View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Demand Volatility and the Lag
between the Growth of Temporary
and Permanent Employment
Sainan Jin, Yukako Ono, and Qinghua Zhang

WP 2007-19

Demand Volatility and the Lag between the Growth of
Temporary and Permanent Employment

Yukako Ono, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
and Qinghua Zhang, Beijing University,
with Sainan Jin, Beijing University

November 2007

Abstract
The growth rate of temporary help service employment is often considered to be a leading
business cycle indicator because the firing and hiring of temporary help workers typically lead
that of permanent workers. However, few works in the literature focus on the mechanism that
generates the lag between temporary and permanent growth. This paper investigates how firms
extract signals of long-lived shocks from noisy transitory shocks and how this influences their
hiring/firing decisions. Our simple model predicts that the average size of transitory demand
shocks increases the lag while the average size of long-lived shocks shortens the lag. Our
empirical findings based on cross-city analysis seem to support the above predictions, after
controlling for city size, share of good-producing sectors and other city-specific demographic
characteristics. In addition, we find that the effect of the size of transitory shocks depends on the
degree to which transitory demand shocks of different industries is correlated.

Key words: temporary help workers, leading business cycle indicator, demand volatility,

JEL: J01 R1

1

1. Introduction
The temporary help services (THS) industry grew drastically over the last few decades. Between
January 1990 and January 2006 in the U.S., THS employment more than doubled, growing from
1.2 million to 2.6 million workers, but total non farm employment grew only by 26%.1 Moreover,
a significant share of workers flow through the THS industries (Katz and et al., 1999). The use of
temporary workers has spread across various industries and occupations, including temporary
construction workers and temporary registered nurses. The rapid THS employment growth has
attracted substantial attention from researchers (e.g., Segal and Sullivan, 1995, 1997; Golden,
1996; Polivka, 1996; Katz and et al., 1999; and Autor, 2003) who, along with industry analysts,
have identified a number of reasons that the use of temporary workers may be attractive to firms.
One of the main reasons for firms’ use of temporary workers is the need for flexibility in
adjusting employment levels (see Ono and Sullivan (2006) for a description of other reasons). As
compared to permanent work arrangements, temporary work arrangements allow firms to use
labor for a short period of time without being responsible for workers’ benefits as well as costs
associated with hiring/firing workers. In contrast, permanent work arrangements may have an
advantage in being able to motivate workers more easily but incur costs when adjusting
employment level. Supporting the view that temporary workers facilitate flexibility in the labor
market, Golden (1996) finds evidence that a rise in demand for output above the long-run trend
produces a strong concurrent rise in THS employment.2
Consistently with such a role, THS employment growth is often considered to lead
overall employment and is used as a leading business cycle indicator, as many firms use THS as a
means to quickly adjust their operations to meet fluctuating demands for their products and
services. Economists in various business areas as well as government institutions monitor trends
in THS employment along with several other leading indicators to better forecast economic
activity. At the U.S. level, Segal and Sullivan (1995) find that THS employment growth lead
aggregate employment by at least a quarter or two over a course of a business cycle.3 They also
show that the lagged THS employment growth improves the forecast of aggregate employment
growth even though THS employment is only a small fraction of the overall economy.
1

The data are obtained from BLS Current Employment Statistics Survey in June, 2007 and can be found at
http://data.bls.gov/PDQ/outside.jsp?survey=ce .
2
Note that there are many ways that “temporary employment,” or “workers with alternative arrangements”
are defined. It may include not only workers in a THS industry but also include independent contractors,
on-call workers, and workers provided by contract firms. Our analysis focuses on THS workers.
3
Findings in Segal and Sullivan (1995) are based on their calculations of five-quarter-centered moving
averages of quarterly temporary and aggregate employment growth rates between 1973:Q2 and 1994:Q4.

2

Despite the increasing academic interest in the THS industry and the wide-spread role
that THS employment series plays as a leading indicator, few empirical papers test the
mechanism behind firms’ decisions on timings to adjust temporary and permanent employment.
In this paper, as a step toward understanding such a mechanism, we investigate determinants of
the lag between the THS and permanent employment growth rates. In particular, we develop a
model to shed light on the role that THS employment plays at a turning point of economic state
(i.e. boom and downturn) when individual firms are not sure about the change in economic state.
Our model shows that, on average over time, firms’ lag between the adjustment of temporary
employment and that of permanent employment is associated with the size of both transitory and
long-lived demand shocks. For empirical analysis, we examine cross-city variations of the lag
between temporary and permanent employment growth and test how these are related to the
degree of demand fluctuations caused by different types of shocks. Several papers (Autor, 2003;
Ono and Zelenev, 2003) consider that the use of THS workers differs across geographical areas.
However, there is little documentation on cross-city variation of lags nor is there empirical testing
on its determinants.
Our paper is related to the literature of irreversible investment cost and factor demand
under uncertainty (Pindyck, 1991); more specifically it is related to the literature of adjustment
costs and labor demand under uncertainty. Hamermesh (1989) investigates the effect of
adjustment costs on firms’ employment decision, which is motivated by the seemingly slowness
in the adjustment of employment in response to shocks. Bentolia and Bertola (1990) study how
the reduction in firing costs influences firms’ firing and hiring decisions differently and how this
affects the overall employment. Aguirregabiria and Alonso-Borrego (1999) and Campbell and
Fisher (2004) introduce the use of temporary labor, i.e., labor with costless adjustment in their
analyses of firms’ hiring and firing decisions. In particular, Aguirregabiria and Alonso-Borrego
(1999) use Spanish manufacturing data that record the number of temporary workers to
investigate the effects of introducing temporary contracts on employment and firms’ profits.
Campbell and Fisher show that firms with higher idiosyncratic risks tend to have a higher portion
of temporary labor in their total employment, which makes them more responsive to shocks since
the firing and hiring of temporary workers incur no adjustment costs.
As compared to the previous papers, our paper focuses on the lag between the
adjustment of permanent employment and that of temporary employment in response to demand
shocks. By distinguishing long-lived shocks from transitory shocks, our paper shows that the
sizes of different types of shocks have different impacts on the lag. Unlike the above mentioned
papers that emphasize the role of adjustment costs in explaining the delay in the response of

3

permanent employment, our paper mainly addresses how firms identify signals of long-lived
shocks from noisy transitory shocks, based on which the firms make their employment decisions.
Our model is a stylized model that focuses on firms’ hiring/firing decision at the turning
point of an economic state. In our model, when an economic state shifts, the firm cannot
instantaneously tell whether the observed level of demand is due to transitory shock or the change
in economic state. In order to avoid costs associated with hiring or firing permanent workers,
firms adjust only THS workers until the firm becomes more confident that the change in demand
is due to the shift of economic state and will persist in the long run. The firm infers the
probability that a state has changed by comparing the current demand shock with the extent to
which demand usually fluctuates around mean demand in each economic state. If the transitory
volatility is higher, it is more difficult for the firm to tell whether the state has shifted, since the
signal conveyed by the current demand level is too noisy. As a result, the firm is more hesitant to
adjust permanent employment. Our first prediction is that the THS employment growth leads
permanent employment growth more in a city with greater volatility of transitory shocks. In
addition, our model also implies that the lead is shorter in a city with greater differences in mean
demand levels between a downturn and boom, because it, on average, allows firms to distinguish
a shock that is transitory from that is due to a shift of an economic state. This is the second
prediction of our model.
Our cross-city examination tests the above two predictions of the model in the reduced
form. Note that the temporary workers described in our theory can be not only temporary workers
in the THS industry but also other workers under the flexible work arrangements such as
individual contractors or on-call workers. However, the data for those occupations are not readily
available at the appropriate level of time or geographical unit as we require for our examination.
The relatively better availability of the data on THS employment is consistent with wide use of
THS employment data for economic analysis in both business and academics. We examine how
the variation in the average lag between THS and permanent employment growth rates across
cities is associated with volatility that different cities face. Note that our theoretical model takes
the relative wage of temporary workers as given. In the empirical estimation, we take into
account the effect of relative wage.
Most of our data are from U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS). Included in our study
are 74 MSAs, for which we can learn monthly movement of THS employment.4 Our measures of

4

MSA definitions are based on the CBSA, which is used in the version of BLS employment data we used.
For a few MSAs, the data are not available at an MSA level, but some of the subdivisions are available. We
included MSA subdivisions in such cases.

4

city-level volatility are weighted averages of national level volatilities of each industry. We also
control for other variables such as city size and demographic characteristics. While we outline our
theoretical model focusing on one cause of THS employment growth leading permanent
employment growth, there might be other factors. We provide more detailed discussion and
interpretations in the empirical section.5
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we present our model.
Section 3 describes our empirical implementation. Section 4 discusses the empirical results.
Section 5 concludes.

2. Model
This section presents a theoretical model that provides two predictions regarding the effect of the
demand volatility on the lag between the growth of temporary employment and that of permanent
employment. Section 2-1 explains a basic setup for the model. In Section 2-2, we demonstrate a
firm’s employment decision in the stationary case where there is no persistent demand shock.
Then in Section 2-3, we show how the firm adjusts its permanent and temporary employment
level when facing a persistent demand shock, with a focus on the timing of its adjustment.

