View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Earnings Inequality and the Business
Cycle
Gadi Barlevy and Daniel Tsiddon

WP 2004-08

Earnings Inequality and the Business Cycle¤
Gadi Barlevy

Daniel Tsiddon

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
230 South La Salle
Chicago, IL 60604
USA

Department of Economics
Tel Aviv University
Tel Aviv, 69978
Israel

and

and

NBER

CEPR
April 27, 2004

Abstract
Economists have long viewed recessions as contributing to increasing inequality. However, this conclusion is largely based on data from a period in which inequality was increasing
over time. This paper examines the connection between long-run trends and cyclical variation in earnings inequality. We develop a model in which cyclical and trend inequality are
related, and …nd that in our model, recessions tend to amplify long-run trends, i.e. they
involve more rapidly increasing inequality more when long-run inequality is increasing, and
more rapidly decreasing inequality when long-run inequality is decreasing. In support of this
prediction, we present evidence that during the …rst half of the 20th Century when earnings
inequality was generally declining, earnings disparities indeed appeared to fall more rapidly
in downturns, at least among workers at the top of the earnings distribution.

¤

The authors would like to acknowledge Boyan Jovanovic and Kiminori Matsuyama for useful discussions,
and for seminar participants at Northwestern, Tel Aviv, the Chicago Fed, and the NBER. We would also like
to thank Zvi Eckstein and two anonymous referees for their suggestions on improving the paper. The views
expressed here do not necessarily re‡ect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal
Reserve System.

Introduction
In recent years, economists have resurrected the question of how earnings inequality evolves
over the business cycle. While this question was raised long ago by economists concerned with
the impact of downturns on the poor, the renewed interest in this question comes instead from
economists concerned with whether earnings are more volatile in recessions, which would imply
greater earnings dispersion in recessions. Conventional wisdom based on the last 40 years
suggests both wage and income inequality rise during recessions. However, it is also well-known
that this same period was characterized by a dramatic secular increase in earnings inequality.
Should we be concerned that the evidence for increasing inequality during recessions comes
from a period in which inequality was generally increasing? Are changes in inequality over the
cycle related to whatever forces are driving long-run trends in the earnings distribution?
This paper tackles these questions by introducing cyclical ‡uctuations into a model of secular
changes in earnings inequality. We …nd that recessions in our model serve to amplify longrun trends in inequality, rather than necessarily contributing to greater inequality. That is,
recessions contribute to more rapid growth in earnings inequality in periods of rising inequality,
but they accelerate the fall in earnings disparities in periods of declining inequality. Focusing
on a period of rising inequality may therefore overstate the extent to which recessions involve
increased earnings inequality.
To assess the plausibility of our assertion that business cycles need not have a uniform
impact on the distribution of earnings, we look back in history to a period in which inequality
was secularly decreasing, namely the period from the late 1920s to the early 1950s. According
to our model, we should observe that economic downturns during this period, notably the
Depression of 1929-1932 and the subsequent recession of 1937, were associated with a more
rapid decline in earnings dispersion among employed workers, speci…cally among workers at the
top of the wage distribution. We assemble various pieces of evidence that suggest inequality
among employed workers at the top of the earnings distribution indeed decreased more rapidly
during these downturns. This stands in sharp contrast with the e¤ect of downturns that both
preceded and proceeded this period, when inequality was generally increasing. Of course,
given the limitations on the data and the exceptional nature of the Great Depression as a
historical episode, these patterns are at best suggestive rather than conclusive proof of our
assertion. Moreover, both our model and our empirical analysis ignore unemployment and other
considerations that systematically contribute to higher inequality in recessions. Nevertheless,
our results suggest long-run trends in earnings inequality may be relevant for how cyclical
‡uctuations ultimately e¤ect the distribution of earnings.
1

Interestingly, our …ndings raise questions about a growing strand of literature which argues
that countercyclical earnings volatility, and hence countercyclical earnings inequality, can help
to resolve some key macroeconomic puzzles. For example, Mankiw (1986), Constantinides and
Du¢e (1996), Heaton and Lucas (1996), and Storesletten, Telmer, and Yaron (2003) argue that
if incomes are more volatile in recessions, equities whose dividends are correlated with aggregate
income would command large premia even among moderately risk-averse agents, since the return
on equity is low precisely when income risk is greatest. Thus, a strong countercyclical pattern
in inequality can potentially explain the puzzlingly high equity premium in the U.S. From a
di¤erent angle, Imrohoroglu (1989), Storesletten, Telmer, and Yaron (2001), and Krebs (2003)
argue that if earnings are more volatile during recessions, consumption risk over the cycle would
be larger than the volatility of per-capita consumption, so cycles will be more costly than the
puzzlingly low cost computed by Lucas (1987). Since our …ndings suggest that recent data may
overstate the contribution of recessions to inequality, claims regarding the quantitative success
of these theories may need to be revisited.
The paper is organized as follows. Section 1 develops the model and our theoretical results.
Section 2 provides empirical support for the prediction of our model. Section 3 concludes.

1. A Model of Earnings Inequality
We begin by developing a model which we can use to explore the connection between trend
inequality and cyclical variation in inequality. We model trend inequality as being driven by
technological change, in line with recent work that identi…es technical change as a key factor
behind the rising inequality of the last few decades. More precisely, we model an economy
that undergoes waves of drastic technological innovation, i.e. every so often a new mode of
production becomes available. This new mode is fundamentally incompatible with previous
technologies and renders any knowledge associated with them obsolete. Examples of such
innovations include the electri…cation and mechanization of production in the early 20th century
and computerization in the late 20th century. The reason such technological changes can a¤ect
the distribution of earnings is that agents typically di¤er in the rate at which they incorporate
the new technology. As a result, when a technology …rst arrives, those who are quick to absorb it
will increase their earnings and drift apart from their slower counterparts. Eventually, laggards
will catch up as the new technology becomes di¤use, and earnings disparities decline until the
next technology arrives. Over the life span of each new technology, then, inequality will …rst rise
and then fall, much as Kuznets (1955) conjectured should be the natural course for a developing
economy. Our model is thus similar to Galor and Tsiddon (1997), Greenwood and Yorukoglu
2

(1997), and Caselli (1999), who also argue that technical change should …rst raise inequality and
then lower it. However, our modelling approach makes the introduction of cyclical ‡uctuations
easier.
For expositional purposes, we only track the life span of a single technology. That is, assuming
a new technology arrives at date t = 0, we solve for the outcome that would prevail at any date
t > 0 assuming this technology is still in use. Implicitly, we have in mind that new technologies
arrive stochastically at a constant rate, and that our analysis describes the evolution of the
economy conditional on no new technology having arrived. When a new technology does arrive,
our assumption that it renders all previous knowledge obsolete implies we can reset the clock
to t = 0 and restart the process.
We assume labor is the only factor of production and is supplied by a continuum of workers.
The productivity of each worker depends on how adept he is in the new technology. Formally,
let sit 2 [0; 1) denote worker i’s skill level at date t. Heuristically, sit can be viewed as the
number of tasks worker i can perform using the new technology. Alternatively, sit could re‡ect
how intensively worker i’s job at date t makes use of the new technology; a higher sit implies
the worker makes greater use of the new technology, e.g. he starts to work with an electric
motor or a computer, either on his current job or by moving to a new job that makes use of
such technologies. A worker’s productivity depends on his s, in a way to be made precise below.
All individuals start out with the same skill level at date t = 0 when the technology is …rst
introduced, i.e. si0 = s0 for all i. However, they can become more adept at using this technology
over time. We model this process as in Ben-Porath (1967). That is, each individual has a unit
of time each instant that he can allocate to either production or becoming more pro…cient in
the new technology. Let nit 2 [0; 1] denote the fraction of time that individual i spends on
becoming pro…cient, i.e. the time he spends learning new tasks or searching for a job that is
more intensive in the new technology. The remaining 1 ¡ nit is allocated to working. Worker
i’s output at date t is given by
yit = zt sit (1 ¡ nit)
(1.1)
where zt denotes the productivity of the underlying technology. Thus, the more pro…cient a
worker is in the new technology, as re‡ected by a higher sit , the more productive he will be. For
now, we assume zt is constant over time, i.e. zt = Z for all t, so we can study secular paths of
inequality. In a more general framework each new invention would have been associated with a
higher value for Z. However, given that we only track a single technology how Z varies across
technologies is irrelevant . There is free entry in using technology (1.1), so workers earn their

3

marginal product in equilibrium. That is, individual i will earn a wage of wit = Zsit per unit
of labor, for an income yit = Zsit (1 ¡ nit ).
Time spent acquiring additional skills contributes to sit according to the technology
s_it = ai (sit nit)b

(1.2)

where ai > 0 measures the speed at which individual i learns new skills, and b 2 (0; 1) is a
constant common to all individuals. The more time the worker devotes to acquiring skills, the
more quickly his sit will rise, albeit at a diminishing rate. The rate at which an individual
becomes skilled also depends on how many skills he already knows, i.e. past familiarity with
the technology aids in accumulating further skills.
Two features of the above technology are essential for our results. First, individuals di¤er
in their speed of learning ai , i.e. some individuals are inherently quicker to adapt to the
new technology. This will drive the dynamics of inequality in earnings across workers. Second,
accumulating new skills requires time away from production, so the opportunity cost of learning
is the value of producing output. This feature will be especially important when we introduce
cyclical ‡uctuations. The fact that it is workers and not employers who adapt to the new
technology is not in itself essential. Of course, in our model there is no incentive for employers
to raise their workers’ productivity, so only workers would ever undertake such investments.1
But as Acemoglu and Pischke (1999) note, there are various labor market frictions we could
introduce that would allow employers to bene…t from having a more productive worker, in which
case employers would have incentive to raise the productivity of their workers. As long as …rms
invest in upgrading the skill of di¤erent workers at di¤erent rates and the opportunity cost of
such investments involves foregone production, our intuition should still go through.
So far, our model is identical to Ben-Porath (1967). However, we introduce one key modi…cation, namely that sit is bounded above by some …nite s. Formally, we replace (1.2) with
½
a (sn)b if s < s
s_ =
(1.3)
0
if s = s
This assumption implies there is only so much one can get out of a technology; in the long
run, sustained growth requires the advent of new technologies. For our purposes, the relevant
feature of this assumption is that it introduces diminishing returns to skill, i.e. the return to
learning additional skills beyond s drops to zero. More moderate degrees of diminishing returns
1

For a more in depth discussion of who would undertake investment in general skills, see Becker (1975).

4

should similarly lead quicker workers to eventually slow down and allow their slower colleagues
to catch up, and this is the feature we require of our model.2
If individuals are risk-neutral and share a common discount rate ½, each will choose to
maximize the present discounted value of his income. Thus, the worker’s problem is given by
Z1
max
Zst (1 ¡ nt ) e¡½t dt
(1.4)
nt

0

subject to

1: 0 · nt · 1
½
a (sn)b if s < s
2: s_ =
0
if s = s
3: Initial condition s0

To solve (1.4), note that when st = s, there is no point to learning, so it is optimal to set
nt = 0. An individual will earn a constant ‡ow Zs, which discounted at rate ½ implies that the
present discounted utility of an agent for whom s = s and who solves (1.4) is given by
V (s) =

Zs
½

(1.5)

For s < s, we apply dynamic programming to solve the worker’s maximization problem. The
present discounted utility V (s) of an optimizing agent with a current level of skills s is governed
by the asset equation
n
o
½V (s) = max Zs (1 ¡ n) + V 0 (s) a (sn)b
n

Setting aside momentarily the constraint that 0 · nt · 1, the …rst-order condition for the
above maximization is given by
µ
¶ 1
abV 0 (s) 1¡b
sn =
Z
This optimum necessarily satis…es the condition that nt ¸ 0. As long as s is su¢ciently large,
one can show that it will also be true that nt · 1. We will henceforth assume that s0 is
su¢ciently large to insure an interior optimum. Substituting back into the asset equation
yields a non-linear di¤erential equation

2

¡
¢ 1
½V (s) = Zs + m V 0(s) 1¡b

(1.6)

With a uniform bound s, all workers earn the same wage asymptotically. Our results would go through if
we assumed each individual has his own ceiling si , as long as we do it in such a way that those who are quicker
to learn reach their ceilings …rst. In that case, earnings inequality would still fall eventually, but the distribution
of wages would converge to a non-degenerate distribution.

