View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Equilibrium Bank Runs Revisited
Ed Nosal

WP 2011-13

Equilibrium Bank Runs Revisited
Ed Nosal
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
August 2011
This version: November 2011

Abstract
Peck and Shell (2003) show that it is possible to get a bank run in a
Diamond-Dybvig environment. The mechanism they use, however, is not an
optimal one. When an optimal mechanism is used, the bank run equilibrium
disappears.

1

Introduction

Although Diamond and Dybvig’s (1983) seminal article is associated with bank runs,
it’s actually di¢ cult to generate them. For example, when there is no aggregate risk,
they demonstrate that a bank run equilibrium cannot exist when the deposit contract
is appropriately designed. The optimal contract is a “standard” deposit contract
augmented by a suspension of convertibility if too many people want to withdraw
early. In the second part of their article, they assert, but do not demonstrate, that
deposit contracts will be subject to bank runs when there is aggregate risk. It was not
until Green and Lin (2003), GL, that an optimal deposit contract under aggregate risk
was fully characterized. GL take a mechanism design approach and demonstrate that
the optimal deposit contract does not have a bank run equilibrium. Subsequently,
Peck and Shell (2003), PS, modify the GL environment, and produce a bank run
equilibrium.
In a departure from GL, PS assume that depositors do not know their positions
in the service queue. This seems important. Among other things, it means that
GL’s powerful backward induction argument— that appears to eliminate bank run
equilibria— does not apply. One can interpret PS’s modi…cations as generalizing the
GL environment. In particular, if depositors do not know their positions in the service
I would like to thank Marco Bassetto, Todd Keister, Ali Shourideh, Nico Trachter, and Neil
Wallace for helpful discussions, and for comments on earlier versions of the paper.

1

queue, as in GL, then, in principle, the mechanism (or planner) can choose to either
inform or not inform depositors regarding their positions. (GL can be interpreted as
restricting the mechanism to always inform depositors about their positions in the
queue.)
Independent of how one views the GL environment vis-à-vis the PS environment,
the mechanism that GL adopt is optimal for their economic environment. Their
mechanism is a direct revelation mechanism, where each depositor announces his
private information or type to the planner. PS also use a direct revelation mechanism.
But for their more general economic environment, the direct revelation mechanism
may not be an optimal one. I pursue this idea by constructing an indirect mechanism
and show that it uniquely implements the best allocation, or at least an allocation
that is arbitrarily close to it. In other words, my indirect mechanism does not admit
a bank run equilibrium. This result reinforces an earlier observation: When deposit
contracts are appropriately designed, bank runs are hard to come by in the DiamondDybvig environment.
A bank run equilibrium can arise in a GL environment when depositors’ types
are correlated and allocations are implemented by a direct revelation mechanism,
see Ennis and Keister (2009b).1 Cavalcanti and Monteiri (2011) examine indirect
mechanisms in this environment and demonstrate that the best allocation can be
uniquely implemented in dominant strategies. Their backward induction argument,
however, will not work in the more general PS environment, where depositors do not
know their positions in the queue.2 The indirect mechanism that I construct can
uniquely implement the best allocation for either GL- and PS-type environments in
Nash equilibrium strategies.
The paper is organized as follows. The next section describes the economic environment. Section 3 characterizes the best implementable allocation. Sections 4 and 5
construct mechanisms that uniquely implements it. Some concluding comments are
o¤ered in the …nal section.

2

Environment

There are three dates: 0, 1 and 2. The economy is endowed with Y > 0 units of
date-1 goods. A constant returns to scale technology transforms y units of date-1
goods into yR > y units of date-2 goods.
There are N ex ante identical agents. An agent is one of two types t 2 T = f1; 2g:
patient, t = 1, or impatient, t = 2. The utility function for an impatient agent is
u (c1 ) and the utility function for a patient agent is v (c1 + c2 ), where c1 is date-1
1

GL assume that depositor types are identically and independently distributed.
Cavalcanti and Monteiri (2011) propose an alternative indirect mechanism when they examine
a PS environment. In one example, they show that their indirect mechanism uniquely implements
the best implementable allocation. However, in another example, their indirect mechanism has a
bank run equilibrium.
2