2-1. Setup
Consider a firm with production function

f (l ) = Al α , 0 < α < 1,

A > 0,

where l is efficient units of labor. When l is composed of labor by both permanent workers ( l P )
and temporary workers ( l T ), it is equal to l = cl T + l P ,

0 < c < 1 . Temporary workers are less

productive than permanent workers ( c < 1 ). The firm’s product is sold at price p. The wage rate

5

Note that hiring and firing temporary workers is not the only way that firms accommodate demand
fluctuations. Firms could adjust their inventory or overtime of permanent workers, which do not typically
incur sunk fixed costs but increase variable costs. It is beyond the scope of this paper to analyze the
interaction between these adjustments and the adjustment of temporary workers. Note also that firms could
also perform temporary layoffs, which we consider as a way to lower the fixed costs of adjusting
permanent employees (i.e. firms could save costs of training workers if the firms recall the workers they
laid off). Firms’ use of temporary workers, however, seems to suggest that a temporary layoff is not a
sufficient measure to adjust labor. Note that since the early 1990s, the use of temporary layoffs over the
recessions seems to have been diminished (McConnell and Tracy, 2005). If the diminished use of
temporary layoffs is reflecting greater costs of adjusting permanent workers, it is possible that the lags
between temporary and permanent worker growth is also increasing. While we focus on cross-city analysis
using the period after 1990 in this paper, it would be interesting to examine the link between these declines
and the increased use of temporary workers in future research.

5

of temporary labor is w , while that of permanent labor is normalized to be 1.6

Note that

w / c > 1 for firms to ever use permanent workers.
We assume that the firm can hire or let go temporary workers without any cost. We
assume, however, that the firm has to bear certain costs to adjust its permanent employment level.
Specifically, the adjustment cost is λ | Δl p | , where λ > 0 . In addition, we assume a one-time
adjustment period; a permanent worker hired today has to be trained through the current period
before becoming productive next period. A permanent worker laid-off today is also entitled to a
grace period and remains on the payroll until the end of the period. This assumption simplifies
our analysis as shown later. However, relaxation of this assumption will not change the key
results of our model qualitatively.
At time t, the maximum units of efficient labor the firm can use is
(1)

lt = ltP−1 + cltT , 0 < c < 1.

We assume that the firm takes the prices for its product and inputs as given. We also assume that
the firm’s demand is exogenously given. Given the demand yt and the level of permanent
employment from last period ltP−1 , the firm’s employment of temporary labor at t is

(2)

1
⎧
α
y
⎛
⎞
⎪ ⎜ t ⎟ − ltP−1
⎪
ltT = ⎨ ⎝ A ⎠
, if yT > A(ltP−1 )α .
c
⎪
⎪⎩0, otherwise

We specify that yt = μt + ε t , where ε t is a random i.i.d. draw from a uniform distribution
and represents the transitory demand shock. Thus, the demand yt is uniformly distributed
conditional on μt (i.e. yt | μt ∼ UNI ( μt − σ , μt + σ ) . The standard deviation of yt conditional
on μt is σ / 3 . From what follows, we use σ to measure the degree of volatility of the demand
caused by the transitory shock ε . We assume that μt is independent of ε t and serially autocorrelated over time. A change in μt represents a persistent shock to the demand. The firm can
observe demand yt at time t, while it cannot observe ε t or μt .

2-2. Firms’ decision on permanent labor when there is no persistent demand shock
6

Here, w is the relative wage of temporary labor to permanent labor. In our model, w is exogenously
given. In the empirical section, we discuss the possible endogeneity of w and how this would affect our
estimation results.

6

Let us consider the stationary case where μt remains at μ . Note that because of the assumed
one-time adjustment period, any change in permanent employment today does not affect the
firm’s contemporaneous gross profit. The firm determines the current permanent employment
level to maximize the sum of expected future profits net of adjustment cost. The firm’s value
function at time t is

J (ltP−1 ; μ ) = max l P Eπ (ltP−1 ; μ ) − λ | ltP − ltP−1 | + β J (ltP ; μ ),

(3)

t

where Eπ (.) is the expected gross profit of the firm and

Eπ (ltP−1 ; μ ) = ∫

(4)

μ +σ

μ −σ

( pyt − wltT (ltP−1 ) − ltP−1 ) dyt ,

where ltT (.) is a function of the level of permanent employment from the previous period, which
is defined by (2).
Solving the above Bellman equation (3), we have the optimal decision rule on the
permanent employment level at time t as follows:

ltP*

(5)

⎧lt+ P > ltP−1 : β J1 (lt+ P ; μ ) = λ , if β J1 (ltP−1 ; μ ) > λ
⎪
= ⎨lt− P < ltP−1 : β J1 (lt− P ; μ ) = −λ , if β J1 (ltP−1 ; μ ) < −λ
⎪P
P
⎩lt −1 , if β J1 (lt −1 ; μ ) ∈ [−λ , λ ]

where J1 (.) is the first order derivative of the value function with respect to last period’s
permanent employment; lt+ P is the targeted optimal level if the firm needs to increase its
permanent employment from below; lt− P is the targeted optimal level if the firm needs to decrease
its permanent employment from above. Using (5), and considering the stationary setup, we obtain

J (lt+ P ; μ ) =

Eπ (lt+ P ; μ )
Eπ (lt− P ; μ )
and J (lt− P ; μ ) =
. Let us denote Eπ 1 (.) as the first order
1− β
1− β

derivative of the expected one-time gross profit with respect to last period’s permanent
employment. Note that because of the adjustment period, permanent employment from the
previous period is the amount of permanent labor ready to be used this time.
Assumption 1. The parameter space of our model is such that Eπ 1 (.) is a strictly decreasing
function of ltP−1 .

7

Under Assumption 1, it is straightforward to show that both lt+ P and lt− P are uniquely
determined and lt+ P < lt− P . Note that neither lt+ P nor lt− P depends on ltP−1 . Thus from now on, for
notational simplicity, we omit the subscript “t”.
It can also be shown that under Assumption 1, J1 (.) is a strictly decreasing function of ltP−1 .

Therefore, we can write

⎧> λ , if ltP−1 < l + P
⎪
β J1 (ltP−1 ; μ ) ⎨< −λ , if ltP−1 > l − P
⎪∈ [−λ , λ ], o.w.
⎩

Thus, we have another decision rule which is equivalent to (5),

(5’)

ltP*

⎧l + P , if ltP−1 < l + P
⎪
= ⎨l − P , if ltP−1 > l − P
⎪P
⎩lt −1 , o.w.

This tells us that the firm increases its permanent employment level to l + P if it starts from
below l + P , and the firm reduces its permanent employment level to l − P if it starts from below l − P .
If the initial level lies within the interval [l + P , l − P ] , then the firm will not make any adjustment of
its permanent employment. This interval consists of all the sustainable permanent employment
levels. The existence of such an interval is due to the adjustment cost.
In our stationary setting, demand fluctuates around μ over time due to the transitory
shock ε . In any sustainable equilibrium, the firm’s temporary employment fluctuates while
permanent employment remains unchanged. Suppose the permanent employment is l + P . The
expected temporary employment at any given time is the same and from (2), it is calculated

(6)

1+α
1+α
⎛
α
α ⎜ (μ + σ ) − y α
E (ltT ) = ⎝
1
α
2cσ A (1 + α )

⎞
⎟ +P
⎠ − l ( μ + σ − y ) , where y = A(l + P )α .
2cσ

2-3. Firms’ adjustment of permanent labor when there is a persistent demand shock
Now, let us examine how firms respond (by adjusting permanent labor) to persistent demand
shocks, which affect μ . One example of persistent shocks is the national business cycle shock
that has a persistent effect on firms’ demand. When such a shock occurs at time t, firms are

8

alerted about the possibility of a persistent shock. For example, at the turning points of national
business cycles, there is a lot of speculation going on in the media. However, they may not be
able to tell the exact type of the shock instantaneously. This is because a firm can only observe
the overall level of demand yt at time t. We assume that the change in μ is revealed in the next
period.
For simplicity, we assume there are two states of μ specified by μ l and μ h (low and
high states), where μl < μ h and μl + σ > μ h − σ . The conditional distribution of demand is

yt | μl ~ UNI ( μl − σ , μl + σ ) for the low state and yt | μh ~ UNI ( μh − σ , μh + σ ) for the high
state. We consider the case of positive persistent demand shocks. The case of negative shocks can
be analyzed in a similar way. For simplicity, we focus on three periods τ − 1 , τ , and τ + 1 . Up to

τ − 1 , the state of mean demand remains unchanged at the low state. At τ , the mean demand
switches to the high state and remains unchanged from time τ on. At τ + 1 , the true state of μ is
revealed to the firm. Note that at τ , the firm cannot observe μ , and the firm can only draw
inference on the probability of a state change according to the overall demand at τ and the
average demand volatility it faced in the past.
Let ls+ P ≡ l + P ( μ s ) , and let ls− P ≡ l − P ( μ s ) , where s ∈ {l , h} . We make the following
assumption.
Assumption 2. The parameter space of our model is such that ll− P < lh+ p .