5

· ¸ 1
1 ¡ b ab 1¡b
where m =
, with (1.5) as its boundary condition. To solve this di¤erential
b
Zb
equation, it will be easier to work with the variable
x (s) = V (s) ¡

Zs
½

The variable x(s) has an economic interpretation: it is the value of the option to learn additional skills when the current skill level is s. This is because if the agent were prevented from
learning any additional skills, he would allocate all of his time endowment to work, giving him
Zs
a discounted utility of
. The di¤erence between this and V (s) must then re‡ect how much
½
the worker would pay to acquire skills beyond s. After some algebraic manipulation, we can
rewrite (1.6) as a di¤erential equation in terms of x (s):
dx (s)
=
ds

µ

½x (s)
m

¶1¡b

¡

Z
½

(1.7)

with a boundary condition x (s) = 0. As illustrated in the Appendix, we can use the …rst
condition above to express s_ in terms of the value of learning x (s):
s_ = a

1
1¡b

b µ
· ¸ 1¡b
¶
b
½x (s) b
Z
m

(1.8)

The above equation has an appealing interpretation, namely that individuals accumulate more
skills when the option to acquire additional skills is more valuable, i.e. when x (s) is larger.
In the Appendix, we solve the dynamical system comprised of (1.7) and (1.8) and use it to
characterize the optimal path. Our results are summarized in the following Proposition:
Proposition 1: For any a > 0, the solution to (1.4) implies
1. The path of the skill level st is concave in t.
2. There exists a Ti < 1 such that sit = s for all t ¸ Ti.

3. For any two individuals i and j where ai > aj, sit ¸ sjt for all t, with strict inequality
when sit 2 (s0; s).

Figure 1 depicts these results graphically. Panel (a) illustrates the skill paths for several
individuals with di¤erent ai . Each accumulates s at a declining rate over time. To appreciate
why, note that one reason for accumulating s is to facilitate accumulating skills in the future
(recall that s_ is increasing in s). As agents draw near s and anticipate they will soon stop
learning, the incentives to accumulate skills are naturally smaller. The more able workers
proceed to s at a faster average rate than the less able workers. As a result, the distribution
6

of skills across workers, which at t = 0 corresponds to a mass point at s0 , fans out as workers
accumulate skills at di¤erent average rates, then collapses back to a mass point at s. Panel (b)
illustrates the same paths, but with the skill level of each individual depicted relative to the
skill level of the least able worker in the population, infj sj t. Note that the skill distribution
can simultaneously become less disperse at the top and more disperse at the bottom, i.e. the
relative skill of those at the top can fall at the same time as the relative skill of those in the
middle of the distribution rise. Thus, it may not be possible to generically characterize trends
in inequality across all agents in our model, and the only precise statements we can make is
about inequality between any two given workers (or any two workers in given percentiles of the
relevant distribution). When we later take our model to the data, we will de…ne a period of
declining inequality as one in which those at the top of the distribution fall relative to those
further down the distribution, as illustrated in Panel (b). As such, we will need to focus on the
relative earnings of those at the top of the distribution.
To relate inequality in skills to inequality in earnings, recall that the wage of individual i is
equal to wit = Zsit. Thus, wages are proportional to skills, and the ratio of the wages of any
two individuals is equal to the ratio of their skill levels, so inequality in wages as measured by
wage ratios is identical to inequality in skills. From Proposition 1, wage inequality between any
two workers will …rst rise and then fall over the lifetime of a given technology.
The evolution of income inequality is a bit more involved, but follows a roughly similar
pattern. At date t = 0 when the technology …rst arrives, all agents earn the same wage Zs0,
but the more able workers spend more time accumulating skills so their income Zs0 (1 ¡ ni0)
is lower. Thus, initially the most able workers will earn the lowest incomes. But this pattern is
quickly reversed since the incomes of the most able individuals grow faster on average. At that
point, the income of those at the top of the distribution will drift apart from the incomes of
those further down the distribution, although eventually the latter catch up to them and income
inequality will disappear. Abstracting from early transitional dynamics, income inequality is
thus parallel to wage inequality: there is a distinct phase in which income disparities increase
over time, followed by another distinct phase in which they decrease over time.
To summarize, our model gives rise to secular trends in earnings inequality, …rst rising and
then falling. What we are ultimately interested in, though, is how these trends interact with
cyclical ‡uctuations. To allow for ‡uctuations, we let zt vary stochastically over time; in
particular, zt can assume two values, Z0 < Z1 , and switches between the two values at a
constant rate ¹ per unit of time. Our decision to model cyclical ‡uctuations this way does
not imply we view productivity shocks as the unique source of aggregate ‡uctuations. Instead,
7

our motivation comes from the fact that skill accumulation is driving changes in earnings
distribution in our model, and the rate at which individuals accumulate skills depends on the
behavior of wages. Since in our model wages depend on productivity, it is only natural to model
cyclical ‡uctuations as productivity shocks. Recessions in our model correspond to periods of
low productivity, so wages are procyclical, in line with micro evidence from the past 30 years,
e.g. Solon, Barsky, and Parker (1994).
Admittedly, our approach is stylized and abstracts from important considerations such as
unemployment distribution. However, such considerations are not important for the particular
channel we focus on. Still, it is useful to keep in mind that any predictions that emerge from
our model will only be relevant for the distribution of earnings across stably employed workers
rather than across the labor force as a whole.
When zt follows a stochastic process, each worker will act to maximize his expected present
discounted value of income, i.e. he will solve
·Z 1
¸
¡½t
max Et
zt st (1 ¡ nt ) e dt
(1.9)
nt

0

subject to

1: 0 · nt · 1
½
a (sn)b if s < s
2: s_ =
0
if s = s

3: zt follows a Markov process
4: Initial conditions z0 ; s0
where nt is measurable with respect to fz¿ gt¿ =0 . We …rst show that along the optimal path,
an individual will accumulate skills at a more rapid pace in recessions, i.e. when zt = Z0. The
proof of this, and all remaining propositions, is contained in an Appendix.
Proposition 2: For any realized path fz¿ g¿ 2[0;t) , the solution to (1.9) dictates more rapid
skill accumulation at date t if aggregate productivity at date t is low, i.e.
s_it jzt =Z0 ¸ s_ it jzt=Z1
The intuition for this result is based on an intertemporal substitution argument: since the
opportunity cost of accumulating skills is lower in recessions, it is better to concentrate skill
accumulation in periods of low productivity and rent our labor services for a high price in periods
of high productivity.3 While we have no direct evidence if this is how technology-speci…c skills
3

Dellas and Sakellaris (2003) show in a similar model of human capital accumulation that it is optimal to

8

are accumulated over the cycle, other forms of human capital accumulation do indeed appear
to be countercyclical. For example, Betts and McFarland (1995) document signi…cant increases
in enrollment in two-year colleges during recessions. Dellas and Sakellaris (2003) look at the
fraction of 18-22 year old who report attending college and …nd it to be strongly countercyclical,
especially in two-year colleges and among part-time students. Sepulveda (2002) …nds evidence
that time spent in formal training, either employer-provided training or o¤-site training, is
likewise negatively correlated with various cyclical indicators.
Since skill accumulation ultimately drives long-run changes in earnings inequality, the fact
that recessions encourage more rapid skill accumulation suggests changes in the distribution
of earnings would simply be accelerated in recessions. Intuitively, in times of rising inequality,
more able workers would presumably have more incentive to take advantage of downturns to
accumulate skills, and earnings disparities would grow at a faster rate. Conversely, in times of
falling inequality, the less able workers would catch up more quickly to those who have already
mastered the new technology. We now con…rm these conjectures formally.
Turning …rst to the case of rising inequality, we proceed by analyzing the special case of the
model where there is no upper bound, i.e. s = 1. This case can be solved analytically. As
the next proposition shows, for s = 1 individuals will never cease learning, and as a result less
able workers never catch up to their more able colleagues. Thus, the model exhibits rising skill
and wage inequality, and one can show that this secular increase in inequality is accelerated in
recessions.
Proposition 3: Consider two individuals i and j where ai > aj , both of whom face the
maximization problem (1.4). If s = 1, we have
1. For any path fz¿ g¿2[0;1) , the ratio
to a …nite upper bound

wit
is increasing and continuous in t and converges
wjt

wit
lim
=
t!1 wjt

µ

ai
aj

1
¶ 1¡b

>1

2. Wage inequality grows more rapidly in recessions, i.e. for any path fz¿ g¿2[0;t) ,
µ
¶¯
µ
¶¯
d wit ¯¯
d wit ¯¯
>
>0
dt wjt ¯zt=Z0
dt wjt ¯zt =Z1

accumulate skills in recessions. The notion that recessions encourage investment in growth-enhacing activities
has also been raised by Hall (1991), Cooper and Haltiwanger (1993), and Aghion and Saint Paul (1998). However,
none of the above addresses the implications of such results for inequality.

9

Returning to the case where s is …nite, one can show that the model exhibits the following
‘turnpike’ property: for a …xed s0 and any " > 0, there exists some …nite s such that the optimal
path fnt g will be within an "-neighborhood of the optimal path fntg for the case of s = 1,
except for some …nal time period. Thus, one can extend the result a period of rising inequality
will be associated with more rapidly increasing inequality during recessions to the case where
the level of skills is strictly bounded above, as long as it is su¢ciently larger than s0.4
Next, we turn to the case of decreasing inequality. Here, we can establish that recessions will
have the opposite e¤ect, i.e. if wage di¤erentials between two individuals are decreasing, they
will decrease at an ever faster rate when zt = Z0:
Proposition 4: Consider two individuals i and j where ai > aj . Then sit ¸ sjt for all t,
with strict inequality if s0 < sit < s. Moreover, there exists an " > 0 such that
1. If jsit ¡ sj = ", then

wit
decreases with t for any continuation path fzs g1
s=t .
wjt

2. Wage inequality declines more rapidly in recessions, i.e. for any realized path fz¿ g ¿2[0;t) ,
if sit ¸ s ¡ ", then

d
dt

µ

¶¯
µ
¶¯
wit ¯¯
d wit ¯¯
<
<0
wjt ¯zt=Z0
dt wjt ¯zt =Z1

Propositions 3 and 4 are only concerned with wage inequality. Once again, analogous results
can be derived for income inequality, subject to certain caveats. Turning …rst to Proposition 3,
the proof in the Appendix implies that the optimal policy when s = 1 sets sitnit equal to a
constant that depends on the value of zt. Thus, income is given by
yit = zt sit (1 ¡ nit) = wit ¡ constant
Rising wage inequality must eventually translate into rising income inequality, then, since any
di¤erences in the constant term across individuals are eventually swamped by di¤erences in
wages across individuals. Likewise, the fact that wages drift apart more rapidly in recessions
implies that incomes must drift apart more rapidly as well. However, a recession will decrease
income dispersion on impact, since high ability workers will shift more of their time to acquiring
skills the instant zt falls. After this initial compression, incomes will diverge at a faster rate so
long as zt is equal to Z0. Hence, a long enough recession will result in greater income dispersion
4

For small but …nite s, we can only solve the model numerically. For all the parameter values we experimented
¢

¢

with, we con…rmed (wit =wjt ) j zt=Z0 > (wit=wj t) j

zt =Z 1

10

> 0 within in a neighb orhood of t = 0.

than if productivity had stayed at its high value throughout. Similarly, we can establish an
analog to Proposition 4 in terms of income inequality. Given two individuals, when the more
able individual is close to the upper bound s, the income of the less able individual will converge
to the income of the more able individual at a faster rate in recessions. However, on impact
a negative shock to zt will widen income di¤erentials, since the less able households will shift
time away from production while the high ability households essentially devote all their time
endowment to production and will not vary their labor supply. Still, a long enough recession
will result in less income dispersion than if productivity had stayed at its high value throughout.
As a …nal note, we should emphasize that our model is not intended to capture all of the
variation in the distribution of earnings over the cycle. For example, by ignoring unemployment, we abstract from the fact that if low-income households are particularly vulnerable to
unemployment, the relative income of poorer households would fall in recessions. As another
example, if skilled and unskilled labor were imperfect substitutes, and if skilled workers were
more likely to temporarily take on low-skill jobs in recessions, the relative wages of low-skill jobs
would also fall in recessions. Both of these would tend to increase inequality in recessions. The
point of our analysis, however, is not to fully characterize inequality over the cycle. Rather, it
is to point out that ‡uctuations might interact with the forces that lead to long-run changes in
earnings inequality. As a result, even if we were to account for all of the ways in which business
cycles a¤ect the distribution of earnings, we should still observe a smaller rise in inequality in
recessions when long-run inequality is declining than when it is increasing, even after properly
detrending the data. Treating long-run changes in earnings inequality as exogenous trends to
be taken out can lead to biased estimate for the e¤ects of recessions on inequality, where the
direction of the bias depends on the direction of long-run trend inequality.