2

consumption and c2 is date-2 consumption. u and v are increasing, strictly concave,
and twice continuously di¤erentiable. Agents maximize expected utility.
The number of patient agents in economy is drawn from the probability distribution = ( 0 ; : : : ; N ), where n > 0, n 2 f1; : : : N g
N, is the probability that
there are n patient agents. A queue is the vector tN = (t1 ; : : : ; tN ) 2 T N , where
tk 2 T is the type of agent that occupies the k th position/coordinate in the queue.
Let Pn = tN 2 T N j#2 2 tN = n and Qn = jjtj = 2 for tN 2 Pn , where ‘#2’is
the number of patient agents. Pn is the set of queues with n patient agents and Qn is
the queue positions of the n patient agents in tN 2 Pn . The probability that tN 2 Pn
is n =#Pn = n = Nn , where #Pn is the number of queues tN 2 Pn . This speci…cation
implies that all potential queues with n patient agents are equally likely. Agents are
randomly assigned a position in the queue, where the (unconditional) probability that
an agent is assigned to position k is 1=N . For convenience, call the agent assigned to
position k agent k.
The queue realization, tN , is observed by no one: not by any of the agents nor
the planner. Each agent, however, privately observes his type t 2 T .
The timing of events and actions is as follows. At date 0, the planner constructs a
mechanism that determines how date-1 and date-2 consumption are allocated among
the N agents, and queue tN is realized. A mechanism is a set of announcements, M
and A, and a allocation rule, c = (c1 ; c2 ) where c1 = (c11 ; : : : c1N ) and c2 = (c21 ; : : : c2N ).
At date 1, agents sequentially meet the planner, starting with agent 1. In a meeting
with agent k, the planner announces ak 2 A and agent k responds with mk 2 M .
Only agent k and the planner can directly observe ak and mk . (But the planner
can reveal (ak ; mk ) to agent j
k via announcement aj , if he wishes.) There is
a sequential service constraint at date 1, which means the planner allocates date1 consumption to agent k 2 N based on the announcements of agents j
k, i.e.,
1
k 1
k 1
3
ck m ; mk , where m
= (m1 ; : : : ; mk 1 ). Agents consume the date-1 good at
their date-1 meetings with the planner. After all agents have met the planner, the
planner simultaneously allocates the date-2 consumption good to each agent based on
all of the date-1 announcements made by the agents, i.e., agent k receives c2k mN ,
where mN = (m1 ; : : : ; mN ) 2 M N .

3

Best Weakly Implementable Allocation

An allocation is weakly implementable is if it is an outcome to some equilibrium of
the mechanism; it is strongly (or uniquely) implementable if it is an outcome to every
equilibrium of the mechanism. Among the set of weakly implementable allocations,
the best weakly implementable allocation provides agents with the highest expected
3 1
ck

is also a function of ak . The notation in the text anticipates the result that the best implementable allocation is consistent with ak = ;, i.e., the planner does not make an announcement (or
does not reveal any information) to agents. As a result, the best implementable allocation is only a
function of agents’announcements.

3

utility. To characterize the best weakly implementable allocation, it is without loss of
generality to restrict the planner to use a direct revelation mechanism, where agents
make truthful announcement, mk = tk 2 M D = f1; 2g. The economy-wide welfare—
which is the expected utility of an agent before he learns his type— associated with
allocation rule c when agents use strategies mk 2 M D is
N
X
n=0

N
X X
n
U
N
n tN 2Pn k=1

c1k mk 1 ; mk ; c2k mN
1 ; tk ;

(1)

where
1
k 1
U c1k mk 1 ; mk ; c2k mN
; mk
1 ; tk = u ck m

if tk = 1

and
1
k 1
U c1k mk 1 ; mk ; c2k mN
; mk + c2k mN
1 ; tk = v ck m

if tk = 2

The allocation rule c is feasible, i.e., there exists su¢ cient resources to pay for c
for all mk 2 M D , k 2 N, if
!
N
N
X
X
1
k 1
c2k mN :
(2)
ck m ; mk
R Y
k=1

k=1

Allocation rule c must be incentive compatible in the sense that agent k has no
reason to announce mk 6= tk . Since impatient agent k only values date-1 consumption,
he always announces mk = 1.4 When A = ;,5 patient agent k has no incentive to
depart from the strategy mk = 2, assuming that all other agents j announce mj = tj ,
if
N
X

