View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Finance as a Barrier to Entry: Bank
Competition and Industry Structure in
Local U.S. Markets
Nicola Cetorelli and Philip E. Strahan

WP 2004-04

FINANCE AS A BARRIER TO ENTRY:
BANK COMPETITION AND INDUSTRY STRUCTURE IN LOCAL U.S.
MARKETS*
Nicola Cetorelli
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
Wharton Financial Institutions Center &
University of California, Davis

&
Philip E. Strahan
Boston College,
Wharton Financial Institutions Center &
NBER
November 10, 2003

Abstract
This paper tests how competition in local U.S. banking markets affects the market structure of
non-financial sectors. Theory offers competing hypotheses about how competition ought to
influence firm entry and access to bank credit by mature firms. The empirical evidence,
however, strongly supports the idea that in markets with concentrated banking, potential entrants
face greater difficulty gaining access to credit than in markets where banking is more
competitive.
JEL Classification Codes: L2, G2, G3

*

The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago or the Federal Reserve System. We thank seminar participants at Boston College, the Federal Reserve
Banks of Chicago and New York, The Ente Einaudi of Rome, Italy and Wesleyan University.
Page 1 of 42

I. Introduction
Economic research has focused intensely in recent years on the role played by financial
markets for real economic activity. Based on ideas tracing back at least to Schumpeter (1912),
and inspired by the early contributions of Goldsmith (1969), Gurley and Shaw (1955), and
McKinnon (1973), the work of King and Levine (1993 a,b), Demirguc-Kunt and Maksimovic
(1998), Levine and Zervos (1998), Rajan and Zingales (1998), Levine, Loayza and Beck (2000),
among others, has provided robust empirical evidence that broader, deeper financial markets are
strongly associated, causally, with better prospects for future economic growth.
Having established this basic finding, the research effort is now focused on the analysis
of the mechanisms through which finance affects real economic activity. What are the specific
characteristics of financial markets that seem to affect firms and industries in non-financial
sectors of production? For example, does it matter whether banks are privately or government
owned (La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes and Shleifer, 2001), or whether there is higher or lower
protection for financial contracts (Levine, 1999), or whether banks are in a more or less
competitive environment (Jayaratne and Strahan, 1996, Cetorelli and Gambera, 2001)? And,
what specific characteristics of firms and industries are especially affected by finance so that it
eventually translates into higher economic activity?
This paper contributes to this line of research by investigating the role of well-defined
characteristics of banking markets on equally well-defined industry characteristics in production
sectors. More precisely, we investigate the impact of bank concentration and bank deregulation
on measures of industry structure in non-financial sectors. We ask whether concentration of

Page 2 of 42

market power in banking has an effect on the number of firms in a given sector, on the average
size of existing firms in a sector, and on the overall firm size distribution within a sector.
Using data on U.S. local markets for banking and non-financial sectors, we find that more
vigorous banking competition – that is, lower concentration and looser restrictions on
geographical expansion -- is associated with more firms in operation and with a smaller average
firm size. In fact, the whole firm-size distribution shifts toward the origin as our measures of
banking competition increase. Because we exploit data at the industry level, we are able to
control for alternative (omitted) variables that may drive market structure both within and
outside banking by exploiting differential reliance on bank finance across industrial sectors.
Whether bank competition is “good or bad” for economic activity has been and continues
to be a lively topic of research and policy analysis.1 In addition to the conventional argument
that concentration of market power in banking means lower equilibrium amounts of credit, it has
also been claimed that banking market power is actually needed for banks in order to establish
valuable lending relationships.2 Hence, whether more or less competition in banking is socially
desirable is still under discussion. This paper thus contributes to expand our understanding of
the economic role of bank concentration and competition.
The number of competitors in a sector, the average firm size and the composition
between small and large firms are all important factors having a bearing on conduct and market
performance. They are therefore important determinants of the sector’s capital accumulation and
1

A conference titled “Bank Competition: Good or Bad?” was organized in 2000 by The Wharton School and the
Center for Financial Studies at Frankfurt University. More recently, in 2003, two conferences on the role of bank
concentration and competition have been organized by the World Bank and by the Cleveland Fed-JMCB.
2
There is also a heated debate (outside the scope of this paper) on the potential effect of banking market structure on
systemic risk and overall financial fragility. See, e.g. Hellman, Murdock, and Stiglitz (2000), Beck, Demirguc-Kunt
and Levine (2003) and Boyd, De Nicolo’ and Smith (2003).
Page 3 of 42

growth and consequently of the sector’s contribution to the overall level of economic activity.
Various related streams of literature have focused on determinants of product market competition
(e.g., Brander and Lewis (1986), Chevalier (1995), Kovenock and Phillips (1995, 1997),
Maksimovic (1988)), on firm size (e.g., Kumar, Rajan and Zingales (2001), Campbell and
Hopenhayn (2002)) and on firm-size distribution and more general industry dynamics (e.g.,
Lucas (1978), Jovanovic, (1982), Evans (1987), Hopenhayn (1992)). This paper relates to these
parallel lines of research and makes a contribution bridging them together.
Our evidence is consistent with that documented in several recent papers focusing on
banking concentration and competition policies across countries. Cetorelli (2001) provides
evidence of larger average firm size in countries with more concentrated banking. Along similar
lines, Cetorelli (2003a) finds that enhanced bank competition following passage of the Second
European Banking Directive brought a reduction in average firm size. Matching data on job
creation and destruction in US manufacturing sectors with banking data across US markets,
Cetorelli (2003b) shows that more bank concentration implies less entry and thriving of younger
firms and also delayed exit of older firms. Again based on cross-country data, Beck, DemirgucKunt and Maksimovic (2003) find that higher bank concentration is associated with more
financing obstacles, especially for smaller firms. In contrast, Bonaccorsi and Dell’Arriccia
(forthcoming) find that concentration in banking reduces entry rates for Italian firms in industries
with relatively opaque assets (i.e. few intangible assets) relative to entry in industries with less
asset opacity.
Our study is an important addition to this literature because we are able to measure
banking structure at the local level rather than at the country level. Thus, our data offer a distinct

Page 4 of 42

advantage because much of the research on bank market power suggests that the relevant
geographical market for banking services, especially for small firms or potential entrepreneurs, is
local (see, for example, Berger, Demsetz and Strahan, 1999). Moreover, this is the first paper
that explores not only how average firm size responds to banking competition, but how the
whole size distribution responds. By doing so, we are able to test more directly whether more or
less bank competition is beneficial for all firms in a sector, or whether instead the effect may be
different for firms in distinct size classes.
In the remainder of the paper we first flesh out the theoretical links between banking
concentration and industrial structure in order to motivate our empirical tests (Section II). In
Section III, we present the data set and the main variables used in the analysis. Section IV
documents the empirical results, and Section V concludes.

II. Estimation Strategy
How does bank competition affect the market structure of non-financial industries? As
pointed out in Cetorelli (2001), several countervailing forces are potentially in play. The first
force emphasizes that lending to opaque firms requires the bank and the borrower to forge a
long-term relationship. Information gained over the course of time by the bank can be used to
make value-enhancing credit decisions (i.e. expand credit to “winners” and restrict credit to
“losers”). Banks can sustain the cost of starting a relationship with unknown, risky
entrepreneurs, however, only if market power allows them to recoup the cost at later stages if

Page 5 of 42

such entrants turn out to be successful (Petersen and Rajan, 1995).3 To the extent that it
forecloses the opportunity to extract profits from successful relationships, vigorous competition
may mitigate banks’ willingness to invest in relationships at all. This force, applied to our case,
suggests that banks with market power should guarantee more industry entry than competitive
banks would. Consequently, and ceteris paribus, one should expect to find more firms in an
industry, a lower average firm size, and a larger prevalence of small rather than large firms
where banks have more market power.
Two countervailing forces suggest that market power may both dampen entry and reduce
the relative importance of smaller firms. First, bank market power may reduce credit availability
generally. This standard channel, whereby increased concentration in banking leads to less
credit supply and higher loan prices, justifies antitrust enforcement. While less credit hurts all
firms, smaller firms and potential entrants are likely to be more reliant on bank credit than larger
and better established firms. Thus, these smaller firms may be harmed more by reduced credit
supply than larger firms.
In addition to this standard channel, banks with market power may tend to favor their
established borrowers over new borrowers. The value of a bank’s current lending relationships
will depend on the incumbent borrowers’ future profitability, which in turn depends on
prospective entry and growth of new competitors. A bank’s incentive to support the profitability
of its older clients could thus restrain its willingness to extend credit to potential industry
entrants (or emerging small firms). In recent papers, Spagnolo (2000) and Cestone and White
(forthcoming) have presented theoretical frameworks in which existing lending relationships do
3

Another solution is for the lender to hold an equity, or equity-like, claim against the establishment, as is commonly

Page 6 of 42

indeed affect the behavior of lenders vis-à-vis potential new borrowers.4 The less competitive
the conditions in the credit market, the lower the incentive for lenders to finance newcomers.
Hence, banking concentration (as well as regulatory impediments to competition) can represent a
form of financial barrier to entry in product markets. Banking market power may lead to fewer
firms, a larger average firm size, and a higher proportion of large firms in markets where banks
have more market power.
These ideas suggest that bank concentration and competition play a key role in
determining industrial structure, particularly if banks choose to privilege their older clients rather
than potential new entrants in the same industries, or the other way around. Indeed, this latter
conjecture is in large measure about competition for funding between industry incumbents and
newer entrants. Consequently, it may be the case that bank competition is good for some firms
but it is bad for other firms within the same sector.
The difficulty in empirical implementation is that there may be common factors that drive
the structure of both banking and industrial sectors that are difficult to measure and thus control
in a regression. For industry-specific technological reasons, however, sectors differ in their
dependence on external sources of finance (Rajan and Zingales, 1998). Our empirical strategy
exploits these differences. Firms in sectors more dependent on bank finance ought to be affected
more by variation (both across time and across states) in banking competition. Related to the
specifics of our regressions, we emphasize an interaction term between bank dependence

observed in the venture capital industry.
4
Also related are the contributions of Battacharya and Chiesa (1995) and Helmann and Da Rin (2002).

