky product choices
to decline for all FICO score groups in the treated zip codes. If product selection is driven by
cost avoidance, members of a given FICO score group would avoid products that trigger
counseling for their group. That is, we would expect fewer interest-only loans by mid-FICOscore households, but not high-FICO-score ones. Similarly, we would expect both mid- and
high-FICO-score (but not low-FICO-score) households to choose fewer negative amortization
loans and mortgages with prepayment penalty.
Table 7 presents the results of this exercise. Category I Risky Products denotes choices
that subject only the mid-FICO borrowers to counseling (hybrid ARMs, interest-only loans, and
low-documentation loans), while Category II indicates choices that trigger counseling for both
mid- and high-FICO borrowers (prepayment penalty and negative amortization loans). As
reported in the top panel, we find no evidence that low-FICO borrowers who always had to
attend counseling stayed away from either of these categories of risky products at lenders that
remained active during the pilot period. Instead, we find much lower prevalence of Category I
products among mid-FICO borrowers in pilot areas, but not high-FICO borrowers. Although
taking a Category II loan triggers counseling for all borrowers, only high-FICO borrowers in HB
4050 zips reduce their use of such products. Although these results are consistent with both
signaling and cost avoidance, they do not support the hypothesis of direct information effects.

28

The striking result here is that treated (low-FICO) borrowers did not, on average,
materially change their product mix as a result of counseling. The ones that did alter their
product choice appreciably were the mid- and high-FICO borrowers who would thereby be able
to eschew counseling. In other words, the regulator achieved the goal of risk reduction by the
threat of counseling and not by the content of counseling.
The results thus far point to the limited ability (or willingness) of the low-FICO-score
borrowers to act on counseling information. Yet, we find strong evidence of improvement in
their ex post performance. One remaining possibility is that the counseling mandate caused
lenders to modify their behavior as well. We consider this in the following section.

5.5 Changes in Lender Behavior
In this section we analyze the response of lenders who stayed in the market to the
increased oversight of their actions by counselors and, implicitly, by the state. If lenders are
apprehensive of the consequences of such oversight, we would expect them to tighten their
screening of prospective borrowers, allowing fewer doubtful cases to enter the counseling
process. Such behavior would be reflected in a temporary spike in rejection rates among the
affected lenders during the HB 4050 period. In the same vein, we would expect lenders affected
by HB 4050 to cut back on offering low-documentation loans. Under HB 4050, there is little
reason to offer such loans to any but high-FICO-score borrowers, as income and expenses
information would be gathered during counseling and then furnished to the state-run database.
The simple time series of Figure 4a indeed show a dramatic spike in the rejection rates of
state-licensed mortgage bankers issuing subprime loans in the pilot area. This does not occur
among similar lenders in control areas or among lenders exempt from HB 4050. This spike
comes from two sources: exit of loosely screening lenders and further tightening of underwriting
standards by the ones that remain active during HB 4050.
The first source is illustrated by the time series in Figure 4b that show the decomposition
of lender rejection rates in the HB 4050 area between active and non-active lenders, as defined in
29

Section 4.1. The subprime lenders that ultimately remained active experienced a very fast run-up
in their rejection rates in the 6 months prior to implementation of HB 4050. During this time,
their rejection rates went from about 30 percent to 50 percent (solid line, left panel) while their
application volumes remained unchanged (Figure 2b). In contrast, the lenders that left the HB
4050 zip codes kept rejecting applications at just above the 20 percent rate (the dashed line, left
panel), and then left the market altogether. Consequently, as seen in the figure, the total rejection
rate spikes with the onset of HB 4050, as the lenders with tighter screening are the only ones left.
The rejection rate comes down when HB 4050 is rescinded as the lenders with looser screening
practices return to the market (Figure 2b).
The further tightening of lending standards by the lenders that stayed in the pilot zip
codes is captured by the regression results in Table 8. As seen in columns (3)–(4) of Panel A, the
rejection rates rise by an additional 3.4 to 3.9 percentage points among active subprime lenders.
When we do not restrict the regression sample to such lenders, the spike in rejection rates is
greater, in line with the decomposition in Figure 4b.
Earlier we found that state-licensed lenders that specialize in subprime loans were more
likely to exit the market than lenders exempt from HB 4050. One possible explanation for lender
exit is inability to make a profit in the presence of the $300 counseling fee. If this were the case,
we would expect to see greater lender rejection of low-dollar-value loans, since lender
compensation is roughly proportional to the value of originated loans. We test this hypothesis by
testing whether smaller loans (measured as logged mortgage size) are more likely to be rejected
during the HB 4050 treatment. Table 8, Panel B, shows that there is no empirical support for this
hypothesis: small mortgages were not subject to higher rejection rate.
Finally, we look at changes in availability of low-documentation loans under the
counseling mandate. The results, reported in the panel B of Table 7, indeed show substantially
lower likelihood of low-doc mortgages for both low- and mid-FICO-score borrowers. This is not
surprising, since document review by counselors made such loan offers difficult to defend.

30

6. Policy Discussion and Conclusion
Mandated financial counseling and increased oversight of lenders (anti-predatory
legislation) are important policy tools being considered for implementation following the
meltdown of the housing market in 2007-2008. 29 Both policies impose restrictions on free
contracting between borrowers and lenders. As such, they can be expected to shrink credit
markets, in particular for the financially disadvantaged segments of the population.
In this paper, we evaluate the impact of one such pilot legislative program implemented
in parts of Chicago in late 2006. The design of the pilot allows us to disentangle the effects of
financial education on the behavior of borrowers from those of increased oversight on lenders.
Our main results show that the legislation had material effects on market composition of
both lenders and borrowers, on borrower default rates, and on borrowers’ and lenders’ behavior.
We find that the pilot caused low-FICO borrowers and lenders with relatively lax approval
standards to exit the market. 30 Yet, controlling for observable characteristics of the remaining
borrowers and holding the sample of lenders constant, we find that mortgage default rates among
low-FICO-score counseled borrowers declined dramatically. Loan terms for counseled borrowers
improved as well, albeit only marginally. While the product choice for the low-FICO borrowers
did not change appreciably (the borrower group always subject to counseling), we find that midand high-FICO borrowers switched toward products that did not subject them to counseling.
Our results are consistent with the explanation that in this specific implementation of a
mortgage counseling mandate, the threat of third-party oversight and the desire to avoid the costs
of counseling had a greater impact on borrowers and lenders than the informational content of
counseling as such. We find that borrowers altered their mortgage choice to minimize interaction
with counselors. Specifically, borrowers who could eschew counseling did so by choosing less
29

As announced on June 17, 2009, by President Obama, a new Consumer Financial Protection Agency will be
created to protect consumers across the financial sector from unfair, deceptive, and abusive practices. See
http://online.wsj.com/public/resources/documents/reform.pdf.