^n

n=1

N
X
n=1

^n

X 1 X
v c1k tk 1 ; 2 + c2k tk 1 ; 2; tN
k+1
n
N
k2Q

t 2Pn

n

X 1 X
v c1k tk 1 ; 1 + c2k tk 1 ; 1; tN
k+1
n
N
k2Q

t 2Pn

(3)

+ ;

n

4

This anticipates the result that the best weakly implementable allocation provides zero date-1
consumption to patient agents, which implies that the incentive compatibility constraint for impatient agents is always slack.
5
To characterize the best weakly implementable allocation, one wants to choose from the largest
possible set of incentive compatible allocations. This occurs when A = ;, i.e., the planner makes no
announcements. In particular, when A = ;, there is only one incentive compatibility constraint for
all patient agents, (3). When A 6= ;, there will be distinct incentive constraints for agents k who
receive information ak from the mechanism. For example, if ak = k, i.e., the planner announced to
each agent his place in the queue, then there would be N incentive compatability constraints for
patient agents; one for each queue position. Since an appropriately weighted average of these distinct
incentive constraints reduces to the single incentive constraint (3), the set of incentive compatible
allocations when A 6= ; is a subset of the set of incentive compatible allocations when A = ;.

4

where xji = (xi ; : : : ; xj ),

0 is a parameter, and
^ n = PN

N
n= n

n=1

N
n= n

is the conditional probability that agent k is in a speci…c queue that has n patient
agent. The 1=n terms that appear in (3) re‡ect that a patient agent has a 1=n chance
of occupying each of the patient queue positions in Qn .
Denote the solution to the problem
max (1) subject to (2) and (3);
c

(4)

where mk = tk for all k 2 N in (1) and (2),
as c ( ) = (c1 ( ) ; c2 ( )). When agents use truth-telling strategies, c ( ) has the
feature that impatient agents consume only at date 1 and patient agents consume
only at date 2. The best-weakly implementable allocation is c (0); the allocation
rule c (0) corresponds to the analysis contained in PS’s Appendix B.
Both PS and Ennis and Keister (2009b) demonstrate, by example, that mechanism
M D ; c (0) can have two equilibria: one where agents play truth-telling strategies,
mk = tk for all k 2 N, and another where agents play bank run strategies, mk = 1 for
all k 2 N.6 The bank run equilibria arise in these examples because the direct revelation mechanism M D ; c (0) is not an optimal mechanism. An optimal mechanism
may be a direct mechanism with A 6= ; or an indirect mechanism, (or both).

Direct Mechanisms with A 6= ;

4

When c (0) cannot be uniquely implemented by the direct mechanism M D ; c (0) ,
the optimal mechanism may be a direct mechanism with A 6= ;, i.e., A; M D ; c (0) .
Consider …rst the example provided by Ennis and Keister (2009b), where, as in PS,
agents do not know their place in the queue. Ennis and Keister (2009b) assume the
preference speci…cation of GL, which implies that incentive constraint (3) does not
bind for the allocation rule c (0). In addition, we know from GL that when A = N
and ak = k, i.e., the planner announces the agent’s position in the queue, none of
the N incentive compatibility constraints for patient agents bind for the allocation
rule c (0). This means that mechanism A = N; M D ; c (0) can weakly implement
the best allocation in c (0). And the main result of GL implies that mechanism
A = N; M D ; c (0) can strongly implement c (0). Therefore, A = N; M D ; c (0) is
an optimal mechanism; M D ; c (0) admits a bank run equilibrium only because it
is a suboptimal mechanism.
6

The Ennis and Keister (2009b) example that I refer to is their bank run example in section 4.2
of their paper, where agents do not know their position in the queue, as in PS, but where the utility
functions of patient and impatient agents are the same, as in GL.

5

Consider now the example provided by PS in their Appendix B. Nosal and Wallace
(2009) show that the best weakly implementable allocation, c (0), is not weakly implementable if the direct mechanism is characterized by A = N and M = f1; 2g. This
implies that the mechanism used by PS, M D ; c (0) , is an optimal direct mechanism.
But the optimal mechanism may not be a direct mechanism.

