View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

82-3
c
a
E
E

o
u
TJ

C

Z

a
;
>
a
)

c
*

TH E FED’S PO ST-O C TO BER 1979 TEC H N IC A L O PERA TIN G
PRO C ED U RES: RED U C ED A B ILITY TO C O N TR O L M O N EY




George G. Kaufman
m
D

m
70

>

r
—
70
m
m

co
70
<

m

09

>
Z

*
0
■n
n
i
n
>

o
o

82-3

The Fed's Post-October 1979 Technical Operating Procedures:
Reduced Ability to Control Money

by
k
George G. Kaufman

Loyola University and
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

k
The views expressed in this paper are solely those of the author
and do not necessarily represent the views of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Chicago or the Federal Reserve System.




May 1982

THE FED'S POST-OCTOBER 1979 TECHNICAL OPERATING PROCEDURES:
REDUCED ABILITY TO CONTROL MONEY
George G. Kaufman*

On October 6 , 1979, the Federal Reserve changed its "open market
operating procedures to place more emphasis on controlling reserves
directly so as to provide more assurance of attaining basic money supply
objectives."^

The change was widely expected to increase, at least in

the near-term, volatility in short-term interest rates as the "new
procedures entail greater freedom for interest rates to change over the
short-run in response to market forces"

and the Federal Open Market

Committee widened the target intermeeting Federal funds range.
it did.

2

And so

The standard deviation in weekly percentage changes in the

interest rates on three-month Treasury bills more than doubled from 2.4
percent to 5.3 percent between the four years before and the two years
after October 1979.

Less expected, however, was an increase in the

short-term volatility of long-term rates.

The standard deviation in

weekly percentage changes in rates on 20-year Treasury bonds jumped from
0.8 percent in the four years before October 1979 to 2.5 percent in the
two years after.

These results are shown in Table 1.

The standard

deviations in daily changes in these rates show a similar pattern and
are plotted in Figure 1.

3

*Loyola University of Chicago and Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.
Patricia Walker provided research assistance. The author benefited from
discussions with and comments by Thomas Gittings, David Lindsey, Robert
Laurent, Thomas Mayer, Harvey Rosenblum, Steve Strongin, Vefa Tarhan,
Robert Weintraub and William Wilby. An earlier version of this paper
was presented at the Midwest Finance Association meetings in Chicago,
April 1-3, 1982.




2

Although the Fed warned that "even in evaluating money growth
itself* which the Federal Open Market Committee sets as a target in the
policy process, recognition has to be given to the likelihood that money
growth can vary substantially on a month-to-month basis in view of
inherently large and erratic money flows in as vast and complex an
economy as ours," the new operating procedures were expected to decrease
the short-and long-term volatility in monetary aggregates by reducing
4
the need for changes in reserves to stabilize interest rates.
did not happen.

But this

Both short and long-term volatility in major monetary

aggregate series increased after the change.

For example, the standard

deviation in weekly percentage changes in not seasonally adjusted M1B
less currency rose from 1.90 percent in the period January 1975 October 6 , 1979 to 2.13 percent in the period October 6 , 1979 December 2, 1981 (Table 2).

Similar results are obtained for

alternative definitions of monetary aggregate, alternative sample
periods, and seasonally adjusted data.^

Longer-term volatility in M1B

has increased even more since October 1979 as is clearly evident in
Figure 2.
Thus, the Fed appears to have achieved the worst of both worlds.
It has increased the volatility in both interest rates and money supply.
This paper analyzes the new operating procedure to identify why this
might have occured.

The analysis suggests that, in the absence of

deliberate Federal Reserve policy to permit greater short-run volatility
in monetary aggregates, an important cause of the problem is the
inappropriate grafting of a monetary aggregate target on a lagged
reserve requirement accounting system.




This alone increases the

3

complexity of controlling money supply.

But, in addition, within this

environment, the Fed has chosen to adopt technical operating procedures
that reduce even further its ability to control the money supply.
It would appear that at least in theory the operating procedures
for controlling reserves directly would be straightforward.

The FOMC

could determine either a total reserve growth rate target or a monetary
aggregate growth rate target.

If the latter, the staff could translate

the monetary aggregate target into a total reserve target by estimating
the composition of deposits and thereby the appropriate multiplier.

The

total reserves target is then obtained by dividing the monetary
aggregate target by the estimated multiplier.

Money supply would

respond directly and concurrently to changes in reserves.

Because the

Open Market Desk controls directly only the System's portfolio of
securities, other factors that affect reserves, such as float and
borrowing at the discount window, must be adjusted for.

In the best of

all worlds, these factors, including borrowing, could be predicted.

But

in reality it may be necessary to respond to them with a brief lag,
e .g ., one day.
Unfortunately, such a straightforward procedure is not possible
under two week lagged reserves accounting, which separates the deposit
accounting week from the reserve settlement week.^

Although any

individual bank may obtain its necessary reserves in the reserve
settlement week from a variety of sources, for the banking system as a
whole, the Fed has to provide all the reserves required by the dollar
amount of total deposits established two weeks earlier in the deposit
accounting week.