Page 7 of 42

(described below) and several measures of banking competition. That is, we estimate models
fitting into the following general structure:
Ys,j,t = β (Bank Dependence)j(Banking Competition)s,t + Control Variables + Fixed Effects + es,j,t (1),

where the unit of observation varies across states (s), industries(j) and time(t).
In estimating equation (1), we use several measures of industry structure (Ys,j,t) and
several measures of banking competition (described below). Moreover, because our dataset
varies across three dimensions, we are able to control for local demand conditions (by
controlling for state-specific, time-varying fixed effects), as well as industry-specific
technological trends (by including industry-specific, time-varying fixed effects). By exploiting
differences in bank dependence across industries, we can also effectively control for trends in
structure that are specific to the local area (and common to both banks and industrial sectors) by
focusing on the interaction effect (β).5 This identification strategy minimizes the risk that our
results will be driven by either reverse causality (changes in industry structure driving changes in
banking structure), or by an omitted factor (one that drives both banking structure and the
structure of non-financial businesses). Finally, because we have data over a long span of time,
we can exploit policy innovations that relaxed restrictions on banks’ ability to expand both
within and across state lines that occurred during our sample period (again, described below).

III. Variable Definitions and Data Sources

5

This identification strategy was first advocated by Rajan and Zingales (1998) in linking predetermined measures of
financial depth to cross-country growth rates. Specifically, they emphasize that because financial depth has a
greater correlation with future growth for financially dependent sectors than for other sectors, the correlation reflects
a causal chain running from finance to growth rather than the other way around.
Page 8 of 42

Our panel data starts in 1977, the beginning of the period of dramatic state-level
deregulation. We end the sample in 1994, when deregulation of restrictions on banks’ ability to
expand across local markets was completed with passage of the Riegle-Neal Interstate Banking
and Branching Efficiency Act. After 1994, it becomes increasingly less plausible to view
markets in banking as local, both because of the completion of deregulation and because the
advent of new technologies in bank lending began allowing banks to lend to borrowers not
physically close to their bank. For example, Petersen and Rajan (2002) show that banks during
the 1990s are much more likely to lend over long geographic distances than they were in the
1970s. Also, banks began branching across state lines in 1995, making it impossible to construct
measures of bank size and banking productivity at the state level after that point.6
Constructing an Instrument for Bank Dependence
As we discussed in the previous section, the effects of banking competition on industry
structure ought to depend on the relative bank dependence of firms in an industry. The trick
empirically is to construct a measure of bank dependence that reflects demand for bank finance,
rather than one that confounds demand-side effects with variation in the availability of credit
supply from banks.7 We construct an instrument for bank dependence using information from
Compustat, and justify that choice by documenting its high correlation with small firms’ actual
use of bank (and other intermediary) funds.
Table 1 reports three measures of external financial dependence. The first two are based

6

For example, NationsBank consolidated banks from several other states into its primary North Carolina bank
(NationBank NC N.A.), leading to an increase of this bank’s assets from $31 billion in 1994 to $79 billion in 1995.
7

Variation in bank credit supply introduces noise (measurement error) into the actual use by small firms of bank
finance. Moreover, the extent of that noise will be greater for firms in industries that are more bank dependent.
Page 9 of 42

on Compustat firms, and the third comes from the 1998 Survey of Small Business Finance. Our
procedure for the first two measures follows closely the one described in Rajan and Zingales
(1998). Our key identifying assumption, as in Rajan and Zingales, is that the use of finance by
Compustat firms will allow us to observe their demand for external funds. These firms are large
and well established, with access to well-developed U.S. securities markets. Hence, there is little
danger that observed financial policy will be skewed by constraints on the supply side.
We begin by taking all of the Compustat firms between 1980 and 1997 and define any
firm that was on Compustat for more than 10 years as “mature”, and any firm in Compustat for
10 years or less as “young”. Next, we sum across all years each firm’s total capital expenditures
(Compustat item #128) minus cash flow from operations (item #110) net of changes in
inventories, account receivable and accounts payable.8 This sum equals the total external funds
needed to finance the firm’s investments. If the total is negative, it means the firm had free cash
flow available for disbursement to shareholders or to pay down debt; otherwise, the firm needed
to raise additional capital to finance its investment. We then divide this free cash flow figure by
total capital expenditure. After constructing this ratio for each firm, we use the median value for
all firms in each 2-digit SIC category.9
Panel A of Table 1 reports this measure of external financial dependence for both the
mature and the young Compustat firms. The figures show, as expected, that the mature firms
have a lower need for external finance than the younger firms. For example, the median value
for the mature firms is exactly zero, compared to 0.41 for young firms. Looking across sectors,
8

These items are only defined for cash flow statements with codes 1, 2 or 3. For format code 7, we use the sum of
items #123, 125, 126, 106, 213 and 217.

Page 10 of 42

we find that leather and leather products, tobacco manufactures and apparel have the lowest need
for external funds as mature firms, whereas electronic equipment and instruments and related
products exhibit the highest need for external finance. In contrast, all of the “young” firms are
using external funds.
For each 2-digit SIC manufacturing sector, we also construct the share of small firms’
assets financed with debt (loans, capital leases and lines of credit) from financial institutions
(“loans”) for the median firm (Table 1, column 3). These loans are supplied mainly by
commercial banks (70% of the surveyed firms use banks for credit), but they also include some
funds from other depository institutions (thrifts, credit unions) as well as unregulated finance
companies (Bitler, Robb and Wolken, 2001). This variable represents the actual use of bank
finance by small firms, as a share of their balance sheet.10 The data for the loans-to-asset ratio
are taken from the 1998 Survey of Small Business Finance. This survey was conducted by the
Federal Reserve and covers a sample of 3,561 small firms with fewer than 500 employees. The
sample was designed to be nationally representative, but was structured to ensure representation
across firm-size categories, location, and race of the owner.
Panel B of Table 1 reports the correlation between the three measures of financial
dependence. External financial dependence across industries for mature Compustat firms
exhibits a high correlation with the loans-to-assets ratios for small firms (ρ=0.51). This high
correlation suggests that financial dependence for mature Compustat firms makes a powerful
instrument for small firms’ demand for bank credit. In contrast, there is no correlation between
9

Rajan and Zingales also use a somewhat shorter sample from Compustat to construct their external dependence
measures.

Page 11 of 42

the use of external funds by young Compustat firms and the loan-assets ratio for small
businesses. These young firms have recently gone public, presumably because they have a
(temporarily) high demand for funds due to their strong growth and investment opportunities.
Thus, the measured “external dependence” for the young firms will not reflect financing
demands, either of typical start-ups and other small firms, or of well-established and stable firms.
In our main set of specifications, we use an indicator for external dependence for the mature
Compustat firms (equal to one if the use of external funds positive) as our instrument for an
industry’s bank dependence. For robustness, we report results using observed financial
dependence for mature Compustat firms (rather than a zero-one indicator variable) and results
using the actual loans-to-assets ratio for small firms.
Competition in the Local Banking Market
We focus on several measures of competition in the local banking industry. Our first two
measures exploit policy innovations. Restrictions on bank expansion across geographical
boundaries in the United States date back to the nineteenth century. Although there was some
deregulation of branching restrictions in the 1930s, most states either prohibited branching
altogether (the “unit banking” states) or limited branching until the 1970s, when only twelve
states allowed unrestricted statewide branching. Between 1970 and 1994, however, 38 states
deregulated their restrictions on branching (see Jayaratne and Strahan, 1996, Kroszner and
Strahan, 1999 and Stiroh and Strahan, forthcoming).
In addition to facing restrictions on in-state branching, the Douglas Amendment to the
1956 Bank Holding Company Act prohibited a bank holding company from acquiring banks
10

The Survey of Small Business Finance only reports data for a single year, hence balance sheet measures are more

Page 12 of 42

outside the state where it was headquartered unless the target bank’s state permitted such
acquisitions. Since no state allowed such transactions in 1956, the amendment effectively barred
interstate banking organizations. Starting in the earlier 1980s, many states began to enter
regional or national reciprocal arrangements whereby their banks could be bought by any other
state in the arrangement. This history presents us with a convenient way to test how industry
structure in non-financial sectors has been affected by the increased competition (real and
potential) in banking that followed state-level deregulation.11
We capture the effects of each type of deregulation by including an indicator equal to one
after a state permits branching by means of merger and acquisition within its borders, and
another indicator equal to one after a state permits interstate banking (that is, after a state allows
bank holding companies in other states to buy their banks).12 The two types of deregulation are
somewhat distinct in their effects. Deregulation of restrictions on branching reduces entry
barriers into new markets and also enhances the corporate takeover market by making it easier
for banks to gain control over other bank’s assets. With full branching deregulation, a bank may
enter a new market, either by buying existing branches or by opening new branches. Also, the
cost of acquiring another bank is reduced because an acquiring bank may merge the target bank’s
operation into its existing franchise. By reducing entry barriers, branching deregulation
constrains banks’ ability to exploit market power. Interstate banking deregulation, however,
only affects who can own bank assets. Prior to deregulation, only bank holding companies
representative of financial policy than flow-based measures using capital expenditures and gross cash flow.
11
Deregulation of restrictions on bank expansion, both within and across states, has been shown to improve bank
efficiency, to enhance corporate control, and to limit market power. See Jayaratne and Strahan (1998).