According to Assumption 2, when there is a state change from s1 to s2 , as long as the initial
permanent employment level is within the sustainable range of state s 1 , it is optimal for the firm
to adjust its permanent employment to match the need of state s2 , if there is no uncertainty about
the state change. However, with incomplete information, there would be a delay in the firm’s
response to a state change due to incomplete information.
Let V (lτP ;θ ) be the expected future profits when the firm sets the permanent
employment to be lτP at τ and when the firm believes that the probability that the state shifted
from s1 to s2 is θ . Note that θ is subjective probability. We discuss how the firm forms such a

9

probability later in this section. The firm needs to choose lτP in order to maximize the following
objective function

max l P βV (lτP ;θ ) − λ | lτP − lτP−1 | ,

(7)

τ

where

V (lτP ;θ ) = θ J (lτP ; μ s2 ) + (1 − θ ) J (lτP ; μ s1 ) .
The optimal decision rule is

lτP*

(8)

⎧lτ+ P > lτP−1 : β V1 (lτ+ P ;θ ) = λ , if β V1 (lτP−1 ;θ ) > λ
⎪
= ⎨lτ+ P < lτP−1 : β V1 (lτ+ P ;θ ) = −λ , if β V1 (lτP−1 ;θ ) < −λ
⎪P
P
⎩lτ −1 , if β V1 (lτ −1 ;θ ) ∈ [−λ , λ ]

where V1 (.) is the first order derivative of V (.) with respect to lτP .
Next, let us examine the case when the state switches from low to high.7 Suppose the
initial level of permanent employment before the state change is within the sustainable range of
the low state. We have the following proposition.
Proposition 1. Suppose lτP−1 ∈ [ll+ P , ll− P ] . Under Assumption 1 and 2, we have:
i) V1 < 0
ii) lτP* ∈ [lτP−1 , lh+ P ) and lτP* is uniquely determined by β V1 (lτP ;θ ) = λ when lτP* > lτP−1
iii) V1 (lτP ;θ ) > V1 (lτP ;θ '), ∀lτP ∈ [lτP−1 , lh+ P ), ∀θ > θ '
iv) lτP* increases with θ and strictly increases with θ when lτP* > lτP−1 ; v) lτP+*1 = lh+ P .

Proof. See Appendix B.

Proposition 1 tells us that due to uncertainty at the turning point, the firm either maintains its
permanent employment level or makes a partial adjustment. The amount of adjustment (if there
is any) at the turning point is bigger when the firm’s subjective probability that the state switched
is higher.
The intuition is clear. If the firm increases its permanent employment to the high state
level at τ , the firm could rake in more profits next period if the revealed state is indeed high
because the newly hired permanent workers today become productive in next period and
7

The analysis of the case from high state to low state can be done in a similar way.

10

contribute to meeting the greater demand. On the other hand, if the economic state remains low,
the firm would have to readjust its permanent employment back to the low state level and thus
double pay the adjustment cost. The firm’s decision hinges on the subjective probability that the
state has shifted from low to high, which we denote by θ .
Define d ≡ (lh+ P − lτP−1 ) / 2 , where d is equal to half of the full adjustment that the firm
needs to make in permanent employment from the low state to the high state. We measure the lag
between the state change and the adjustment of permanent employment in the following way. If
the adjustment at the turning point τ is greater than or equal to d, which is half of the full
adjustment, then the lag is zero; otherwise, the lag is 1. This is the median lag idea. According
to iv) of Proposition 1, the firm’s adjustment is greater than d at τ if and only if the firm’s
subjective probability of a state change exceeds a certain threshold, denoted by θˆ s.t.
(9)

lτP* (θˆ) = lτP−1 + d .

In Appendix C, we show in detail how to solve for the permanent employment at the turning
point., as well as for the threshold probability.
We assume that the firm derives the subjective probability θ in the following way.8
Observing the current demand, yτ , the firm asks itself what is the underlying probability with
which the realized value yτ is greater than a random drawn demand level if the current state of
mean demand is still low. This probability gives the confidence level at which the firm could
reject the hypothesis that μτ remains at its low level. Because we assume the demand follows a
uniform distribution and the only difference between the high state and the low state distribution
lies in the mean, we know that the firm faces uncertainty about the current mean only when the
observed demand level falls within the intersection of the high state distribution interval and the
low state distribution interval, namely μ h − σ < yτ < μl + σ . Therefore, θ is calculated as
(10)

⎧0, if yτ < μh − σ
⎪
y − μh + σ
⎪
,if μ h − σ < yτ < μl + σ
θ = ⎨ prob( y < yτ | μτ = μl , μh − σ < yτ < μl + σ ) = τ
2
σ
μ
μ
−
+
h
l
⎪
⎪⎩1, otherwise

8

There are other methods with which a firm derives the subjective probability. Although studying these
methods is an interesting and important research topic, it is beyond the scope of this paper.

11

Based on (13), the threshold demand level, ŷ , at which the subjective probability exceeds the
threshold value θˆ can be derived from

y = (2σ − μh + μl )θ + μh − σ ,

(11)
Where θˆ is defined in (12).

Now let us derive the probability that the firms increase permanent labor at τ , which is just
equal to the probability that yτ ≥ yˆ given μτ = μ h :

prob R =

(12)

μh + σ − yˆ
μ −μ
= (1 − θˆ) + h l θˆ .
2σ
2σ

Thus, under the above framework, the average time lag between the increase in the mean demand
and the recruiting of permanent workers is

L = 0 × prob R + 1× (1 − prob R ) = θˆ −

(13)

μ h − μl ˆ
θ.
2σ

Next, let us look at the movement of temporary employment. Prior to the change of the
state, the expected temporary employment is El T (lτP−1 ; μl ) . At time τ , whether or not the firm
increases its permanent labor responding to the shock, the productive permanent labor remains at
the level that corresponds to the low state due to the adjustment period. Thus, the firm is likely to
use more temporary workers as it is likely to face higher demand at time τ ; that is, the expected
temporary employment, denoted El T (lτP−1 ; μ h ) , should increase instantaneously when the state
of mean demand switches from low to high.
From (6), we can show that El T (lτP−1 ; μh ) > El T (lτP−1 ; μl ) . This implies that on average,
the increase in temporary employment leads that of permanent employment by L, while L stands
for the average lag between the growth in temporary employment and that of permanent
employment when there is a positive persistent demand shock. How does the volatility of demand
influence the average lag between the growth in temporary employment and permanent
employment? It is clear from (12) that prob R decreases with the size of transitory shocks,
measured by σ .
From (13), the average lag L between the change in temporary employment and
permanent employment increases with σ , given θˆ .

Moreover, prob R increases with the

difference in the mean demand between the high state and the low state, μ h − μ l , given θˆ . Note
that μ h − μ l reflects the size of persistent demand shocks. Thus the average lag between the

12

movement in temporary and permanent employment shortens with, the size of persistent shocks,
given θˆ . Because θˆ is endogenously determined and is a function of demand volatility, next, we
solve for the threshold value θˆ and the corresponding average lag numerically, through
simulations under various demand volatility. In the simulations, we let the initial permanent
employment level to be at the upper end of the sustainable interval, i.e., lτP−1 = ll− P . The values of
parameters used in the simulations are:

α = 0.67, β = 0.982, A = 0.2, p = 500, μl = 800,
μh − μl = 200 (or 100), λ = 0.5, w = 0.8, c = 0.5.
We let the one time interval here to have a length of 6 months. Therefore, the discount rate is
approximately 0.982 if the monthly discount rate is 0.997. Three parameters are essential; they
are marginal adjustment cost of permanent employment λ , the wage ratio of temporary labor to
permanent labor w, and the productivity ratio of temporary labor to permanent labor c. It is hard
to measure the marginal adjustment costs. Campbell and Fisher (2004) take the severance
payment as between 0.5 to 1.5 times of the quarterly salary. We let the marginal adjustment costs
to be equal to 0.5 times of the half-year salary. As for the wage ratio, we let w=0.8, since the
wage ratio of temporary labor to permanent labor is about 0.8 on average in the U.S. over 19902006. We experiment with different values of c, and we obtain qualitatively similar results
regarding the relationship between the average lag and the volatility of demand, as long as c < w .
Our simulations demonstrate that as σ increases, prob R decreases, and the average lag
L between the growth of permanent and temporary employment increases (see Figure 1-a). The
intuition behind this prediction is that when the firm faces less volatility caused by transitory
shocks, it is easier for the firm to identify persistent shocks. Thus the firm responds more quickly
to a positive persistent shock by increasing its permanent employment. Our simulations also
show that as δ increases, prob R increases, and the average lag L decreases (see Figure 1-a). The
firm responds more quickly by increasing the permanent employment when the size of a
persistent shock is greater. This is because the greater the persistent shock, the easier the firm can
identify it. It is also because the firm would suffer more loss if it were slow in increasing
permanent employment level in response to greater increase in the mean demand level. From
Figure 1-a, one can see that the average lag between temporary and permanent employment is
shorter when the amplitude of a shift in the mean demand is 200 compared to the case of 100.

13

We have so far examined the case where the state shifts from low to high. Similar results
can be obtained in the case of negative persistent shocks where the state of μ changes from

μh to μl . In this case, the subjective probability of μ = μl is calculated as
⎧0, if yτ > μl + σ
⎪
μ + σ − yτ
⎪
(14) θ = ⎨ prob( y > yτ | μ = μ h , μ h − σ <yτ < μl + σ ) = l
,if μh − σ < yτ < μl + σ
2σ − μ h + μ L
⎪
⎪⎩1, otherwise
The expression of the average lag is the same as (13). Figure 1-b shows that the previous two
predictions apply to the case of a negative persistent demand shock as well.