5

Indirect Mechanisms

Suppose that mechanism M D ; c (0) weakly, but not strongly, implements the best
allocation in c (0), and that mechanism A; M D ; c (0) , where A 6= ;, cannot weakly
implement the best allocation in c (0). Since a direct mechanism cannot uniquely
implement the best allocation in c (0), I construct an indirect mechanism that can
uniquely implement an allocation that is arbitrarily close to c (0), i.e., allocation
c ( ), where is arbitrarily close to zero.
The indirect mechanism M I ; c has M I 2 f1; 2; gg. One can think of the payo¤
associated with the announcement g as providing the depositor with a (minimum)
guaranteed payo¤ in date 2. This is in contrast to the date 2 payo¤ of agent k who
announces mk = 2 when allocation rule c (0) is in place; his minimum guaranteed
payo¤ is the lowest possible date-2 payo¤ associated with announcing mk = 2. Before I describe the payo¤s associated with announcements, the following notation is
needed. The allocation rule for the indirect mechanism is c = (c1 ; c2 ), and the date-s
payo¤ to agent j who announces mj is denoted as csj jmj . De…ne Z as the set of queue
positions for agents who announce g, i.e., Z = fjjmj = gg and #Z as the number
of agents in Z. De…ne m
^ k 1 as the message vector of length k 1 where for each
j k 1, m
^ j = 1 if either mj = 1 or mj = g, and m
^ j = 2 if mj = 2.
I now specify the allocation rule c for the indirect mechanism M I ; c . The basic
construction of c uses c ( ), where > 0 is arbitrarily small. To reduce notational
clutter I will suppress the ‘ ’when using allocations in c ( ) to describe c. If agent
j announces mj = g, then
c1j jg = 0

c2j jg = c1j

(5)
m
^ j 1 ; 1 (1 + "(#Z)) for all j; " > 0;

where 0 < " (1) < " (2) <
< " (#Z) <
< " (N ), and R > 1 + " (N ). The date-2
payo¤s are feasible since R > 1 + " (N ). Note that the date-2 payo¤ from announcing
mj = g is guaranteed to be at least c1j (mj 1 ; 1) (1 + " (1)). I will assume that " (N )
is arbitrarily small.
If agent j announces mj = 1, then
c1j j1 =

c1j (m
^ j 1 ; 1)
c1j (m
^ j 1 ; 1) +

c2j j1 = 0:
6

if j < N
;
if j = N

(6)

Allocation rule (5) has the feature that if some agents announce mk = g, then the
planner accumulates “excess goods” since R > 1 + " (j) for all j 2 N. The total
amount of this excess after all agents make their date-1 announcements, denoted as
, is
X (R 1 " (#Z)) c1 (m
^ z 1 ; 1)
z
:
=
R
z2Z
According to (6), agents who announce mk = 1 and occupy the …rst N 1 positions
in the queue receive the consumption payo¤ that they would get under the direct
revelation mechanism M D ; c ( ) , assuming that m
^ k 1 is used as the announcement
vector. Agent N who announces mN = 1 receives an additional consumption payment
of .
Finally, if agent j announces mj = 2, then
c1j j2 = 0;
c2j j2 =

(7)
m
^N
m
^N +

c2j
c2j

if j < N
:
R if j = N

The structure of the payments associated announcing mj = 2 resembles that of
announcing mj = 1, except that in the former positive payments are made at date
2 and in the latter at date 1. Note that the allocation rule (5)-(7) has the planner
sometimes throwing away goods. This happens when agent N announces mN = g.
Proposition 1 The indirect mechanism M I ; c uniquely implements in Nash equilibrium an allocation that is arbitrarily close to the best weakly implementable allocation in c (0).
Proof. First, there does not exist an equilibrium where all patient agents j randomize between announcing mj = 1 and mj = 2 or where all patient agents j announce mj = 1 with probability one. Suppose that such an equilibrium exists. Then,
suppose that patient agent k defects from proposed play and announces mk = g
with probability one. The payo¤ associated with this announcement, given by (5),
is c1k mk 1 ; 1 (1 + " (1)), which strictly exceeds the proposed equilibrium payment
associated with announcing mk = 1, c1k mk 1 ; 1 ; a contradiction.
Second, there does not exist an equilibrium where all patient agents j announce
mj = g with probability one. Suppose such an equilibrium exists. Then, the equilibrium expected utility to patient agent k is
N
X
n=1