30

Arguably, the extent of market exit by lenders could have been mitigated by a more careful design of compliance
rules. For instance, Bates and Van Zandt (2007) argue that the decline in the supply of credit in the HB 4050 area
was related to the absence of the “safe harbor” provision in the legislation and the resulting uncertainty about lender
ability to foreclose on the assets.

31

risky products. Those who were required to attend counseling did not appear, on average, to
follow the counselor’s advice, and seemed to have only limited bargaining power in
renegotiations. They also tended to not walk away from the original offer following counseling
and reapply for a restructured mortgage, which would have required another counseling session.
Furthermore, we find evidence consistent with lenders rejecting borrowers more often based on
unobservable characteristics when loan proposals were reviewed by third-party counselors. In
order to avoid public scrutiny, lenders appear to have fine-tuned their lending model and rejected
applications they may have previously accepted. Thus, it was the forced disclosure of lender
information and its collection and recording by an outside party that generated the desired result.
It may be tempting to conduct a back-of-the-envelope welfare analysis by linking the
estimates of reductions in defaults with the costs of such defaults and of counseling itself. 31
However, doing so will fail to take into account a number of important effects—losses in utility
incurred by excluded borrowers, positive spillovers on neighborhood property values from lower
defaults, losses from inefficient contract choices guided by avoidance of counseling sessions, and
many others. Moreover, evaluating the overall welfare effect of this intervention requires
weighing the benefits of fewer foreclosures against changes in utility incurred by the excluded
borrowers and lenders. 32 It is further complicated by the various distortions that already exist in
the housing market resulting from unique tax treatment, zoning restrictions, etc., as well as
potential externalities produced by individual housing decisions.
Our results suggest several policy recommendations. First, this paper shows that
counseling is perceived as a burden by borrowers. Hence, many borrowers either stay away from

31

For instance, we could have noted that the average house value in the treated area during the treatment period was
about $190,000 and that the expected deadweight loss due to foreclosure can be assumed to be about 30%
(Campbell, Giglio, and Pathak 2009). Using the point estimate of a 5.04% improvement in default rates of the lowFICO-score borrowers (relative to the counterfactual of the control group in column 1 of Table 4), we could
compute the expected benefit of counseling as $2,850 (0.05*$190,000*30%). Since approximately 60% of all
counseled borrowers had low FICO scores, their gains would have to be offset by the $300 counseling fee charged
to all counseled borrowers.
32

Some recent attempts to theoretically model the welfare effects of policy choices in household financial markets;
see Carlin and Gervais (2008), Bolton, Freixas and Shapiro (2007), and Carlin (2008).

32

the market altogether (as in the case of refinancing versus home-purchasing mortgages) or switch
to mortgages that allow them to avoid counseling. Second, the gains from the informational
content of counseling are tempered by the limited negotiating power of the borrowers. A likely
possibility is that even after the (admittedly brief) counseling session mortgage applicants cannot
negotiate well with mortgage brokers who steer them between products, without real
improvement in the loan terms for the borrower. Furthermore, in the current set-up borrowers
have a disincentive to shop for alternative mortgage proposals, given that they need to incur new
application fees. A potential remedy that would improve borrowers’ negotiating leverage would
be to require lenders to reimburse borrowers for their upfront application fee if they change their
minds following counseling. Third, the mere presence of the regulator in the marketplace and the
third-party review of mortgages seem to have a large effect on the quality of mortgages
originated. We observe that lenders with looser screening criteria exit the market, and the
remaining lenders cut back substantially on origination of low-documentation loans.

33

References
Abadie, Alberto, and Javier Gardeazabal, 2003. The Economic Costs of Conflict: A Case Study of the
Basque Country, American Economic Review, 93(1), 113-132.
Ai, Chunrong, and Edward C. Norton, 2003, Interaction Terms in Logit and Probit Models, Economic
Letters, 80, 123-129.
Agarwal, Sumit, John Driscoll, Xavier Gabaix, and David Laibson, 2007, The Age of Reason: Financial
Decisions over the Lifecycle, NBER Working Paper #13191.
Bair, Sheila C., 2007, Improving Federal Consumer Protection in Financial Services, Statement before the
Financial Services Committee, U.S. House of Representatives, June 13.
Bates, Lisa K. and Shannon Van Zandt, 2007, Illinois’ New Approach to Regulating Predatory Lending:
Unintended Consequences of Borrower Triggers and Spatial Targeting, University of Illinois, Spatial
Policy Analysis Research Consortium, working paper 2007-02.
Ben-David, Itzhak, 2008, Financial Constraints and Inflated Home Prices during the Real-Estate Boom,
Ohio State UniversityWorking Paper.
Bernheim, Douglas B., 1995, Do Households Appreciate Their Financial Vulnerabilities? An Analysis of
Actions, Perceptions, and Public Policy, in Tax Policy and Economic Growth, American Council for
Capital Formation, Washington, DC, 1-30.
Bernheim, Douglas B., 1998, Financial Illiteracy, Education and Retirement Saving, in O. Mitchell and S.
Schieber (eds.), Living with Defined Contribution Pensions, University of Pennsylvania Press,
Philadelphia, 38-68.
Bernheim, Douglas B., Daniel M. Garrett, and Dean H. Maki, 2001, Education and Saving: The LongTerm Effects of High School Financial Curriculum Mandates, Journal of Public Economics, 80(3),
435-65.
Bertrand, Marianne, Esther Duflo, and Sendhil Mullainathan, 2004, How Much Should We Trust
Difference in Differences Estimates?, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(1), 249-275.
Bertrand, Marianne, and Adair Morse, 2009, Financial Literacy, Cognitive Biases and Payday Lending,
University of Chicago Working Paper
Bostic, Raphael, Souphala Chomsisengphet, Kathleen C. Engel, Patricia A. McCoy, Anthony PenningtonCross, and Susan Wachter, 2008, Mortgage Product Substitution and State Anti-Predatory Lending
Laws: Better Loans and Better Borrowers?, Working Paper.
Bucks, Brian K., and Karen M. Pence, 2008, Do Borrowers Know their Mortgage Terms?, Journal of
Urban Economics, 64, 218-33.
Campbell, John Y., and Joao F. Cocco, 2003, Household Risk Management and Optimal Mortgage
Choice, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(4), 1449-1494.
Campbell, John Y., Stefano Giglio, and Parag Pathak, 2009, Forced Sales and House Prices, Harvard
University Working Paper.
Carlin, Bruce, 2008, Strategic Price Complexity in Retail Financial Markets, Working Paper.
Carlin, Bruce, and Simon Gervais, 2008, Legal Protection in Retail Financial Markets, Working Paper.