3. Data source and the construction of key variables
In our theoretical model, we consider the fluctuations of temporary and permanent employment
that are caused by stochastic shocks and examine the lag between temporary and permanent
employment series. However, in reality, both permanent and temporary employment grow with
some time trend that is deterministic. Therefore, in the empirical section, we use growth rates of
temporary and permanent employment, which removes the linear trend from both temporary and
permanent employment series. This allows us to better capture the lag associated with stochastic
shocks.
Based on the above theoretical prediction, we test to see how the lag between temporary
and permanent employment growth rates for each city i, Li , is associated with our measures for
the average size of transitory shock , viT and that of long-lived shock, viP , using the observations
available for 74 MSAs. Below, we explain details on data availability as well as how we construct
our key variables.

3-1. Lag between temporary and permanent employment growth rates for a city
To calculate the lag between temporary and permanent employment growth rates for each city,
we use BLS monthly employment data between January 1990 and May 2005. Starting with 1990,
the BLS provides MSA level data for each city if the size of the industry in the city is larger than
a certain level. In most cases, the narrowest industry category available is the 4-digit NAICS
level. This limits us to the employment series of NAICS 5613 (Employment Services), which
include NAICS 56132 (THS), to capture the growth rate of temporary employment. At the U.S.
level, about 70% of workers in the employment services sector belong to the THS industry during
our sample period, while the rest belong to employment placement agencies and professional

14

employment organizations. When we compare the growth rates for these industries, the
correlation coefficient between the growth rate of the THS industry and that of employment
services is .97.
During our study period, employment data for the employment services sector (NAICS
5613) are available for 74 MSAs, which we use for our analysis. As for permanent employment,
we use total employment of all private sectors excluding the employment services sector. Note
that the time series data of temporary employment for each industry is not available at either the
national level or MSA level.
In Figure 2, we plot the 12-month growth rates for both temporary and permanent
employment for two cities. Figure 2-a is that for Colorado Springs, CO, and Figure 2-b is
Portland-Vancouver-Beaverton, OR-WA. Temporary employment growth rates seem to lead in
Portland, but such a relationship is weak in Colorado. An issue in this paper is to what extent can
such a cross-city variation in lags be explained by variation in volatilities.
We use several methods to estimate the lag (denoted as Lk ) between the temporary
employment growth rate (denoted as g kT ) and the permanent employment growth rate (denoted as

g kP ) for each city k. We seasonally adjust monthly growth rates and estimate the lag using not
only the monthly growth rates themselves but also the smoothed series (i.e., moving averages) of
temporary and permanent employment growth rates. As we demonstrated in our model, the mean
value of temporary employment growth shifts in response to the shift of the mean demand, while
its actual value fluctuates depending on realized value of outputs.
As one way to measure the lag, for each city k, we estimate a finite distributed lag
model,9

g ktP = α 0 k + β 0 k g ktT + β1k g ktT −1 + β 2 k g ktT − 2 + β3k g ktT −3 + ... + β Lk g ktT − L + ε kt ,
where L is set as 12. The sum of the β coefficients represents the cumulative effects of a unit
increment in temporary employment growth on permanent employment growth. We calculate
both median and mean lags. Note that while the total effects (the sum of 13 point estimates
including the contemporaneous effect and the effects 1 to 12 months later) are positive for almost
all the cities, the point estimates for β are not always zero; the cumulative effects are not
necessarily monotonic. We focus on using a median lag measure, which we define as the first

9

An implicit assumption here is that temporary employment leads permanent employment. We will relax
this assumption to do a robustness check.

15

month when the cumulative effect on permanent employment growth exceeds half of the total
effects.10
Table 1 shows the summary statistics of lag measures and total effects. The median lags
are around 4.5, which is consistent with Segal and Sullivan’s (1995) findings for the national
level. The total increment of the permanent employment growth rate 12 months after a unit
increase in temporary employment growth is about one tenths, which corresponds to the
difference between the s.d. of temporary and permanent growth rates. Among the cities included
in our study, the s.d. of permanent employment growth is .00473 and that of temporary growth
rate is .0407. For the three month moving average (MA) series, the s.d.s of permanent and
temporary growth rates are .0028 and .0229, respectively. For other MA series, we also find
similar tendencies.

3-2. Average size of transitory and permanent demand shocks faced by industries in a city
To capture the transitory and persistent demand shocks faced by industries in a city, we first
capture the volatilities of each industry at the national level. To obtain city-level volatility, we
then calculate the weighted average of industry volatilities using the industry mix of the city.
Even for the U.S. as a whole, monthly industry output data are not available for many industries
especially among non-manufacturing industries.11 While monthly employment data are readily
available for many industries, such data record the number of permanent employees (workers on
payroll). The fluctuation of permanent employees would not be ideal to capture the transitory
shock based on our framework. Moreover, the volatility of permanent employment would be
endogenous to an industry’s tendency to use temporary workers. We use the BLS monthly data
for total weekly production labor hours including overtime,12 which is likely to fluctuate with
transitory demand shock. In particular, we consider that the overtime portion of labor hours
would fluctuate with transitory shocks as adjusting overtime would not generally incur fixed
costs.13

10

The correlation coefficients between the median and mean lags range between .70 and .75. Some lags are
measured as below zero or greater than 12 by applying the definition of mean lag.
11
The U.S. Census Bureau produces a monthly indicator for output based on their M3 (Manufacturers’
shipments, inventories, and orders) survey for many manufacturing industries. However, such data are not
available for non-manufacturing industries.
12
The data are from the Current Employment Statistics report performed by the BLS. The production
workers (in both goods producing and non-goods producing sectors) are generally defined as nonsupervisory employees. The data on overtime are separately available only for manufacturing sectors.
13
To capture the fluctuation of labor and corresponding outputs, it would be ideal to look at the total labor
hours that also include hours worked by temporary workers. However, since temporary workers are on the
payroll of THS firms, their hours are not included in the industry to which they actually contribute.

16

Note also that while it is not feasible to use MSA-level hour data because of the limited
availability of such series, the use of national-level data is preferable because it removes possible
effects of unobserved city-specific factors. If there are any city-specific factors that influence both
the lag and the output fluctuations of all industries in the city, by using city-level data to capture
fluctuation, we would capture a spurious relationship between these variables. The volatility of
national-level industry labor hours data is unlikely to be endogenous to a city-level lag between
temporary and permanent employment growth.
To distinguish between transitory and persistent demand shocks, we apply the filtering to
the data for total production labor hours including overtime. We decompose the fluctuations of
labor hours into cycles of different periodicities. Cycles of shorter periodicities correspond to
volatility driven by higher frequency (transitory) shocks while cycles of longer periodicities
correspond to volatility driven by lower frequency shocks.
Specifically, we construct two filters. One is the High Pass (HP) filter that passes
components of the demand series with periodicity less than or equal to 4 months. The HP filter
passes high frequency and noisy components that are considered transitory (see Gan and Zhang,
2006). Therefore, the filtered time series reflects transitory shocks. We also construct the Band
Pass (BP) filter that passes cycles between 18 and 96 months in periodicity. This BP filter is well
known as the business cycle, which is defined by Burns and Mitchell as cyclical components of
no less than 6 quarters (18 months) in duration and no more than 32 quarters (96 months). We
consider the resulting time series through the BP filter to capture the long-lived shocks.14
For each industry at a national level, we use the standard deviation of a filtered business
cycle series (denoted as σ Pj for industry j) as a measure of the size of the long-lived shock, and
use the standard deviation of a filtered high pass series to measure the size of the transitory shock
(denoted as σ Tj ). We then calculate the volatility measures for each city taking weighted
averages of industry-level volatility using a city’s industry mix. In particular, the volatility of
long-lived shocks for city i is vkP =

∑w σ
j∈I j

kj

P
j

, where I i is the set of industries in city k, and wij is

the share of industry j in city c. The transitory volatility for city i is vkT =

∑w σ
j∈I j

kj

T
j

. We calculate

the industry mix based on the 1998 County Business Patterns (CBP) data. The year 1998 is
14

There are various ways to construct filters. Here, we follow Baxter and King (1999). In approximating
the ideal filter, a truncation point needs to be specified. The truncation point we chose, denoted as K, is 36.
We tested a range of values for K=[24, 32, 54, 72] and find shocks are not sensitive to the choice of K. We
also experimented with other ways to construct filters, such as that of Corbae, Ouliaris, and Phillips (2002).
The results are similar.

17

almost the middle of the period for which we use BLS hours data, as well as the first year when
the CBP uses NAICS as industry classification that is used for the BLS hour data.15
Analogous to the way we calculate the lag, we use the growth rates of total labor hours
(including overtime) rather than the level to capture the volatility. Note that we also could have
used the level of labor hours for capturing the volatility of demand in each industry.
However, the volatility measure based on level is subject to the size of industry. By using the
growth rates instead of the level of total labor hours, we naturally solve this problem. We thus
can use the share of each industry in a city as a weight and obtain the city-level volatility as a
weighted average volatility across industries.