2. Evidence on Earnings Inequality over the Cycle
We now turn to empirical evidence in support of our hypothesis. To verify our prediction that
downturns are associated with more rapid growth in inequality in periods of rising inequality
but with more rapid reductions in inequality in periods of falling inequality, we look back at
U.S. history over the past century. This period was marked by an increase in measures of
inequality between the early 1900s and the late 1920s, a decline in these same measures from
the late 1920s to the early 1950s, and …nally a resurgence in earnings inequality starting from
the late 1960s persisting until at least the end of the century. These patterns can be reconciled
with our model, where changes in inequality are driven by technological upheavals: the rise and
fall in inequality in the …rst half of the century occurred at a time of signi…cant technological
11

change, namely the electri…cation and mechanization of production, as did the rise in inequality
in the second half of the century, namely computerization.
Rather than proceed chronologically, we …rst focus on the period of declining inequality in
the middle of the century and show that the two major downturns of the period were in fact
associated with a more rapid decline in earnings inequality. We then contrast these …ndings
with the behavior of the same measures of inequality in periods of rising inequality, both those
that predate and postdate this era.
2.1. The Era of Declining Earnings Inequality
We begin with the one episode of declining earnings inequality during the past century. In
many respects, it seems reasonable to associate this decline with the tail end of the process of
electri…cation and mechanization of production that dramatically altered the nature of production in the U.S. Although electricity was …rst introduced at the end of the 19th century, by 1929
it was already widely defused in industry. Schurr et al (1990) report that in 1929, nearly 80%
of the mechanical drive in manufacturing was already electri…ed. As such, starting from the
late 1920s, there should have been a marked catching-up among remaining production arrangements, and a concomitant compression in the distribution of earnings, at least until the arrival
of the next new technology. Indeed, during the 1930s, U.S. producers built signi…cantly on previous technological innovation, in part as …rms tried to wring out e¢ciency gains during these
particularly dire times. Bernstein (1987) documents signi…cant technical change even during
the depths of the Depression, including further mechanization and electri…cation of production.
Perazich and Field (1940) report that the number of workers devoted to product and process
innovation grew at a more rapid rate between 1927 and 1931 than it did during the 1920s.
Field (2003) dramatically refers to this period as “the most technologically progressive decade
of the century.”5 The fact that long-run inequality was declining during this period suggests
that much of this technological progress disproportionately bene…tted low-wage workers. If so,
we should observe that most of the decline in inequality should have been concentrated during
the Great Depression and the recession of 1937. We now argue this was indeed the case, …rst
using evidence on wage inequality and then using evidence on income inequality.
5

There is also evidence of increased human capital accumulation in the Depression that is more directly
related to the channel we emphasize in our model. Goldin (1998) documents an unprecedented surge in high
school enrollments and graduation rates b etween 1929 and 1932, similar to the increase in schooling in more
recent recessions we described above. Once again, technology-speci…c skills are probably not accumulated by
formal schooling, but the incentives to acquire such skills and the incentive to acquire general human capital are
likely to b e similar.

12

2.1.1. Wage Inequality
Unfortunately, there is no comprehensive data on the distribution of wages for the late 1920s.
We instead draw on selected data compiled by economists writing in the wake of the Great
Depression, as well as more recent archival work by economic historians. Our contribution lies
not in o¤ering new data, but in bringing together a variety of sources and providing a coherent
framework to interpret them. The fact that certain measures of inequality fell during the Great
Depression but not in other contractions was known for at least 50 years, and economists have
always found this …nding troubling. Our observation that the e¤ects of the cycle depend on
long-run trends allows us to make better sense of the data and resolve this puzzle.
We begin with the evidence on wage di¤erentials within economic sectors. In this regard,
Bernstein (1966) writes in his survey of the period
There is some evidence that wage-cutting in the later years of the depression had a greater
impact upon high than upon low rates, with the result that the extraordinarily wide differentials between the skilled and the unskilled that prevailed in 1929 were narrowed by
1933. The data are so skimpy that they merely suggest rather than con…rm this conclusion.
Between 1930 and 1932, according to BLS, the average hourly earnings of top and bottom
classi…cations declines as follows: in boots and shoes, turn sewers’ earnings decreased 29.1%
in comparison to 21% for female table workers; in textile dyeing and …nishing, machine
engravers fell o¤ 19.5% and female plaiters dropped 14.6%; in hosiery, footers’ earnings
declined 47.4% as winders’ actually rose 7.1%; in men’s clothing, cutters fell 19.2% as female examiners went down 16.1%; in motor vehicles, hammermen’s earnings declined 20.4%
in comparison to a drop of 47% for female laborers; in rayon mills, spinning bathmen fell
31.6%, but female truckers increased 9%. In all these cases, of course, the cents per hour
decline for the top job far exceeded that for the bottom job. (p320-1).

Using richer BLS wage data drawn from unpublished sources, Dunlop (1939) also documents
declines in the wage premia paid to skilled workers relative to unskilled workers between 1928
and 1932 in various manufacturing industries. In all eight industries for which he reports wages
for common laborers, the median wages of laborers declined by a smaller percentage than the
median wages of at least one category of more skilled workers within the same sector, and
typically by less than all skilled workers within that industry. For example, between 1928 and
1932, the median nominal wage of common laborers in the automobile industry fell by only 4:0%,
whereas the wages of other job categories in the same sector fell by 11:2 ¡ 28:3%; the median

nominal wage of laborers in blast-furnace plants declined by 22:2% compared with declines of
13

23:2 ¡ 28:1% for remaining job categories; in open-hearth plants, the median wages of laborers

fell by 19:8% compared with 30:0¡ 39:9% for other job categories; and in the cement industry,
median nominal wages of laborers declined by 20:0 ¡ 23:6%, compared with 20:1 ¡ 28:6% for
other job categories.6,7

Further evidence that skill di¤erentials within industries declined over this period comes from
Dighe (1997), who uses survey data from the National Industrial Conference Board (NICB) for
25 manufacturing industries. He reports that relative to 1929, the average nominal wage of
unskilled workers in all industries declined by 4:8% by September 1931, compared with 6:1%
for skilled and semi-skilled workers. The same data suggests that the relative gain of unskilled
labor was reversed as the economy began to recover, and by June 1933 the wages of both groups
fell by virtually the same percentage relative to their 1929 average.8 The gains of low-wage
unskilled labor relative to skilled and semi-skilled labor in the depths of the Great Depression is
remarkable. First, it is astonishing that unskilled labor, which by de…nition is easily replaceable,
succeeded in achieving relative gains despite the increase in the number of unemployed workers
during this period. Moreover, unskilled workers managed to avoid large wage cuts without
the aid of labor unions, which as we discuss below had very weak legal standing until later on
in the decade. The wage gains of unskilled labor in this period must therefore re‡ect either
the generosity of employers towards low-wage workers, or, as our model suggests, technological
improvements that allowed employers to pay unskilled labor relatively higher wages.9
6
These …gures come from Table 2 of Dunlop (1939). We should also note that Dunlop …nds that over the
same period, in 11 out of the 14 industries he examines, the wage gap between the top quartile and the bottom
quartile of male wage-earners within a given industry increased. This is not necessarily inconsistent with our
model, since wage compression in our model will tend to be concentrated at the top of the wage distribution,
which may be above the top quartile of the wage distribution.
7

Interestingly, unskilled labor achieved the smallest relative wage gains in lumb er, which Bernstein (1987)
identi…es as having invested little in technical change during the Great Depression, and the largest relative gains
in iron and tin, which invested a great deal in innovation.
8

Dighe (1997) breaks down wage changes for each of the 25 manufacturing industries in the NICB data.
Unskilled male workers gain relative to skilled and semi-skilled in 10 out of the 25 industries, and female workers
gain relative to skilled and semi-skilled workers in 11 out of 22 industries. The same results are reported by Bell
(1951), who …nds skill premia declined in 6 out of 10 industries between 1928 and 1932 in NICB data.
9

Bell (1951) argues social pressures might have compelled employers to spare unskilled labor from large wage
cuts. But since all measures imply unemployment in 1929 and 1930 was below 12%, it is hard to explain why
employers were so generous to laborers in these years given the wage cuts for unskilled labor in 1920-21 when
unemployment was above 15%. Piketty and Saez (2001) also argue social norms can account for changes in the
distribution of income over the century, but do not discuss the Depression in particular.

14

Since all of the evidence on wage inequality above concerns the period of the Great Depression
between 1929 and 1932, they cannot be used to address the question of whether the Great
Depression involved a more rapid compression of wage earnings as our model predicts. Luckily,
Bell (1951) considers this exact question, and con…rms our observation. He begins his discussion
with the following observation:
The prevalent feeling concerning movements in occupational wage di¤erentials in the United
States seems to be that there has been a trend toward a narrowing of the percentage
di¤erential between skilled and unskilled workers during the past half-century, and that this
trend is accentuated in boom periods of full employment and reversed in depressions. This
article has a threefold purpose [which includes] pointing out an important exception to the
conventional model (the depression of 1929-33). (p329)

Bell reports his results only in abbreviated form, and so we can only cite his conclusions
rather than his data. However, at one point, Bell does report that the gap between wages of
skilled and semi-skilled workers in the NICB was constant between 1933 and 1936, the last year
in which NICB data were available. By comparison, recall that Dighe (1997) …nds this gap fell
between 1929 and 1931 using the same NICB data.
We next consider wage di¤erentials across sectors. Comparing wages across sectors is not
quite in the spirit of our model in which workers assimilate the same set of skills; after all,
bricklayers, no matter how much they make use of the new technology, will never become
neurosurgeons. But our analysis would still apply if workers each applied the new technology in
their own respective occupations, and workers in higher paying professions tended to assimilate
it more quickly. Of course, the use of relative wages from di¤erent industries and occupations
is subject to important caveats. First, the wage rates for particular groups may be a¤ected by
circumstances speci…c to those groups that are neither representative of changes in the earnings
of a particular wage percentile nor related to productivity growth associated with the integration
of new technologies. Second, our results might simply re‡ect the fact that workers in low-wage
sectors are disproportionately laid o¤ during contractions. We can o¤er no evidence to rule out
this hypothesis, but it is noteworthy that some of the compression at the top of the distribution
we describe below occurred in the early years of the Great Depression when unemployment was
still fairly low – below 9% prior to 1931 – and comparable to earlier contractionary periods in
which such gaps increased, while such composition e¤ects would presumably have been more
pronounced at high unemployment.
15

Our evidence on occupational wage di¤erentials comes primarily from Williamson and Lindert
(1980), who construct data on relative wages for self-employed physicians, associate professors,
public school teachers, skilled workers in building trades, and skilled workers in manufacturing,
all expressed relative to the wage rates of unskilled workers. Goldin and Margo (1992) construct
additional wage series for the relative pay of skilled workers in the railroad industry, as well
as for clerical workers in New York State. Since these wage series together cover a diverse set
of occupations, we can potentially use the wages from di¤erent occupations as proxies for the
di¤erent wage percentiles. Figure 2 illustrates the wage ratios for these various occupations.
As can be seen from Figure 2, the wages of physicians rank systematically at the top, followed
by associate professors, clerks, teachers, and skilled workers in building trades and manufacturing. Given that unskilled labor are among the lowest wage earners, Figure 2 should be
analogous to the region we identify as the area of decreasing inequality in Figure 1(b). Indeed,
the paths of relative wages from the onset of the Great Depression bear close resemblance to
the right half of Figure 1(b): the distribution of wages becomes compressed at the top but fans
out at the bottom. As is obvious from Figure 2, all groups gain relative to the highest-wage
group, physicians.10 But the extent of compression is not limited only to physicians. For example, clerks register wage gains at the height of the Depression not only relative to the very
top group, physicians, but also relative to the next highest group, professors: their wages rose
from 57% of the wage of professors in 1929 to 73% by 1933, then remained at roughly this level
until the end of the decade. Finally, between 1932 and 1941, unskilled workers gained relative
to many of the higher paid occupations. Thus, the period between 1929 and 1941 appeared
to involve both increasing and decreasing inequality across subgroups, with compression at the
top of the wage distribution accompanied by a greater fanning out at the bottom. Moreover,
from Figure 2, the compression at the top of the wage distribution seems to be concentrated in
the downturns of 1929 and 1937 as suggested by our model, although this is driven primarily
by the relative wage series of a few occupation groups.
10

A natural concern is whether this decline re‡ects a drop in demand for physician services rather than wage
patterns due to channels we describe. Stevens (1989) reports demand for physician services actually increased
during the Great Depression: “Overall, despite the increased burden of free care, hospitals fared less badly than
many other sectors of the economy... the average general hospital grew from 84 beds in 1929 to 104 in 1940.
And although patient payments to nongovernmental hospitals and sanitoria (of all types) declined by 17 p ercent
between 1929 and 1933, this was less than half the decline in consumer expenditures as a whole. Patient payments
to governmental hospitals of all types actually increased by 21 percent between 1929 and 1933, as local general
hospitals and state and local psychiatric hospitals sought free-paying patients. None of these …gures, moreover,
includes adjustments for declining prices” (p148-9).