Page 13 of 42

located within a state may buy banks chartered in that state, while, after deregulation, bank
holding companies operating in other states may do so.
In addition to looking at changes in competition induced by deregulation of the industry,
we also include a direct measure of local market concentration, equal to the deposit HerfindahlHirschmann Index (HHI). The HHI is calculated as the deposit-weighted average of the HHI
indexes of the Metropolitan Statistical Areas (MSAs) in a state/year. The Herfindahl index for
each local market is defined as the sum of squared market shares, where market shares are based
on branch-level deposit data from the FDIC’s Summary of Deposits dataset.13 So, for example, if
a bank owned 10 branches within an MSA, this bank’s market share would equal the sum of all
of its deposits in those 10 branches, divided by the total deposits held in by all bank branches
within that market. For a market with a single bank owning all of the branches, the HHI would
equal one, whereas in a perfectly atomistic market the HHI would approach zero.
Industrial Structure
Establishment counts and number of workers per establishment are available at a
disaggregated level on an annual basis from the County Business Patterns, which is an annual
survey by the Census Bureau. These data provide the best way to consider industry structure
over a long span of time at a disaggregated level. Moving to a more finely disaggregated level,
either by industry SIC code or by locality, creates substantial difficulties with missing values, so

12

Most states first permit banks to branch by buying existing branches in new markets or by purchasing whole
banks and then creating branches out of the purchased bank’s offices. Then, states typically open up their markets to
unrestricted branching in which banks may open new branches anywhere in the state.
13
The deposit HHI is the standard tool used in antitrust oversight of bank mergers. Local markets (usually MSAs or
non-MSA counties) with HHI below 1800 are deemed to be served by enough banks to assume that conditions are
competitive. For localities with HHI above 1800, antitrust concerns by the Federal Reserve and the Department of
Justice are sometimes raised. See Berger, Demsetz and Strahan (1999) for an overview of bank mergers and
antitrust policy.
Page 14 of 42

we have decided to focus on the 2-digit level of aggregation by industry and the state level for
geography. We focus on just industries within the manufacturing sector. From this data set, we
compute the total number of establishments in an industry/state/year (in logs), and the average
establishment size (log of workers per establishment). As shown in Table 2, there are, on
average, 0.07 establishments per capita, and the average establishment has 69 workers.
Before moving forward, it is worth noting that our data are based on employment at
establishments rather than at firms. An establishment is an economic unit where production
occurs, such as a plant, a factory, or a restaurant that employs people. So, there is some
measurement error in our dependent variable induced by the fact that large firms often own many
establishments. Nevertheless, we think that the number of new establishments ought to be highly
correlated with the economic quantity that we are trying to observe. Early research has shown,
for example that the rate of creation of new businesses is correlated with the share of new
establishments in a local economy (Black & Strahan, 2002). The existence of a close correlation
between the number of establishments and the number of firms is also documented in Cetorelli
(2001) for a cross-section of countries.
To characterize the whole distribution of establishment sizes, we construct the share of
establishments in an industry, state and year in each of four categories: establishments with
fewer than five employees, establishments with fewer than 20 employees, establishments with
fewer than 100 employees and establishments with fewer than 250 employees. Unconditionally,
31 percent of establishments are in the smallest size category, while 94 percent of establishments
have fewer than 250 establishments (Table 2).
Chart 1 presents a picture of the cumulative distribution of establishments across these

Page 15 of 42

four size categories, where each probability is constructed using the simple mean across
industries, states and time during a “pre-deregulatory” period (1977-82) and a “postderegulatory” period (1990-94).14 The figure shows a clear migration of the size distribution
toward the smaller firms, with a five percentage point increase in the share of establishments
with fewer than five employees (29% to 34%), a five percentage point increase in the share of
establishments with fewer than 20 employees (60% to 65%), a three point increase in the share
with fewer than 100 employees (85% to 88%), and a two point increase for establishments with
under 250 employees. Given the regulatory changes that enhanced competition during the
1980s, the movement of the distribution is, on its face, consistent with the idea that more
vigorous banking competition helps the prospects of small firms and potential entrants. At the
same time, some of the long-run trends are likely to be the result, in part, of common factors (e.g.
technology) affecting market structure in both banking and non-financial sectors.
Recognizing the importance of these other factors, our identification strategy is to
emphasize the differential effects of bank competition across bank dependent and non-dependent
sectors. By differencing out the effect of bank competition in the non-dependent sectors, we can
construct a simple “difference-in-differences” estimate of the effect of changes in bank
competition on industry structure. Table 3 illustrates the intuition behind this strategy using the
raw data for average establishment size and for a single slice the cumulative size distribution (the
fraction of establishments with less than 100 employees).15 We have averaged the data across
four clusters, by sectors with high and low financial dependence, and either by markets/years
14

State-level moves toward removal of restrictions on branching and interstate banking were largely completed by
1990, although completion of the deregulation occurred in 1994, with passage of the Interstate Banking and
Branching Efficiency Act.

Page 16 of 42

with high and low bank concentration or with tight and relaxed bank regulation.
Starting with the first panel, rows one and two show that establishment size is higher
among sectors with high external dependence. Similarly, comparing columns one and two, size
is higher in un-concentrated markets. As mentioned above, these observed patterns may be the
result, respectively, of confounding industry or market factors. To understand the role of bank
competition, consistent with the theoretical priors illustrated earlier, we observe that in
concentrated banking markets the average establishment has 30 more employees in highdependence sectors than in low-dependence ones. This difference goes down to 21 employees in
un-concentrated markets. Hence, the data suggests that going from concentrated to unconcentrated banking markets, the difference in establishment size between high- and lowdependence sectors falls by about 33 percent (9/30). Similarly, the data in the second panel
suggests that when moving from a regulated to a deregulated period, the difference in
establishment size between high- and low-dependence sectors goes down by 12 employees, or
approximately by 35 percent. Both mean differences are statistically significant at the one
percent level of confidence.
Moving to the size distribution data, the third panel shows that the difference in the share
of establishments with fewer than 100 employees between high- and low-dependence sectors
increases by 3.2 percentage points, i.e. there is a relatively larger mass of smaller firms in high
dependence sectors in un-concentrated banking markets. The 3.2 percentage point increase is
about 60% of the original difference. The data in the fourth panel give no particular indication of
a differential effect of banking deregulation on the establishment size distribution, since the

15

For brevity we do not report data on number of establishments in this table.
Page 17 of 42

calculated mean difference is small and not statistically significant.
These simple mean comparisons illustrate the identification strategy and give a first
indication consistent with the conjecture that in the absence of competition banks may tend to
favor incumbents over potential new entrants in product markets.

IV. Regression Results
In presenting our regressions, we report three sets of results for each dependent variable.
The first set includes a state fixed effects (fixed across time and industry), and time-varying
industry effects (i.e. a dummy variable for each industry in each year, or 18 indicators per
industry). In these first specifications (column 1), we can identify the direct effect of the
measures of banking competition because these variables have both time variation and state
variation. In the second specification, we include industry fixed effects (fixed across time and
state) and time-varying state effects (i.e. 18 indicators per state), and in the third specification we
allow both the state and industry effects to vary across time, thereby absorbing state-specific
annual shocks and industry-specific annual shocks. In the latter two specifications, we can not
identify the direct effects of competition, since these do not vary across industries. Recall that
our identification strategy, however, is to focus on differences in the effects of banking on
industry structure for financial dependent sectors relative to less dependent sectors. Thus, in all
cases, the coefficients of interest are those in which the competition variables are interacted with
the external dependence indicator.
Control variables

Page 18 of 42

At the same time that banking has become more competitive, we have seen a marked
consolidation of the industry. A large number of research articles in recent years have raised the
concern that this decline in small banks may be having adverse consequences for small
borrowers.16 The theoretical motivation for this notion is that bank lending to some borrowers
depends on “soft” information; that is, information that can not be verified or communicated
credibly by the holder of that information to others. For example, an individual loan officer’s
personal knowledge of a borrower’s character or her propensity to pay back a loan despite
opportunities to shift costs onto the lender would be difficult to verify absent making the same
investment in knowing the borrower’s character made by the original loan officer. Stein (2002)
argues that smaller organizations can compensate workers more efficiently than large ones for
investing in such “soft” information, thereby giving smaller banks a comparative advantage in
making loans to small firms or to potential entrepreneurs. If scale economies in other aspects of
banking (e.g. collection of deposits, back office functions, etc.) are sufficiently important (and
scope economies tie these other functions to lending), then reductions in the presence of small
banks motivated by such scale economies could reduce the supply of capital to small and new
firms.