34

Cole, Shawn, and Gauri Kartini Shastry, 2008, Smart Money: The Effects of Education, Financial
Literacy and Cognitive Ability on Financial Market Participation, Working Paper.
Freixas, Xavier, Patrick Bolton, and Joel David Shapiro, 2008, Conflicts of Interest and Credible
Information Provision by Specialized and One-Stop Banks, Working Paper.
Genesove, David, and Christopher Mayer, 2001, Loss Aversion and Seller Behaviour: Evidence from the
Housing Market, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(4): 1233-1260.
Hirshleifer David, 2007, Psychological Bias as a Driver of Financial Regulation, University of California
Irvine Working Paper.
Housing Action Illinois, 2007, Findings from the HB 4050 Predatory Lending Database Pilot Program.
Keys, Benjamin J., Tanmoy K. Mukherjee, Amit Seru, and Vikrant Vig, 2009, Did Securitization Lead to
Lax Screening? Evidence from Subprime Loans, Quarterly Journal of Economics, forthcoming.
Lusardi, Annamaria, 2007, Household Saving Behavior: The Role of Literacy, Information and Financial
Education Programs, written for the conference Implications of Behavioral Economics for Economic
Policy held at the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston on September 27-28, 2007.
Lusardi, Annamaria, 2008, Financial Literacy: An Essential Tool for Informed Consumer Choice,
Working Paper.
Lusardi, Annamaria, and Olivia S. Mitchell, 2006, Financial Literacy and Planning: Implications for
Retirement Wellbeing, MRRC Working Paper n. 2006-144.
Lusardi, Annamaria, and Olivia Mitchell, 2008, Planning and Financial Literacy: How Do Women Fare?,
American Economic Review, 98(2), 413-417.
Lusardi, Annamaria, and Peter Tufano, Debt Literacy, Financial Experience and Overindebtedness,
Dartmouth College and Harvard Business School Working Paper.
Merrick, Ann, 2007, Illinois Tries New Tack Against Predatory Loans, Wall Street Journal, August 22.
Moore, Danna, 2003, Survey of Financial Literacy in Washington State: Knowledge, Behavior, Attitudes,
and Experiences, Technical Report n. 03-39, Washington State University.
Stark, Debra P., 2005, Unmasking the Predatory Loan in Sheep's Clothing: A Legislative Proposal,
Harvard BlackLetter Law Journal, 21, 129-162.
Stark, Debra P., and Jessica M. Choplin, 2009, A License to Deceive: Enforcing Contractual Myths
Despite Consumer Psychological Realities, NYU Journal of Law and Business, Spring 2009.
Rajan, Uday, Amit Seru, and Vikrant Vig, 2008, The Failure of Models that Predict Failure: Distance,
Incentives and Defaults, Working Paper.
White, Michelle, 2007, Bankruptcy Reform and Credit Cards, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21(4),
175-199.

35

Table 1. Summary Statistics
Panel A: Construction of a Control Sample on the Basis of pre-Treatment Socioeconomic
Characteristics
(2005 IRS and 2000 Census data)
HB 4050 zip codes
(10 zip codes)

Control ZIP codes
(12 zip codes)

all non-HB4050
Chicago zip codes
(53 zip codes)

729,980
259,884

713,155
244,326

2,181,267
888,354

0.813
0.200

0.863
0.245

0.505
0.174

$31,579
0.823

$30,844
0.837

$56,976
0.720

0.141

0.151

0.101

Total population
Total number of 2005 tax returns
Share of minority households*
Share of households below poverty level*
Average taxable income in 2005#
Share of households with income < $50,000 in 2005
Unemployment rate (2000 Census)*
* population-weighted averages
#
weighted by number of 2005 IRS tax returns

Panel B: Pre-Treatment Mortgage Market and Borrower Characteristics of HB 4050 and
Control Zip Codes
(Loan Performance data, January 2005 - December 2005)

I(Default within 18 months) (x 100)
FICO
LTV (%)
Debt Service-to-Income (%)
log(Valuation)

HB 4050 zip codes
(n=15,216)
14.01
627.68
84.14
39.94
12.12

36

Control ZIP codes
(n=12,925)
13.69
628.64
82.92
40.28
12.22

all non-HB4050
Chicago zip codes
(n=28,060)
9.06
648.77
81.85
40.20
12.47

Panel C: Key Variable Means in LoanPerformance Data (1/2005-12/2007)

I(Default within 18 months) x 100
Low FICO Borrowers
Mid-FICO Borrowers
High-FICO Borrowers
Risky Products Category I
Risky Products Category II
I(Low Doc) x 100
FICO
Margin (%)
Annual Mortgage Payment (%)
Loan-to-Value (%)
Debt-Service-to-Income (%)
log(House Value ($))

1/2005-8/2006
9/2006-12/2007
HB 4050
Control
Matched
HB 4050
Control
Matched
Zip Codes
Sample
Sample
Zip Codes
Sample
Sample
n = 24,014 n = 20,686 n = 24,014 n = 2,802 n = 4,445 n = 2,802
17.36
17.29
15.03
21.66
25.47
20.92
44.14
44.21
40.69
35.58
42.32
36.54
19.93
19.57
20.79
20.91
20.13
20.74
35.93
36.22
38.52
43.50
37.55
42.73
88.39
88.43
91.36
81.66
84.52
86.23
20.34
20.10
18.05
13.20
15.84
15.15
44.66
45.62
49.94
46.57
48.03
51.90
629.66
629.92
634.19
641.19
632.39
639.90
4.69
4.70
4.77
4.33
4.57
4.54
8.55
8.49
8.34
8.66
8.58
8.42
84.20
83.01
83.91
83.32
82.67
83.66
40.46
40.85
41.07
40.32
41.28
41.02
12.15
12.23
12.33
12.29
12.37
12.32

37

Table 2. Effects of HB 4050 on Market Activity: Application and Transaction Volume
(Source: HMDA)

All Lenders
State-Licensed
Other
Subprime Lenders
Lenders
(1)
(2)

Active Lenders
State-Licensed
Other
Subprime Lenders
Lenders
(3)
(4)

Panel A: Dependent: log(# Applications)
-0.727***
-0.072***
-0.113***
(-0.038)
(-0.02)
(-0.036)

HB 4050

0.002
(-0.023)

Month FE
Month FE x log(Avg Income)
Zip Code FE

Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes

Observations

792

792

792

792

0.98

0.975

0.959

0.97

2

Adj. R

HB 4050

Panel B: Dependent: log(# Originated Purchase-Related Mortgages)
-0.663***
-0.108***
-0.112**
(-0.041)
(-0.029)
(-0.051)

-0.006
(-0.031)