Thus, the minimum amount of total reserves in any

settlement period is predetermined by events two weeks earlier and is




4

beyond Fed control in that period.

Lagged reserves do not merely delay

bank response by two weeks; they alter the bank decision making process.
To influence the amount of deposits and thereby the money supply in the
deposit accounting week, the Fed has to influence bank deposit decisions
two weeks before the settlement week when it provides the reserves for
that week.

Short of rewriting history, this may be achieved in a number

of ways that affect the cost of reserves either or both in the current
g

deposit week or in the reserve settlement week two weeks later.

The

Fed has chosen to do so by affecting the mix of reserves between
borrowed and unborrowed reserves.

9

The strategy is based on the

assumption that a dollar of borrowed reserves affects banks differently
than a dollar of unborrowed reserves either directly by changing the
pressures to repay or indirectly by changing the Fed funds rate as banks
are "forced” into or out of the discount window.

In the words of the

Fed:
Suppose that the demand for money ran stronger than was being
targeted...The increased demand for money and also for bank re­
serves to support the money would in the first instance be ac­
companied by more intensive efforts on the part of banks to
obtain reserves in the Federal funds market, thereby tending to
bid up the Federal funds rate, and by increased borrowing at the
Federal Reserve discount window. As a result..emerging market
conditions reflect or induce adjustments on the part of banks
and the public. These responses on the part of banks, for example,
could induce sales of securities to the public (thejgby extin­
guishing deposits) and changes in lending policies.
Likewise, Chairman Paul Volcker has testified in 1980 that:
As soon as monetary growth picked up, our operating techniques
’automatically’ began to bring bank reserve positions under mild
pressure as use of the discount window increased. The pressure
was reinforced on several occasions by reducing the provision of
nonborrowed reserves. Total bank reserves have, to be sure,
expanded sharply— a mechanical concomitant of the rise in Ml— but
banks have had to borrow those reserves from the Federal Reserve;
we have^ijiot supplied them on our own initiative through the open
market.




5

Borrowed reserves are thus the key variable in affecting bank decisions
on deposits determination.

The higher are borrowed reserves, the lower

is the tendency to create deposits, and conversely.

12

The FOMC assigns the Open Market Desk the task of achieving a
specified target growth in unborrowed reserves.

As unborrowed reserves

are total reserves minus borrowings, this requires that the committee
first establish a target or initially assumed level of borrowed reserves
that it believes will provide the degree of bank restraint that is
consistent with achieving the previously established target money
growth.

Given the initial amount of unborrowed reserves so determined,

the desk operates to increase or decrease the amount from this initial
level at some target rate until the next meeting of the FOMC.

If during

this intermeeting period, banks demand more reserves than are consistent
with the sum of the target change in unborrowed reserves and the
initially assumed amount of borrowed reserves, the necessary reserves
are provided through the discount window.

This temporarily increases

borrowings above the initially assumed level and increases the degree of
restraint, encouraging banks to slow their deposit growth.

Conversely,

if banks demand fewer reserves than are provided by the sum of the
target change in unborrowed reserves and the initially assumed borrowed
reserves, the amount of borrowings will decline below the initially
assumed level.

This will reduce the restraint pressures on the banks

and encourage them to speed up their loan and deposits expansion.

In

the words of Peter Sternlight, Manager of the Fed’s Open Market Account:
Under this approach monetary growth in excess of path causes
increases in borrowings from the Fed, which would be associated
with higher interest rates and pressure on the banking system that
would, over time, tend to return growth of money supply and
reserves toward the desired path. Shortfalls in growth would have




6

the opposite effect, reducing the need for borrowings and thus
encour '
lower interest rates and more vigorous monetary
expans-Luu.

How is the initial borrowing target (assumption) established?

At

first, the FOMC did so by fassuming a level of borrowing near that
,
prevailing in the most recent period.”

14

But this restricted the FOMC’s

freedom to change the target money growth.

To exert greater control

over money growth within the FOMC’s framework, it was necessary to
estimate the amount of borrowed reserves consistent with the desired
target growth rate in money supply.

Then the level of borrowing ncould

be set higher or lower if it were desired to impart some initial thrust
toward some greater or lesser pressures on bank reserve positions".^
Ceteris paribus, borrowings are generally viewed as being determined by
the spread between the Fed funds rate and the discount rate.

16

If the

discount rate is set, the level of borrowed reserves depends on the Fed
funds rate.

Thus, in principle if not in practice, determination of the

target borrowed reserves that will achieve the target money growth
requires that the Fed funds rate that is consistent with the target
money growth be estimated first.
But this Fed funds rate was the basic rate that was estimated (and
targeted) under the old operating procedures.