16

Although it is clear that small banks lend more of their assets to small establishments, the evidence that small
banks lend better or more efficiently to small establishments is mixed. For example, some papers find that lending
to small business increases when small banks are acquired, suggesting the increased scale increases a banks
willingness to lend, while others find declines in lending following mergers. See Keeton (1996,1997), Peek and
Rosengren (1996,1998), Strahan and Weston (1998), Craig and Santos (1997), Kolari and Zardkoohi (1997a,b),
Zardkoohi and Kolari (1997), Berger, Saunders, Scalise, and Udell (1998), Sapienza (1998), Berger, Demsetz and
Strahan (1999). More recently, studies have explored whether in small-bank-dominated markets small
establishments have better or worse access to credit. Again, results are mixed. See Jayaratne and Wolken (1999),
Black and Strahan (2002), and Berger, Miller, Petersen, Rajan, and Stein (2003) report evidence that large banks are
more likely to interact with small borrowers in impersonal ways (e.g. via the telephone and mail).
Page 19 of 42

We have also seen trends in banking toward greater use of information technologies to
make lending decisions. As banks increasingly substitute automated information technologies
(e.g. credit scores) for the judgment of human loan officers, firms which rely on less
quantifiable, “soft” information may find credit more difficult to attain. Again, since small and
new firms are least likely to be able to certify their quality with a long track record of audited
financial statements, the advent of information technology in banking could be harmful to them,
even if they reduce costs on average.
To control for the effects of consolidation, we include the share of assets held by banks
with assets under $100 million in the state in our regressions. For information technology, we
construct a measure of bank labor productivity by simply dividing the real value of total
operating income for all banks in a state-year (a broad-based measure of output that incorporates
off-balance sheet activity) by total full-time equivalent employees at all banks in the state-year.
In states where more output is produced by banks per worker, we infer that banks take more
advantage of information technologies such as credit scoring models.
In addition, we control for the overall share of employment in the state coming from the
industry in question. This variable controls for possible differences across states and time in the
importance of the industry to the overall state economy that may stem from exogenous factors
such as, for example, the availability of natural resources. In our first set of specifications we
control for these factors, although when we include state by year fixed effects, these coefficients
are not identified.
Table 4 reports results for the log of the number of establishments. We find a positive
effect of interstate banking reform, with a coefficient suggesting that opening up the banking

Page 20 of 42

industry to out-of-state entry leads to a 12 percent increase in the number of establishments
(columns 1 and 3; the effect in column 2 is about 8 percent). This large increase suggests that
there is significant entry of new firms after banking deregulation, which is consistent with Black
and Strahan (2002), who find that the number of new incorporations in a state increases by 6 to
11 percent following interstate banking reform. The effect of banking concentration is also
large, both statistically (t>4) and economically: a one standard deviation decrease in
concentration comes with a 3 percent increase in the number of establishments. This effect is
also similar in magnitude to the one reported for new incorporations in Black and Strahan
(2002).
For control variables, we find more establishments in industries with a larger share of
total state employment. In the first specification, we also find that the number of establishments
falls with the market share of small banks (consistent with Black and Strahan, 2002) and rises
with personal income growth. We do not find, however, any statistically significant effect of
bank labor productivity on the total number of establishments. These last three coefficients lose
identification in the models with time-varying industry effects because we have no variation
across industry: all industries in a given market face the same banking structure, the same level
of bank productivity and the same local economic conditions.
Table 5 reports a similar set of specifications with the log of average establishment size
(employees per establishment) as the dependent variable. These results are consistent with those
obtained for number of establishments, suggesting that average size falls as banking becomes
more competitive. Following branching deregulation, establishment size falls slightly (by 1.8
percent), although the coefficient is not statistically significant. Following interstate banking

Page 21 of 42

deregulation, establishment size falls more, by 5 to 10 percent, and the decline is statistically
significant at the one percent level. A standard-deviation decrease in concentration is associated
with a decrease in establishment size of a little more than 3 percent. Control variables suggest
that average establishment size increases with an industry’s total share of employment and with
economic growth in the state. Bank labor productivity appears negatively correlated with
establishment size.
Next, we report our results focusing on banking competition and the distribution of
establishment size in Tables 6-9. Each table corresponds to the share of establishments in a
given size bin. For example, Table 6 reports the logit of the share of establishments with fewer
than 5 employees, Table 7 the share with fewer than 20 employees, etc.17 The results suggest,
broadly, that increases in banking competition lead to increases in the importance of small firms
across all size categories. That is, the size distribution of establishments shifts to the left (toward
small establishments) as the banking industry becomes increasingly competitive. The results are
therefore consistent with the notion that market power in banking creates a barrier to entry (or
expansion) of relatively small firms.
In contrast to the average size results where interstate banking reform was very
important, competition’s effect on share of establishments in each size category is most
statistically robust for the deposit-based HHI, our measure of local-market banking
concentration. For example, we estimate a negative and significant coefficient on the interaction
between the HHI with the external dependence indicator across all four size categories and

17

Since the logit (log of the odds) is undefined at 0 or 1, we replace the share with 0.005; for cases where the share
was 1, we replace the share with 0.995. These changes do not affect our conclusions. The statistical significance of
our results remain when we use actual shares (rather than logits).
Page 22 of 42

across all three specifications of the fixed effects. The coefficient estimate is also stable across
all three approaches to modeling the fixed effects.
The results for the banking deregulation indicators, while consistent with the idea that
banking competition helps small firms, are much less robust statistically than the results on
concentration. We estimate a positive effect of deregulation of restrictions on bank branching
(interacted with external dependence) across all models and for all four size categories, but the
coefficient never achieves statistical significance at the five percent level. For deregulation of
interstate banking, we find a small negative effect for the smallest size category (under 5
employees) and a small positive effect for the next largest category (under 20). For
establishments with fewer than 100 or fewer than 250 employees, however, we estimate a
statistically significant positive coefficient on the interstate banking interaction variable,
suggesting that in states open to entry by out of state banks, there is a greater share of
establishments in the small (but not too small) category. This effect loses statistical significance,
however, when we leave out the industry-year fixed effects.
To understand the economic magnitude of these effects, we have also estimated the
models using the share of establishments in the various size bins, rather than the logit, which is
harder to interpret due to its non-linearity. According to these results (not reported), for
industries with above-median use of external finance, the share of establishments with fewer than
20 employees is 0.9 percentage points higher after branching deregulation than before, and 0.7
percentage points higher after interstate banking. For concentration, a one standard deviation
decline in banking concentration would raise the share of establishments with under 20
employees by 0.7 percentage points (again, focusing on the interaction; that is, the effect pertains

Page 23 of 42

to industries with greater-than-average using of external funds). For establishments with fewer
than 100 employees, interstate banking reform increases their share by 1.6 percentage points, and
a standard deviation decline in concentration increases their share by about 1.1 percentage
points. So, a “competitive” banking market – one with interstate banking and low banking
concentration – would have something like 2.7 percent more establishments with fewer than 100
employees, relative to an average market with about 86 percent of establishments in this category
(the unconditional mean). This effect of competition seems particularly large relative to the
increase in the share of establishments over the whole period of just three percentage points,
from 85% in the early years to 88% in the later years (recall Chart 1).
As anticipated earlier, for robustness we have also run regressions using observed financial
dependence for mature Compustat firms (rather than the zero-one indicator variable) and using
the actual loans-to-assets ratio for small firms. We present results for the most stringent model
specification only, the one with state-year and industry-year fixed effects. As indicated in Table
10 and 11, all the results presented in the paper are strongly confirmed using these two
alternative measures of external financial dependence.
As a final test, we considered whether regulatory change has altered the effects of
banking concentration on the firm-size distribution. Black and Strahan (2002) argue that after
states opened up their local banking markets to outside entry, the effects of concentration ought
to have been mitigated by the threat of entry. And, in fact, they find that the effect of
concentration on the rate of creation of new incorporations does fall significantly with
deregulation. We have run similar tests using our measure of the size distribution and the
number of establishments. Specifically, we add variables interacting the deregulation variables

Page 24 of 42

with our measure of bank concentration. In these regressions, we do estimate a generally
positive coefficient (six out of eight) on these interaction terms, suggesting that the effects of
concentration on the size distribution may be attenuated by regulatory reform, although the
coefficients are not statistically significant (not reported).

V. Conclusions
We have found that banking competition in local U.S. markets has been associated with a
greater number of establishments, a smaller average establishment size and a greater share of
small establishments across the whole size distribution. Theory does not paint a clear picture
about how competition in banking ought to affect the firm-size distribution, but the empirical
work does. Comparing industry structure across local markets within the U.S., or comparing
structure across a large number of countries (both developed and developing), one reaches the
same conclusion. Our empirical evidence is consistent with the idea that banks with market
power erect an important financial barrier to entry to the detrimant of the entrepreneurial sector
of the economy, perhaps in part to protect the profitability of their existing borrowers. The
evidence thus indicates that banking competition has a significant impact on important structural
characteristics of sectors of production. Moreover, it indicates that such impact is not uniform
across firms, but rather that depending on the degree of banking competition some firms will
benefits while others will lose. This is an important insight updating the conventional wisdom
that banking competition is either good or bad overall.
The policy implications associated with this issue are especially relevant. Banking market
structure is a traditional policy variable whose control regulators across countries and over time

Page 25 of 42

often attempt to influence, although sometimes in conflicting ways. For example, in the United
States bank mergers have sometimes been altered to avoid excessive concentration in local
markets. At the same time, however, until the 1980s many states protected their banks from
competition through branching and interstate banking restrictions. Similar restraints on
competition have been common elsewhere; for example, many countries continue to protect their
banks from foreign entry. One can well understand why political forces lead to tight restraints
on banking competition if both incumbent banks and incumbent firms benefit from the restraints.
In fact, Rajan and Zingales (2003) use historical evidence to argue very broadly that incumbent
firms often fought hardest to prevent financial openness, sometimes leading to long-term
declines in a country’s growth prospects.
The good news is that many of the political, legal and regulatory barriers to bank
expansion and competition have been dismantled. State-level restrictions were removed in the
1970s and 1980s in the United States, the E.U. is now open to cross-border banking, and foreign
banks have made great inroads into Latin America. Our results suggest that these changes will
help small and entrepreneurial firms gain access to credit from banks. It seems reasonable to
suppose (or at least to hope) that lower financial barriers to entry and greater entrpreneurship will
lead to faster growth.