3-3. Other control
Note that while our model takes the relative wage of temporary workers as given, it is possible
that greater transitory volatility causes higher wages for temporary workers because it increases
the demand for temporary workers in general. The higher relative wage for temporary workers
may weaken the positive effect of the transitory volatility on the lag because it diminishes the
benefit from using temporary workers. Such an effect may be more pronounced in a city where
transitory shocks of different industries in the city co-move more closely. If many industries
require temporary workers at the same time, the companies providing temporary labor services
cannot smooth their supply of temporary workers and may increase the mark-up to offset such a
risk (Ono and Zelenev, 2003). Thus, we expect that the positive effect of the transitory volatility
on the lag is smaller when the co-movement is greater. Therefore, we incorporate the interaction
between the transitory volatility and a co-movement measure.
The co-movement measure we use is defined as ρk ≡

∑∑ w
i

i≠ j

ki

wkj σTij , where σTij is a

covariance of transitory shocks between industry i and industry j , and wki is the share of industry
i in city k . We obtain transitory shocks for each industry at the national level through filtering as
specified in section 3-2.
In addition, we control for city size as represented by the average of the log of city
permanent employment during our study period because the thick market effect may influence the
efficiency of matching in the labor market. We also control for some demographic characteristics
of MSA population, such as the share of the population by age, education, and race in order to

15

We checked to what extent industry mix in a given MSA change over time using 1987 and 1997 CBP
data. The correlation between industry shares in 1987 and those in 1997 for each MSA is on average .96.

18

control for the supply of temporary workers. As demonstrated in Polivka (1996), demographic
characteristics of temporary workers are quite different from that of permanent workers. Thus, the
differences in demographic characteristics across cities may influence the supply of temporary
workers. Moreover, we control for the city’s share of good producing sector. The intensity of
their use of temporary employment is higher as compared to the service sector (Cohany, 1998).
We discuss more details as we show results. Table 2 shows the summary statistics of all variables.

4. Empirical Results
Table 3 shows our estimation results. The results with the lag measure based on monthly growth
rates are in Table 3-a, those with the lag based on 5-month MA series, 9-month MA series, 11month MA series and 15-month MA series are in Tables 3-b, c, d, and e, respectively. All the
results we present here are based on median lags.
Among the regressions with various moving average series, we found the results using the
lag measures based on 9- and 11-month MAs reveal statistically significant evidence that
supports our hypothesis. To compare different results, we show the results with lag measures
based on simple growth rates, 5-month MA, 9-month MA, 11-month MA, and 15-month MA.
First, the regressions based on a simple specification without co-movement measures
show only a few statistically significant coefficients (see column (1) in Table 3). Among them,
the results based on 11-month and 15-month MAs show the expected sign for the average size of
long-lived shocks.
With the interaction term between the average size of transitory shocks and the comovement measure, the effects of all the variables are more tightly estimated, as you can see in
the results in column (2) in the series of tables. In particular, the coefficient for the size of
transitory shocks is significant and positive; its interaction with the co-movement measure is
significant and negative in the results based on 9-month and 11-month MA. The results remain
qualitatively the same even after we control for demographic variables (see column (3) of Table
3-c and 3-d). The effect of the average size of transitory shock is positive when the co-movement
measure is small, and the effect is negative when the co-movement measure is large. Using the
results with specification (3) in both 9- and 11-month MAs (Tables 3-c and 3-d), with a simple
calculation, we can see that the effect of the average size of transitory shocks turn from positive
to negative as the co-movement measure exceeds a threshold that is slightly above its mean.
When the transitory shocks are diversified enough across industries in a city, greater average size
of such shocks increases the lag between temporary and permanent employment of the city,
which is consistent with our model’s prediction. However, when transitory shocks are more

19

correlated among industries, as we discussed previously, it is possible that the negative effect of
higher relative wage for temporary workers dominates the positive effects that our theory
predicts. While our model does not incorporate the wage effect, it may be instructive to do so in
the future.
We calculate the magnitude of the effect of a s.d. change in the size of transitory shock
(.000411), which depends on the degree of co-movement. Using the specification (3) with a 9month MA, in a city with an average co-movement measure (.00646), the effect is positive but
small at around .4 months. However, in a city with the lowest co-movement measure (.00574), it
is 2 months. We also calculate the magnitude of the effect of the size of a long-lived shock using
the same result. A s.d. increase in the size of a long-lived shock decreases the lag by 1.08 months.
Note that the coefficients for the size of long-lived shocks are quite different between the 9- and
11-month MA results, although they both have the predicted sign. The estimated effect based on
the 11-month MA series is greater than that based on the 9-month MA. According to column (3)
in Table 3-d, a s.d. increase in the size of the long-lived shock decreases the lag by 2.46 months.
As a robustness check, using 11-month MA series, we additionally control for the ratio of
the city’s temporary to permanent employment. Such a ratio would help control for city-level
relative temporary wage. It is also suggested by other papers that the size of adjustment costs
would influence such a ratio. The qualitative results for all the variables remain the same, and we
obtain even slightly stronger effects of both volatility measures
The significance of coefficients for city size vary across specifications. The city size
effect is marginally significant according to the results based on the 9-month MA (see column
(3), Table 3-c). The lag declines with city size when the city size is small; however, the lag
increases with city size once the city size exceeds a certain level. There are various reasons why
city size may be associated with the lag. An explanation lies in another role of temporary workers
on which our model does not focus. Due to the imperfect information problem in the labor
market, firms often use temporary workers before they find a qualified permanent worker, or they
use temporary arrangements to screen for permanent workers. The longer it takes for firms to find
a qualified permanent worker, the longer the lag between temporary and permanent employment
growths would be. In a larger city, because of the thick market effect, firms are able to find better
matched workers on average. This may shorten the search and screening process. On the other
hand, in a larger city, firms may form a higher expectation of matching and become more
selective in hiring permanent workers. This may cause a longer search and screening process.
The results seem to indicate that, among smaller cities, the thick market effect dominates; once
the city size reaches a certain level, the selective effect begins to take over.

20

The demographic controls included in the regressions are the share of population with
characteristics more common among temporary workers as compared to that of permanent
workers. On average, temporary workers tend to be younger, low-educated, and non-white. In our
results, the share of non-whites has a significant and positive impact on the lag based on the 11month MA results (see column (3), Table 3-d). This may be because of the supply effect. The
share of young population in a city tends to be negatively associated with the lag. Significant
coefficients were not obtained for the low-educated population share.
Finally we note that several specifications suggest that the share of the good-producing
sector is positively associated with the lag (see column (3), Table 3-c and 3-d). One story behind
this result is that the cost per efficient temporary labor may be lower for the good-producing
sector as compared to the service sector, given the same wage. It is possible that manufacturers
require more standardized and well-defined tasks than service sectors, which causes productivity
difference between permanent and temporary workers in the good-producing sector to be smaller
than that in the service sector.

5. Conclusion
By combining uncertainty and adjustment costs, this paper shows that incomplete information
may have important implications for firms’ responses to demand shocks.

Specifically, our

findings seem to suggest that firms draw inference on the mean demand based on the volatility
that they experience. The average sizes of both transitory and long-lived shocks seem to affect
the inference and in turn affect firms’ timing of adjusting permanent and temporary workers. Our
cross-city analysis finds that the demand volatility caused by transitory shocks increases the lag
between the temporary and permanent employment growth in cities where the degree to which
transitory shocks are correlated across industries is low enough. The volatility of permanent
shocks seems to have the opposite effect on the lag. These findings shed light on the dynamics
of permanent and temporary employment over business cycles.

21

Tables and Figures

Table 1

Lag measures based on monthly growth rates:
Total effects
N. of MSAs Median lag1
with positive
total effects
70
4.84 (2.61)
.0956 (.0559)

Non-smoothed series
Moving average series
5 month moving average
73
4.63 (3.18)
9 month moving average
73
4.70 (3.72)
11 month moving average
74
5.05 (4.10)
15 month moving average
73
5.86 (4.40)
1
The first month that the cumulative effects exceed half of the total effects.
( ): standard deviation

.102 (.0606)
.110 (.0639)
.116 (.0659)
.119 (.0661)

Correlation between lags based on different MAs
5 month MA
9 month MA
11 month MA
15 month MA

Non-smoothed
0.691
0.655
0.526
0.412

5-month MA

9-month MA

11-month MA

0.857
0.670
0.627

0.804
0.755

0.792

Table 2 Volatility measures and other controls: 74 cities
Variables

Mean

Transitory shock s.d.: Cycle < 4 months
Long-lived shock s.d.
Co-movement measure

.0108 .000411
.00214 .000131
.00646 .000318

City size: Log permanent workers: average over the sample period
Share of good producing industries
Share of population
Population of the age between 18 and 24
(out of age between 18 and 66 )
Population without four year college degree
Non-white population

S.d.

6.01
.224

.97
.0705

.142

.016

.801
.249

.0526
.109

22

Table 3 Results of regressions of the median lag between temporary and permanent
employment growth rates on volatility measures and other controls
Table 3-a Lag based on monthly growth rates
(1)
Transitory shock s.d.:
Cycle < 4 month

(2)
-76.309
(-0.30)

(3)
11955
(0.92)

13664
(1.10)

-2019188
(-1.04)

-2306807
(-1.25)

-5080
(-1.19)

-4137
(-1.12)

26232
(1.22)

28945
(1.42)

-5.78
(-1.25)

-7.41*
(-1.70)

-7.39*
(-1.75)

City size squared

.426
(1.21)

.535
(1.58)

.527
(1.59)

Share of good producing

-1.08
(0.15)

12.4
(1.42)

8.102
(1.00)

Transitory shock s.d:
× Comovement measure
Long-lived shock s.d.