The new procedures in

effect use the same underlying system of equations as the old procedures
plus one additional equation.

Greatly abbreviated versions of the two

systems of equations are shown in Table 3 . ^

Before October 1979, the

near-term target money supply was believed to be attainable by achieving
the target Federal funds rate; after October 1979, the target money
supply was believed to be attainable by achieving the target aggregate
borrowed reserves.




The target Fed funds rate is established by

7

transposing and solving a demand for money type equation containing
target values of money supply and predicted values of nominal income for
the Treasury bill rate.

Money and income are assumed independent of

each other in the short-term.

The Fed funds rate is then obtained

through a term structure equation.

The new procedures use the Fed funds

rate solution from this equation as an independent variable in the
borrowed reserves equation.
But it was in large measure because the appropriate Fed funds rate
could not be reliably estimated that the old procedures were abandoned
in October 1979.

In explaining the changes in procedures to Congress,

Chairman Volcker stated that:
Translation of money stock objectives into day-to-day
management of the federal funds rate is effective if
the relationship between the public’s demand for cash
balances and short-term market interest rates is ef­
fectively stable and predictable. But in an environ­
ment of high and volatile inflation rates the relation­
ship between^nterest rates and money...is more difficult
to appraise.
Likewise, in its directive adopted at the special meeting on October 6 ,
1979, the FOMC stated:
The principal reason advanced for shifting to an operating
procedure aimed at controlling the supply of reserves more
directly was that it would provide greater assurance that
the Committee’s objectives for monetary growth can be
achieved. In the present environment of rapid inflation,
estimates of interest rates, monetary growth, < i d economic
j^
activity had become less reliable than before.
Empirically, the new aggregate borrowing equation specifying
primarily the Fed funds-discount rate spread as an independent variable
appears to be even less reliable than the other equations in the system
for a number of reasons.

One, the effective discount rate charged banks

is not the nominal discount rate posted.




The Fed administers the window

8

to ration credit more directly and the degree and quality of
administration varies from Fed district to Fed district and even from
district home office to district branch.

Two, the Fed has periodically

imposed a surcharge on borrowings by larger banks in excess of a
designated minimum dollar amount and frequency of usage per period.
Both the magnitude of the surcharge and the minimum number of times per
period borrowings are not subject to the surcharge have been changed.
Three, the decision to borrow is likely to be a function of more than
the Fed funds rate, and it is unlikely that the Fed funds rate is an
appropriate proxy at all times for the spectrum of all other interest
rates no less all nonrate forces.

Lastly, under a system of lagged

reserve accounting and strict unborrowed reserves targeting, the
aggregate dollar amount of borrowing in a reserve settlement week is
effectively determined by aggregate deposits and required reserves two
weeks earlier.

Only the indentities of the individual banks tapping the

discount window and for how much is determined by interest rates in that
week.

The aggregate amount of borrowing by the banking system is

determined by its estimates of the Fed funds and discount rates in the
reserve settlement week during the deposit accounting week two weeks
earlier.

The equation, of course, also entails considerable

simultaneity between the dollar amount of borrowings and the Fed funds
rate.

Do higher borrowings raise the Fed funds rate or do higher Fed

funds rates increase borrowings?

As a result, internal Federal Reserve

studies by Levin, Goodfriend, and Kasriel and Merris find the aggregate
borrowing equation to have low and unstable explanatory power.

20

Likewise, Judd and Throop find that 1the average absolute deviation of
1
borrowed reserves from projected levels was...twice as large as either




9

of the other two types of operating errors,1 namely, errors in hitting
1
the statistically projected multiplier and the level of nonborrowed
reserves.

21

Thus, the new procedures use the statisticaly unreliable output of
the system of equations underlying the old procedure as input for an
even less reliable equation underlying the new procedure.

It follows

that the bottom line money supply growth-target borrowings equations is
unreliable and entails significant slippage.

22

Moreover, the money supply-borrowing relationship is asymmetical.
Increases in target borrowings, ceteris paribus, are associated with
slower monetary growth over the entire range, although the relationship
is unlikely to be linear.

On the other hand, decreases in target

borrowings are associated with faster monetary growth only to the point
where borrowing is zero or at a minimum frictional level.

At that

point, a wide range of faster money growth rates can be associated with
the same initial level of borrowings depending on the Fed funds rate.
Borrowings becomes a poor target.

It was primarily for this reason that

the Fed abandoned its borrowing target in the 1930s, when borrowings
dropped to near zero, in favor of free reserves (excess reservesborrowed reserves), which are not restricted to positive values.

From

this line of reasoning, one would expect that:
1.

Short-run (weekly) money supply growth will be more variable for a
given borrowings assumption than for a given Fed funds target as
the slippage is greater,

2.