Page 26 of 42

References
Bhattacharya, Sudipto and Gabriella Chiesa, 1995, “Proprietary Information, Financial
Intermediation, and Research Incentives”, Journal of Financial Intermediation, October 1995.
Beck, Thorsten, Asli Demirguc-Kunt and Vojislav Maksimovic, 2003, “Bank Competition,
Financing Obstacles and Access to Credit,” mimeo, January 2003.
Berger, Allen N., Rebecca S. Demsetz and Philip E. Strahan, 1999, “The Consolidation of the
Financial Services Industry: Cause, Consequences and Implications for the Future,” Journal of
Banking and Finance 23, 135-94.
Berger, Allen N., Nathan H, Miller, Mitchell A. Petersen, Raghuram G. Rajan and Jeremy C.
Stein, 2003, “Does Function Follow Organizational Form? Evidence from the Lending Practices
of Large and Small Banks,” Mimeo, March 2003.
Berger, Allen N., Anthony A. Saunders, Joseph K. Scalise, and Gregory F. Udell, 1998, “The
Effects of Bank Mergers and Acquisitions on Small Business Lending,” Journal of Financial
Economics 50.
Bitler, Marianne P., Alicia M. Robb, and John D. Wolken, 2001, “Financial Services Used by
Small Businesses: Evidence from the 1998 Survey of Small Business Finance,” Federal Reserve
Bulletin, 183-205.
Black, Sandra E. and Philip E. Strahan, 2002, “Entrepreneurship and Bank Credit Availability,”
Journal of Finance 57(6), 2807-33.
Bonaccorsi di Patti, Emilia and Giovanni Dell’Ariccia, forthcoming, “Bank Competition and
Firm Creation,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking.
Boyd, John H., Gianni De Nicolo, and Bruce Smith, 2003, “Crisis in Competitive versus
Monopolistic Banking Systems,” mimeo, March 10, 2003
Brander, James and Tracy Lewis, “Oligopoly and Financial Structure: The Limited Liability
Effect”, The American Economic Review, Vol. 76, No. 5. (Dec., 1986), pp. 956-970
Campbell, Jeffrey R., and Hugo A. Hopenhayn, 2002, “Market Size Matters,” mimeo.
Cetorelli, Nicola and Michele Gambera, 2001, “Bank Structure, Financial Dependence and
Growth: International Evidence from Industria Data,” Journal of Finance.
Cetorelli, Nicola, 2001, “Does Bank Concentration Lead to Concentration in Industrial Sectors?”
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago WP# 01-01, April 2001.

Page 27 of 42

Cetorelli, Nicola, 2003a, “Real Effects of Bank Concentration and Competition in Europe”
Cetorelli, Nicola, 2003b, “Life-Cycle Dynamics in Industrial Sectors. The Role of Banking
Market Structure”, Quarterly Review, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Forthcoming
Cestone, Giacinta and Lucy White, forthcoming, “Anti-Competitive Financial Contracting: The
Design of Financial Claims,” Journal of Finance.
Chevalier, Judith, 1995, “Capital Structure and Product Market Competition: Empirical
Evidence from the Supermarket Industry,” American Economic Review.
Craig, Ben R. and Joao A.C. dos Santos, 1997, “Banking Consolidation: Impact on Small
Business Lending,” working paper, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
Demirguc-Kunt, Asli and Vojislav Maksimovic, 1998, “Law, Finance and Firm Growth,”
Journal of Finance 53, 2107-37.
Evans, David S., 1987, “The Relationship Between Firm Growth, Size, and Age: Estimates for
100 Manufacturing Industries (in Competition in the Long Run)”, Journal of Industrial
Economics, Vol. 35, No. 4, pp. 567-581.
Goldsmith, Raymond, Financial Structure and Development, (New Haven: Yale University
Press, 1969).
Gurley, John G. and Edward S. Shaw, 1955, “Financial Aspects of Economic Development,”
American Economic Review, 45, 515-38.
Hellmann, Thomas and Marco Da Rin, 2002 , “Banks as Catalysts for Industrialization,” Journal
of Financial Intermediation, 11, 366-397.
Hellmann, Thomas, Kevin Murdock and Joseph Stiglitz, 2000, “Liberalization, Moral Hazard in
Banking and Prudential Regulation: Are Capital Requirements enough?” American Economic
Review, 2000, 90(1), 147-165.
Hopenhayn, Hugo A., 1992, “Entry, Exit, and Firm Dynamics in Long Run Equilibrium,”
Econometrica, Vol. 60, No. 5. (Sep., 1992), pp. 1127-1150.
Jayaratne, Jith and Philip E. Strahan, 1996, “The Finance-Growth Nexus: Evidence from Bank
Branch Deregulation,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 101, 639-70.
Jayaratne, Jith and Philip E. Strahan, 1998, “Entry Restrictions, Industry Evolution and Dynamic
Efficiency: Evidence from Commercial Banking,” Journal of Law and Economics 41, 239-74.

Page 28 of 42

Jayaratne, Jith and John D. Wolken, 1999, “How Important are Small Banks to Small Business
Lending? New Evidence from a Survey of Small Businesses,” Journal of Banking and Finance
23, 427-58.
Jovanovic, Boyan, 1982, “Selection and Evolution of Industry,” Econometrica, Vol. 50, No. 3.,
pp. 649-670.
Keeton, William R., “Do Bank Mergers Reduce Lending to Businesses and Farmers? New
Evidence from Tenth District States,” 1996, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Economic
Review 81 (3), 63-75.
Keeton, William R., 1997, “The Effects of Mergers on Farm and Business Lending at Small
Banks: New Evidence from Tenth District States,” working paper, Federal Reserve Bank of
Kansas City.
King, Robert and Ross Levine, 1993a, "Finance, Entrepreneurship and Growth," Journal of
Monetary Economics, 32, 513-542.
King, Robert and Ross Levine, 1993b, "Finance and Growth: Schumpeter Might Be Right,"
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108, 717-738.
Kolari, J., and A. Zardkoohi, 1997a, “The Impact of Structural Change in the Banking Industry
on Small Business Lending,” Report to the Small Business Administration.
Kolari, J., and A. Zardkoohi, A., 1997b, “Bank Acquisitions and Small Business Lending,”
working paper, Texas A&M University.
Kovenock and Phillips, 1995, “Capital Structure and Product Market Rivalry: How do we
Reconcile Theory and Evidence?” American Economic Review 85, 408-408.
Kroszner, Randall S. and Philip E. Strahan, 1999, “What Drives Deregulation? Economics and
Politics of the Relaxation of Bank Branching Restrictions,” Quarterly Journal of Economics
114(4), 1437-67.
Kumar, Krishna, Raghuram G. Rajan and Luigi Zingales, 2001, “What Determines Firm Size?”
NBER Working paper no. 7208.
Laporta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes and Andrei Shleifer, 2001, “Government
Ownership of Banks,” Journal of Finance.
Levine, Ross, 1999, “Law, Finance and Economic Growth”, Journal of Financial
Intermediation.

Page 29 of 42

Levine Ross, Norman Loayza, and Thorsten Beck, 2000, “Financial intermediation and growth:
Causality and Causes,” Journal Of Monetary Economics 46(1), 31-77.
Levine, Ross and Sara Zervos, 1998, “Stock Markets, Banks and Economic Growth,” American
Economic Review 88(3), 537-58.
Lucas, Robert E., 1978, “On the Size Distribution of Firms, Bell Journal of Economics 9(2), 50823.
Maksimovic, Vojislav, 1988, “Capital Structure in a Repeated Oligoploy,” Rand Journal of
Economics, 389-407.
McKinnon, Ronald, Money and Capital in Economic Development, (Washington, DC: Brookings
Institution, 1973).
Peek, Joe and Eric S. Rosengren, 1996, “Small Business Credit Availability: How Important is
the Size of the Lender?” In Financial System Design: The Case for Universal Banking, edited by
A. Saunders and I. Walter (Burr Ridge, IL, Irwin Publishing), 628-55.
Peek, Joe and Eric S. Rosengren, 1998, “Bank Consolidation and Small Business Lending: It=s
not Just Bank Size that Matters,” Journal of Banking and Finance 22.
Petersen, Mitchell A. and Raghuram G. Rajan, 1994, “The Benefits of Firm-Creditor
Relationships: Evidence from Small Business Data,” Journal of Finance 49, 3-37.
Petersen, Mitchell A. and Raghuram G. Rajan, 1995, “The Effect of Credit Market Competition
on Lending Relationships,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 110, 407-43.
Petersen, Mitchell A. and Raghuram G. Rajan, 2001, “Does Distance Still Matter? The
Informatation Revolution in Small Business Lending,” mimeo, March 2001.
Rajan, Raghuram G. and Luigi Zingales, 1998, “Financial Dependence and Growth,” American
Economic Review 88, 559-87.
Rajan, Raghuram G. and Luigi Zingales, 2003, Saving Capitalism from the Capitalists, Crown
Business Division of Random House.
Sapienza, Paola, 1998, “The Effects of Banking Mergers on Loan Contracts,” Northwestern
University working paper.
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1912. Theorie der Wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung. Leipzig: Dunker &
Humblot, [The Theory of Economic Development, translated by Redvers Opie. Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press, 1934.]