^n

X 1 X
f
v c1k
n k2Q
N

t 2Pn

n

7

m
^ k 1 ; 1 (1 + " (n)) g:

(8)

Suppose that patient agent k defects from the proposed equilibrium and announces
mk = 1. Using (6), his expected utility is
N
X

^n

n=1

X 1 X
f
v[c1k
n
N
k2Q

t 2Pn

m
^ k 1; 1 +

X

(R

1

" (n

1)) c1j

m
^ j 1 ; 1 ]; (9)

j2Qn
j6=k;N

n

where
=

1 if k = N;
:
0 otherwise

Note that as " (N ) ! 0, the di¤erence between (9) and (8) is
N
X
n=2

^n

X 1 X
f
v[c1k
n
N
k2Q

t 2Pn

n

m
^ k 1; 1 +

X

j2Qn
j6=k;N

(R

1) c1j

m
^ j 1 ; 1 ] v c1k

m
^ k 1 ; 1 g > 0:

Hence, for any given N , , and R > 1, the mechanism can choose " (N ) > 0 su¢ ciently small so that the value of (9) strictly exceeds that of (8), a contradiction.
Third, there does not exist an equilibrium where patient agents j randomize over
announcing mj = g and other announcements. Suppose that the proposed equilibrium has patient agents announcing mj = g with probability g , where 0 < g < 1.
Since patient agent k randomizes he must be indi¤erent between announcing mk = g
and announcing mk = 1 and/or mk = 2, (depending on the speci…cation of the proposed equilibrium). However, given (5), if agent k announces mk = g with probability
one, he can increase his expected payo¤, compared to the proposed equilibrium payo¤, since the expected number of agents who announce mj = g increases compared to
the proposed equilibrium. Therefore, there cannot be an equilibrium where patient
people announce mj = g with probability g , where where 0 < g < 1.
Finally, consider an equilibrium where agents of type tj announce mj = tj with
probability one. Since > 0 in contract c ( ), incentive constraint (3) implies that all
patient agents j strictly prefer to announce mj = 2 to mj = 1. Note that patient agent
k strictly prefers to announce mk = g to mk = 1 when all other agents j 2 Nn fkg
announce mj = tj . But for any > 0, there exists an " (N ) > 0 su¢ ciently small
so that patient agent k strictly prefers announcing mk = 2 to mk = g, (since > 0
implies that agent k strictly prefers announcing mk = 2 to mk = 1). Therefore, for
> 0 arbitrarily small, c ( )
c (0), and the unique equilibrium for mechanism
I
M ; c is characterized by mj = tj for all j 2 N.
Agents do not know their positions in the queue for the indirect mechanism
M I ; c . Suppose that the economic environment is modi…ed so agents not only
learn their type, but they also (somehow) learn their position in the queue. Proposition 1 and the basic proof remains valid for the modi…ed economic environment,
where agents know their positions in the queue.7
7

Of course, the allocation rule c ( ) for the modi…ed environment may be di¤erent than the

8

6

Final Comments

In a way, the message that underlies this paper is a rather negative one: A well
designed deposit contract can prevent bank run equilibria in the classic DiamondDybvig environment. The message is negative because the Diamond-Dybvig model
is supposed to be a model of banking instability. Green and Lin (2000, 2003) conjectured that the overlapping generations nature of depositors in the real world and/or
moral hazard associated with the people who operate banks may prevent agents from
using e¢ cient mechanisms, which has implications for banking instability. These
conjectures, unfortunately, do not appear to supported by subsequent research.8 An
important assumption in the Diamond-Dybvig environment is that the planner can
ex ante commit to implement contract allocations. Relaxing this assumption may
result in bank run equilibria; see, for example, Ennis and Keister (2009a). Perhaps
assuming that agents cannot not fully commit is a fruitful avenue for future work.