1113
(0.29)

Comovement measure

City size

Age: 18~24

Low education

Non-white

-35.5*
(-1.68)
7.41
(1.00)
.161
(.05)

*** indicates statistical significance at the 1% level.
** indicates statistical significance at the 5% level.
* indicates statistical significance at the 10% level.
( ): t-statistics based on robust standard errors
Constant term is included in the regression; 70 cities with positive total effects are included in the
regressions.

23

Table 3-b Lag based on 5-month MA series
(1)
Transitory shock s.d.:
Cycle < 4 month

(2)
-26.2
(-0.30)

(3)
13095
(0.92)

14432
(0.95)

-2084150
(-0.97)

-2251267
(-0.98)

261
(0.07)

-2095
(-0.48)

24378
(1.02)

25809
(1.02)

-8.82
(-1.75)

-9.49*
(-1.81)

-9.56*
(-1.83)

City size squared

.716
(1.82)

.761
(1.87)

.745*
(1.84)

Share of good producing

6.50
(0.71)

13.0
(1.35)

16.43
(1.55)

Transitory shock s.d:
× Comovement measure
Long-lived shock s.d.

3090
(0.80)

Comovement measure

City size

Age: 18~24

-38.3
(-1.49)

Low education

-6.22
(-0.69)

Non-white

2.75
(.98)

*** indicates statistical significance at the 1% level.
** indicates statistical significance at the 5% level.
* indicates statistical significance at the 10% level.
( ): t-statistics based on robust standard errors
Constant term is included in the regression; 73 cities with positive total effects are included in the
regressions.

24

Table 3-c Lag based on 9-month MA series
(1)
Transitory shock s.d.:
853
Cycle < 4 month
(-0.74)

(2)
36907***
(3.08)

(3)
37696***
(2.88)

-5623776***
(-3.05)

-5690817***
(-2.82)

-5817
(-1.36)

-8280*
(-1.67)

63014***
(3.06)

63446***
(2.83)

-9.19
(-1.47)

-10.1
(-1.6)

-10.7*
(-1.68)

City size squared

.776
(1.60)

.837*
(1.71)

.863*
(1.84)

Share of good producing

14.2
(1.43)

22.5*
(1.99)

26.33**
(2.10)

Transitory shock s.d:
× Comovement measure
Long-lived shock s.d.

-1821
(-.48)

Comovement measure

City size

Age: 18~24

Low education

Non-white

-31.96
(-1.11)
-9.46
(-.92)
1.06
(.33)

*** indicates statistical significance at the 1% level.
** indicates statistical significance at the 5% level.
* indicates statistical significance at the 10% level.
( ): t-statistics based on robust standard errors
Constant term is included in the regression; 72 cities with positive total effects are included in the
regressions.

25

Table 3-d Lag based on 11-month MA series
(1)
Transitory shock s.d.:
188
Cycle < 4 month
(.17)
Transitory shock s.d:
× Comovement measure
Long-lived shock s.d.

City size squared

Share of good producing

Age: 18~24

Low education

Non-white

(3)
31249*
(1.97)

-4692915**
(-2.15)

-4916061**
(-2.04)

-14377***
(-2.78)

-18782***
(-2.98)

55113**
(2.83)

56965**
(2.13)

-1.82
(-.27)

-3.25
(-.47)

-2.18
(-.30)

.238
(.45)

.333
(.60)

.206
(.35)

16.72
(1.47)

32.6***
(2.88)

40.5***
(3.00)

-7137*
(-1.68)

Comovement measure

City size

(2)
29636**
(2.06)

-53.0*
(-1.68)
-6.52
(-.64)
9.87**
(2.06)

*** indicates statistical significance at the 1% level.
** indicates statistical significance at the 5% level.
* indicates statistical significance at the 10% level.
( ): t-statistics based on robust standard errors
Constant term is included in the regression; 73 cities with positive total effects are included in the
regressions.

26

Table 3-e Lag based on 15-month MA series
(1)
Transitory shock s.d.:
-29.5
Cycle < 4 month
(.03)

15883
(1.21)

-2438084**
(-1.29)

-2470415
(-1.23)

-13179**
(-2.45)

-18531***
(-3.20)

29191
(1.35)

28898
(1.27)

-2.94
(-.47)

-3.86
(-.61)

-3.87
(-.59)

.365
(.75)

.425
(.86)

.391
(.74)

35.66***
(3.42)

45.1***
(4.13)

53.8***
(4.87)

-9131**
(-2.21)

Comovement measure

City size

City size squared

Share of good producing

(3)
15177
(2.06)

Transitory shock s.d:
× Comovement measure
Long-lived shock s.d.

(2)

Age: 18~24

-70.5*
(-1.94)

Low education

-14.0
(-1.25)

Non-white

4.53
(.68)

*** indicates statistical significance at the 1% level.
** indicates statistical significance at the 5% level.
* indicates statistical significance at the 10% level.
( ): t-statistics based on robust standard errors
Constant term is included in the regression; 73 cities with positive total effects are included in the
regressions.

27

Figure 1 Relationship between lag and sizes of shocks

28

Figure 2. Temporary and permanent employment growth rates
Fig. 2-a Colorado Springs, CO

.1
.05
-.05

0

0
-.5

Temp 12 m growth rate

.5

Colorado Springs, CO

1990m1

1995m1

2000m1

2005m1

period...
Temp 12 m growth rate

Perm 12 m growth rate

Graphs by area_name

Fig. 2-b Portland-Vancouver-Beaverton, OR-WA

.04
.02
0

0

-.04

-.02

-.2
-.4

Temp 12 m growth rate

.2

.06

Portland-Vancouver-Beaverton, OR-WA

1990m1

1995m1

2000m1

2005m1

period...
Temp 12 m growth rate

Perm 12 m growth rate

Graphs by area_name

29

References
Aguirregabiria, V. and Alonso-Borrego, C. (1999), “Labor Contracts and Flexibility: Evidence
from a Labor Market Reform in Spain”
Autor, D. (2003), “Outsourcing at Will: Unjust Dismissal Doctrine and the Growth of Temporary
Help Employment”, Journal of Labor Economics, January.
Baxter, M. and King, R. (1999), “Measuring Business Cycles: Approximate Band-Pass Filters for
Economic Time Series”, Review of Economics and Statistics, 81(4), pp. 575-593.

Bentolila, S. and Bertola, G. (1990), “Firing Costs and Labor Demand: How Bad is
Eurosclerosis?”, Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 57, pp. 381-402.

Campbell, J., and Fisher, J. (2004), “Idiosyncratic risk and aggregate employment dynamics”,
Review of Economic Dynamics, Vol. 7, pp. 331-353

Corbae, D., Ouliaris, S. and Phillips, P. (2002), “Band Spectral Regression with Trending Data,
Econometrica”, 170(3), pp. 067-1109.

Chan, K. (1992), “A Further Analysis of the Lead--Lag Relationship Between the Cash Market
and Stock Index Futures Market”, Review of Financial Studies, 5(1), pp. 123-152.

Golden, L. (1996), “The expansion of temporary help employment in the US, 1982-1992: A test
of alternative economic explanations,” Applied Economics, Vol. 28, pp. 1127-1141

Gan, L. and Zhang, Q. (2006), “The Thick Market Effect on Local Unemployment Rate
Fluctuations,” Journal of Econometrics.

Hamermesh, D.S. (1989), “Labor Demand and the Structure of Adjustment Costs,” American
Economic Review, Vol.79, No.4, pp. 674-689.

Hamermesh, D.S. and Pfann, G. (1996), “Adjustment Costs in Factor Demand,” Journal of
Economic Literature, Vol. XXXIV, pp. 1264--1292.

Katz, L., Krueger, A., Burtless, G. and Dickens, W. (1999), “The High Pressure U.S. Labor
Market of the 1990s,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 1999, No. 1, pp. 1-87.

30

Ono, Y. and Zelenev, A. (2003), “Temporary help services and the volatility of industry output”,
Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Vol. XXVII, No. 2.

Pindyck, R.S. (1991), “Irreversibility, Uncertainty and Investment”, Journal of Economic
Literature, 29, pp. 1110-1152.

Segal and Sullivan (1995),“The temporary labor force”, Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago, Vol. 19, No. 2.

31

Appendix

A. Definition of the industries

5613 Employment Services
This industry group includes establishments classified in the following industries: 56131,
Employment Placement Agencies, 56132, Temporary Help Services, and 56133, Professional
Employer Organizations.

56131 Employment Placement Agencies
This industry comprises establishments primarily engaged in listing employment vacancies and in
referring or placing applicants for employment. The individuals referred or placed are not
employees of the employment agencies.

56132 Temporary Help Services
This industry comprises establishments primarily engaged in supplying workers to clients'
businesses for limited periods of time to supplement the working force of the client. The
individuals provided are employees of the temporary help service establishment. However, these
establishments do not provide direct supervision of their employees at the clients' work sites.