Page 30 of 42

Stiroh, Kevin and Philip E. Strahan, forthcoming, “Competitive Dynamics of Deregulation:
Evidence from U.S. Banking,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking.
Spagnolo, Giancarlo, 2000, “Debt as a (Credible) Collusive Device”, SSE Ec.&Fin. W.P. No.
243.
Strahan, Philip E. and James P. Weston, 1998, “Small Business Lending and the Changing
Structure of the Banking Industry,” Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 821-45.
Zardkoohi, A. and J. Kolari, 1997, “The Effect of Structural Changes in the U.S. Banking
Industry on Small Business Lending,” working paper, Texas A&M University.

Page 31 of 42

Share of Establishments

CHART 1
CDF for Establishments
100%
85% 88%

90%

93% 95%

80%
70%

60%

60%

65%

50%
40%
30%

29%

34%

20%
Under 5

Under 20

Under 100

Number of Employees
1977-1982

1990-1994

Under 250

Table 1
External Financial Dependence for Manufacturing Sectors
External
External
Dependence
Median
Dependence
for Young
Loans/Assets
for Mature
for 1998 SSBF
Compustat
Compustat
Panel A: Medians by Industry Sector
Firms
Firms
Firms
(2-digit SIC)
Leather and leather products (31)
-0.96
0.14
0.04
Tobacco manufactures (21)
-0.92
0.94
N/A
Apparel and other textiles (23)
-0.61
0.72
0.13
Food and kindred products (20)
-0.24
0.48
0.12
Fabricated metal products (34)
-0.24
0.35
0.27
Furniture and fixtures (25)
-0.23
0.22
0.36
Stone, clay, glass, and concrete products (32)
-0.20
0.40
0.31
Miscellaneous manufacturing (39)
-0.20
0.91
0.28
Printing and publishing (27)
-0.07
0.16
0.33
Instruments and related products (38)
-0.04
1.82
0.29
Transportation equipment (37)
0.01
0.35
0.06
Industrial machinery and equipment (35)
0.01
0.97
0.21
Primary metal industries (33)
0.03
0.34
0.31
Lumber and wood products (24)
0.04
0.42
0.49
Rubber and plastic products (30)
0.04
0.23
0.30
Paper and allied products (26)
0.06
0.21
0.37
Petroleum and coal products (29)
0.09
0.68
0.60
Textile mill products (22)
0.10
0.23
0.47
Electrical and electronic equipment (36)
0.22
0.83
0.14
Chemicals and allied products (28)
0.28
3.04
0.33
0
0.41
0.30
Median

Panel B: Correlation Matrix
External Dependence, Mature Firms
External Dependence, Young Firms
Loans/Assets Small Firms

External
Dependence,
Mature Firms
1

External
Dependence,
Young Firms
0.24
1

Loans/Assets
Small Firms
0.51
0.03
1

External dependence equals the proportion of capital expenditures financed with external funds. A negative value
indicates that firms have free cash flow, whereas a positive value indicates firms must issue debt or equity to finance
their investment. The figures represent the median value for Compustat firms in each industry sector over the 1980
to 1997 period. Mature firms are those that have been on Compustat for 10 years or more; all other firms are
defined as young. The rows are sorted by the external finance measure for mature firms, which is our baseline
measure of an industry’s long-term financing needs.

Page 32 of 42

Table 2
Summary Statistics
Establishments Per Capita

Mean
0.07

Standard
Deviation
0.09

Share of Establishments with < 5 Employees

0.31

0.16

Share of Establishments with <20 Employees

0.62

0.19

Share of Establishments with <100 Employees

0.86

0.13

Share of Establishments with <250 Employees

0.94

0.08

Average Establishment Size (# of Employees)

69

83

HHI (Sum of squared local-market deposit share)

0.19

0.07

Post Branching Deregulation Indicator

0.60

-

Post Interstate Banking Deregulation Indicator

0.45

-

Small Bank Share (“Small” means < $100 million in assets, 1994 $s)

0.14

0.13

$221,000

74,000

Operating Income / FTE (1994 $s)

Page 33 of 42

Table 3
Comparison of Means for Competitive and Non-competitive Banking Markets
Share of Establishments with Under 100 Employees
Un-concentrated Banking
Markets
High External Dependence
0.848
Low External Dependence
0.874
Difference =
-0.026

High External Dependence
Low External Dependence
Difference =

Deregulated Banking
Markets
0.852
0.897
-0.045

Average Size (Employees per Establishment)
Un-concentrated Banking
Markets
High External Dependence
82
Low External Dependence
61
Difference =
21
Deregulated Banking
Markets
74
52
22

Concentrated Banking
Markets
0.863
0.921
-0.058
Difference-in-Differences =
Regulated Banking
Markets
0.831
0.872
-0.041
Difference-in-Differences =

Concentrated Banking
Markets
71
41
30
Difference-in-Differences =

Difference
-0.015
-0.047
0.032**
Difference
0.021
0.025
-0.004

Difference
11
20
-9**

Regulated Banking
Markets
Difference
High External Dependence
90
-16
Low External Dependence
56
-4
Difference=
34
Difference-in-Differences =
-12**
Concentrated markets have an HHI in the first quartile of the distribution (below 1400); unconcentrated markets
have an HHI in the top quartile (above 2400). Regulated markets allow neither branching nor interstate banking;
deregulated markets permit both.
* significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%, based on a simple t-test.

Page 34 of 42

Table 4
Regression of Number of Establishments on Banking Competition Measures
Log of Establishments per capita
Post-Branching Indicator
0.018
(1.06)
Post-Interstate Banking Indicator
-0.082
(3.59)**
Post-Branching * Ext. Dep. Indicator, Mature firms (1 if > median)
-0.006
-0.007
-0.006
(0.34)
(0.36)
(0.30)
Post-Interstate Banking * Ext. Dep. Indicator, Mature firms
0.120
0.081
0.122
(4.16)**
(4.40)**
(4.14)**
Local-Market HHI
0.153
(0.97)
Local-Market HHI * Ext. Dep. Indicator, Mature firms
-0.459
-0.460
-0.457
(4.10)**
(4.05)**
(4.03)**
Industry share of employment
7.648
7.666
7.647
(95.75)**
(94.98)**
(94.44)**
Market Share of Bank Assets in Small Banks
-0.308
(2.62)**
Bank Productivity: Real Operating Income per Banking FTE
-0.042
(1.51)
Personal Income Growth
0.583
(3.72)**
Observations
15127
15127
15127
R-squared
0.54
0.88
0.89
State
Industry
Industry*
Fixed Effects
Industry*
State*
Year
Year
Year
State*Year
Absolute value of t statistics in parentheses
* significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%

Page 35 of 42

Table 5
Regression of Average Establishment Size on Banking Competition Measures
Log of Average Establishment Size
Post-Branching Indicator
0.015
(0.74)
Post-Interstate Banking Indicator
0.072
(2.66)**
Post-Branching * Ext. Dep. Indicator, Mature firms (1 if > median)
-0.018
-0.010
-0.018
(0.79)
(0.42)
(0.77)
Post-Interstate Banking * Ext. Dep. Indicator, Mature firms
-0.106
-0.045
-0.105
(3.06)**
(2.04)*
(2.98)**
Local-Market HHI
-0.748
(3.96)**
Local-Market HHI * Ext. Dep. Indicator, Mature firms
0.940
0.926
0.934
(7.05)**
(6.85)**
(6.88)**
Industry share of employment
6.672
6.696
6.672
(70.04)**
(69.75)**
(68.83)**
Market Share of Bank Assets in Small Banks
-0.155
(1.10)
Bank Productivity: Real Operating Income per Banking FTE
-0.081
(2.47)*
Personal Income Growth
0.546
(2.92)**
Observations
15127
15127
15127
R-squared
0.51
0.55
0.56
State
Industry
Industry*
Fixed Effects
Industry*
State*
Year
Year
Year
State*Year
Absolute value of t statistics in parentheses
* significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%

Page 36 of 42

Table 6
Regression of Share of Small Establishments on Banking Competition Measures
Logit of:
Share of Establishments <5 employees
Post-Branching Indicator
-0.038
(1.05)
Post-Interstate Banking Indicator
-0.075
(1.56)
Post-Branching * Ext. Dep. Indicator, Mature firms (1 if > median)
0.064
0.056
0.063
(1.60)
(1.41)
(1.57)
Post-Interstate Banking * Ext. Dep. Indicator, Mature firms
-0.051
-0.056
-0.052
(0.84)
(1.44)
(0.85)
Local-Market HHI
0.984
(2.95)**
Local-Market HHI * Ext. Dep. Indicator, Mature firms
-0.934
-0.910
-0.929
(3.97)**
(3.84)**
(3.91)**
Industry share of employment
-3.287
-3.334
-3.283
(19.56)**
(19.82)**
(19.36)**
Market Share of Bank Assets in Small Banks
0.088
(0.35)
Bank Productivity: Real Operating Income per Banking FTE
-0.009
(0.16)
Personal Income Growth
-1.262
(3.82)**
Observations
15127
15127
15127
R-squared
0.14
0.19
0.21
State
Industry
Fixed Effects
Industry*
State*
Industry*Year
Year
Year
State*Year
Absolute value of t statistics in parentheses
* significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%