Month FE
Month FE x log(Avg Income)
Zip Code FE

Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes

Observations

784

792

779

792

0.955

0.905

0.92

0.879

2

Adj. R

HB 4050

Panel C: Dependent: log(# Originated Refinancing-Related Mortgages)
-0.788***
-0.059**
-0.083
0.005
(-0.049)
(-0.022)
(-0.057)
(-0.026)

Month FE
Month FE x log(Avg Income)
Zip Code FE

Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes

Observations

792

792

791

792

0.968

0.976

0.921

0.969

2

Adj. R

38

Table 3. Effects of HB 4050 on Credit Supply
Panel A: Supply of Credit -- Total Number of Active# Lenders (Source: HMDA)

Before HB 4050 (9/05 - 8/06)
During HB 4050 (9/06 - 1/07)
After HB 4050 (2/07 - 6/07)

State-Licensed Lenders
Specializing in Subprime loans
HB 4050
Control
31
30
9
23***
13
15

All Other Lenders
HB 4050
Control
83
76
56
65
66
66

#

Active lenders are defined as those that originate an average of at least 1 loan per week over a given five-month
period, with at least 1 origination in every given month.
*** means statistically different from the number of active lenders in HB 4050 zip codes at 1 percent level.

Panel B: Which Lenders Stayed in the Market?#
(Pre-HB 4050 characteristics: January 2006 – August 2006)
*

Stayed in Market (n = 9)
Left Market (n = 21)
Mean
Median
Mean
Median
Mortgage Amount
147.9
147.0
144.4
147.6
Income
72.8
70.8
76.4
72.4
Total Originations
459.4
169.0
231.2
126.0
Refi (%)
50.0
51.1
56.6
53.0
Rejection Rate (%)
33.4
33.8
27.9
27.2
Lien Ratio (%)
22.4
19.8
19.8
18.9
* The summary statistics are based on 1/2006 to 8/2006. Two lenders did not lend in this period.
# Mean lender characteristics averaged across lenders in a given group (stayed in the market, left the market)

39

Table 4. Effects of HB 4050 on Mortgage Performance
Panel A: Default Rates (Source: LoanPerformance)

Control

HB 4050 x Low FICO
HB 4050 x Mid FICO
HB 4050 x High FICO

FICO
Margin (%)

Contract Type Controls
Contract Terms Controls
Borrower Controls
Property Type Controls
Zip Code
Month FE
Month FE * log(Avg Income)

(1)
-5.04**
(1.97)
0.12
(2.65)
-1.48
(1.43)

Dependent variable: I(Default within 18 months) (x 100)
Rergression: OLS
Matched Control Matched
Control Matched Control Matched
Active Active
Active Active
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
-4.72** -5.39** -4.11*
-4.75** -4.34** -5.19** -3.85*
(1.88) (2.26) (2.12)
(1.96) (1.88) (2.26) (2.12)
1.23
0.43
2.34
0.50
1.67
0.84
2.81
(2.66) (2.59) (2.50)
(2.60) (2.61) (2.54) (2.44)
-0.27
-1.25
0.77
-1.58
-0.44
-1.33
0.60
(1.44) (1.49) (1.39)
(1.45) (1.46) (1.51) (1.41)

-0.08*** -0.07*** -0.08*** -0.08***
(0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00)
1.77*** 1.54*** 1.68*** 1.46***
(0.13) (0.11) (0.15) (0.12)

-0.08*** -0.08*** -0.09*** -0.08***
(0.00) (0.01) (0.00) (0.00)
1.72*** 1.43*** 1.61*** 1.35***
(0.16) (0.14) (0.18) (0.14)

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Observations

55600

57619

40041

40425

55600

57619

40041

40425

2

0.10

0.09

0.10

0.09

0.10

0.09

0.10

0.09

Adj. R

The set of controls not shown in the table includes the following variables: contract type (flags for low doc loans,
negative amortization loan, interest only loan, loan with a prepayment penalty, refinance loan, cashout refinance);
contract terms (log of appraised value, LTV ratio); borrower characteristics (FICO score range (low- and mid-),
investor and second mortgage flags); and property type (flags for single family residence, townhouse, or
condominium). All standard errors are clustered at the zip code level.

40

Table 4. Effects of HB 4050 on Mortgage Performance (Continued)
Panel B: Default Rates, Robustness to Functional Form and Identification Strategy
(Source: LoanPerformance)

Control

HB 4050 x Low FICO
HB 4050 x Mid FICO

(1)
-5.20***
(1.72)
0.49
(2.87)

HB 4050 x High FICO

FICO

-0.08*** -0.08*** -0.08*** -0.08*** -0.001***-0.001***-0.001***-0.001***
(0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.01)
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
1.71*** 1.46*** 1.63*** 1.34*** 0.020***0.017***0.019***0.017***
(0.13) (0.11) (0.15) (0.11)
(0.001) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001)

Margin (%)

Borrower Controls
Contract Terms Controls
Property Type Controls
Zip Code
Month FE
Month FE * log(Avg Income)
Zip Code * Month FE
Observations
2

I(Default within 18 months)
Regression: OLS
Regression: Probit
Matched Control Matched
Control Matched Control Matched
Active Active
Active Active
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
-3.90** -5.35** -3.90** -0.040***-0.032** -0.042** -0.034**
(1.66) (1.96) (1.88)
(0.015) (0.014) (0.017) (0.015)
2.55
0.93
3.11
0.002
0.017
0.004
0.016
(2.61) (2.77) (2.47)
(0.022) (0.023) (0.022) (0.021)
-0.003 0.018 -0.002 0.016
(0.012) (0.013) (0.014) (0.014)

2

Adj. R (pseudo R )

Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

55600

57619

40041

39935

55600

48114

40041

40416

0.09

0.08

0.09

0.07

0.110

0.105

0.111

0.105

The set of controls not shown in the table includes the following variables: contract terms (log of appraised value,
LTV ratio); borrower characteristics (FICO score range (low- and mid-), investor and second mortgage flags); and
property type (flags for single family residence, townhouse, or condominium). All standard errors are clustered at
the zip code level.