56133 Professional Employer Organizations
This industry comprises establishments primarily engaged in providing human resources and
human resource management services to staff client businesses. Establishments in this industry
operate in a co-employment relationship with client businesses or organizations and are
specialized in performing a wide range of human resource and personnel management duties,
such as payroll accounting, payroll tax return preparation, benefits administration, recruiting, and
managing labor relations. Employee leasing establishments typically acquire and lease back some
or all of the employees of their clients and serve as the employer of the leased employees for
payroll, benefits, and related purposes. Employee leasing establishments exercise varying degrees
of decision making relating to their human resource or personnel management role, but do not
have management accountability for the work of their clients' operations with regard to strategic
planning, output, or profitability. Professional employer organizations (PEO) and establishments
providing labor or staff leasing services are included in this industry.

32

B. Proof of Proposition 1
i) Because V (lτP ;θ ) = θ J (lτP ; μ h ) + (1 − θ ) J (lτP ; μl ) , and because J1 (.) <0 under Assumption 1,
we have V1 (.) < 0 .
ii)

Because lτP−1 ∈ [ll+ P , ll− P ] ,

and

because

β J1 (lτP−1 ; μh ) > λ under Assumption 2 and

β J1 (lτP−1 ; μl ) > −λ according to the optimal decision rule (5), we have βV1 (lτP−1 ;θ ) > −λ . Also,
because

β J1 (lh+ P ; μh ) = λ and

β J1 (lh+ P ; μl ) < −λ under

Assumption

2,

we

have

βV1 (lh+ P ;θ ) < λ . Therefore, according to the optimal decision rule (10), lτP* ∈ [lτP−1 , lh+ P ) . Lastly,
because V1 (.) < 0 , we know lτP* is uniquely determined by β V1 (lτP ;θ ) = λ when lτP* > lτP−1 .
iii) This is because J1 (lτP ; μ h ) > J1 (lτP ; μl ), ∀lτP ∈ [ll+ P , lh+ P ) under Assumption 2.
iv) Because of ii) and iii), we have lτP* increases with θ and strictly increases with θ when

lτP* > lτP−1 .
v) Because of ii), and according to the optimal decision rule (5’), we have lτP+*1 = l + Ph .

C. Solution for the optimal permanent employment
First, we illustrate how to solve for l + P . The case of l − P is similar.

(C.1)

Firstly,

1
⎧
α
y
⎛
⎞
+P
⎪
⎜ ⎟ −l
⎪
+P
π (l ) = ⎨ py − w ⎝ A ⎠
− l + P , if y > A(l + P )α
c
⎪
⎪ py − l + P , o.w.
⎩

Let us denote A(l + P )α by y . Then we can obtain

(C.2)

1
⎛
⎞
w ⎛ μ + σ − y ⎞ wα y ⎜ ⎛ A ⎞ α
⎟ −1 .
+
−
1
Eπ 1 (l ) = ⎜
⎟
⎜ ⎟
⎜
⎟
c ⎝ 2σ
⎠ 2cσ ⎝ w ⎠
⎝
⎠
+P

Plugging (C.2) into β J1 (l + P ; μ ) = β Eπ 1 (l + P ; μ ) + βλ = λ and replacing y with A(l + P )α , we
obtain

33

l+ p

(C.3)

⎛
⎜
⎛ λ (1 − β ) + β ⎞ 2cσ
⎜ μ +σ − ⎜
⎟ w
β
⎜
⎝
⎠
=⎜
1
⎛
⎛
⎞⎞
⎜
⎛ A ⎞α
⎜
⎜
A 1 − α ⎜ ⎟ − 1⎟ ⎟
⎜
⎜⎜
⎜⎝ w ⎠
⎟ ⎟⎟
⎜
⎝
⎠⎠
⎝
⎝

1

⎞α
⎟
⎟
⎟
⎟ .
⎟
⎟
⎟
⎠

From (C.3), one can see that permanent employment is a function of the mean level of demand

μ and the degree of demand volatility caused by transitory shocks measured by σ .
Similarly, we can get

l− p

(C.4)

⎛
⎜
⎛ −λ (1 − β ) + β ⎞ 2cσ
⎜ μ +σ −⎜
⎟ w
β
⎜
⎝
⎠
=⎜
1
⎛
⎛
⎞⎞
⎜
⎜ 1 − α ⎜ ⎛ A ⎞ α − 1⎟ ⎟
A
⎜
⎜⎜
⎜ ⎜⎝ w ⎟⎠
⎟ ⎟⎟
⎜
⎝
⎠⎠
⎝
⎝

1

⎞α
⎟
⎟
⎟
⎟
⎟
⎟
⎟
⎠

Suppose the mean demand shifts from the low state to the high state. And suppose before
the shift, the permanent employment level is at the upper end of the sustainable range
corresponding to the low state. Then, according to the optimal decision rule (11), the optimal
permanent employment at the turning point τ is
1

(C.5)

lτp*

⎛
⎞α
⎜
⎛ (1 − β (2θ − 1))λ + β ⎞ 2cσ ⎟
⎜ θ ( μh + σ ) + (1 − θ )( μl + σ ) − ⎜
⎟ w ⎟
β
⎜
⎟
⎝
⎠
=⎜
⎟
1
⎛
⎛
⎞⎞
α
⎜
⎟
A
⎛
⎞
A ⎜1 − α ⎜ ⎜ ⎟ − 1⎟ ⎟
⎜
⎟
⎜⎜
⎜⎝ w ⎠
⎟ ⎟⎟
⎜
⎟
⎝
⎠
⎝
⎠
⎝
⎠

From (C.5), we can see that lτp* is a function of θ , the subjective probability of a state shift.
Combining (C.3-5), and using (9), we can calculate the threshold probability θˆ such that the
adjustment of permanent employment at the turning point is more than half of the full adjustment.

34

Working Paper Series
A series of research studies on regional economic issues relating to the Seventh Federal
Reserve District, and on financial and economic topics.
Standing Facilities and Interbank Borrowing: Evidence from the Federal Reserve’s
New Discount Window
Craig Furfine

WP-04-01

Netting, Financial Contracts, and Banks: The Economic Implications
William J. Bergman, Robert R. Bliss, Christian A. Johnson and George G. Kaufman

WP-04-02

Real Effects of Bank Competition
Nicola Cetorelli

WP-04-03

Finance as a Barrier To Entry: Bank Competition and Industry Structure in
Local U.S. Markets?
Nicola Cetorelli and Philip E. Strahan

WP-04-04

The Dynamics of Work and Debt
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-04-05

Fiscal Policy in the Aftermath of 9/11
Jonas Fisher and Martin Eichenbaum

WP-04-06

Merger Momentum and Investor Sentiment: The Stock Market Reaction
To Merger Announcements
Richard J. Rosen

WP-04-07

Earnings Inequality and the Business Cycle
Gadi Barlevy and Daniel Tsiddon

WP-04-08

Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets: The Case of Payment Networks
Sujit Chakravorti and Roberto Roson

WP-04-09

Nominal Debt as a Burden on Monetary Policy
Javier Díaz-Giménez, Giorgia Giovannetti, Ramon Marimon, and Pedro Teles

WP-04-10

On the Timing of Innovation in Stochastic Schumpeterian Growth Models
Gadi Barlevy

WP-04-11

Policy Externalities: How US Antidumping Affects Japanese Exports to the EU
Chad P. Bown and Meredith A. Crowley

WP-04-12

Sibling Similarities, Differences and Economic Inequality
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-04-13

Determinants of Business Cycle Comovement: A Robust Analysis
Marianne Baxter and Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-04-14

The Occupational Assimilation of Hispanics in the U.S.: Evidence from Panel Data
Maude Toussaint-Comeau

WP-04-15

1

Working Paper Series (continued)
Reading, Writing, and Raisinets1: Are School Finances Contributing to Children’s Obesity?
Patricia M. Anderson and Kristin F. Butcher

WP-04-16

Learning by Observing: Information Spillovers in the Execution and Valuation
of Commercial Bank M&As
Gayle DeLong and Robert DeYoung

WP-04-17

Prospects for Immigrant-Native Wealth Assimilation:
Evidence from Financial Market Participation
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-04-18

Individuals and Institutions: Evidence from International Migrants in the U.S.
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-04-19

Are Technology Improvements Contractionary?
Susanto Basu, John Fernald and Miles Kimball

WP-04-20

The Minimum Wage, Restaurant Prices and Labor Market Structure
Daniel Aaronson, Eric French and James MacDonald

WP-04-21

Betcha can’t acquire just one: merger programs and compensation
Richard J. Rosen

WP-04-22

Not Working: Demographic Changes, Policy Changes,
and the Distribution of Weeks (Not) Worked
Lisa Barrow and Kristin F. Butcher

WP-04-23

The Role of Collateralized Household Debt in Macroeconomic Stabilization
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-04-24

Advertising and Pricing at Multiple-Output Firms: Evidence from U.S. Thrift Institutions
Robert DeYoung and Evren Örs

WP-04-25

Monetary Policy with State Contingent Interest Rates
Bernardino Adão, Isabel Correia and Pedro Teles

WP-04-26

Comparing location decisions of domestic and foreign auto supplier plants
Thomas Klier, Paul Ma and Daniel P. McMillen