Money supply will be procyclical if changes in the state of the




economy are underpredicted as they often are in periods of strong
economic swings because the "correct" initial borrowing assumption

10

is likely to be mis-estimated at least to the same degree that the
Fed funds rate target was under the old system,
3.

23

and

Acceleration in money growth in periods of weak economic activity
will be delayed.

Without specific guidance by the FOMC, when

assumed and actual borrowings are close to zero, the desk is likely
to lower the Fed funds rate only cautiously in progressive steps.
Additionally, although the Fed funds rate is permitted to vary over a
wider range, it is unlikely that for a given borrowing target it will
vary greatly and that it will remain particularly steady once it hits an
upper or lower boundary.

At this point, if past performance is a guide,

it is unlikely that the borrowing target will be changed consistently by
enough to moderate the ongoing monetary growth to target rates.

An

examination of the use of borrowing targets (initial assumptions) in
1980 in Table 4 and the actual pattern of money change in Figure 2
confirms this interpretation.

Money growth declined sharply in the

second quarter of the year at the same time that the initial borrowing
target was lowered from $2,750 million to $75 million and increased even
more sharply in the third quarter as the initial borrowing target was
increased again to $1,300 million.

This suggests that the behavior of

money supply within that year would have been little different if a Fed
funds target had been used consistent with the old procedure.

Indeed,

because of the inability to lower the borrowing target below zero in the
spring of 1980, the dramatic procyclical swing in money is likely to
have been greater than under the old procedure.
A more direct test of the ability of the new procedures to control
the money supply accurately is to compare the short-run money growth
targets (tolerance ranges) specified by the FOMC at every meeting with




11

the actual changes in money supply in the same period.
the Fed has made this difficult to do.

Unfortunately,

Before October 1979, the FOMC

established clear, unchanged two-month targets for Ml and M2 that held
for the entire period.

Shortly after October 1979, however, the FOMC

switched over to longer three- to six-month targets that could be and
often were modified at least once during the period.

Thus, it is

difficult to identify the target against which the actual money change
for a period should be compared.

The target moves and is frequently

revised during the period to correspond more closely to the developing
actual rates of money growth.

For example, as can be seen from Table 4,

on January 9, 1980, the FOMC set targets for the first quarter of the
year.

It revised these targets at its next meeting on February 5.

On

March 18, targets were changed and set for the first half of the year,
including the first quarter that had almost ended.

These targets were

revised on April 22, and on May 20 the committee set targets for the
last two months of this period, May and June.

24

Thus, the target

periods overlap and the evaluation problem is analagous to that of base
drift that plagues attempts to measure meaningfully the Fed’s ability to
meet its longer-term targets.

25

That lagged reserve accounting has significant unfavorable
implications for short-term monetary control is denied by the Federal
Reserve.

In November 1981, the Board requested public comment on a

proposal to introduce more contemporaneous reserve accounting.

In its

announcement, the Board stated that:
Contemporaneous reserve requirements (CRR) have some potential
for improving the implementation of monetary policy by
strengthening the linkage between the reserves held by depository
institutions and the money supply. There is some question,
however, whether such potential gains would increase short-run
volatility in the money market. The Board noted that any potential




12

gains in monetary control should not be exaggerated, in view of the
sizable remaining slippages between reserves and mon^, and in view
of the inherent volatility of short-run money flows.
In sum, to the extent the post-October 1979 operating procedure
differs from the pre-October 1979 operating procedure, it has increased
the difficulty of attaining the Fed’s money supply objectives and has
increased the short-term volatility in both interest rates and money
supply and the cyclical volatility in money supply.

These results are,

of course, either accidently or by design, contrary to the Fed’s
announced intentions.

Because the peculiarities of the technical

aspects of the new procedures reflect the need to operate in a lagged
reserve accounting world, greater control over both interest rates and
money supply is best guaranteed by abandoning lagged reserves ac­
counting.

Although, as noted in footnote 8 , there are alternative ways

of influencing deposits under lagged reserves, these means appear
considerably less efficient than those that are possible under
concurrent reserves accounting.

There are at least some officials

within the Federal Reserve who remain unconvinced that greater short-run
control of the money supply is either desirable or necessary.

For

example, Governor Lyle Gramley testified in March 1982 that:
However, several implications for monetary targeting that can be
drawn from the experience of recent years. First, short-run
movements of the money stock have even less meaning than they once
did as indicators of monetary policy. What happens to money growth
over longer periods is what counts. Second, monetary targets
should be expressed in rather wide ranges; the present ranges of
three percentage points are certainly not too wide. Third, we need
to continue to use multiple targets, rather than to focus on any
single measure of money. Indeed, somewhat greater weight may need
to be given to the broader monetary aggregates in the future as a
consequence of the relative instability of the demand for Ml.
Finally, we need to stand ready to accept growth of money outside
our target ranges— or even to modify t ^ ranges— if changes in the
public’s asset preferences warrant it.