41

Table 5. Effects of HB 4050 on Mortgage Leverage and Spread
Panel A: Key Mortgage Terms (Source: LoanPerformance)

HB 4050 x Low FICO
HB 4050 x Mid FICO
HB 4050 x High FICO
Borrower Controls
Contract Controls
Property Type Controls
Month FE, Zip Code FE
Month FE * log(Avg Income)
Observations
Adj. R

2

Loan-to-Value (%)
Control Control
Active
(1)
(2)
-0.75* -0.81*
(0.41)
(0.42)
-0.12
-0.24
(0.37)
(0.38)
-0.02
0.13
(0.37)
(0.41)

Margin (bp)
Control Matched Control Matched
Active Active
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
-7.64**
-2.49
-3.06
5.10
(3.01)
(3.35)
(3.16)
(3.16)
-13.53***-11.37*** -4.71
0.22
(4.04)
(3.75)
(4.64)
(3.95)
-16.92***-15.55*** -5.60
-2.87
(4.23)
(4.20)
(4.32)
(4.45)

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

55,600

40,041

55,600

57,619

40,041

40,425

0.26

0.26

0.22

0.21

0.22

0.21

Panel B: Mortgage Affordability (Source: LoanPerformance)

HB 4050 x Low FICO
HB 4050 x Mid FICO
HB 4050 x High FICO
Borrower Controls
Contract Controls
Property Type Controls
Month FE, Zip Code FE
Month FE * log(Avg Income)
Observations
Adj. R

2

Debt-Service-toIncome (%)
Control Control
Active
(1)
(2)
-0.49
-0.31
(0.41)
(0.42)
-0.34
-0.41
(0.71)
(0.74)
-0.05
0.07
(0.40)
(0.38)

Annual Mortgage Payment (%)
Control Matched Control Matched
Active Active
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
0.04
0.08
0.02
0.02
(0.05)
(0.05)
(0.05)
(0.05)
0.13*
0.16**
0.13*
0.13*
(0.06)
(0.07)
(0.07)
(0.08)
0.07** 0.17*** 0.06* 0.12***
(0.03)
(0.03)
(0.03)
(0.03)

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

40,024

26,604

55,600

57,619

40,041

40,425

0.07

0.08

0.22

0.24

0.22

0.23

The set of controls not shown in the table includes: borrower characteristics (FICO score and FICO score ranges,
investor and second mortgage flags); contract terms (LTV (only for margin and mortgage payment regressions) and
log of appraised value); and property type (flags for single family residence, townhouse, or condominium). All
standard errors are clustered at the zip code level.

42

Table 6. Effects of Counseling on Borrower Behavior
Panel A: Counseling Outcome (Source: Counseling Agency)
Counselor recommendation

No issues
117
17

Cannot afford
or close to it
39
10

Indicia of
fraud
25
8

Loan above
market rate /
Seek another bid
10
1

14

7

3

4

0

Share of loans not pursued after counseling

19%

15%

26%

32%

10%

Loans originated after counseling
Total matched originations

155
148

101
96

28
27

17
17

9
8

49
47
49%

14
13
48%

8
9
53%

2
6
75%

Lower monthly payments
(percent of all changed loans)

20
43%

10
77%

5
56%

5
83%

Switch from ARM to fixed
(percent of all changed loans)

8
17%

5
38%

4
44%

1
17%

Switch from fixed to ARM
(percent of all changed loans)

12
26%

3
23%

1
11%

2
33%

Lower interest rate

23
49%

11
85%

5
56%

5
83%

Data summary
Number of counseling sessions
Loans not pursued after counseling

Total
Sessions
191
36

memo: abandoned loans re-originated after HB 4050

Comparison of loan terms before and after counseling sessions
No changes at all
Loans with changes post counseling
(percent with changes)

73
75

(percent of all changed loans)

Panel B: Are Applicants More Likely to Reject Mortgage Offers? (Source: HMDA)

HB 4050
log(Mortgage)
log(Income)

Month FE
Month FE x log(income)
Zip Code FE
Observations

Adj. R

2

Dependent: I(Applicant Rejects Offer) x 100
State-Licensed Lenders (Subprime)
All Other Lenders
Control Matched Control Matched
Control Matched Control Matched
Active Active
Active Active
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
-5.38*** -4.75*** -0.85
-0.43
-1.68** -0.98
0.17
0.04
(0.68) (0.73) (0.77) (1.00)
(0.60) (0.65) (0.72) (0.69)
0.64*
0.35
0.03
-0.28
2.54*** 2.20*** 2.16*** 1.89***
(0.36) (0.38) (0.56) (0.52)
(0.35) (0.29) (0.25) (0.24)
2.44*** 2.79*** 1.01*** 0.54*
1.00*** 0.64*** 0.04
-0.22
(0.29) (0.30) (0.22) (0.28)
(0.17) (0.16) (0.19) (0.18)
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes

158307 168789
0.02

0.01

Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes

56900

61929

0.04

0.04

43

Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes

236007 269138 155002 179842
0.01

0.01

0.01

0.01

Table 7. Mortgage Product Choice
Panel A: Selection of Contracts that Subject Borrower to Counseling
(Source: LoanPerformance)

HB 4050 x Low FICO
HB 4050 x Mid FICO
HB 4050 x High FICO

Borrower Controls
Contract Terms Controls
Property Type Controls
Month FE, Zip Code FE
Month FE * log(Avg Income)

I(Risky Products: Category I) x 100
Control Matched Control Matched
Active Active
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
-2.90** -3.04** -2.04
-1.36
(1.36) (1.44) (1.59) (1.56)
-5.28*** -5.07*** -6.67*** -5.80***
(1.27) (1.24) (1.44) (1.28)
0.37
0.87
-0.99
0.39
(1.15) (1.20) (1.31) (1.27)

I(Risky Products: Category II) x 100
Control Matched Control Matched
Active Active
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
-0.40
-1.91
-1.67
-2.31
(1.79) (1.86) (1.79) (1.85)
-0.15
-1.57
-1.04
-1.47
(1.27) (1.42) (1.14) (1.22)
-3.95*** -5.76*** -4.37*** -5.17***
(1.34) (1.44) (1.26) (1.30)

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Observations

55600

57619

40041

41891

55600

57619

40041

41891

2

0.20

0.19

0.20

0.19

0.03

0.03

0.05

0.06

Adj. R

Panel B: Availability of Low-Doc Loans (Source: LoanPerformance)

Control

HB 4050 x Low FICO
HB 4050 x Mid FICO
HB 4050 x High FICO

Borrower Controls
Contract Terms Controls
Property Type Controls
Month FE, Zip Code FE
Month FE * log(Avg Income)

(1)
-5.48***
(1.76)
-7.26***
(2.24)
0.72
(1.36)

I(Low Doc) x 100
Matched Control
Active
(2)
(3)
-7.55*** -4.03**
(1.99)
(1.89)
-8.61*** -7.17***
(2.27)
(2.41)
1.98
1.12
(1.43)
(1.58)

Matched
Active
(4)
-5.23**
(2.04)
-8.03***
(2.48)
3.26*
(1.71)

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Observations

55600

57619

40041

40425

2

0.20

0.18

0.20

0.18

Adj. R

44

Table 8. Lender Rejection Behavior
Panel A: Were Lenders More Likely to Reject Mortgages? (Source: HMDA)

HB 4050
log(Mortgage)
log(Income)

Month FE
Month FE x log(income)
Zip Code FE
Zip Code FE x log(income)
Observations
2