WP-04-27

China’s export growth and US trade policy
Chad P. Bown and Meredith A. Crowley

WP-04-28

Where do manufacturing firms locate their Headquarters?
J. Vernon Henderson and Yukako Ono

WP-04-29

Monetary Policy with Single Instrument Feedback Rules
Bernardino Adão, Isabel Correia and Pedro Teles

WP-04-30

2

Working Paper Series (continued)
Firm-Specific Capital, Nominal Rigidities and the Business Cycle
David Altig, Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum and Jesper Linde

WP-05-01

Do Returns to Schooling Differ by Race and Ethnicity?
Lisa Barrow and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP-05-02

Derivatives and Systemic Risk: Netting, Collateral, and Closeout
Robert R. Bliss and George G. Kaufman

WP-05-03

Risk Overhang and Loan Portfolio Decisions
Robert DeYoung, Anne Gron and Andrew Winton

WP-05-04

Characterizations in a random record model with a non-identically distributed initial record
Gadi Barlevy and H. N. Nagaraja

WP-05-05

Price discovery in a market under stress: the U.S. Treasury market in fall 1998
Craig H. Furfine and Eli M. Remolona

WP-05-06

Politics and Efficiency of Separating Capital and Ordinary Government Budgets
Marco Bassetto with Thomas J. Sargent

WP-05-07

Rigid Prices: Evidence from U.S. Scanner Data
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Benjamin Eden

WP-05-08

Entrepreneurship, Frictions, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-05-09

Wealth inequality: data and models
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-05-10

What Determines Bilateral Trade Flows?
Marianne Baxter and Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-05-11

Intergenerational Economic Mobility in the U.S., 1940 to 2000
Daniel Aaronson and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-05-12

Differential Mortality, Uncertain Medical Expenses, and the Saving of Elderly Singles
Mariacristina De Nardi, Eric French, and John Bailey Jones

WP-05-13

Fixed Term Employment Contracts in an Equilibrium Search Model
Fernando Alvarez and Marcelo Veracierto

WP-05-14

Causality, Causality, Causality: The View of Education Inputs and Outputs from Economics
Lisa Barrow and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP-05-15

3

Working Paper Series (continued)
Competition in Large Markets
Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-05-16

Why Do Firms Go Public? Evidence from the Banking Industry
Richard J. Rosen, Scott B. Smart and Chad J. Zutter

WP-05-17

Clustering of Auto Supplier Plants in the U.S.: GMM Spatial Logit for Large Samples
Thomas Klier and Daniel P. McMillen

WP-05-18

Why are Immigrants’ Incarceration Rates So Low?
Evidence on Selective Immigration, Deterrence, and Deportation
Kristin F. Butcher and Anne Morrison Piehl

WP-05-19

Constructing the Chicago Fed Income Based Economic Index – Consumer Price Index:
Inflation Experiences by Demographic Group: 1983-2005
Leslie McGranahan and Anna Paulson

WP-05-20

Universal Access, Cost Recovery, and Payment Services
Sujit Chakravorti, Jeffery W. Gunther, and Robert R. Moore

WP-05-21

Supplier Switching and Outsourcing
Yukako Ono and Victor Stango

WP-05-22

Do Enclaves Matter in Immigrants’ Self-Employment Decision?
Maude Toussaint-Comeau

WP-05-23

The Changing Pattern of Wage Growth for Low Skilled Workers
Eric French, Bhashkar Mazumder and Christopher Taber

WP-05-24

U.S. Corporate and Bank Insolvency Regimes: An Economic Comparison and Evaluation
Robert R. Bliss and George G. Kaufman

WP-06-01

Redistribution, Taxes, and the Median Voter
Marco Bassetto and Jess Benhabib

WP-06-02

Identification of Search Models with Initial Condition Problems
Gadi Barlevy and H. N. Nagaraja

WP-06-03

Tax Riots
Marco Bassetto and Christopher Phelan

WP-06-04

The Tradeoff between Mortgage Prepayments and Tax-Deferred Retirement Savings
Gene Amromin, Jennifer Huang,and Clemens Sialm

WP-06-05

Why are safeguards needed in a trade agreement?
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-06-06

4

Working Paper Series (continued)
Taxation, Entrepreneurship, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-06-07

A New Social Compact: How University Engagement Can Fuel Innovation
Laura Melle, Larry Isaak, and Richard Mattoon

WP-06-08

Mergers and Risk
Craig H. Furfine and Richard J. Rosen

WP-06-09

Two Flaws in Business Cycle Accounting
Lawrence J. Christiano and Joshua M. Davis

WP-06-10

Do Consumers Choose the Right Credit Contracts?
Sumit Agarwal, Souphala Chomsisengphet, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles

WP-06-11

Chronicles of a Deflation Unforetold
François R. Velde

WP-06-12

Female Offenders Use of Social Welfare Programs Before and After Jail and Prison:
Does Prison Cause Welfare Dependency?
Kristin F. Butcher and Robert J. LaLonde
Eat or Be Eaten: A Theory of Mergers and Firm Size
Gary Gorton, Matthias Kahl, and Richard Rosen
Do Bonds Span Volatility Risk in the U.S. Treasury Market?
A Specification Test for Affine Term Structure Models
Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

WP-06-13

WP-06-14

WP-06-15

Transforming Payment Choices by Doubling Fees on the Illinois Tollway
Gene Amromin, Carrie Jankowski, and Richard D. Porter

WP-06-16

How Did the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut Affect Stock Prices?
Gene Amromin, Paul Harrison, and Steven Sharpe

WP-06-17

Will Writing and Bequest Motives: Early 20th Century Irish Evidence
Leslie McGranahan

WP-06-18

How Professional Forecasters View Shocks to GDP
Spencer D. Krane

WP-06-19

Evolving Agglomeration in the U.S. auto supplier industry
Thomas Klier and Daniel P. McMillen

WP-06-20

Mortality, Mass-Layoffs, and Career Outcomes: An Analysis using Administrative Data
Daniel Sullivan and Till von Wachter

WP-06-21

5

Working Paper Series (continued)
The Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures:
Tying One’s Hand through the WTO.
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-06-22

How Did Schooling Laws Improve Long-Term Health and Lower Mortality?
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-06-23

Manufacturing Plants’ Use of Temporary Workers: An Analysis Using Census Micro Data
Yukako Ono and Daniel Sullivan

WP-06-24

What Can We Learn about Financial Access from U.S. Immigrants?
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-06-25

Bank Imputed Interest Rates: Unbiased Estimates of Offered Rates?
Evren Ors and Tara Rice

WP-06-26

Welfare Implications of the Transition to High Household Debt
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-06-27

Last-In First-Out Oligopoly Dynamics
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-06-28

Oligopoly Dynamics with Barriers to Entry
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-06-29

Risk Taking and the Quality of Informal Insurance: Gambling and Remittances in Thailand
Douglas L. Miller and Anna L. Paulson

WP-07-01

Fast Micro and Slow Macro: Can Aggregation Explain the Persistence of Inflation?
Filippo Altissimo, Benoît Mojon, and Paolo Zaffaroni

WP-07-02

Assessing a Decade of Interstate Bank Branching
Christian Johnson and Tara Rice

WP-07-03

Debit Card and Cash Usage: A Cross-Country Analysis
Gene Amromin and Sujit Chakravorti

WP-07-04

The Age of Reason: Financial Decisions Over the Lifecycle
Sumit Agarwal, John C. Driscoll, Xavier Gabaix, and David Laibson

WP-07-05

Information Acquisition in Financial Markets: a Correction
Gadi Barlevy and Pietro Veronesi

WP-07-06

Monetary Policy, Output Composition and the Great Moderation
Benoît Mojon

WP-07-07

Estate Taxation, Entrepreneurship, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-07-08

6

Working Paper Series (continued)
Conflict of Interest and Certification in the U.S. IPO Market
Luca Benzoni and Carola Schenone
The Reaction of Consumer Spending and Debt to Tax Rebates –
Evidence from Consumer Credit Data
Sumit Agarwal, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles

WP-07-09

WP-07-10

Portfolio Choice over the Life-Cycle when the Stock and Labor Markets are Cointegrated
Luca Benzoni, Pierre Collin-Dufresne, and Robert S. Goldstein

WP-07-11

Nonparametric Analysis of Intergenerational Income Mobility
with Application to the United States
Debopam Bhattacharya and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-07-12

How the Credit Channel Works: Differentiating the Bank Lending Channel
and the Balance Sheet Channel
Lamont K. Black and Richard J. Rosen

WP-07-13

Labor Market Transitions and Self-Employment
Ellen R. Rissman

WP-07-14

First-Time Home Buyers and Residential Investment Volatility
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Martin Gervais

WP-07-15

Establishments Dynamics and Matching Frictions in Classical Competitive Equilibrium
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-07-16

Technology’s Edge: The Educational Benefits of Computer-Aided Instruction
Lisa Barrow, Lisa Markman, and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP-07-17

The Widow’s Offering: Inheritance, Family Structure, and the Charitable Gifts of Women
Leslie McGranahan

WP-07-18

Demand Volatility and the Lag between the Growth of Temporary
and Permanent Employment
Sainan Jin, Yukako Ono, and Qinghua Zhang

WP-07-19

7