13

To the extent that this view is representative, the much heralded
October 1979 change represents still another "self-fulfilling Fed
prophecy," but one less immediately visible and more difficult for the
outsider and even many insiders to recognize.




28

14

FOOTNOTES
^Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, nThe New Federal
Reserve Technical Procedures for Controlling Money," January 30, 1980, p. 1.

2

Board of Governors, p. 1.

3
Paul L. Kasriel, "Interest Rate Volatility in 1980," Economic
Perspectives (Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago), January/February 1981,
p. 10.
4
Board of Governors, p. 8 .
^The results are also unchanged by omitting the period March 15 to
December 31, 1980 when credit controls may have affected the behavior pattern
of financial variables and by omitting January 1981 when the maximum shifting
of deposits in response to the nationwide introduction of NOW accounts
occured. In addition, variability was estimated in demand deposits at member
banks only because a change in reporting series on deposits from nonmember
banks at yearend 1979 may have increased the reported volatility in these
deposits from before that date. The results are not altered materially.
g
It is evident that, unless the different monetary aggregate measures are
perfectly correlated, each will require a different reserve path to achieve.
Thus, this procedure requires use of either a single money measure or explicit
weights for a composite measure.
^It is not clear that the Fed was fully aware of the implications of
lagged reserves accounting for money control when it abruptly changed pro­
cedures in October 1979 in the midst of a "financial crisis." Discussions of
lagged reserves appear in Warren L. Coats, "Lagged Reserve Accounting and The
Money Supply Process," Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, May 1976, pp.
167-180; Daniel E. Laufenberg, "Contemporaneous Versus Lagged Reserve
Accounting," Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, May 1976, pp. 239-246;
Robert D. Laurent, "Reserve Requirements: Are They Lagged in the Wrong
Direction?" Journal of Money Credit and Banking, August 1979, pp. 301-310;
and George G. Kaufman, "Report of the Ad Hoc Subcommittee on Reserve
Proposals" (Memorandum, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, June 13, 1966).
See also Milton Friedman, "Monetary Policy: Theory and Practice", Journal of
Money, Credit and Banking, February 1982, pp. 98-118.
g
These alternatives are discussed in Robert Laurent, "A Critique of the
Federal Reserve’s New Operating Procedure" (Staff Memorandum 81-4, Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago, 1981) and George G. Kaufman, Money, The Financial
System and the Economy (3rd ed.) (Houghton-Mifflin, 1981), pp. 527-529.
9
A complete discussion of the operating procedures is provided in Peter
Sternlight, et. al., "Monetary Policy and Open Market Operations in 1980,"
Quarterly Review (Federal Reserve Bank of New York), Summer 1981, pp. 1-20.
^Board of Governors, pp. 4-5.
^Paul A. Volcker. "Statement Before the Subcommittee on Domestic
Monetary Policy," House of Representatives, November 19, 1980.




12

R.

Alton

Gilbert

Reserves

Targeting"

December

1980).

Fed

in

the
Rates

Brothers,

strategy
described

(New York:

1930).

also

Role

(Working

Paper,

"Consequences

Reserves"

Federal

(Paper

Harper
in

the

Prepared

Kaufman,
Borrowing

Bank

of

Federal

St.

The

that

Chicago,

the

Economic

by

the

Banks

and

W.

of

Federal

February

Under

Riefler,

Harper
the

Reserve"

1965)

R e s e r v e ’s R e - a t t a c h m e n t

for W e s t e r n

used

and Winfield
(New York:

from

Policy

Louis,

Reserve

"A Reexamination

Bank

Reserve
of

1927)

States

of

from

Burgess,

Brothers,

G.

of M o n e t a r y

Bank

different

Randolph

the U n ited

George

"Conduct
Reserve

greatly

i n W.

of M e m b e r

Meltzer,

Resler,
Federal

is n o t

Markets

See

and

H.

Paper,

and

and Money

Significance

David

The

1920s

the M o n e y M a r k e t
Money

and

(Working

and

to

Allan

H.

Free

Association Meeting,

July

1981).
13
Peter

D.

Sternlight,

"Is

The

Misdirected?"

Journal

of M o n e y ,

See

Lindsey

and

also

David

Operating

Procedures"

P r o c e d u r e s , Vol.

II,

in

others,

Federal

February

Federal

Credit,

R e s e r v e ’s M o n e t a r y

and

Banking, February

"Monetary

Reserve

Control

Staff

Control
1982,

Experience

Study,

Under

New Monetary

Policy

p.

126.

the

New

Control

1981.

14
Board
are

not

FOMC

of

Governors,

released

summary

Reserve

Bank

footnote

publicly

minutes.
of

9).

1981

^Sternlight,
^See,
Operating
Staff
York,

February
^For

targets

the

summer

were
1981

Fred Levin

and

level

They
first

of

yet

Paul

not

reserves

reported

published

by

Quarterly

its

been

of b o r r o w e d

are

the

Review

in

the

Federal
(see

reported.