16

2.1.2. Income Inequality
We next turn to changes in income inequality for the period between 1929 and 1941. Recall
that our model implies that changes in income inequality among employed workers will mirror
changes in wage inequality once the new technology is su¢ciently di¤used, except for small
discrepancies that are likely to be unimportant at annual frequencies. Unlike wage data, income
data is relatively abundant for the time period we are interested in. The most well-known source
on income data is Kuznets (1953), who relies on federal income tax returns. Such data may be
biased because of incentives to misreport income to tax authorities, as well as because certain
job categories are exempt from taxes and therefore not recorded. But as we discuss below,
similar patterns can be found using other data sources that are immune to such problems.
One potential shortcoming of Kuznets’ data, at least for our purposes, is that it relies on a
broad notion of economic income that includes wages and salaries as well as income from rents
and dividends, although it does not include capital gains and so is not directly a¤ected by the
stock market crash of 1929. Since the bene…ts of technological progress may accrue to dividend
holders as well as wage earners, it is not obvious that economic income is not the relevant
income measure. However, we argue below that the pattern of declining income inequality we
document is also apparent in income derived from labor alone.
Recall from our model that among continuously employed workers, the incomes of those at
the top of the distribution will be the …rst to fall relative to lower-income workers, while the
income of those further down the distribution may only begin to fall later on. Consequently,
we should observe a systematic decline in the share of the total income of all continuously
employed workers that accrues to the very top income recipients, but perhaps not among the
income shares of lesser-income earners. In his volume, Kuznets reports the share of national
income that accrues to the top percentiles of the U.S. population. This approach is biased
against …nding evidence of declining inequality in downturns, since the fall in income from
the rise in unemployment would tend to increase the share of top income groups who are less
vulnerable to unemployment. Nevertheless, Figure 3 shows that the income share of the top 1%
steadily declined between 1929 and 1941, including during the years of the Great Depression
between 1929 and 1932. The income shares of the top 2-3% and 4-5% also decline, but only
starting in 1932.
As can be seen from Figure 3, most of the decline in the income share of the top 1% occurs
17

during the Depression itself, i.e. between 1929 and 1932. There is a second fall associated with
the recession of 1937. The di¤erences in the rates of decline are summarized in Table 1, which is
taken directly from Kuznets (1953). This table reports changes in the share of economic income
of upper income groups. Between 1929 and 1932, the share of the top 1% declined at a rate of
0.53% per year. In the subsequent recovery between 1932 and 1937, it actually increased slightly
at an average rate of 0.02% per year. In the next contraction between 1937 and 1938, the share
of income of the top 1% fell by 1.46% per year, while in the subsequent recovery it fell by 0.48%
per year. For the top 5% of all taxpayers as a whole, the Depression was associated with only a
small decline in their share of total income, much smaller than the decline in inequality in the
subsequent recovery. But the contraction of 1937-1938 was associated with a sharp decline in
the income share of this group that exceeded the decline in the subsequent expansion: 1.13%
per year compared with 1.02% per year.11
For further evidence that the acceleration in the decline of the top income share was concentrated in periods of economic contraction, we next turn to Schmitz and Fishback (1983), who
disaggregated Kuznets’ federal income tax data by states. That is, they computed the share of
income in each state that went to the top percentile of individuals residing in that state. Of
the 43 states in which the income share of the top 1% declined between 1929 and 1933, this
share declined more between 1929 and 1933 than between 1933 and 1939 in all but one. This
is partly due to the fact that the income share of the top 1% reversed in some states as their
relative income recovered. But in 28 of the 43 states in which the income share of the top 1%
declined between 1929 and 1932, the income share of this group continued to decline to below
its 1933 level by the end of the decade, just at a slower pace. A similar picture emerges for the
income share of the top 2-5%: in 6 out of the 9 states for which the share of income of this
group declined between 1929 and 1933, the decline in the Depression years was greater than the
change in the income share of this group in the subsequent recovery. The bulk of the decline
in the share of the very top income groups appeared to take place in the Depression.
11

Our interpretation of Kuzents’ data is quite di¤erent from McLean (1991). McLean regresses the share of
income of the top 1% from starting from 1919 on aggregate unemployment and a time-trend, and …nds only
a weak negative relationship b etween this income share and unemployment. However, our approach suggests
treating the 1920s and 1930s di¤erently given the di¤erences in trend inequality over these p eriods. When
we repeat McLean’s regression using data only from 1929 on, we …nd a signi…cant negative partial correlation
between the income share of the top 1% and unemployment measures. The signi…cant negative coe¢cient on
unemployment emerges regardless of whether we use the NBER macroeconomic historical database (which is
based on NICB data), the unemployment series reported in Lebergott (1964), and a corrected version of the
Lebergott series constructed by Darby (1976) that excludes workers employed on work-relief.

18

The fact that only the income shares of the very rich decline during the Depression raises
concerns as to whether this pattern is due to the collapse of dividend income from 1929 on,
as opposed to changes in the distribution of labor income as in our model. We now present
evidence that this is not the case. First, consider Table 123 in Kuznets (1953), which reports
the share of aggregate labor income that accrued to those in the top 1% ranked by economic
income. This share is depicted graphically in Figure 4 below. As apparent from the …gure, this
share declined from 8:7% in 1928 to 7:9% in 1931, and stayed at roughly this level until 1938.
Hence, at least part of the reason why the earnings of the very rich fell relative to those further
down in the distribution was that they were earning relatively less labor income than before.
Next, we turn to evidence on the distribution of earnings derived from labor income. In a
recent paper, Piketty and Saez (2003) construct the distribution of wage and salary income
using the same tax data that Kuznets used. Their construction omits entrepreneurial income,
and so is not exactly equivalent to labor income. Nevertheless, it provides evidence on changes
in the distribution of incomes based solely on labor income. In constructing their data, Piketty
and Saez report the fraction of all wage and salary income that accrues to various percentiles of
all wage-earners in a given year. Note the di¤erence from Kuzents’ approach, which considers
percentiles of the entire population. As a result, the number of individuals that Piketty and
Saez count in a given percentile is not constant over time, and changes in the income share
of the top 1 percentile may re‡ect changes in the number of people in that group rather than
changes in relative earnings. To get around this problem, we consider changes only in the very
top of the distribution. If the distribution of income belongs to the class of Pareto distributions,
then to a …rst approximation, the ratio of the income of the top n% of all wage earners to the
n
top m% of all wage earners for m > n depends on the ratio
and not on the number of
m
wage earners. Since Piketty and Saez argue that the income distribution resembles a Pareto
distribution at high income levels, we consider the ratio of the income of the top 1% to that
of the top 5%. Just as with total income, the share of labor income among the top 1% falls
during this period, from a high of 44:8% in 1928 to 42:1% in 1932, and continues to decline at
a slower average rate for the rest of the decade, reaching 41:7% by 1940.
Given the problems inherent in using income data from tax returns, we now consider a study
by Mendershausen (1946) which covers the same time period using di¤erent data series. For
most of his analysis, Mendershausen uses data from the Financial Survey of Urban Housing.

19

The survey was administered by the Civil Works Administration to inhabitants of dwelling
units in 61 large and middle-sized cities. The survey questions include income data (including
both labor and non-labor sources) in 1929 and in 1933 for the same set of households. Mendershausen was able to obtain data for 33 cities.12 Depending on the size of city, his samples vary
between 4:4% and 34:9% of the estimated number of dwelling units in a given city. While this
survey is potentially subject to non-response bias, it is immune to the criticisms that plague
tax return data such as the incentive to misreport income and the exclusion of certain job
categories. Mendershausen computes Lorenz curves for households of all income levels in each
city. These curves reveal a similar pattern as the federal income tax data: the share of total
income that accrues to those at the very top of the distribution declines between these two
periods. Speci…cally, Mendershausen …nds that the share of income that accrue to the top
income earners declined in 21 of the 33 cities in his sample. Mendershausen computes to within
10% the point at which the share of total income belonging to the top group of income earners
begins to rise rather than fall. In 15 of the 21 cities, the income share of top income recipients
declined for the top 1 ¡ 10%. In 5 cities, the share declined for the top 10 ¡ 20% of all income
earners, and in one city the income share declined for the top 20 ¡30% of all income recipients.
Mendershausen then goes on to show that disparities within the group of top income recipients
declined over this period. He computes a coe¢cient of concentration – basically a Gini coe¢cient
– for households reporting an annual income above $2000 in 1929. In most cities, this group
represents the top 30% of income earners. In 24 of the 33 cities, inequality among high income
households as measured by the coe¢cient of concentration decreases between 1929 and 1933.
Thus, even in cities where the share of top income earners did not appear to decline between
these two years, there is still evidence of compression at the top of the income distribution. This
is probably because excluding low income households mitigates the e¤ects of unemployment
on the distribution of income that tend to obscure the compression of incomes at the top of
the distribution. Experimenting with raising the cuto¤ to $3000, or the top 15-20% of all
households, implies inequality at the top of the distribution declined in even more cities.13
12
The cities he considers are Atlanta, Birmingham, Boise, Butte, Cleveland, Dallas, Des Moines, Erie, Indianap olis, Lansing, Lincoln, Little Rock, Minneapolis, Oklahoma City, Peoria, Portland (Maine), Portland
(Oregon), Providence, Racine, Richmond, Sacramento, St. Joseph, St. Paul, Salt Lake City, San Diego, Seattle,
Spring…eld (Missouri), Syracuse, Top eka, Trenton, Wheeling, Wichita, and Worcester.
13

Once again, our interpretation of Mendershausen’s data contradicts the one reached by McLean (1991). The
reason for this di¤erence is that McLean focuses on the income distribution as a whole rather than delineating

20

As further corroboration, Mendershausen examines supplementary state income tax data
for two states, Wisconsin and Delaware. These state income tax returns are superior to the
federal income tax returns because of their expanded coverage: in Delaware every resident was
required to …le a tax return, while in Wisconsin only high income households were required to
…le a tax return, but the threshold was lower than the federally mandated one. For Wisconsin,
he compiles data for 1929 and the years 1934-1936, and for Delaware he compiles data for the
years 1936-1938. Turning …rst to the income shares of the top income earners, Mendershausen’s
data reveals that in Wisconsin, the share of total taxpayer income that accrued to the top 25% of
all taxpayers declined between 1929 and 1934. In Delaware, the evidence is even more extreme:
the share of income at all deciles declined between 1937 and 1938, i.e. the bottom income
group managed to gain relative to all above them who earned a higher income in the second
contraction.
With regards to disparities among the top income recipients, the state income tax data again
con…rms a general decline over this period that was particularly concentrated in contractions.
He computes a Gini coe¢cient for all individuals above an income threshold of $2000 in 1929
for Wisconsin. This group constitutes the top third of all taxpayers in 1929. Limiting attention
to this group of households, the Gini coe¢cient declined from 0:317 in 1929 to 0:254 in 1934.
By 1935, in the midst of the economic turnaround, the Gini coe¢cient fell just slightly to 0:252,
and by 1936 it reversed course and increased to 0:283. In Delaware, Mendershausen once again
divides the data based on whether individuals reported an income in 1936 above a threshold
of $2000, which yields the top 19% of all taxpayers in 1936. This group likewise exhibits a
more pronounced decline in inequality during the recession: between 1936 and 1937, the Gini
coe¢cient declined from 0:621 to 0:589, while between 1937 and 1938 when the economy was
in recession, it fell more sharply to 0:519.
2.1.3. Can Policy Account for Declining Inequality during the Depression?
Before we turn to the evidence on cyclical ‡uctuations in periods of rising inequality, we brie‡y
consider the possibility that the unusual behavior of inequality during the downturns of the
between the upper part and lower part of the income distribution. As suggested by our model, the decline in
earnings disparities at the top of the distribution can be accompanied by an increase in disparities further down
the distribution.