Adj. R

Dependent: I(Lender Rejects Application) x 100
State-Licensed Lenders
Specializing in Subprime loans
All Other Lenders
Control Matched Control Matched
Control Matched Control Matched
Active Active
Active Active
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
3.25*** 2.45*** 1.52** 1.28
11.15***11.33*** 3.93*** 3.44***
(1.37) (1.22) (1.26) (1.23)
(0.63) (0.73) (0.66) (0.82)
0.41 -3.57*** -1.31*** 0.18
-2.91*** -6.18*** -2.87*** -6.98***
(0.27) (0.32) (0.32) (0.61)
(0.26) (0.35) (0.28) (0.38)
-3.67*** -0.25
-1.04 -1.83*** -6.58*** -3.35*** -7.40*** -3.44***
(0.35) (0.28) (0.62) (0.33)
(0.36) (0.22) (0.41) (0.25)
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

158307 168789 56900
0.02

0.02

0.07

61929
0.07

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

236007 269138 155002 179842
0.02

0.03

0.03

0.04

Panel B: Were Small Loans More Likely to Be Rejected? (Source: HMDA)

HB 4050
log(Mortgage)
x HB 4050
log(Income)
x HB 4050

Month FE
Month FE x log(income)
Zip Code FE
Zip Code FE x log(income)
Observations
2

Adj. R

Dependent: I(Lender Rejects Application) x 100
State-Licensed Lenders
Specializing in Subprime loans
All Other Lenders
Control Matched Control Matched
Control Matched Control Matched
Active Active
Active Active
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
-2.51
-4.72
-4.52
-2.53
2.90
1.95
4.48
4.11
(6.18) (6.02) (7.92) (7.32)
(3.33) (3.07) (3.42) (3.29)
-3.81*** -0.24
-1.00 -2.05*** -6.61*** -3.36*** -7.38*** -3.43***
(0.34) (0.28) (0.64) (0.32)
(0.36) (0.22) (0.40) (0.25)
-0.85
-0.26
2.07 2.54**
-0.30
0.09
-0.44
-0.06
(1.02) (1.12) (1.23) (1.24)
(0.53) (0.47) (0.56) (0.52)
0.44 -3.72*** -1.50*** 0.32
-2.89*** -6.18*** -2.84*** -6.93***
(0.27) (0.30) (0.30) (0.62)
(0.27) (0.35) (0.29) (0.37)
4.28** 4.16** -0.40
-1.55
0.43
0.02
-0.23
-0.62
(1.72) (1.70) (1.72) (1.71)
(0.74) (0.73) (0.78) (0.77)
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

158307 168789 56900
0.02

0.02

0.07

61929
0.07

45

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

236007 269138 155002 179842
0.02

0.03

0.03

0.04

Figure 1. HB 4050 Treatment (Shaded) and Control (Striped) Zip Codes

46

Figure 2a. Number of HMDA Loan Application Filings in HB 4050 and Control Areas:
Lenders Subject to HB 4050 vs. Exempt Lenders (Source: HMDA)
Exempt lenders

4,500

4,500

4,000

4,000

Number of Applications

5,000

3,500
HB4050
3,000
Control
2,500
2,000

3,500
3,000
2,500
HB4050

2,000

Nov-07

Jul-07

Sep-07

May-07

Jan-07

Mar-07

Nov-06

Jul-06

Sep-06

May-06

Jan-06

Mar-06

Nov-05

Jul-05

Sep-05

May-05

Jan-05

Nov-07

Jul-07

Sep-07

Ma y-07

Ja n-07

Ma r-07

Nov-06

Jul-06

Sep-06

Jul-05

Ma y-06

0

Ja n-06

0

Ma r-06

500

Nov-05

500

Sep-05

1,000

Ma y-05

1,000

Ja n-05

1,500

Mar-05

Control
1,500

Ma r-05

Number of Applications

Lenders subject to HB 4050
5,000

Figure 2b. Number of HMDA Loan Application Filings in HB 4050 Area:
Lenders that Remained Active and Those who Exited (Source: HMDA)
Exempt Lenders

4000

4000

3500

3500

47

Nov-07

Sep-07

Jul-07

May-07

Mar-07

Jan-07

Nov-06

Sep-06

Jul-06

Sep-07

Nov-07

Jul-07

Mar-07

May-07

Jan-07

Sep-06

Nov-06

Jul-06

Mar-06

May-06

Jan-06

Nov-05

Sep-05

0
Jul-05

0
Mar-05

500

May-05

500

May-06

1000

Mar-06

1000

Not Active
1500

Jan-06

1500

Active

2000

Nov-05

Not Active

Sep-05

2000

2500

Jul-05

Active

May-05

2500

3000

Jan-05

3000

Mar-05

Number of Applications, Active

4500

Jan-05

Number of Applications

Lenders subject to HB 4050
4500

Figure 3a. Cumulative Distribution of FICO Scores of Mortgages
Originated Before the HB 4050 Period (1/2005 – 8/2006) (Source: LoanPerformance)

Cumulative Distribution
Function

1
0.9

HB 4050 ZIPs

0.8
0.7

Control ZIPs

0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
480 500 520 540 560 580 600 620 640 660 680 700 720 740 760 780 800 820

FICO Score

Figure 3b. Cumulative Distribution of FICO Scores of Mortgages Originated
During the HB 4050 Period (9/2006 – 1/2007) (Source: LoanPerformance)

Cumulative Distribution
Function

1
0.9

HB 4050 ZIPs

0.8
0.7

Control ZIPs

0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
480 500 520 540 560 580 600 620 640 660 680 700 720 740 760 780 800 820

FICO Score

48

Jan-05

Sep-07

49

Nov-07

0.5

Sep-07

Jul-05

Nov-07

Sep-07

Jul-07

May-07

Mar-07

Jan-07

Nov-06

Sep-06

Jul-06

May-06

Mar-06

Jan-06

Nov-05

0.20

Jul-07

May-07

Mar-07

Jan-07

0

Nov-06

0.1

Sep-06

0.2

Jul-06

0.3

May-06

0.4

Mar-06

Lenders Subject to HB4050

Jan-06

Active
Not Active
Total
Sep-05

Lenders Subject to HB 4050

Nov-05

0.6

Sep-05

0.00
May-05

0.10

Jul-05

Control

May-05

Jan-05

HB4050

Mar-05

0.30

Jan-05

0.40

Fraction of Loans Rejected by Lenders

0.50

Fraction of Loans Rejected by Lenders

Nov-07

Sep-07

Jul-07

May-07

Mar-07

Jan-07

Nov-06

Sep-06

Jul-06

May-06

Mar-06

Jan-06

Nov-05

Sep-05

Jul-05

May-05

0.60

Mar-05

0.5

Nov-07

Jan-05
Mar-05

Fraction of Loans Rejected by Lenders

0.20

Jul-07

May-07

Mar-07

Jan-07

Nov-06

Sep-06

Jul-06

May-06

Mar-06

Jan-06

Nov-05

Sep-05

Jul-05

May-05

Mar-05

Fraction of Loans Rejected by Lenders

Figure 4a. Shares of HMDA-Reported Applications Rejected by Lenders:
Lenders Subject to HB 4050 vs. Exempt Lenders (Source: HMDA)