125.

The

View

from

Control

on Demand

the

Meek,

Trading

"Implementing

Desk"

P r o c e d u r e s , Vol.

for

Borrowing"

I,

in

(February

(Federal

the

Federal

Reserve

New

Reserve

1981)
Bank

and

of

Fred

New

1981).

a more

complete
and

Review

basis.

not

Lombra

E.

Economic

11,

F e d ’s t a r g e t

have

New Monetary
Work

The

regular

1980

in

example,

"Further

Raymond
pp .

for

p.

3.
a

targets

Procedures:

Study,

Levin,

The

New York

The

p.
on

description

Raymond

(Federal

G.

of

Torto,

Reserve

Bank

the

"The

of

old

system

Strategy

Richmond),

of

equations

of M o n e t a r y

see

Policy"

September-October

1975,

3-14.
18

Paul A. Volcker, "Statement to Congress" Federal Reserve Bulletin
(December 1 9 7 9 ) , pp. 9 5 9 - 9 6 0 .
19

"Record

Federal

20

Levin

Borrowing,
Operating

1981).

(February

Monetary
1981);

an

Discount

possible

decision

Determinants

by

D.H.

For

of M e m b e r

are

Bank

1966.

see

J.R.

Paper,

modeling
Stephen

Borrowing:

C.

(Federal

Changing

An

6,

Committee,"

"Discount

1979

Reserve

Randall

obtained

Resler,

detailed

Open Market

974.2
0

Goodfriend,

Federal

and

Working

example

p.

Post-October

Target"

Estimating

Federal

Marvin

Paper,

results

through more

Finance, September




and

the

1979),

the

Paul Kasriel
Borrowing

Borrowings"

process.

1981);
and

(Working

techniques

Window

of

(December

11,

better

"Detecting

Actions

Policy

and

Initial

Somewhat

estimation

be

Policy

Bulletin

Procedure"

September
Choosing

Davis,

of

Reserve

Bank

Merris,

Reserve

using

Barth,

more

of

of

Swamy

Relationships:
Improved

of

individual

Goldfeld

and

Econometric

in

Chicago,

August

sophisticated

1981.
the

Reserve

Richmond,

"Difficulties

Bank

P.A.V.B.

Economic

Window

Federal

and W.D.
The

estimates
bank

"The

Journal

of

of

also

borrowing

Edward Kane,
Study,"

case

may

16
21 ■
John
Letter

22
is

In a

less

that

P.

recent

shifts
in

short-term
are

created
shift

in

in

greater

the

borrowed

argues

than

for m o ney

function

direction
rates

nonborrowed
however,
under

tended

out

the

new

that
are

to m o v e

automatically

in

Thus,

the

same

target

operating

supply

procedures

than

the

reserve

old

target

target

and

accommodated

"money

(as)

the

function
(p.

be

smaller

as

may

be

weekly

volatility

reserves

reserves

target

"Nonborrowed

Conference
of

St.

so

on

same

See

target

that

in m o n e y
is

less,

the m o n e y

Reserve

also,

and

Washington

conclusion

is

under
not

supply

Targeting

Improving Monetary

Louis

The

9).

for
seen

a

If
given

from

the

new procedures
flexible

function

Control

by

St.

Gilbert

by

the

(Paper
Federal

October

that

nonborrowed

frequently.

Louis,

and

suggests

the

Control"

sponsored
of

than

shifts

and Monetary

University

reached

the

more,

David
presented
Reserve

30,

1981) .

Resler.

24
Report
FOMC
St.

by

and

direction
supply

procedure"

should

I , " Weekly

1981.

reserve

sloping money

in m o n e y

Rate:

30,

the b o r r o w e d

reserves.

an upward

reserves

changes

Discount

the nonborrowed

in b o r r o w e d

have

tracing

Lindsey,
Bank

Lindsey

demand

the

demand

Penalty

Francisco), October

below:

The

at

David

Throop,"

San

short-run

same

the
so,

of

the

interest

by

Bank

paper

essentially

this w e r e
figure

in
the

a n d A d r i a n W.

Reserve

inflexible

changes
data

Judd

(Federal

Board

of Governors

198 0 , p p . 87-125,

in

1980:

Louis),

A

Year

and

of

R.

Reserve

August/September

of

Alton

Policy,"

L.

Journal

26
Board
November

Pierce,

1 9 8 1 v pp.

9,

of

"The Myth

of M o n e t a r y

.:
.
.
G o v e r n o r s of

1981,

pp.

Federal

Targeting",

25
James

the

Gilbert

of

Review

System,
E.

(Federal

Annual

Trebing,
Reserve

"The
Bank

of

2-16.

!'
Congressional

Economics, November
the

Reserve

and Michael

Federal

Reserve

Supervision
1978,

pp.

System,

of M o n e t a r y

363-376.