21

1930s was instead due to unprecedented government intervention during this era. Much of
the decline in the relative earnings of those at the top of the distribution occurred during the
downturn between 1929 and 1932, when many of the forces that could have potentially brought
about declining wage gaps would not have been present. The Hoover administration intervened
in labor markets only to a limited extent. Appointed commissions such as the President’s
Emergency Committee for Employment and later the Teagle Committee advocated in favor of
shortening work shifts and spreading the work across workers, although this was never codi…ed.
In principle, such work-sharing arrangements could contribute to reducing income inequality.
Moreover, as Bernanke (1986) argues, employers might be reluctant to cut the incomes they
pay workers too much, in which case work sharing would have contributed more to the decline
of the incomes of high-wage workers than among low wage workers. But work-sharing was not
widely adopted until later in the Great Depression, and was incorporated into law only with the
adoption of the National Industrial Recovery Act (NIRA) under the Roosevelt administration
in 1933. But recall that much of the compression in the distribution of earnings occurred in
the early years of the Great Depression, suggesting it had little to with work-sharing.
Other forms of government intervention involved restrictions on immigration intended to
alleviate the rising tide of unemployment, which should have raised the relative wage of unskilled workers given many immigrants at the time were unskilled. But legislation to limit
immigration was enacted long before the Depression, and Congress voted to allocate additional
resources to enforcement of immigration laws only in 1932. Government regulation also helped
to strengthen the labor movement during this decade, which again could have contributed to
lowering inequality since unions tended to organize unskilled workers. However, union activity
was fairly minimal prior to 1933, and most of the major industries were unionized only later
during the decade. The legal protection unions received was only part of the New Deal, which
came too late to account for the decline in inequality during the Great Depression. For example, the Norris-LaGuardia Anti-Injunction Act which precluded employers from forcing workers
to commit not to organize was passed only in 1932. The main boost to the labor movement
came with the passage of the NIRA in 1933, and then again with the passage of the National
Labor Relations Act (NLRA) in 1935. If anything, the fact that government intervention under
the New Deal facilitated wage compression in the latter part of the decade makes the sharper
decline of inequality prior to 1932 seem even more striking.14
14

Bell (1951) similarly rejects the role of labor unions and government policies; see especially pages 333-5.

22

2.2. Eras of Rising Earnings Inequality
We next brie‡y discuss the two periods of rising inequality in the past century, to highlight
that the e¤ect of business cycles on the same measures of inequality was exactly the opposite
as it was during the period of the Depression. This includes both the past four decades as
well as the period of rising inequality prior to the Great Depression. The virtue of using data
from a period of rising inequality prior to the Great Depression is that it can help address the
claim that pre-War business cycles were inherently di¤erent than post-War business cycles. For
example, Bernanke and Powell (1986) o¤er evidence that wages tended to be more procyclical in
the post-War period than in the pre-War period, suggesting di¤erences in the way labor markets
operated in the pre-War period. The evidence below reveals that recessions did contribute to
greater inequality in the pre-War period, but only when long-run inequality was increasing.
2.2.1. Rising Inequality in the pre-War Era
The period from the early 1910s to the late 1920s was marked by a dramatic increase in earnings
inequality, driven in part by the e¤ects of new technologies and production methods made
possible by the commercialization of electricity. For example, Williamson and Lindert (1980)
report that by 1929, “gaps between traditionally high-paid and low-paid jobs were almost as
wide as in 1916, when the widest gaps in American history seem to have prevailed.” (p81).
Turning …rst to measures of wage inequality, there unfortunately is not much reliable evidence
concerning the behavior of skill premia prior to the Great Depression. One exception is the
survey by Bell (1951) of over 600 occupations in various industries, drawing wage data for
various industries using BLS, NICB, the Department of Commerce and the Interstate Commerce
Commission. He argues that recessions tended to increase occupational wage di¤erentials, with
the Depression of 1929-33 serving as an important exception. Summarizing his …ndings, based
on data which unfortunately are not reported in his article, he notes that during the recession of
1920-1921, “six of the eight industries for which BLS and other government material is available
experienced a widening of the spread” whereas “during the Great Depression a decade later,
none of the 16 industries surveyed by BLS experienced a de…nite widening of occupational
di¤erentials” (p332). With regard to wage di¤erentials across sectors, here too there is some
evidence that wage di¤erentials tended to increase during recessions prior to 1929. For example,
23

Williamson and Lindert (1980) argue that during the ‘uneven plateau’ between the Civil War
to the Great Depression, the wages of various occupation groups relative to those of unskilled
labor we examine in Figure 4 appear to be countercyclical. Prior to 1929, they note that
Like our measures of income dispersion, the pay ratios show a generally counter-cyclical
pattern. The pay ratios tend to drop in booms and to rise in recessions. This tendency is
much more pronounced when the boom or contraction comes rapidly than when it takes a
few years to gather momentum. (p82)

The evidence on income inequality, for which more comprehensive data is available, also
o¤ers a case for the uniqueness of the 1930s. As Table 1 illustrates, contractions earlier in the
century, which occurred when the income share of the top 1% was generally increasing, were
associated with faster growth in the share of the top 1%. This observation is based on the same
data sources which point to declining inequality during the Great Depression. Kuznets himself
commented on the puzzling lack of consistency in the direction of these shares over the cycle and
called for further work on this question. Moreover, as demonstrated in Figure 4, the uniqueness
of the Great Depression does not simply re‡ect the dramatic decline in dividend income during
this time. In all four contractions prior to 1929, the share of service incomes (compensation
and entrepreneurial income) of the top 1% of all income earners ranked by economic income
tended to rise. By contrast, their share of labor incomes in both the Great Depression and the
recession of 1937 tended to fall.
2.2.2. Rising Inequality in the Post-War Era
Evidence on income inequality for the post-War period has been studied by a variety of di¤erent
authors. We therefore provide only a brief overview of the results to emphasize the comparability
of their measures to the measures we focus on in studying the Great Depression, rather than
explore these results in detail.
In terms of wage data, there is surprisingly little work on wage inequality over the cycle;
instead, most work on the evolution of wages over the cycle has emphasized the behavior of
average wages and whether these are procyclical or countercyclical. A few of these papers note
in passing that wages are more procyclical for low-wage workers than for high wage workers,
which would suggest recessions would increase wage dispersion. Rubinstein and Tsiddon (2000)
24

explicitly consider the distribution of wages over the cycle, and …nd that in the modern era, lowskill and low-wage workers su¤ered disproportionately large wage cuts in contractions. Thus,
the same measure of wage dispersion that appears to fall during the Great Depression rises in
more recent recessions.
Turning to measures of income inequality, much of the evidence focuses on the behavior of
the income share of the top income earners of the population. For example, Blinder and Esaki
(1978), Blank and Blinder (1986), Burtless (1990), and Cutler and Katz (1991) all argue that
recessions foster inequality by appealing to the fact that the income share of the top 20% of
all households has tended to rise in post-War recessions. This is not directly comparable to
the top 1% of households that Kuznets (1953) considers. However, recall that Mendershausen’s
analysis …nds several instances in which the income share of the top 20% that fell during the
Great Depression, e.g. in several of the cities in his study as well as in both the Wisconsin and
Delaware state income tax data. Once again, the same measure of inequality that rises during
recessions in recent periods seemed to fall during the Great Depression.
To summarize, the accelerated decline in relative wages and income shares of those at the
top of the distribution appears to be unique to the contractions of the 1930s, and goes against
the pattern of rising inequality in contractions during both the pre-Depression and post-War
period. Since the Great Depression was such a unique episode in economic history, it is di¢cult
to assess whether this pattern is due to the di¤erence in long-run trend inequality during this
period, as our model would suggest, or whether this is just another way in which the Great
Depression was di¤erent from any other recession. But regardless of the true reason for the
unusual patterns in earnings inequality that appear during this period, our …ndings certainly
raise questions about the presumption in recent work in macroeconomics that views recessions
as systematically contributing to greater earnings disparities.

3. Conclusion
Our motivation in this paper is to call attention to the fact that most of the recent work on
changes in earnings disparities over the cycle is disconnected from changes in long-run inequality.
We …nd this practice to be unsatisfactory, and demonstrate this by showing how ‡uctuations
interact with the forces that drive long-run inequality. According to the mechanism we outline,
25

recessions should contribute more to raising inequality when inequality is rising over the long
run than when it is falling. Evidence from the …rst half of the 20th century supports our
contention that the cyclicality in earnings inequality is not uniform, and instead depends on
the direction of trend inequality.
Of course, ours is but one way in which cyclical ‡uctuations a¤ect the distribution of earnings;
other factors, such as changes in the incidence of unemployment, search and matching, dynamic
contracting, and so on, all a¤ect earnings over the business cycle, and are all important in
ultimately shaping the distribution of earnings. Our goal here is not to present a comprehensive
model to account for all of the changes in the distribution of earnings over the cycle. Rather,
it is to illustrate that if we wish to identify and measure the e¤ect of cyclical ‡uctuations on
inequality, we need to take into account how such ‡uctuations interact with long-run changes
in the distribution of earnings; otherwise, changes in inequality over the cycle are measured in
a biased way. Our analysis thus suggests that accounting for long-run changes in measures of
inequality requires more than just allowing for a time trend, since cyclical ‡uctuations can have
a di¤erent impact on the distribution of earnings when inequality is generally rising than when
it is falling. Instead, we need to explicitly model the evolution of long-run inequality, even if
we are only interested in studying cyclical phenomena.
Finally, the fact that trends can in‡uence the degree of cyclical sensitivity of earnings inequality has important implications for using evidence on the cyclicality of earnings inequality
in resolving various macroeconomic puzzles. The source of changes in earnings inequality over
the cycle we focus on in this paper has nothing to do with income risk, and is instead driven
by the endogenous decisions of agents. Since at least part of the increase in inequality observed
during the recessions of the past three decades probably captures the e¤ects of cyclical ‡uctuations on the same endogenous decisions that lead to rising inequality rather than as evidence
of greater income volatility, calibrating income volatility to earnings data compiled from a period of rising inequality as previous work has implicitly done would tend to overstate the true
increase in income volatility during downturns (just as it would tend to understate the true
increase if estimates were based on a period of decreasing inequality). While it is not obvious
how large this bias is, the historical evidence we reviewed here suggests trends may play enough
of a role that they can be discerned in the earnings data, and so the implications for estimates
of income volatility need not be negligible.

26

Appendix
Proof of Proposition 1: Let us rewrite (1.7) with x as a function of t rather than s t. To do this, let
us rewrite s_ in terms of x as follows:
s_

where m =

b

= a (sn)
b
µ
¶ 1¡b
ab 0
= a
V (s)
Z
b
µ ·
¸¶ 1¡b
ab 0
Z
= a
x (s) +
Z
½
b
" µ
¶1¡b # 1¡b
ab ½x (s)
= a
Z
m

· ¸ 1
1 ¡ b ab 1¡b
. This last expression simpli…es to
b
Zb
·

½bx (s)
s_ = a
(1 ¡ b) Z
We use this to write out the law of motion for
dx
dt

=
=
=
=

dx ds
¢
ds dt
·³ ´
½x 1¡b

¸b

dx
as follows:
dt

¸ ·
¸b
Z
½bx
¢a
m
½
(1 ¡ b) Z
·
¸b
µ ¶1¡b µ
¶b
b
Z
bx
b¡1
a
m
½x ¡ a
(1 ¡ b) Z
½
1¡b
" µ ¶
¶b#
1¡b µ
½
Z
b
x¡ a
xb
1¡ b
½
1¡b
¡

This yields a non-linear di¤erential equation for x (t) known as a Bernoulli equation, which can be solved
in closed form. Simply de…ne y = x 1¡b and rewrite the above equation as
" µ
¶ 1¡ b #
dy
(1 ¡ b) Z
= ½y ¡ a
bb
dt
½
which has the solution

" µ
¶ 1¡b #
a (1 ¡ b) Z
y=
b b + Ce ½t
½
½

(3.1)

for some constant C: Since y t > 0 for t = 0 but lim y = 0, it follows that C < 0 and that y_ · 0 for all
t!1

t. Using the fact that

s_ = a

·

½b
(1 ¡ b) Z

¸b

b

y 1¡b

and the fact that y_ < 0, it follows that Äs < 0, establishing s is concave in t. The fact that C < 0 insures
there exists a …nite T for which y T = 0.
Finally, to show that the paths sit and sjt for ai > aj do not cross, note that since the option to learn
must be more valuable for those who are more able, y i ¸ y j whenever si = sj . Hence, if there exists a

date t0 s.t. sit0 = sjt0 6= s, it must be true that s_it0 > s_jt0 at date t0 . Since si0 = sj0 = s0 , it follows that
s_i0 > s_j0 , and so sit > sjt within a neighborhood of t = 0. Now, suppose there was some date t0 > 0 s.t.

sit0 = sjt0 6= s, and w.l.o.g. suppose this is the …rst such date at which this occurs. Since sit > s jt for
all t 2 (0; t0 ), it must be the case that s_it0 < s_jt0 , which is a contradiction. ¥

Proof of Proposition 2: For an individual with skill level s < s, the asset equations are given by
n
o
b
½V k (s) = max Zk s (1 ¡ n) + Vk0 (s) a (sn) + ¹ [V ¡k (s) ¡ V k (s)]
n

Taking the …rst order condition with respect to n and substituting in yields
1

½V k (s) = Zk s + m k (V k0 (s)) 1¡b + ¹ [V¡ k (s) ¡ V k (s)]
where mk =
skills

1¡b
b

µ

ab
Zkb

1
¶ 1¡b

(3.2)

. Once again, let x k (s) denote the value of the option to learn additional
xk (s) = V k (s) ¡

(½ + ¹) Zk + ¹Z¡k
s
½ (½ + 2¹)

and rewrite the system of di¤erential equations for V k (s) in terms of x k (s):
·

(½ + ¹) x k (s) ¡ ¹x ¡k (s)
mk

¸1¡ b

(½ + ¹) Z k + ¹Z¡ k
(3.3)
½ (½ + 2¹)
½
¾
½+¹
¹
The above system of di¤erential equations is de…ned only over the region (x0 ; x 1 ) :
x 0 > x1 >
x0 .
¹
½+ ¹
The values of xk (s) along the optimal path solve the system of di¤erential equations (3.3) together with
x 0k (s) =

¡

the boundary condition x 0 (s) = x 1 (s) = 0.
Figure A1 depicts the phase diagram for (3.3). The region over which the system is de…ned corresponds
¹
½+¹
to the unshaded region between the two rays x 1 =
x0 and x 1 =
x0 . The condition that
½+¹
¹
dxk
= 0 implies (½ + ¹) xk ¡ x¡ k = constant, so is parallel to the boundary of region in which the
ds
system is de…ned. The dynamics of (x 1; x 0 ) are indicated by the arrows. The optimal path is the unique
path that goes through the origin, which corresponds to the boundary condition x 0 (s) = x 1 (s) = 0, and
is depicted in the …gure as a thick line.