0.60

Exempt Lenders

0.50

0.40

0.30
HB4050

Control

0.10

0.00

Figure 4b. Shares of HMDA-Reported Applications Rejected by Lenders:
Lenders that Remained Active and those who Exited Pilot Areas (Source: HMDA)

0.6

Exempt Lenders
Active
Not Active
Total

0.4

0.3

0.2

0.1

0

Appendix A. An alternative evaluation of HB 4050 effects on default rates
As mentioned in footnote 16, an alternative identification of treatment across borrower
groups can be based on both the FICO score and observed product choice. Specifically, we label
all low-FICO borrowers as being subject to “counseling by mandate”. Higher-FICO borrowers
had to go to counseling only if they chose certain mortgage contracts. These borrowers are
labeled as being subject to “counseling by choice”. Finally, transactions that involved neither
risky borrowers nor risky products are “exempt from counseling.” The results from estimating
the default regressions with treatment dummy interacted with these borrower groups are shown
below. In every other respect, these regressions are identical to those in Table 4.
The results in the first four columns suggest that for the set of counseled borrowers as a
whole, the treatment produced only a statistically insignificant improvement. The partitioning of
the treated into the mandatory and voluntary subsets (columns (1)–(8)) makes the picture clearer.
Those who could not avoid counseling had much better ex post performance, while the other
group had insignificantly higher default rates. As shown in section 5.4, contract choices for the
higher-FICO-score borrowers changed in response to the treatment, making those receiving
treatment different from their counterparts in the control groups. This endogeneity in treatment
selection is the primary reason why we chose to base the analysis in the paper on FICO score
groupings that are not affected by the treatment regime.

HB 4050 x Counseled
HB 4050 x Mandatory Counseling
HB 4050 x Voluntary Counseling

Dependent variable: I(Default within 18 months) (x 100)
Rergression: OLS
Control Matched Control Matched Control Matched Control Matched
Active Active
Active Active
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
-2.49
-1.96 -2.61
-1.16
(1.99) (1.96) (2.19) (2.08)
-5.14** -4.75** -5.42** -4.09*
(1.91) (1.82) (2.20) (2.06)
1.83
2.67
2.14
3.91
(2.77) (2.78) (2.77) (2.67)

HB 4050 x Exempt

-2.21
(1.32)

Within Counseling Criteria

0.77* 1.12*** 0.74* 0.92**
(0.43) (0.38) (0.43) (0.41)
…
…
…
…
55,600 57,619 40,041 40,425

………..
Observations
2

2

Adj. R (pseudo R )

0.10

-0.93
(1.31)

0.09

-2.06
(1.43)

0.10

50

-0.05
(1.31)

0.09

-2.21
(1.32)

-0.90
(1.32)

-2.06
(1.43)

-0.01
(1.32)

0.63 0.97** 0.54
0.71*
(0.41) (0.37) (0.40) (0.40)
…
…
…
…
55,600 57,619 40,041 40,425
0.10

0.09

0.10

0.09

Working Paper Series
A series of research studies on regional economic issues relating to the Seventh Federal
Reserve District, and on financial and economic topics.
U.S. Corporate and Bank Insolvency Regimes: An Economic Comparison and Evaluation
Robert R. Bliss and George G. Kaufman

WP-06-01

Redistribution, Taxes, and the Median Voter
Marco Bassetto and Jess Benhabib

WP-06-02

Identification of Search Models with Initial Condition Problems
Gadi Barlevy and H. N. Nagaraja

WP-06-03

Tax Riots
Marco Bassetto and Christopher Phelan

WP-06-04

The Tradeoff between Mortgage Prepayments and Tax-Deferred Retirement Savings
Gene Amromin, Jennifer Huang,and Clemens Sialm

WP-06-05

Why are safeguards needed in a trade agreement?
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-06-06

Taxation, Entrepreneurship, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-06-07

A New Social Compact: How University Engagement Can Fuel Innovation
Laura Melle, Larry Isaak, and Richard Mattoon

WP-06-08

Mergers and Risk
Craig H. Furfine and Richard J. Rosen

WP-06-09

Two Flaws in Business Cycle Accounting
Lawrence J. Christiano and Joshua M. Davis

WP-06-10

Do Consumers Choose the Right Credit Contracts?
Sumit Agarwal, Souphala Chomsisengphet, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles

WP-06-11

Chronicles of a Deflation Unforetold
François R. Velde

WP-06-12

Female Offenders Use of Social Welfare Programs Before and After Jail and Prison:
Does Prison Cause Welfare Dependency?
Kristin F. Butcher and Robert J. LaLonde
Eat or Be Eaten: A Theory of Mergers and Firm Size
Gary Gorton, Matthias Kahl, and Richard Rosen

WP-06-13

WP-06-14

1

Working Paper Series (continued)
Do Bonds Span Volatility Risk in the U.S. Treasury Market?
A Specification Test for Affine Term Structure Models
Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

WP-06-15

Transforming Payment Choices by Doubling Fees on the Illinois Tollway
Gene Amromin, Carrie Jankowski, and Richard D. Porter

WP-06-16

How Did the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut Affect Stock Prices?
Gene Amromin, Paul Harrison, and Steven Sharpe

WP-06-17

Will Writing and Bequest Motives: Early 20th Century Irish Evidence
Leslie McGranahan

WP-06-18

How Professional Forecasters View Shocks to GDP
Spencer D. Krane

WP-06-19

Evolving Agglomeration in the U.S. auto supplier industry
Thomas Klier and Daniel P. McMillen

WP-06-20

Mortality, Mass-Layoffs, and Career Outcomes: An Analysis using Administrative Data
Daniel Sullivan and Till von Wachter

WP-06-21

The Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures:
Tying One’s Hand through the WTO.
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-06-22

How Did Schooling Laws Improve Long-Term Health and Lower Mortality?
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-06-23

Manufacturing Plants’ Use of Temporary Workers: An Analysis Using Census Micro Data
Yukako Ono and Daniel Sullivan

WP-06-24

What Can We Learn about Financial Access from U.S. Immigrants?
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-06-25

Bank Imputed Interest Rates: Unbiased Estimates of Offered Rates?
Evren Ors and Tara Rice

WP-06-26

Welfare Implications of the Transition to High Household Debt
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-06-27