References
[1] Andolfatto, David, and Nosal, Ed. “Bank Incentives, Contract Design and Bank
Runs,”J. Econ.Theory 142 (2008): 28-47.
[2] Cavalcanti, Ricardo, de O., and Monteiri, Paulo, K. “Enriching Information to
Prevent Bank Runs.”manuscript, February 2011.
[3] Diamond, Douglas, and Dybvig, Phillip. “Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and
Liquidity.”J.P.E. 91 (June 1983): 401-19.
[4] Ennis, Huberto, M., and Keister, Todd. “Bank Runs and Institutions: The Perils
of Intervention,”A.E.R. 99 (2009a): 1588-1607.
[5] Ennis, Huberto, M., and Keister, Todd. “Run Equilibria in the Green-Lin Model
of Financial Intermediation.”J. Econ. Theory 144 (2009b): 1996-2020.
[6] Green, Edward J., and Lin, Ping. “Diamond and Dybvig’s Classic Theory of
Financial Intermediation: What’s Missing?” Fed Res. Bank of Minn. Quarterly
Review 24 Winter (2000): 3-13.
solution to (4). The best weakly implementable allocation for the new environment is given by
maxc (1) subject to (2) and N incentive compatibility constraints, one for each patient agent in
position j 2 N in the queue.
8
The Peck and Shell (2003) can be interpreted as a way of modeling overlapping generations in
the sense that there is no “last” depositor in an overlapping generations model, and in Peck and
Shell (2003) depositors do not know if they are the last depositor. Andolfatto and Nosal (2008)
assume that one of the agents operates the bank in a Diamond-Dybvig environment, and …nd that
there do no exist bank run equilibria.

9

[7] Green, Edward J., and Lin, Ping. “Implementing Allocations in a Model of Financial Intermediation,”J. Econ. Theory 109 (2003): 1-23.
[8] Nosal, Ed, and Wallace, Neil. “Information Revelation in the Diamond-Dybvig
Banking Model.” Policy Discussion Paper no. 7, Chicago, IL: Fed. Res. Bank of
Chicago, December 2009.
[9] Peck, James, and Shell, Karl. “Equilibrium Bank Runs.”J.P.E. 111 (2003): 10323.

10

Working Paper Series
A series of research studies on regional economic issues relating to the Seventh Federal
Reserve District, and on financial and economic topics.
A Leverage-based Model of Speculative Bubbles
Gadi Barlevy

WP-08-01

Displacement, Asymmetric Information and Heterogeneous Human Capital
Luojia Hu and Christopher Taber

WP-08-02

BankCaR (Bank Capital-at-Risk): A credit risk model for US commercial bank charge-offs
Jon Frye and Eduard Pelz

WP-08-03

Bank Lending, Financing Constraints and SME Investment
Santiago Carbó-Valverde, Francisco Rodríguez-Fernández, and Gregory F. Udell

WP-08-04

Global Inflation
Matteo Ciccarelli and Benoît Mojon

WP-08-05

Scale and the Origins of Structural Change
Francisco J. Buera and Joseph P. Kaboski

WP-08-06

Inventories, Lumpy Trade, and Large Devaluations
George Alessandria, Joseph P. Kaboski, and Virgiliu Midrigan

WP-08-07

School Vouchers and Student Achievement: Recent Evidence, Remaining Questions
Cecilia Elena Rouse and Lisa Barrow

WP-08-08

Does It Pay to Read Your Junk Mail? Evidence of the Effect of Advertising on
Home Equity Credit Choices
Sumit Agarwal and Brent W. Ambrose

WP-08-09

The Choice between Arm’s-Length and Relationship Debt: Evidence from eLoans
Sumit Agarwal and Robert Hauswald

WP-08-10

Consumer Choice and Merchant Acceptance of Payment Media
Wilko Bolt and Sujit Chakravorti

WP-08-11

Investment Shocks and Business Cycles
Alejandro Justiniano, Giorgio E. Primiceri, and Andrea Tambalotti

WP-08-12

New Vehicle Characteristics and the Cost of the
Corporate Average Fuel Economy Standard
Thomas Klier and Joshua Linn

WP-08-13

Realized Volatility
Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

WP-08-14

Revenue Bubbles and Structural Deficits: What’s a state to do?
Richard Mattoon and Leslie McGranahan

WP-08-15

1

Working Paper Series (continued)
The role of lenders in the home price boom
Richard J. Rosen

WP-08-16

Bank Crises and Investor Confidence
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-08-17

Life Expectancy and Old Age Savings
Mariacristina De Nardi, Eric French, and John Bailey Jones