Substituting in from the …rst-order condition, we can show that the rate at which skills are acquired
along the optimal path for a particular realization of zt = Zk is given by
¯
µ
¶b ·
¸b
ds t ¯¯
b
½xk (s) + ¹ [xk (s) ¡ x ¡k (s)]
b
= a (sn) = a
dt ¯zt =Zk
1¡ b
Zk

¯
¯
dsit ¯¯
dsit ¯¯
½x0 + ¹ [x0 ¡ x 1 ]
½x1 + ¹ [x 1 ¡ x 0 ]
It follows that
>
if and only if
¸
, or, upon
dt ¯ zt=Z 0
dt ¯zt =Z1
Z0
Z1
rearranging
(½ + ¹) Z1 + ¹Z0
x1 ·
x0
(3.4)
(½ + ¹) Z0 + ¹Z1
which describes a region in (x 1 ; x0 ) space whose boundary is a line with slope greater than 1 that cuts
through the origin. The boundary is illustrated as the dashed line in Figure A1, and the region where
agents acquire skills more rapidly during recessions is to the right of this half-line.
At (x 0 ; x1 ) = (0; 0), we can apply L’Hopital’s rule to show that for the true values of learning x0 (s)
and x1 (s), we have
lim

s!s

½x0 (s) + ¹ [x 0 (s) ¡ x1 (s)]
½x 00 (s) + ¹ [x00 (s) ¡ x 01 (s)]
Z0
= lim
=
0
0
0
s!s
½x1 (s) + ¹ [x 1 (s) ¡ x0 (s)]
½x 1 (s) + ¹ [x1 (s) ¡ x 0 (s)]
Z1

This implies that the optimal path (x 0 (s) ; x 1 (s)) is tangent to the line de…ned by (3.4) at (0; 0), as
illustrated in Figure A1.
Next, we show that the path (x0 (s) ; x 1 (s)) lies in the region de…ned by (3.4). Consider a path
(e
x 0 (s) ; e
x1 (s)) that satis…es (3.3) for which there exists an se such that
xe1 (e
s) =

and where
Using equation (3.3), we have
e00 (e
x
s) =
x01
e

(e
s) =
=
=

·
·
·

(½ + ¹) Z1 + ¹Z0
xe0 (e
s)
¹Z1 + (½ + ¹) Z0

xe00 (e
s) ; e
x01 (e
s) < 0
(½ + ¹) xe0 ¡ ¹e
x1
m0
(½ + ¹) xe1 ¡ ¹e
x0
m1

¸1¡ b
¸1¡ b

¡

(½ + ¹) Z0 + ¹Z1
½ (½ + 2¹)

¡

(½ + ¹) Z1 + ¹Z0
½ (½ + 2¹)

¸1¡ b
m0 (½ + ¹) e
x 0 ¡ ¹e
x1
(½ + ¹) Z1 + ¹Z0
¡
m1
m0
½ (½ + 2¹)
·
¸1¡ b
b
Z1 (½ + ¹) e
x 0 ¡ ¹e
x1
(½ + ¹) Z1 + ¹Z0
¡
b
Z0
m0
½ (½ + 2¹)

Since xe0k (e
s) 6= 0, then for s = e
s, we have
de
x1
de
x0

=

=

<

<

de
x 1 =ds
de
x 0 =ds

¸b ·
¸1¡b
Z1
(½ + ¹) e
x0 ¡ ¹e
x1
Z0
m0
·
¸1¡b
(½ + ¹) e
x0 ¡ ¹e
x1
(½ + ¹) Z0 + ¹Z1 ¡ ½ (½ + 2¹)
m0
·
¸1¡b
(½ + ¹) e
x0 ¡ ¹e
x1
(½ + ¹) Z1 + ¹Z0 ¡ ½ (½ + 2¹)
m0
·
¸1¡b
(½ + ¹) e
x0 ¡ ¹e
x1
(½ + ¹) Z0 + ¹Z1 ¡ ½ (½ + 2¹)
m0
(½ + ¹) Z1 + ¹Z0
(½ + ¹) Z0 + ¹Z1
(½ + ¹) Z1 + ¹Z0 ¡ ½ (½ + 2¹)

·

where the two inequalities use the fact that (½ + ¹) x 1 ¡ ¹x0 > 0. Thus, the slope of such a curve is
lower than the line de…ned by (3.4). To show that the optimal path (x0 (s) ; x 1 (s)) satis…es (3.4), we
can now use a simple contradiction argument: if (x 0 (s) ; x1 (s)) ever violated (3.4), it would require the
(½ + ¹) Z1 + ¹Z0
path to have a steeper slope that
along the line de…ned by (3.4) for the region where
(½ + ¹) Z0 + ¹Z1
x 0k (s) < 0, which was we just proved is impossible. ¥
Proof of Proposition 3: Suppose s = 1. The asset equations along the optimal path are still given
by (3.2), but now the boundary condition is replaced with a transversality condition. Appealing to the
method of undetermined coe¢cients, we can con…rm that in this case the value function V (s) is linear
in s, and use this to solve directly for the law of motion
¯
·
¸ b
1
ds ¯¯
b (½ + ¹) Zk + ¹Z¡ k 1¡b
1¡b
=a
dt ¯ zt= Zk
½ (½ + ¹) Z k + ¹Zk
Since all agents start with the same skill level s0 , it follows that at t = 0, the wage ratio (which equals
the skill ratio) is equal to 1. For t > 0, let k (t) 2 f0; 1g denote which state zt assumes at date t. The
skill level for individual i is then given by
¯
Z t
dsi¿ ¯¯
sit = s0 +
d¿
dt ¯ z¿ =Zk(¿)
0
Z t·
¸ b
1
b (½ + ¹) Zk(¿ ) + ¹Z¡ k(¿ ) 1¡b
1¡b
= s0 + ai
d¿
½ (½ + ¹) Zk(¿ ) + ¹Z k( ¿ )
0
1

´ s0 + ai1¡b g (t)
t

where
path fz¿ g ¿ =0 . For any such path, g (t) is increasing in t given that
µ g (t) is a function of the entire
¶
b (½ + ¹) Z k( ¿) + ¹Z¡k(¿ )
min
> 0, lim g (t) = 1, and g (t) is continuous in t. Given that ai > aj ,
t!1
k
½ (½ + ¹) Zk(¿ ) + ¹Zk(¿ )
it follows that the skill ratio
1
sit
s0 + ai1¡b g (t)
=
1
sjt
s0 + aj1¡b g (t)

µ

¶ 1
ai 1¡b
is increasing in t for any realized path, and that in the limit, the ratio converges to
. Di¤erµ
¶aj
b (½ + ¹) Zk(t) + ¹Z¡k(t)
entiating with respect to t and using the fact that g 0 (t) =
is higher when
½ (½ + ¹) Zk(t) + ¹Zk(t)
k (t) = 0 establishes the second part of the claim. ¥
Proof of Proposition 4: To show that sit ¸ sjt , recall from the proof of Proposition 3 that when
aggregate productivity is equal to Z k , the change in skills is given by
¯
µ
¶b ·
¸b
dst ¯¯
b
½x k (s) + ¹ [x k (s) ¡ x¡k (s)]
=a
dt ¯ zt=Z k
1¡b
Zk

Fix the value of s, and consider the two individuals i and j . For the individual with the higher ability,
we know that a is higher. We need to show that ½x k (s) + ¹ [xk (s) ¡ x¡ k (s)] is increasing in a. But
½xk (s) + ¹ [x k (s) ¡ x ¡k (s)] is just the ‡ow value of the option to accumulate skills beyond s, i.e. it is
equal to
½
¾
dxk
b
0
max [Zk s0 (1 ¡ n) ¡ Z k s] +
a
(s
n)
n
ds0
But agents with higher a bene…t
more from learning, this expression must be increasing in a. Hence,
¯
dst ¯¯
a given level of s < s,
is strictly increasing in a for both values of k, i.e. starting from the
dt ¯ zt= Zk
same skill level, the more able worker will accumulate more skills. By a similar argument to the proof
of Proposition 1, one can show that sit > sjt if sit 2 (s0 ; s).

Next, we establish that an individual still reaches s in …nite time, i.e. there exists a time T such that
for any realization zt where t 2 [0; 1), st = s for t ¸ T . We do this by proving that if either k = 0 or
k = 1, the individual would reach s in …nite time. It follows from this that for any realization zt , the
individual would reach s in …nite time.
Let yk ´ (½ + ¹) x k (s) ¡ ¹x¡k (s). Combining the evolution of x k (s) and s t yields the following law
of motion for x k as a function of t conditional on zt = Zk :
¯
¯
dxk ¯¯
dx k ds ¯¯
=
¢
dt ¯ zt=Z k
ds
dt ¯zt =Zk
õ
! µ
¶1¡b
¶b · ¸b
yk
(½ + ¹) Zk + ¹Z¡k
b
yk
=
¡
a
mk
½ (½ + 2¹)
1¡b
Zk
µ
¶b
µ
¶b
a
b mk
b 1
a (½ + ¹) Zk + a¹Z¡k b
=
yk ¡
yk
m k 1 ¡ b Zk
1 ¡ b Zk
½ (½ + 2¹)
´

Ak y k ¡ Bk y bk

and the coe¢cients Ak and Bk are positive. Di¤erentiating y with respect to time yields
Ã
!
¯
¯
¯
¯
dy k ¯¯
dxk ¯¯
dx k ¯¯
dx ¡k ¯¯
= ½
+¹
¡
dt ¯zt =Zk
dt ¯ zt=Z k
dt ¯zt =Zk
dt ¯zt =Zk
Ã
!
¯
¯
£
¤
dx k ¯¯
dx¡ k ¯¯
b
= ½ A k y k ¡ Bk y k + ¹
¡
dt ¯zt =Zk
dt ¯zt =Zk

Note that except for the last term, the dynamics of y k are similar to those as for xk in the case where zt
is constant. In that case, we already established that y hits 0 in …nite time. Turning to the additional
component, we have
¯
¯
¯
µ
¶
dx k ¯¯
dx ¡k ¯¯
dx k
dx¡k
ds ¯¯
¡
=
¡
¢
dt ¯ zt=Zk
dt ¯ zt=Z k
ds
ds
dt ¯zt =Zk
Applying Proposition 3, we know that as s ! s,

dx1 =ds
(½ + ¹) Z1 + ¹Z0
!
>1
dx0 =ds
(½ + ¹) Z0 + ¹Z1

Hence, there exists an " > 0 such that if s < s ¡ ", the laws of motion for y when z = Z1 satisfy
¯
£
¤
dy1 ¯¯
< ½ A1 y 1 ¡ B1 y b1
¯
dt z t=Z1
This insures y1 will hit 0 in …nite time, so that if zt = Z1 for all t, s is reached in …nite time.
To insure y 0 also hits 0 in …nite time, we note that
dx k =dtjzt =Zk
dxk =dtjzt=Z ¡k

=
=

and so
lim

s!s

dsk =dtjzt =Zk
dsk =dtjzt=Z ¡k
·
¸b
Z ¡k (½ + ¹) x k (s) ¡ ¹x ¡k (s)
Zk (½ + ¹) x k (s) ¡ ¹x ¡k (s)

dxk =dtjzt=Z k
dx k =dtjzt =Z¡k

!