Page 37 of 42

Table 7
Regression of Share of Small Establishments on Banking Competition Measures
Logit of:
Share of Establishments <20 employees
Post-Branching Indicator
-0.044
(1.21)
Post-Interstate Banking Indicator
-0.099
(2.03)*
Post-Branching * Ext. Dep. Indicator, Mature firms (1 if > median)
0.071
0.053
0.070
(1.76)
(1.32)
(1.70)
Post-Interstate Banking * Ext. Dep. Indicator, Mature firms
0.064
-0.063
0.064
(1.03)
(1.62)
(1.02)
Local-Market HHI
0.847
(2.51)*
Local-Market HHI * Ext. Dep. Indicator, Mature firms
-0.974
-0.947
-0.963
(4.08)**
(3.93)**
(3.98)**
Industry share of employment
-5.548
-5.579
-5.542
(32.55)**
(32.62)**
(32.05)**
Market Share of Bank Assets in Small Banks
0.357
(1.42)
Bank Productivity: Real Operating Income per Banking FTE
0.071
(1.21)
Personal Income Growth
-1.118
(3.34)**
Observations
15127
15127
15127
R-squared
0.30
0.24
0.26
State
Industry*
Fixed Effects
Industry*
Industry
Year
Year
State*Year
State*Year
Absolute value of t statistics in parentheses
* significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%

Page 38 of 42

Table 8
Regression of Share of Small Establishments on Banking Competition Measures
Logit of:
Share of Establishments <100 employees
Post-Branching Indicator
-0.054
(1.41)
Post-Interstate Banking Indicator
-0.167
(3.31)**
Post-Branching * Ext. Dep. Indicator, Mature firms (1 if > median)
0.043
0.013
0.042
(1.01)
(0.30)
(0.97)
Post-Interstate Banking * Ext. Dep. Indicator, Mature firms
0.268
0.008
0.267
(4.17)**
(0.19)
(4.07)**
Local-Market HHI
1.047
(2.97)**
Local-Market HHI * Ext. Dep. Indicator, Mature firms
-1.744
-1.721
-1.736
(7.02)**
(6.84)**
(6.86)**
Industry share of employment
-7.684
-7.729
-7.684
(43.28)**
(43.23)**
(42.53)**
Market Share of Bank Assets in Small Banks
-0.122
(0.47)
Bank Productivity: Real Operating Income per Banking FTE
0.109
(1.78)
Personal Income Growth
-0.733
(2.10)*
Observations
15127
15127
15127
R-squared
0.38
0.33
0.35
State
Industry*
Fixed Effects
Industry*
Industry
Year
Year
State*Year State*Year
Absolute value of t statistics in parentheses
* significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%

Page 39 of 42

Table 9
Regression of Share of Small Establishments on Banking Competition Measures
Logit of:
Share of Establishments <250 employees
Post-Branching Indicator
0.008
(0.23)
Post-Interstate Banking Indicator
-0.080
(1.72)
Post-Branching * Ext. Dep. Indicator, Mature firms (1 if > median)
0.014
-0.003
0.014
(0.36)
(0.08)
(0.36)
Post-Interstate Banking * Ext. Dep. Indicator, Mature firms
0.163
0.047
0.161
(2.75)**
(1.25)
(2.66)**
Local-Market HHI
0.878
(2.70)**
Local-Market HHI * Ext. Dep. Indicator, Mature firms
-1.506
-1.494
-1.501
(6.56)**
(6.44)**
(6.42)**
Industry share of employment
-7.998
-7.993
-7.997
(48.73)**
(48.48)**
(47.87)**
Market Share of Bank Assets in Small Banks
0.023
(0.10)
Bank Productivity: Real Operating Income per Banking FTE
0.103
(1.82)
Personal Income Growth
-0.655
(2.03)*
Observations
15127
15127
15127
R-squared
0.41
0.42
0.43
Industry*
Fixed Effects
State
Industry
Year
Industry*Year
State*Year
State*Year
Absolute value of t statistics in parentheses
* significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%

Page 40 of 42

Table 10
Bank Dependence Interaction using Level of External Financial Dependence for Mature Compustat Firms

Post-Branching * Ext. Dep.
Post-Int. Banking * Ext. Dep.
Local-Market HHI * Ext. Dep.
Industry share of employment
Observations
Fixed Effects
R-squared

Log of Est.
per capita

Log of
Average Est.
Size

Share of
Establishments
<5 employees

Share of
Establishments
<20 employees

Share of Est.
<100
employees

Share of
Establishments
<250
employees

-0.025
(0.81)
0.039
(0.77)
-1.245
(6.56)**
7.652
(94.57)**
15127

0.120
(3.22)**
-0.263
(4.41)**
2.377
(10.49)**
6.675
(69.11)**
15127

-0.040
(0.61)
0.182
(1.74)
-2.221
(5.59)**
-3.300
(19.48)**
15127

-0.075
(1.12)
0.278
(2.61)**
-4.502
(11.15)**
-5.569
(32.36)**
15127

-0.152
(2.18)*
0.522
(4.70)**
-4.830
(11.43)**
-7.688
(42.72)**
15127

-0.358
(5.55)**
0.604
(5.86)**
-2.253
(5.76)**
-7.986
(47.91)**
15127

State * Year
Industry * Year

0.89

0.56

0.21

Absolute value of t statistics in parentheses

* significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%

Page 41 of 42

0.26

0.35

0.43

Table 11
Bank Dependence Interaction using Small Firm Loans/Asset Ratio

Post-Branching * Loans/Assets
Post-Int. Banking * Loans/Assets
Local-Market HHI * Loans/Assets
Industry share of employment
Observations
Fixed Effects

Log of Est.
per capita
-0.095
(1.49)
0.152
(1.58)
-1.104
(2.96)**
7.581
(101.56)**
14717

R-squared
0.86
Absolute value of t statistics in parentheses

Log of
Average Est.
Size
-0.145
(1.96)
-0.904
(8.04)**
3.490
(8.02)**
6.497
(74.54)**
14717
0.62

Share of
Share of
Establishments
Establishments
<5 employees
<20 employees
-0.073
-0.164
(0.73)
(1.60)
0.431
0.446
(2.86)**
(2.86)**
-4.288
-2.521
(7.35)**
(4.17)**
-3.113
-5.116
(26.65)**
(42.32)**
14717
14717
State * Year
Industry * Year
0.35
0.41

* significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%

Page 42 of 42

Share of Est.
<100
employees
0.249
(2.19)*
1.171
(6.79)**
-2.434
(3.64)**
-6.728
(50.28)**
14717

Share of
Establishments
<250
employees
0.011
(0.11)
1.250
(7.70)**
-3.105
(4.94)**
-6.535
(51.97)**
14717

0.48

0.52

Working Paper Series
A series of research studies on regional economic issues relating to the Seventh Federal
Reserve District, and on financial and economic topics.
Does Bank Concentration Lead to Concentration in Industrial Sectors?
Nicola Cetorelli

WP-01-01

On the Fiscal Implications of Twin Crises
Craig Burnside, Martin Eichenbaum and Sergio Rebelo

WP-01-02

Sub-Debt Yield Spreads as Bank Risk Measures
Douglas D. Evanoff and Larry D. Wall

WP-01-03

Productivity Growth in the 1990s: Technology, Utilization, or Adjustment?
Susanto Basu, John G. Fernald and Matthew D. Shapiro

WP-01-04

Do Regulators Search for the Quiet Life? The Relationship Between Regulators and
The Regulated in Banking
Richard J. Rosen
Learning-by-Doing, Scale Efficiencies, and Financial Performance at Internet-Only Banks
Robert DeYoung
The Role of Real Wages, Productivity, and Fiscal Policy in Germany’s
Great Depression 1928-37
Jonas D. M. Fisher and Andreas Hornstein

WP-01-05

WP-01-06

WP-01-07

Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic Effects of a Shock to Monetary Policy
Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum and Charles L. Evans

WP-01-08

Outsourcing Business Service and the Scope of Local Markets
Yukako Ono

WP-01-09

The Effect of Market Size Structure on Competition: The Case of Small Business Lending
Allen N. Berger, Richard J. Rosen and Gregory F. Udell

WP-01-10

Deregulation, the Internet, and the Competitive Viability of Large Banks
and Community Banks
Robert DeYoung and William C. Hunter

WP-01-11

Price Ceilings as Focal Points for Tacit Collusion: Evidence from Credit Cards
Christopher R. Knittel and Victor Stango

WP-01-12

Gaps and Triangles
Bernardino Adão, Isabel Correia and Pedro Teles

WP-01-13

A Real Explanation for Heterogeneous Investment Dynamics
Jonas D.M. Fisher

WP-01-14

Recovering Risk Aversion from Options
Robert R. Bliss and Nikolaos Panigirtzoglou

WP-01-15

Economic Determinants of the Nominal Treasury Yield Curve
Charles L. Evans and David Marshall

WP-01-16

Working Paper Series (continued)

1

Price Level Uniformity in a Random Matching Model with Perfectly Patient Traders
Edward J. Green and Ruilin Zhou

WP-01-17

Earnings Mobility in the US: A New Look at Intergenerational Inequality
Bhashkar Mazumder
The Effects of Health Insurance and Self-Insurance on Retirement Behavior
Eric French and John Bailey Jones

WP-01-18

The Effect of Part-Time Work on Wages: Evidence from the Social Security Rules
Daniel Aaronson and Eric French

WP-01-20

Antidumping Policy Under Imperfect Competition
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-01-21

WP-01-19

Is the United States an Optimum Currency Area?
An Empirical Analysis of Regional Business Cycles
Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-01-22

A Note on the Estimation of Linear Regression Models with Heteroskedastic
Measurement Errors
Daniel G. Sullivan