WP-08-18

Remittance Behavior among New U.S. Immigrants
Katherine Meckel

WP-08-19

Birth Cohort and the Black-White Achievement Gap:
The Roles of Access and Health Soon After Birth
Kenneth Y. Chay, Jonathan Guryan, and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-08-20

Public Investment and Budget Rules for State vs. Local Governments
Marco Bassetto

WP-08-21

Why Has Home Ownership Fallen Among the Young?
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Martin Gervais

WP-09-01

Why do the Elderly Save? The Role of Medical Expenses
Mariacristina De Nardi, Eric French, and John Bailey Jones

WP-09-02

Using Stock Returns to Identify Government Spending Shocks
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Ryan Peters

WP-09-03

Stochastic Volatility
Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

WP-09-04

The Effect of Disability Insurance Receipt on Labor Supply
Eric French and Jae Song

WP-09-05

CEO Overconfidence and Dividend Policy
Sanjay Deshmukh, Anand M. Goel, and Keith M. Howe

WP-09-06

Do Financial Counseling Mandates Improve Mortgage Choice and Performance?
Evidence from a Legislative Experiment
Sumit Agarwal,Gene Amromin, Itzhak Ben-David, Souphala Chomsisengphet,
and Douglas D. Evanoff

WP-09-07

Perverse Incentives at the Banks? Evidence from a Natural Experiment
Sumit Agarwal and Faye H. Wang

WP-09-08

Pay for Percentile
Gadi Barlevy and Derek Neal

WP-09-09

The Life and Times of Nicolas Dutot
François R. Velde

WP-09-10

Regulating Two-Sided Markets: An Empirical Investigation
Santiago Carbó Valverde, Sujit Chakravorti, and Francisco Rodriguez Fernandez

WP-09-11

2

Working Paper Series (continued)
The Case of the Undying Debt
François R. Velde
Paying for Performance: The Education Impacts of a Community College Scholarship
Program for Low-income Adults
Lisa Barrow, Lashawn Richburg-Hayes, Cecilia Elena Rouse, and Thomas Brock
Establishments Dynamics, Vacancies and Unemployment: A Neoclassical Synthesis
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-09-12

WP-09-13

WP-09-14

The Price of Gasoline and the Demand for Fuel Economy:
Evidence from Monthly New Vehicles Sales Data
Thomas Klier and Joshua Linn

WP-09-15

Estimation of a Transformation Model with Truncation,
Interval Observation and Time-Varying Covariates
Bo E. Honoré and Luojia Hu

WP-09-16

Self-Enforcing Trade Agreements: Evidence from Antidumping Policy
Chad P. Bown and Meredith A. Crowley

WP-09-17

Too much right can make a wrong: Setting the stage for the financial crisis
Richard J. Rosen

WP-09-18

Can Structural Small Open Economy Models Account
for the Influence of Foreign Disturbances?
Alejandro Justiniano and Bruce Preston

WP-09-19

Liquidity Constraints of the Middle Class
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-09-20

Monetary Policy and Uncertainty in an Empirical Small Open Economy Model
Alejandro Justiniano and Bruce Preston

WP-09-21

Firm boundaries and buyer-supplier match in market transaction:
IT system procurement of U.S. credit unions
Yukako Ono and Junichi Suzuki
Health and the Savings of Insured Versus Uninsured, Working-Age Households in the U.S.
Maude Toussaint-Comeau and Jonathan Hartley

WP-09-22

WP-09-23

The Economics of “Radiator Springs:” Industry Dynamics, Sunk Costs, and
Spatial Demand Shifts
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Thomas N. Hubbard

WP-09-24

On the Relationship between Mobility, Population Growth, and
Capital Spending in the United States
Marco Bassetto and Leslie McGranahan

WP-09-25

The Impact of Rosenwald Schools on Black Achievement
Daniel Aaronson and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-09-26

3

Working Paper Series (continued)
Comment on “Letting Different Views about Business Cycles Compete”
Jonas D.M. Fisher

WP-10-01

Macroeconomic Implications of Agglomeration
Morris A. Davis, Jonas D.M. Fisher and Toni M. Whited

WP-10-02

Accounting for non-annuitization
Svetlana Pashchenko

WP-10-03

Robustness and Macroeconomic Policy
Gadi Barlevy

WP-10-04

Benefits of Relationship Banking: Evidence from Consumer Credit Markets
Sumit Agarwal, Souphala Chomsisengphet, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles

WP-10-05

The Effect of Sales Tax Holidays on Household Consumption Patterns
Nathan Marwell and Leslie McGranahan

WP-10-06

Gathering Insights on the Forest from the Trees: A New Metric for Financial Conditions
Scott Brave and R. Andrew Butters

WP-10-07

Identification of Models of the Labor Market
Eric French and Christopher Taber

WP-10-08

Public Pensions and Labor Supply Over the Life Cycle
Eric French and John Jones

WP-10-09

Explaining Asset Pricing Puzzles Associated with the 1987 Market Crash
Luca Benzoni, Pierre Collin-Dufresne, and Robert S. Goldstein

WP-10-10

Prenatal Sex Selection and Girls’ Well‐Being: Evidence from India
Luojia Hu and Analía Schlosser

WP-10-11

Mortgage Choices and Housing Speculation
Gadi Barlevy and Jonas D.M. Fisher

WP-10-12

Did Adhering to the Gold Standard Reduce the Cost of Capital?
Ron Alquist and Benjamin Chabot

WP-10-13

Introduction to the Macroeconomic Dynamics:
Special issues on money, credit, and liquidity
Ed Nosal, Christopher Waller, and Randall Wright

WP-10-14

Summer Workshop on Money, Banking, Payments and Finance: An Overview
Ed Nosal and Randall Wright

WP-10-15

Cognitive Abilities and Household Financial Decision Making
Sumit Agarwal and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-10-16

Complex Mortgages
Gene Amromin, Jennifer Huang, Clemens Sialm, and Edward Zhong

WP-10-17

4

Working Paper Series (continued)
The Role of Housing in Labor Reallocation
Morris Davis, Jonas Fisher, and Marcelo Veracierto

WP-10-18

Why Do Banks Reward their Customers to Use their Credit Cards?
Sumit Agarwal, Sujit Chakravorti, and Anna Lunn

WP-10-19

The impact of the originate-to-distribute model on banks
before and during the financial crisis
Richard J. Rosen

WP-10-20

Simple Markov-Perfect Industry Dynamics
Jaap H. Abbring, Jeffrey R. Campbell, and Nan Yang

WP-10-21

Commodity Money with Frequent Search
Ezra Oberfield and Nicholas Trachter

WP-10-22

Corporate Average Fuel Economy Standards and the Market for New Vehicles
Thomas Klier and Joshua Linn

WP-11-01

The Role of Securitization in Mortgage Renegotiation
Sumit Agarwal, Gene Amromin, Itzhak Ben-David, Souphala Chomsisengphet,
and Douglas D. Evanoff

WP-11-02

Market-Based Loss Mitigation Practices for Troubled Mortgages
Following the Financial Crisis
Sumit Agarwal, Gene Amromin, Itzhak Ben-David, Souphala Chomsisengphet,
and Douglas D. Evanoff

WP-11-03

Federal Reserve Policies and Financial Market Conditions During the Crisis
Scott A. Brave and Hesna Genay

WP-11-04

The Financial Labor Supply Accelerator
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-11-05

Survival and long-run dynamics with heterogeneous beliefs under recursive preferences
Jaroslav Borovička

WP-11-06

A Leverage-based Model of Speculative Bubbles (Revised)
Gadi Barlevy

WP-11-07

Estimation of Panel Data Regression Models with Two-Sided Censoring or Truncation
Sule Alan, Bo E. Honoré, Luojia Hu, and Søren Leth–Petersen

WP-11-08

Fertility Transitions Along the Extensive and Intensive Margins
Daniel Aaronson, Fabian Lange, and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-11-09

Black-White Differences in Intergenerational Economic Mobility in the US
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-11-10

Can Standard Preferences Explain the Prices of Out-of-the-Money S&P 500 Put Options?
Luca Benzoni, Pierre Collin-Dufresne, and Robert S. Goldstein

WP-11-11

5

Working Paper Series (continued)
Business Networks, Production Chains, and Productivity:
A Theory of Input-Output Architecture
Ezra Oberfield
Equilibrium Bank Runs Revisited
Ed Nosal

WP-11-12

WP-11-13

6