·

Z¡k Zk
Zk Z¡k

¸b

=1

Suppose that when zt = Z0 for all t, the individual does not reach s in …nite time. Then it must be the
case that as s ! s, x k ! 0 more rapidly when zt = Z1 , since we just established x k does hit 0 in …nite
time when zt = Z 1 . But this would imply
lim

s!s

dx k =dtjzt =Z1
>1
dx k =dtjzt =Z0

which is a contradiction.
Finally, consider two individuals i and j where ai > aj . Since sit > sjt as long as s 0 < sit < s, it
follows that i reaches s before j. At this point, wage inequality is clearly decreasing, since
µ ¶¯
µ ¶¯
d wi ¯¯
d
s ¯¯
=
<0
¯
dt w j zt =Zk
dt s j ¯zt =Zk

By continuity, there exists an " > 0 such that both derivatives are negative whenever sit < s ¡ ", which
establishes the proof. The …nal part of the Proposition follows as a corollary to Proposition 3. ¥

st

s

si
inf j (s j )
highest
ability

increasing
inequality

decreasing
inequality

lowest
ability

s0
t

t

1

(a)

(b)
Figure 1: Skill Levels and Ratios with Bounded Skills

Note: Each path in panel (a) represents the evolution of skills for an individual at a given percentile in the
distribution of the ability to learn parameter a. Each path in panel (b) represents the ratio of skill between a given
percentile in the ability distribution and the skill level of the least able individual in the population.

physicians

6

assoc prof
NY clerks
skilled bldg

5

RR clerks
teachers
skilled manuf

4

3

2

1
26

27

28

29

30

31

32

33

34

35

36

37

38

39

40

41

Figure 2: Relative Wages during the Great Depression
Notes: The wage series for public school teachers, associate professors, self-employed physicians, and skilled workers in building
trades are series (8), (10), (11), and (13) respectively in Willimason and Lindert (1980). The first three series compare the annual
income of teachers, professors, and physicians with 2000 hours of work at the hourly wage rate of unskilled workers based primarily
on data reported by the National Industrial Conference Board (NICB). The series for skilled workers in building are hourly wages of
skilled workers relative to the hourly wage rates of journeymen, helpers, and laborers in the building trades for various cities. The
series on skilled wokrers in manufacturing, clerks in the railroad industry, and clerks in New York State are columns (1), (4.2), and (6)
respectively from Table VII of Goldin and Margo (1992). The wages of skilled manufacturing and clerks in New York are expressed
relative to the unkilled NICB wages, although the first series is based on hourly wage rates while the latter is based on weekly wage
rates. The series on clerks in the railroad industry denote hourly wages of clerks relative to machinists and laborers.

top 1%
19

top 2-3%
17

top 4-5%
15
13
11
9
7
5
26

27

28

29

30

31

32

33

34

35

36

37

38

39

40

41

Figure 3: Income Shares of Top Taxpayers during the Great Depression
Notes: Each figure denotes the percentage of national income in each year that belonged to the top x% of the population. The data are
taken from Table 122 in Kuznets (1953).

9.00

8.50

8.00

7.50

7.00

6.50

6.00
17

18

19

20

21

22

23

24

25

26

27

28

29

30

31

32

33

34

35

36

37

38

Figure 4: Share of Service Income (Compensation and Entrepreneurial Income)
of Top 1% of Economic Income Recipients
Notes: Shaded regions correspond to contractions as identified by Kuznets (1953). The data are based on Table 123 of Kuznets.

x1 =
x1

ρ+µ
x
µ 0

x1 =

(ρ+µ)Ζ1 +µΖ 0
x
(ρ+µ)Ζ0 +µΖ 1 0
dx0
ds = 0

dx1
ds = 0

µ
x1 = ρ+µ x0

x0

Figure A1: Phase diagram for system with aggregate productivity shocks

Table 1: Change per Year in Shares of Upper Income Groups,
ranked by Economic Income

year

cycle

top 1%

top 5%

1918-19

contraction

0.27

0.44

1919-20

expansion

-0.50

-0.84

1920-21

contraction

1.16

3.40

1921-23

expansion

-0.61

-1.29

1923-24

contraction

0.63

1.40

1924-26

expansion

0.51

0.48

1926-27

contraction

0.46

0.72

1927-29

expansion

0.05

0.06

1929-32

contraction

-0.53

-0.03

1932-37

expansion

0.02

-0.38

1937-38

contraction

-1.46

-1.13

1938-44

expansion

-0.48

-1.02

Source: Kuznets (1953), Table 15

References
[1] Acemoglu, Daron and Ste¤en Pischke, 1999. “The Structure of Wages and Investment in
General Training” Journal of Political Economy, 107(3), June, p539-72.
[2] Aghion, Phillipe and Gilles Saint Paul, 1998. “Virtues of Bad Times: Interaction between
Productivity Growth and Economic Fluctuations” Macroeconomic Dynamics, 2(3), September, p322-44.
[3] Becker, Gary, 1975. Human Capital; a Theoretical and Empirical Analysis, with Special
Reference to Education. Chicago: NBER.
[4] Bell, Philip, 1951. “Cyclical Variations and Trend in Occupational Wage Di¤erentials in
American Industry Since 1914” Review of Economics and Statistics, 33 (4), November,
p329-37.
[5] Ben-Porath, Yoram, 1967. “The Production of Human Capital and the Life Cycle of Earnings” Journal of Political Economy. August, 75(4), p352-65.
[6] Bernanke, Ben, 1986.“Employment, Hours, and Earnings in the Depression: An Analysis
of Eight Manufacturing Industries” American Economic Review, March, 76(1), p82-l09.
[7] Bernanke, Ben and James Powell, 1986. “The Cyclical Behavior of Industrial Labor Markets: A Comparison of the Prewar and Postwar Eras” in The American Business Cycle:
Continuity and Change, edited by Gordon, Robert. Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
p583-621.
[8] Bernstein, Irving,1966. The Lean Years: A History of the American Worker, 1920-1933.
Penguin Books, Baltimore, Maryland.
[9] Bernstein, Michael, 1987. The Great Depression: Delayed Recovery and Economic Change
in America 1929-1939. Cambridge University Press.
[10] Betts, Julian and Laurel McFarland, 1995. “Safe Port in a Storm: The Impact of Labor
Market Conditions on Community College Enrollments” Journal of Human Resources,
30(4), p741-65.

[11] Blank, Rebecca and Alan Blinder, 1986. “Macroeconomics, Income Distribution and
Poverty” in Fighting Poverty: What Works and What Doesn’t, edited by Sheldon Danziger
and D. Weinberg, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, p180-208.
[12] Blinder, Alan and Howard Esaki, 1978. “Macroeconomic Activity and Income Distribution
in the Postwar United States” Review of Economics and Statistics, November, 60(4), p604609.
[13] Burtless, Gary, 1990. “Earnings Inequality over the Business and Demographic Cycles” in
A Future of Lousy Jobs? The Changing Structure of U.S Wages, edited by Gary Burtless,
Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, p77-117.
[14] Caselli, Francesco, 1999. “Technological Revolutions” American Economic Review, March,
89(1), p78-102.
[15] Constantinides, George and Darrell Du¢e, 1996. “Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers” Journal of Political Economy, April, 104(2), p219-40.
[16] Cooper, Russel and John Haltiwanger, 1993. “The Aggregate Implications of Machine
Replacement: Theory and Evidence” American Economic Review, June, 83(3), p181-186.
[17] Cutler, David and Lawrence Katz, 1991. “Macroeconomic Performance and the Disadvantaged” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2, p1-74.
[18] Darby, Michael, 1976. “Three-and-a-Half Million U.S. Employees Have Been Mislaid: Or,
an Explanation of Unemployment, 1934-1941” Journal of Political Economy, February,
84(1), p1-16.
[19] Dellas, Harris and Plutarchos Sakellaris, 2003. “On the Cyclicality of Schooling: Theory
and Evidence” Oxford Economic Papers, January, 55(1), p148-72.
[20] Dighe, Ranjit, 1997. “Wage Rigidity in the Great Depression: Truth? Consequence?”
Research in Economic History, 17, p85-134.
[21] Dunlop, John, 1939. “Cyclical Variations in Wage Structure” Review of Economics and
Statistics, 21 (1), February, p30-9.
[22] Field, Alexander, 2003. “The Most Technologically Progressive Decade of the Century”
American Economic Review, September, 93(4), p1399-1413.

[23] Galor, Oded and Daniel Tsiddon, 1997. “Technological Progress, Mobility, and Economic
Growth” American Economic Review, June, 87(3), p363-82.
[24] Goldin, Claudia, 1998. “America’s Graduation from High School: The Evolution and
Spread of Secondary Schooling in the Twentieth Century” Journal of Economic History,
58(2), p345-74.
[25] Goldin, Claudia and Robert Margo, 1992. “The Great Compression: The Wage Structure
in the United States at Mid- Century” Quarterly Journal of Economics, February, 107(1),
p1-34.
[26] Greenwood, Jeremey and Mehmet Yorukoglu, 1997. “1974” Carnegie Rochester Conference
Series on Public Policy, December, 46(2), p49-95.
[27] Hall, Robert, 1991. “Labor Demand, Labor Supply, and Employment Volatility” NBER
Macroeconomics Annual. Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press.
[28] Heaton, John and Deborah Lucas, 1996. “Evaluating the E¤ects of Incomplete Markets on
Risk Sharing and Asset Pricing” Journal of Political Economy, June, 104(3), p443-87.
[29] Imrohoroglu, Ayse, 1989. “Cost of Business Cycles with Indivisibilities and Liquidity Constraints” Journal of Political Economy, 97(6), December, p1364-83.
[30] Krebs, Tom, 2003. “Growth and Welfare E¤ects of Business Cycles in Economies with
Idiosyncratic Human Capital Risk” Review of Economic Dynamics, October, 6(4), p846868.
[31] Kuznets, Simon, 1953. Shares of Upper Income Groups in Income and Savings. New York:
NBER.
[32] Kuznets, Simon, 1955. “Economic Growth and Income Inequality” American Economic
Review. May, 45(1), p1-28.
[33] Lucas, Robert, 1987. Models of Business Cycles. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
[34] Lebergott, Stanley, 1964. Manpower in Economic Growth; the American Record Since
1800. New York, McGraw-Hill.
[35] Mankiw, N. Gregory, 1986. “The Equity Premium and the Concentration of Aggregate
Shocks” Journal of Financial Economics, September, 17(1), p211-19.

[36] McLean, Ian, 1991. “The Distributional Impact of the Depression in the United States”
in Income Distribution in Historical Perspective, edited by Y. Brenner, Hartmut Kaelble,
and Mark Thomas, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, p189-211.
[37] Mendershausen, Horst, 1946. Changes in Income Distribution During the Great Depression.
New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.
[38] Perazich, George and Philip Field. Industrial Research and Changing Technology. Philadelphia: WPA National Research Project, Report #M-4.
[39] Piketty, Thomas and Emmanuel Saez, 2003. “Income Inequality in the United States,
1913-1998” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(1), February, p1-39.
[40] Rubinstein, Yona and Tsiddon, Daniel 2000. “Born to be Unemployed: Unemployment
and Wages over the Business Cycle” Mimeo, Tel Aviv University.
[41] Schmitz, Mark and Price Fishback, 1983. “The Distribution of Income in the Great Depression: Preliminary State Estimates” Journal of Economic History, 43 (1), March, p217-30.
[42] Schurr, Sam, Calivn Burwell, Warren Devine, and Sidney Sonenblum, 1990. Electricity in
the American Economy: Agent of Technological Progress. New York: Greenwood Press.
[43] Sepulveda, Facundo, 2002. “Training and Business Cycles” Mimeo, Michigan State University.
[44] Solon, Gary, Robert Barsky, and Jonathan Parker, 1994. “Measuring the Cyclicality of
Real Wages: How Important is Composition Bias?” Quarterly Journal of Economics,
February 1994, 109(1), p1-26.
[45] Stevens, Rosemary, 1989. In Sickness and in Wealth: American Hospitals in the Twentieth
Century, New York: Basic Books.
[46] Storesletten, Kjetil, Chris Telmer, and Amir Yaron, 2001. “The Welfare Cost of Business
Cycles Revisited: Finite Lives and Cyclical Variation in Idiosyncratic Risk” European
Economic Review, June, 45(7), p1311-39.
[47] Storesletten, Kjetil, Chris Telmer, and Amir Yaron, 2003. “Asset Pricing with Idiosyncratic
Risk and Overlapping Generations” Mimeo, The Wharton School.

[48] Williamson, Je¤rey and Peter Lindert, 1980. American Inequality: a Macroeconomic Perspective, New York: Academic Press.