WP-01-23

The Mis-Measurement of Permanent Earnings: New Evidence from Social
Security Earnings Data
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-01-24

Pricing IPOs of Mutual Thrift Conversions: The Joint Effect of Regulation
and Market Discipline
Elijah Brewer III, Douglas D. Evanoff and Jacky So

WP-01-25

Opportunity Cost and Prudentiality: An Analysis of Collateral Decisions in
Bilateral and Multilateral Settings
Herbert L. Baer, Virginia G. France and James T. Moser

WP-01-26

Outsourcing Business Services and the Role of Central Administrative Offices
Yukako Ono

WP-02-01

Strategic Responses to Regulatory Threat in the Credit Card Market*
Victor Stango

WP-02-02

The Optimal Mix of Taxes on Money, Consumption and Income
Fiorella De Fiore and Pedro Teles

WP-02-03

Expectation Traps and Monetary Policy
Stefania Albanesi, V. V. Chari and Lawrence J. Christiano

WP-02-04

Monetary Policy in a Financial Crisis
Lawrence J. Christiano, Christopher Gust and Jorge Roldos

WP-02-05

Regulatory Incentives and Consolidation: The Case of Commercial Bank Mergers
and the Community Reinvestment Act
Raphael Bostic, Hamid Mehran, Anna Paulson and Marc Saidenberg

WP-02-06

Working Paper Series (continued)
Technological Progress and the Geographic Expansion of the Banking Industry
Allen N. Berger and Robert DeYoung

WP-02-07

2

Choosing the Right Parents: Changes in the Intergenerational Transmission
of Inequality  Between 1980 and the Early 1990s
David I. Levine and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-02-08

The Immediacy Implications of Exchange Organization
James T. Moser

WP-02-09

Maternal Employment and Overweight Children
Patricia M. Anderson, Kristin F. Butcher and Phillip B. Levine

WP-02-10

The Costs and Benefits of Moral Suasion: Evidence from the Rescue of
Long-Term Capital Management
Craig Furfine

WP-02-11

On the Cyclical Behavior of Employment, Unemployment and Labor Force Participation
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-02-12

Do Safeguard Tariffs and Antidumping Duties Open or Close Technology Gaps?
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-02-13

Technology Shocks Matter
Jonas D. M. Fisher

WP-02-14

Money as a Mechanism in a Bewley Economy
Edward J. Green and Ruilin Zhou

WP-02-15

Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy: Equivalence Results
Isabel Correia, Juan Pablo Nicolini and Pedro Teles

WP-02-16

Real Exchange Rate Fluctuations and the Dynamics of Retail Trade Industries
on the U.S.-Canada Border
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Beverly Lapham

WP-02-17

Bank Procyclicality, Credit Crunches, and Asymmetric Monetary Policy Effects:
A Unifying Model
Robert R. Bliss and George G. Kaufman

WP-02-18

Location of Headquarter Growth During the 90s
Thomas H. Klier

WP-02-19

The Value of Banking Relationships During a Financial Crisis:
Evidence from Failures of Japanese Banks
Elijah Brewer III, Hesna Genay, William Curt Hunter and George G. Kaufman

WP-02-20

On the Distribution and Dynamics of Health Costs
Eric French and John Bailey Jones

WP-02-21

The Effects of Progressive Taxation on Labor Supply when Hours and Wages are
Jointly Determined
Daniel Aaronson and Eric French

WP-02-22

3

Working Paper Series (continued)
Inter-industry Contagion and the Competitive Effects of Financial Distress Announcements:
Evidence from Commercial Banks and Life Insurance Companies
Elijah Brewer III and William E. Jackson III

WP-02-23

State-Contingent Bank Regulation With Unobserved Action and
Unobserved Characteristics
David A. Marshall and Edward Simpson Prescott

WP-02-24

Local Market Consolidation and Bank Productive Efficiency
Douglas D. Evanoff and Evren Örs

WP-02-25

Life-Cycle Dynamics in Industrial Sectors. The Role of Banking Market Structure
Nicola Cetorelli

WP-02-26

Private School Location and Neighborhood Characteristics
Lisa Barrow

WP-02-27

Teachers and Student Achievement in the Chicago Public High Schools
Daniel Aaronson, Lisa Barrow and William Sander

WP-02-28

The Crime of 1873: Back to the Scene
François R. Velde

WP-02-29

Trade Structure, Industrial Structure, and International Business Cycles
Marianne Baxter and Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-02-30

Estimating the Returns to Community College Schooling for Displaced Workers
Louis Jacobson, Robert LaLonde and Daniel G. Sullivan

WP-02-31

A Proposal for Efficiently Resolving Out-of-the-Money Swap Positions
at Large Insolvent Banks
George G. Kaufman

WP-03-01

Depositor Liquidity and Loss-Sharing in Bank Failure Resolutions
George G. Kaufman

WP-03-02

Subordinated Debt and Prompt Corrective Regulatory Action
Douglas D. Evanoff and Larry D. Wall

WP-03-03

When is Inter-Transaction Time Informative?
Craig Furfine

WP-03-04

Tenure Choice with Location Selection: The Case of Hispanic Neighborhoods
in Chicago
Maude Toussaint-Comeau and Sherrie L.W. Rhine

WP-03-05

Distinguishing Limited Commitment from Moral Hazard in Models of
Growth with Inequality*
Anna L. Paulson and Robert Townsend

WP-03-06

Resolving Large Complex Financial Organizations
Robert R. Bliss

WP-03-07

4

Working Paper Series (continued)
The Case of the Missing Productivity Growth:
Or, Does information technology explain why productivity accelerated in the United States
but not the United Kingdom?
Susanto Basu, John G. Fernald, Nicholas Oulton and Sylaja Srinivasan

WP-03-08

Inside-Outside Money Competition
Ramon Marimon, Juan Pablo Nicolini and Pedro Teles

WP-03-09

The Importance of Check-Cashing Businesses to the Unbanked: Racial/Ethnic Differences
William H. Greene, Sherrie L.W. Rhine and Maude Toussaint-Comeau

WP-03-10

A Structural Empirical Model of Firm Growth, Learning, and Survival
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-03-11

Market Size Matters
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Hugo A. Hopenhayn

WP-03-12

The Cost of Business Cycles under Endogenous Growth
Gadi Barlevy

WP-03-13

The Past, Present, and Probable Future for Community Banks
Robert DeYoung, William C. Hunter and Gregory F. Udell

WP-03-14

Measuring Productivity Growth in Asia: Do Market Imperfections Matter?
John Fernald and Brent Neiman

WP-03-15

Revised Estimates of Intergenerational Income Mobility in the United States
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-03-16

Product Market Evidence on the Employment Effects of the Minimum Wage
Daniel Aaronson and Eric French

WP-03-17

Estimating Models of On-the-Job Search using Record Statistics
Gadi Barlevy

WP-03-18

Banking Market Conditions and Deposit Interest Rates
Richard J. Rosen

WP-03-19

Creating a National State Rainy Day Fund: A Modest Proposal to Improve Future
State Fiscal Performance
Richard Mattoon

WP-03-20

Managerial Incentive and Financial Contagion
Sujit Chakravorti, Anna Llyina and Subir Lall

WP-03-21

Women and the Phillips Curve: Do Women’s and Men’s Labor Market Outcomes
Differentially Affect Real Wage Growth and Inflation?
Katharine Anderson, Lisa Barrow and Kristin F. Butcher

WP-03-22

Evaluating the Calvo Model of Sticky Prices
Martin Eichenbaum and Jonas D.M. Fisher

WP-03-23

5

Working Paper Series (continued)
The Growing Importance of Family and Community: An Analysis of Changes in the
Sibling Correlation in Earnings
Bhashkar Mazumder and David I. Levine

WP-03-24

Should We Teach Old Dogs New Tricks? The Impact of Community College Retraining
on Older Displaced Workers
Louis Jacobson, Robert J. LaLonde and Daniel Sullivan

WP-03-25

Trade Deflection and Trade Depression
Chad P. Brown and Meredith A. Crowley

WP-03-26

China and Emerging Asia: Comrades or Competitors?
Alan G. Ahearne, John G. Fernald, Prakash Loungani and John W. Schindler

WP-03-27

International Business Cycles Under Fixed and Flexible Exchange Rate Regimes
Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-03-28

Firing Costs and Business Cycle Fluctuations
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-03-29

Spatial Organization of Firms
Yukako Ono

WP-03-30

Government Equity and Money: John Law’s System in 1720 France
François R. Velde

WP-03-31

Deregulation and the Relationship Between Bank CEO
Compensation and Risk-Taking
Elijah Brewer III, William Curt Hunter and William E. Jackson III

WP-03-32

Compatibility and Pricing with Indirect Network Effects: Evidence from ATMs
Christopher R. Knittel and Victor Stango

WP-03-33

Self-Employment as an Alternative to Unemployment
Ellen R. Rissman

WP-03-34

Where the Headquarters are – Evidence from Large Public Companies 1990-2000
Tyler Diacon and Thomas H. Klier

WP-03-35

Standing Facilities and Interbank Borrowing: Evidence from the Federal Reserve’s
New Discount Window
Craig Furfine

WP-04-01

Netting, Financial Contracts, and Banks: The Economic Implications
William J. Bergman, Robert R. Bliss, Christian A. Johnson and George G. Kaufman

WP-04-02

Real Effects of Bank Competition
Nicola Cetorelli

WP-04-03

Finance as a Barrier To Entry: Bank Competition and Industry Structure in
Local U.S. Markets?
Nicola Cetorelli and Philip E. Strahan

WP-04-04

6

7