"Press

Release,"

1-2.

27
Lyle

E.

Gr a m l e y , ’ tatement
’S

Monetary

Policy

of

the

Committee

House

of

Representatives,

1982,

p.

Before

the

Banking,

Subcommittee

3,. 1 9 8 2 , "

Finance

Federal

and

on Domestic

177 .

March

on

Reserve

Urban

Affairs,

U.S.

Bulletin, March

28
For
Kaufman,

previous

"The

Self-Fulfilling




examples

Federal

of

Fed

self-fulfilling

R e s e r v e ’s I n a b i l i t y

Prophecy,"

Financial

to

Analysts

Control

prophecies
the M o n e y

see

George

Supply:

A

Journal, September/October,

17
1972.

A

similar view
In my
how

opinion,

to

produce

service

to

Committee
are

Friedman

Street




the

real

"The

problem

objective,

the

than

expressed by Milton

stabler monetary

that
of

control

important
Milton

been

Fed

unreconstructed

regard

Wall

has

of

regard

Keynesians

" c r e d i t 1 or
1

Federal

Reserve
1,

that

growth,

the members

do n ot

or

it

of
as

p.

the

Fed

that,

the

does

despite

Open Market

important

classical

central

to

16.

do

not

know

lip
Investment
so.

Most

bankers who

conditions"

growth.

and Monetary

1982,

but

"credit market

steady monetary

Journal, February

is n o t

Friedman:

Instability",

as

far m ore

18

Table 1

Percentage

Change

in W e e k l y
Pre-and

Variability
Post-October

Pre-October

in

Selected

Interest

Rates

1979

1979

Post-October

1979

70:1-

75:53-

79:41-

79:41-

79:41

79:41

79:41

81:48

81:48

81:48

Standard Deviation
Fed

funds

3-month
5-year

3.719

Treasury
Treasury

bill
security

1.903

6.130

5.257

5.309

3.371

2.387

5.323

4.543

4.577

1.788

1.407

3.278

2.979

3.052

10-year

Treasury

security

1.328

1.027

2.683

2.552

2.619

20-year

Treasury

security

1.184

0.828

2.495

2.391

2.444

*0mitted

3/15/80

-

1/1/81

Omitted

3/15/80

-

1/31/81




19

Table 2

Percentage

Change

in W e e k l y

Pre-and

Variability

Post-October

Pre-October

in M o n e y

Stock

1979

Post-October

1979

70:1-

75:53-

79:41-

79:41

79:41

81:48

79:41*
-81:48

1979
79:41**
-81:48

Standard Deviation
M1B
M1B

1.288
Less

Currency

**0mitted
Omitted




3/15/80-1/1/81
3/15/80-1/31/81

1.539

1.729

1.771

1.741

1.557

1.896

2.132

2.168

2.135

20

Table 3
Comparison

of

Abbreviated

Pre-and

Underlying

Post-October

1979

S y s t e m of

Operating

Equations

Pre
Basic

Operating

Relationship:

for

Procedures

H r= f ( F R T )

Establish Target:
*1

Post

MT*f(BT)

“r

Solve

for

for

Consistent

TR=f(MT>Y p )

FRt :

Consistent

Monetary

FR^Target

Fed

TR=Treasury

Aggregate

Funds

Bill

Rate

B^,=Borrowed R e s e r v e
DR=Discount

Rate

Target

p=Predicted




Value

Target

Complex

Y p=Predicted Nominal
T=Fed

Rate

GNP

FR=f(TR)

B T= f ( F R , D R )

Bp

K ex
M^=Target

T R = f ( M x ,Yp )

FRT =f(TR)

Solve

Growth

21
Table 4

Specifications from Directives of the Federal Open Market Committee, 1980

Date
of
meeting

1/9/80

2 /5 /8 0 ...............

Initial
assumption for
borrowed
reserves
(millions of
dollars)

Discount rate on
day of meeting
and subsequent
changes (percent)

1 1 12 - 151
/
/2

1,000

12

6 V2

1112 - 1512
/
/

1,250

12
13 on 2/15
+ 3 percent sur­
charge on 3/17

December to June
41 2
/
5
73
A
(or somewhat slower)

13-20

2.750

13 + 3

December to June
412
/
5
63
A
(or somewhat slower)

13-19

1,375

13 + 3

Specified short-term
annualized rates of
growth for period
mentioned (percent)
M-1 A
M-1 B
M-2

December to March
4- 5 *
7*

December to March
41
/2

3 /1 8 /8 0 .............

4 /2 2 /8 0 .............

Range for
Federal
funds rate
(percent)

5

* Rates for M-1 and old definition for M-2 .