Working Paper Series
A series of research studies on regional economic issues relating to the Seventh Federal
Reserve District, and on financial and economic topics.
Does Bank Concentration Lead to Concentration in Industrial Sectors?
Nicola Cetorelli

WP-01-01

On the Fiscal Implications of Twin Crises
Craig Burnside, Martin Eichenbaum and Sergio Rebelo

WP-01-02

Sub-Debt Yield Spreads as Bank Risk Measures
Douglas D. Evanoff and Larry D. Wall

WP-01-03

Productivity Growth in the 1990s: Technology, Utilization, or Adjustment?
Susanto Basu, John G. Fernald and Matthew D. Shapiro

WP-01-04

Do Regulators Search for the Quiet Life? The Relationship Between Regulators and
The Regulated in Banking
Richard J. Rosen
Learning-by-Doing, Scale Efficiencies, and Financial Performance at Internet-Only Banks
Robert DeYoung
The Role of Real Wages, Productivity, and Fiscal Policy in Germany’s
Great Depression 1928-37
Jonas D. M. Fisher and Andreas Hornstein

WP-01-05

WP-01-06

WP-01-07

Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic Effects of a Shock to Monetary Policy
Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum and Charles L. Evans

WP-01-08

Outsourcing Business Service and the Scope of Local Markets
Yukako Ono

WP-01-09

The Effect of Market Size Structure on Competition: The Case of Small Business Lending
Allen N. Berger, Richard J. Rosen and Gregory F. Udell

WP-01-10

Deregulation, the Internet, and the Competitive Viability of Large Banks
and Community Banks
Robert DeYoung and William C. Hunter

WP-01-11

Price Ceilings as Focal Points for Tacit Collusion: Evidence from Credit Cards
Christopher R. Knittel and Victor Stango

WP-01-12

Gaps and Triangles
Bernardino Adão, Isabel Correia and Pedro Teles

WP-01-13

A Real Explanation for Heterogeneous Investment Dynamics
Jonas D.M. Fisher

WP-01-14

Recovering Risk Aversion from Options
Robert R. Bliss and Nikolaos Panigirtzoglou

WP-01-15

Economic Determinants of the Nominal Treasury Yield Curve
Charles L. Evans and David Marshall

WP-01-16

1

Working Paper Series (continued)
Price Level Uniformity in a Random Matching Model with Perfectly Patient Traders
Edward J. Green and Ruilin Zhou

WP-01-17

Earnings Mobility in the US: A New Look at Intergenerational Inequality
Bhashkar Mazumder
The Effects of Health Insurance and Self-Insurance on Retirement Behavior
Eric French and John Bailey Jones

WP-01-18

The Effect of Part-Time Work on Wages: Evidence from the Social Security Rules
Daniel Aaronson and Eric French

WP-01-20

Antidumping Policy Under Imperfect Competition
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-01-21

WP-01-19

Is the United States an Optimum Currency Area?
An Empirical Analysis of Regional Business Cycles
Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-01-22

A Note on the Estimation of Linear Regression Models with Heteroskedastic
Measurement Errors
Daniel G. Sullivan

WP-01-23

The Mis-Measurement of Permanent Earnings: New Evidence from Social
Security Earnings Data
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-01-24

Pricing IPOs of Mutual Thrift Conversions: The Joint Effect of Regulation
and Market Discipline
Elijah Brewer III, Douglas D. Evanoff and Jacky So

WP-01-25

Opportunity Cost and Prudentiality: An Analysis of Collateral Decisions in
Bilateral and Multilateral Settings
Herbert L. Baer, Virginia G. France and James T. Moser

WP-01-26

Outsourcing Business Services and the Role of Central Administrative Offices
Yukako Ono

WP-02-01

Strategic Responses to Regulatory Threat in the Credit Card Market*
Victor Stango

WP-02-02

The Optimal Mix of Taxes on Money, Consumption and Income
Fiorella De Fiore and Pedro Teles

WP-02-03

Expectation Traps and Monetary Policy
Stefania Albanesi, V. V. Chari and Lawrence J. Christiano

WP-02-04

Monetary Policy in a Financial Crisis
Lawrence J. Christiano, Christopher Gust and Jorge Roldos

WP-02-05

Regulatory Incentives and Consolidation: The Case of Commercial Bank Mergers
and the Community Reinvestment Act
Raphael Bostic, Hamid Mehran, Anna Paulson and Marc Saidenberg

WP-02-06

2

Working Paper Series (continued)
Technological Progress and the Geographic Expansion of the Banking Industry
Allen N. Berger and Robert DeYoung

WP-02-07

Choosing the Right Parents: Changes in the Intergenerational Transmission
of Inequality  Between 1980 and the Early 1990s
David I. Levine and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-02-08

The Immediacy Implications of Exchange Organization
James T. Moser

WP-02-09

Maternal Employment and Overweight Children
Patricia M. Anderson, Kristin F. Butcher and Phillip B. Levine

WP-02-10

The Costs and Benefits of Moral Suasion: Evidence from the Rescue of
Long-Term Capital Management
Craig Furfine

WP-02-11

On the Cyclical Behavior of Employment, Unemployment and Labor Force Participation
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-02-12

Do Safeguard Tariffs and Antidumping Duties Open or Close Technology Gaps?
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-02-13

Technology Shocks Matter
Jonas D. M. Fisher

WP-02-14

Money as a Mechanism in a Bewley Economy
Edward J. Green and Ruilin Zhou

WP-02-15

Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy: Equivalence Results
Isabel Correia, Juan Pablo Nicolini and Pedro Teles

WP-02-16

Real Exchange Rate Fluctuations and the Dynamics of Retail Trade Industries
on the U.S.-Canada Border
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Beverly Lapham

WP-02-17

Bank Procyclicality, Credit Crunches, and Asymmetric Monetary Policy Effects:
A Unifying Model
Robert R. Bliss and George G. Kaufman

WP-02-18

Location of Headquarter Growth During the 90s
Thomas H. Klier

WP-02-19

The Value of Banking Relationships During a Financial Crisis:
Evidence from Failures of Japanese Banks
Elijah Brewer III, Hesna Genay, William Curt Hunter and George G. Kaufman

WP-02-20

On the Distribution and Dynamics of Health Costs
Eric French and John Bailey Jones

WP-02-21

The Effects of Progressive Taxation on Labor Supply when Hours and Wages are
Jointly Determined
Daniel Aaronson and Eric French

WP-02-22

3

Working Paper Series (continued)
Inter-industry Contagion and the Competitive Effects of Financial Distress Announcements:
Evidence from Commercial Banks and Life Insurance Companies
Elijah Brewer III and William E. Jackson III

WP-02-23

State-Contingent Bank Regulation With Unobserved Action and
Unobserved Characteristics
David A. Marshall and Edward Simpson Prescott

WP-02-24

Local Market Consolidation and Bank Productive Efficiency
Douglas D. Evanoff and Evren Örs

WP-02-25

Life-Cycle Dynamics in Industrial Sectors. The Role of Banking Market Structure
Nicola Cetorelli

WP-02-26

Private School Location and Neighborhood Characteristics
Lisa Barrow

WP-02-27

Teachers and Student Achievement in the Chicago Public High Schools
Daniel Aaronson, Lisa Barrow and William Sander

WP-02-28

The Crime of 1873: Back to the Scene
François R. Velde

WP-02-29

Trade Structure, Industrial Structure, and International Business Cycles
Marianne Baxter and Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-02-30

Estimating the Returns to Community College Schooling for Displaced Workers
Louis Jacobson, Robert LaLonde and Daniel G. Sullivan

WP-02-31

A Proposal for Efficiently Resolving Out-of-the-Money Swap Positions
at Large Insolvent Banks
George G. Kaufman

WP-03-01

Depositor Liquidity and Loss-Sharing in Bank Failure Resolutions
George G. Kaufman

WP-03-02

Subordinated Debt and Prompt Corrective Regulatory Action
Douglas D. Evanoff and Larry D. Wall

WP-03-03

When is Inter-Transaction Time Informative?
Craig Furfine

WP-03-04

Tenure Choice with Location Selection: The Case of Hispanic Neighborhoods
in Chicago
Maude Toussaint-Comeau and Sherrie L.W. Rhine

WP-03-05

Distinguishing Limited Commitment from Moral Hazard in Models of
Growth with Inequality*
Anna L. Paulson and Robert Townsend

WP-03-06

Resolving Large Complex Financial Organizations
Robert R. Bliss

WP-03-07

4

Working Paper Series (continued)
The Case of the Missing Productivity Growth:
Or, Does information technology explain why productivity accelerated in the United States
but not the United Kingdom?
Susanto Basu, John G. Fernald, Nicholas Oulton and Sylaja Srinivasan

WP-03-08

Inside-Outside Money Competition
Ramon Marimon, Juan Pablo Nicolini and Pedro Teles

WP-03-09

The Importance of Check-Cashing Businesses to the Unbanked: Racial/Ethnic Differences
William H. Greene, Sherrie L.W. Rhine and Maude Toussaint-Comeau

WP-03-10

A Structural Empirical Model of Firm Growth, Learning, and Survival
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-03-11

Market Size Matters
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Hugo A. Hopenhayn

WP-03-12

The Cost of Business Cycles under Endogenous Growth
Gadi Barlevy

WP-03-13

The Past, Present, and Probable Future for Community Banks
Robert DeYoung, William C. Hunter and Gregory F. Udell

WP-03-14

Measuring Productivity Growth in Asia: Do Market Imperfections Matter?
John Fernald and Brent Neiman

WP-03-15

Revised Estimates of Intergenerational Income Mobility in the United States
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-03-16

Product Market Evidence on the Employment Effects of the Minimum Wage
Daniel Aaronson and Eric French

WP-03-17

Estimating Models of On-the-Job Search using Record Statistics
Gadi Barlevy

WP-03-18

Banking Market Conditions and Deposit Interest Rates
Richard J. Rosen

WP-03-19

Creating a National State Rainy Day Fund: A Modest Proposal to Improve Future
State Fiscal Performance
Richard Mattoon

WP-03-20

Managerial Incentive and Financial Contagion
Sujit Chakravorti, Anna Llyina and Subir Lall

WP-03-21

Women and the Phillips Curve: Do Women’s and Men’s Labor Market Outcomes
Differentially Affect Real Wage Growth and Inflation?
Katharine Anderson, Lisa Barrow and Kristin F. Butcher

WP-03-22

Evaluating the Calvo Model of Sticky Prices
Martin Eichenbaum and Jonas D.M. Fisher

WP-03-23

5

Working Paper Series (continued)
The Growing Importance of Family and Community: An Analysis of Changes in the
Sibling Correlation in Earnings
Bhashkar Mazumder and David I. Levine

WP-03-24

Should We Teach Old Dogs New Tricks? The Impact of Community College Retraining
on Older Displaced Workers
Louis Jacobson, Robert J. LaLonde and Daniel Sullivan

WP-03-25

Trade Deflection and Trade Depression
Chad P. Brown and Meredith A. Crowley

WP-03-26

China and Emerging Asia: Comrades or Competitors?
Alan G. Ahearne, John G. Fernald, Prakash Loungani and John W. Schindler

WP-03-27

International Business Cycles Under Fixed and Flexible Exchange Rate Regimes
Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-03-28

Firing Costs and Business Cycle Fluctuations
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-03-29

Spatial Organization of Firms
Yukako Ono

WP-03-30

Government Equity and Money: John Law’s System in 1720 France
François R. Velde

WP-03-31

Deregulation and the Relationship Between Bank CEO
Compensation and Risk-Taking
Elijah Brewer III, William Curt Hunter and William E. Jackson III

WP-03-32

Compatibility and Pricing with Indirect Network Effects: Evidence from ATMs
Christopher R. Knittel and Victor Stango

WP-03-33

Self-Employment as an Alternative to Unemployment
Ellen R. Rissman

WP-03-34

Where the Headquarters are – Evidence from Large Public Companies 1990-2000
Tyler Diacon and Thomas H. Klier

WP-03-35

Standing Facilities and Interbank Borrowing: Evidence from the Federal Reserve’s
New Discount Window
Craig Furfine

WP-04-01

Netting, Financial Contracts, and Banks: The Economic Implications
William J. Bergman, Robert R. Bliss, Christian A. Johnson and George G. Kaufman

WP-04-02

Real Effects of Bank Competition
Nicola Cetorelli

WP-04-03

Finance as a Barrier To Entry: Bank Competition and Industry Structure in
Local U.S. Markets?
Nicola Cetorelli and Philip E. Strahan

WP-04-04

6

Working Paper Series (continued)
The Dynamics of Work and Debt
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-04-05

Fiscal Policy in the Aftermath of 9/11
Jonas Fisher and Martin Eichenbaum

WP-04-06

Merger Momentum and Investor Sentiment: The Stock Market Reaction
To Merger Announcements
Richard J. Rosen
Earnings Inequality and the Business Cycle
Gadi Barlevy and Daniel Tsiddon

WP-04-07

WP-04-08

7