Last-In First-Out Oligopoly Dynamics
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-06-28

Oligopoly Dynamics with Barriers to Entry
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-06-29

Risk Taking and the Quality of Informal Insurance: Gambling and Remittances in Thailand
Douglas L. Miller and Anna L. Paulson

WP-07-01

2

Working Paper Series (continued)
Fast Micro and Slow Macro: Can Aggregation Explain the Persistence of Inflation?
Filippo Altissimo, Benoît Mojon, and Paolo Zaffaroni

WP-07-02

Assessing a Decade of Interstate Bank Branching
Christian Johnson and Tara Rice

WP-07-03

Debit Card and Cash Usage: A Cross-Country Analysis
Gene Amromin and Sujit Chakravorti

WP-07-04

The Age of Reason: Financial Decisions Over the Lifecycle
Sumit Agarwal, John C. Driscoll, Xavier Gabaix, and David Laibson

WP-07-05

Information Acquisition in Financial Markets: a Correction
Gadi Barlevy and Pietro Veronesi

WP-07-06

Monetary Policy, Output Composition and the Great Moderation
Benoît Mojon

WP-07-07

Estate Taxation, Entrepreneurship, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-07-08

Conflict of Interest and Certification in the U.S. IPO Market
Luca Benzoni and Carola Schenone

WP-07-09

The Reaction of Consumer Spending and Debt to Tax Rebates –
Evidence from Consumer Credit Data
Sumit Agarwal, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles

WP-07-10

Portfolio Choice over the Life-Cycle when the Stock and Labor Markets are Cointegrated
Luca Benzoni, Pierre Collin-Dufresne, and Robert S. Goldstein

WP-07-11

Nonparametric Analysis of Intergenerational Income Mobility
with Application to the United States
Debopam Bhattacharya and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-07-12

How the Credit Channel Works: Differentiating the Bank Lending Channel
and the Balance Sheet Channel
Lamont K. Black and Richard J. Rosen

WP-07-13

Labor Market Transitions and Self-Employment
Ellen R. Rissman

WP-07-14

First-Time Home Buyers and Residential Investment Volatility
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Martin Gervais

WP-07-15

Establishments Dynamics and Matching Frictions in Classical Competitive Equilibrium
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-07-16

Technology’s Edge: The Educational Benefits of Computer-Aided Instruction
Lisa Barrow, Lisa Markman, and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP-07-17

3

Working Paper Series (continued)
The Widow’s Offering: Inheritance, Family Structure, and the Charitable Gifts of Women
Leslie McGranahan
Demand Volatility and the Lag between the Growth of Temporary
and Permanent Employment
Sainan Jin, Yukako Ono, and Qinghua Zhang

WP-07-18

WP-07-19

A Conversation with 590 Nascent Entrepreneurs
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-07-20

Cyclical Dumping and US Antidumping Protection: 1980-2001
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-07-21

Health Capital and the Prenatal Environment:
The Effect of Maternal Fasting During Pregnancy
Douglas Almond and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-07-22

The Spending and Debt Response to Minimum Wage Hikes
Daniel Aaronson, Sumit Agarwal, and Eric French

WP-07-23

The Impact of Mexican Immigrants on U.S. Wage Structure
Maude Toussaint-Comeau

WP-07-24

A Leverage-based Model of Speculative Bubbles
Gadi Barlevy

WP-08-01

Displacement, Asymmetric Information and Heterogeneous Human Capital
Luojia Hu and Christopher Taber

WP-08-02

BankCaR (Bank Capital-at-Risk): A credit risk model for US commercial bank charge-offs
Jon Frye and Eduard Pelz

WP-08-03

Bank Lending, Financing Constraints and SME Investment
Santiago Carbó-Valverde, Francisco Rodríguez-Fernández, and Gregory F. Udell

WP-08-04

Global Inflation
Matteo Ciccarelli and Benoît Mojon

WP-08-05

Scale and the Origins of Structural Change
Francisco J. Buera and Joseph P. Kaboski

WP-08-06

Inventories, Lumpy Trade, and Large Devaluations
George Alessandria, Joseph P. Kaboski, and Virgiliu Midrigan

WP-08-07

School Vouchers and Student Achievement: Recent Evidence, Remaining Questions
Cecilia Elena Rouse and Lisa Barrow

WP-08-08

4

Working Paper Series (continued)
Does It Pay to Read Your Junk Mail? Evidence of the Effect of Advertising on
Home Equity Credit Choices
Sumit Agarwal and Brent W. Ambrose

WP-08-09

The Choice between Arm’s-Length and Relationship Debt: Evidence from eLoans
Sumit Agarwal and Robert Hauswald

WP-08-10

Consumer Choice and Merchant Acceptance of Payment Media
Wilko Bolt and Sujit Chakravorti

WP-08-11

Investment Shocks and Business Cycles
Alejandro Justiniano, Giorgio E. Primiceri, and Andrea Tambalotti

WP-08-12

New Vehicle Characteristics and the Cost of the
Corporate Average Fuel Economy Standard
Thomas Klier and Joshua Linn

WP-08-13

Realized Volatility
Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

WP-08-14

Revenue Bubbles and Structural Deficits: What’s a state to do?
Richard Mattoon and Leslie McGranahan

WP-08-15

The role of lenders in the home price boom
Richard J. Rosen

WP-08-16

Bank Crises and Investor Confidence
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-08-17

Life Expectancy and Old Age Savings
Mariacristina De Nardi, Eric French, and John Bailey Jones

WP-08-18

Remittance Behavior among New U.S. Immigrants
Katherine Meckel

WP-08-19

Birth Cohort and the Black-White Achievement Gap:
The Roles of Access and Health Soon After Birth
Kenneth Y. Chay, Jonathan Guryan, and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-08-20

Public Investment and Budget Rules for State vs. Local Governments
Marco Bassetto

WP-08-21

Why Has Home Ownership Fallen Among the Young?
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Martin Gervais

WP-09-01

Why do the Elderly Save? The Role of Medical Expenses
Mariacristina De Nardi, Eric French, and John Bailey Jones

WP-09-02

Using Stock Returns to Identify Government Spending Shocks
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Ryan Peters

WP-09-03

5

Working Paper Series (continued)
Stochastic Volatility
Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

WP-09-04

The Effect of Disability Insurance Receipt on Labor Supply
Eric French and Jae Song

WP-09-05

CEO Overconfidence and Dividend Policy
Sanjay Deshmukh, Anand M. Goel, and Keith M. Howe

WP-09-06

Do Financial Counseling Mandates Improve Mortgage Choice and Performance?
Evidence from a Legislative Experiment
Sumit Agarwal,Gene Amromin, Itzhak Ben-David, Souphala Chomsisengphet,
and Douglas D. Evanoff

WP-09-07

6