Source:




FRBNY Quarterly Review . Summer 1981, pp

68-69

Notes

The Committee’s objectives were
set in terms of M-1 and the old
definitions of M-2 and M-3. In
July 1979, the Committee had set
growth of objectives for M-1, M-2,
and M-3 from the fourth quarter
of 1978 to the fourth quarter of
1979 of 3 to 6, 5 to 8, and 6 to
9 percent, respectively. (The
M-1 objective incorporated later
revisions in assumptions about
the growth of NOW and ATS
accounts.) The Committee antici­
pated growth in 1980 within
those ranges.
FOMC indicated its objectives
would be furthered by growth of
M-1 A, M-1 B, M-2, and M-3 from
the fourth quarter of 1979 to the
fourth quarter of 1980 within
ranges of 3 1 2 to 6, 4 to 6 1 2 ,
/
/
6 to 9, and 61 to 9 1 2 per­
/2
/
cent, respectively. The associ­
ated range for bank credit was 6
to 9 percent. On February 22,
the upper limit of the range for
Federal funds rate was raised to
I 6 V percent. On March 6, 1980
2
the upper limit of the range for
Federal funds was raised to 171/2
percent. The next day the Com­
mittee further modified the
domestic policy directive to
raise the upper limit of the
range for Federal funds
to 18 percent.

On May 6 the lower limit of the
range for Federal funds rate was
reduced to 1 0 1/2 percent. The
3 percent surcharge was
removed effective May 7.

22
Table 4 (con't)

Specifications from Directives of the Federal Open Market Committee1
0

Range for
Federal
funds rate
(percent)

Initial
assump­
tion for
borrowed
reserves
(millions of
dollars)

81
/2-14

100

13
12 on 5/30
11 on 6/13

June to September
7
8
8

81
/2-14

75

11
10 on 7/28

June to September
61/2
9
12

8-14

75

10

August to December
4
61
/2
81
/2

8-14

750

10
11 on 9/26

September to December
212
/
5
71
A

9-15

1,300

11
12 + 2
on 11/17

September to December
2 1
/2
5
7%
(or somewhat less)

13-17

1,500

12 + 2
13 + 3
on 12/5

December to March
4Va
4 3/4
7
(or somewhat less)

15-20

1,500

13 + 3

Specified short-term
annualized rates of
growth for period
mentioned (percent)
M-1A
M-1B
M-2

Date
of
meeting
5 /2 0 /8 0 .............

April to June
7-7 V
z
7V
,2-8
8
(or moderately faster)

7 /9 /8 0 ...............

8 /1 2 /8 0 .............
9 /1 6 /8 0 .............

1 0 /21 /8 0 ...........

11/18 /8 0 ...........

1 2 /19 /8 0 ...........




Discount rate on
day of meeting
and subsequent
changes (percent)

Notes

Objectives for 1980 remained the
same. In addition, on July 29 the
Committee agreed that, for the
period from the fourth quarter of
1980 to the fourth quarter of 1981,
it looked for a reduction of
the ranges for growth of Vz per­
centage point from the ranges
adopted for 1980, abstracting from
institutional influences affecting
the behavior of the aggregates.

On November 26 the Committee
raised the upper limit of the
range for the Federal funds rate
to 18 percent. On December 5
the Committee modified the
directive by providing leeway
for pursuit of the Committee’s
short-run objectives for the
behavior of reserve aggregates
without operations being pre­
cisely constrained by the inter­
meeting range for the Federal
funds rate for one week, and
then extended it to the meeting
on December 18-19, 1981.
The objectives abstracted from
the effects of deposit shifts
connected with the introduction
of NOW accounts on a nationwide basis. It was recognized
that the introduction of NOW
accounts nationwide at the
beginning of 1981 could widen
the discrepancy between
growth of M-1 A and M-1B.

23

Figure

1

Daily percentage changes in selected interest rates
federal funds rate

three-month Treasury bill rate

Source: Paul L. Kasriel "Interest Rate Volatility in 1980," Economic
Perspectives (Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago), (January/February 1981),
pp. 17.




Figure 2
Variability

in M l B

and M2

SEASONALLY ADJUSTED, ANNUAL RATES, MONTHLY
PERCENT

rmn i in) in i mil m
M1-B

CURRENCY, DEMAND OEPOSITS, AN OTHER CHECKABLE
O
DEPOSITS AT BANKS AND THRIFT INSTITUTIONS

20

10

♦
0

3-MONTH M
OVIN AVERAGE
G
CENTERED

10
October

1979-^

20

30

M2 M1-B PLUS CONSUMER-TYPE TIME AND SAVINGS DEPOSITS

AT BANKS AND THRIFT INSTITUTIONS, OVERNIGHT RPa
AND EURODOLLARS, AND MONEY MARKET MUTUAL FUNO SHARES

3-MONTH M
OVIN AVERAGE
G

20

CENTERED

10

IO+

-

Source:

1977

1975

1973

Board




of

Governors

of

the F ederal

Reserve System,

1979

Federal

Reserve Chart

1981

Book

(February

1982),

p..6