View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Cyclical Dumping and US
Antidumping Protection: 1980-2001
Meredith A. Crowley

REVISED
January 2011
WP 2007-21

Cyclical Dumping and US Antidumping Protection: 1980-2001
Meredith A. Crowley1
Economic Research
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
January 2011
Abstract
This paper estimates the impact of economic conditions in foreign industries on the filing
of antidumping petitions by US industries and the US government’s decision in preliminary
and final antidumping investigations. Exploiting cross-country variation in economic shocks in
manufacturing, I estimate a joint model of filing decisions by the US industry and antidumping
decisions by the US government.
I find strong evidence that economic weakness in a foreign industry is associated with an
increase in the probability of antidumping protection. After controlling for other political and
economic factors that likely drive industry filing and government decisions including US GDP
growth, I find that a one standard deviation fall in the growth of employment (consumption)
in a foreign economy’s manufacturing industry doubles (triples) the joint probability that the
US industry will file an antidumping petition and the US government will impose a preliminary
(temporary) antidumping measure. The effect of weakness in a foreign economy is even larger for
final antidumping measures. A one standard deviation fall in foreign employment (consumption)
growth increases the joint probability that a petition will be filed and a final (long-lasting)
antidumping measure will be imposed by a factor of five (seven). In finding that US trade
policy is applied counter-cyclically to foreign economic fluctuations, the paper suggests that
trade policy may reduce the extent of business cycle transmission across countries.

JEL Codes: F12, F13
Keywords: dumping, anti-dumping, counter-cyclical policy

1

Economic Research, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 230 S. LaSalle St., Chicago, IL 60604; phone: (312) 9195856; email: crowley.meredith@gmail.com. The views expressed here are those of the author and do not necessarily
reflect those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal Reserve System. I thank Gadi Barlevy, Chad
Bown, Bob Feinberg, Eric French, Anna Paulson, Tom Prusa, Rich Rosen and seminar participants at the Chicago
Fed, the MWIEG Spring 2008 meetings, the Econometric Society NASM 2008, Georgetown, the Federal Reserve
System Committee on International Economic Affairs, the US International Trade Commission, and the World Bank
for helpful comments. Adam Hogan, Saad N. Quayyum and Erik Vogt provided excellent research assistance.

1

Introduction
Under the GATT-WTO system, countries which have negotiated reductions in tariffs and other

trade barriers have limited ability to institute new trade barriers. However, the GATT includes
provisions which allow countries to reintroduce trade barriers if specific economic criteria are met.
Antidumping duties, permitted under the GATT’s agreement on dumping, have become extremely
popular among WTO members around the world (Miranda, Torres and Ruiz, 1998). According to
the GATT, antidumping duties may be imposed if a country’s trading partners are selling products
at “dumped” prices and if there is evidence that the country’s domestic industry is injured by this
dumping.
This paper tests the theory that weak economic conditions in a foreign economy can induce
a particular type of dumping prohibited by the GATT, cyclical dumping or temporarily pricing
below the average total cost of production.2 Models of cyclical dumping (Ethier, 1982; Staiger
and Wolak, 1992; Crowley, 2010) predict that declines in the demand for a product in a foreign
market will lead to increased exports sold at a price in the importing country that is below the
average total cost of production. Using country-specific information on foreign economic shocks
in manufacturing industries, I estimate a joint model of filing decisions by the US industry and
antidumping decisions by the US government. I find that a decline in economic conditions in a
foreign industry has a statistically and economically significant effect on the filing of antidumping
petitions and the government’s decision to impose antidumping measures. After controlling for
other political and economic factors that likely drive industry filing and government decisions,
including US GDP growth, I find that a one standard deviation fall in the growth of employment
(consumption) in a foreign economy’s manufacturing industry doubles (triples) the joint probability
that the US industry will file an antidumping petition and the US government will impose a
preliminary (temporary) antidumping measure. The effect of weakness in a foreign economy is
even larger for final antidumping measures. A one standard deviation fall in foreign employment
(consumption) growth increases the joint probability that a petition will be filed and a final (longlasting) antidumping measure will be imposed by a factor of five (seven).
Because even temporary, preliminary antidumping measures can have trade-restricting effect, I
estimate models of both preliminary and final outcomes. In a binary model of the government’s
2

Clarida (1996) presents estimates from a variety of sources that the definition of dumping as pricing below the

average total cost of production is used in about 2/3 of US antidumping cases.

2

preliminary protection decision with industry selection into the antidumping process, the growth
rate of employment in the foreign industry affects the government’s decision to apply a preliminary
antidumping measure. Conditional on an industry filing a request for antidumping protection, a one
standard deviation fall in the growth of industry-level foreign employment in the year prior to the
filing of the petition is associated with a modest increase in the probability of a preliminary measure
of 0.74 percentage points. More importantly, a one standard deviation fall in foreign employment
growth increases the probability of filing (0.23 percentage points) and, thus, more than doubles
the joint probability that a petition will be filed and a preliminary measure will be imposed from
0.14% to 0.32%.
An interesting difference arises in estimating the role of foreign demand shocks on the government’s final determination of whether or not to impose a final measure jointly with the industry’s
decision to file a petition. In the final decision, which takes place between 235 and 295 days after the
filing of a petition3 , the lagged growth of industry-level foreign employment is not a statistically
significant determinant of the government’s decision to impose a final long-lasting antidumping
measure. However, because foreign economic conditions are a significant determinant of industry
filings, a one standard deviation fall in foreign employment growth dramatically increases the joint
probability of a filing and a final measure from 0.09% to 0.52%
This is the first paper that I am aware of to show empirically that US trade policy responds
to adverse economic fluctuations in a foreign economy. This paper shares similarities with earlier
work by Knetter and Prusa (2003) on the macro-economic factors underlying antidumping filing
in that both papers exploit inter-temporal variation to identify the relationship between economic
fluctuations and antidumping. Consistent with their findings and those of Feinberg (2005) and
Jallab, Sandretto, and Gbakou (2006), I find that the probability of filing is increasing with an
appreciation of the importing country’s real exchange rate. However, my analysis differs from
Knetter and Prusa (2003) by utilizing country and industry-specific inter-temporal variation to
explain differences in filing behavior across accused countries and industries. While Knetter and
Prusa found no statistically significant relationship between filing rates aggregated across industries
and across accused countries and an aggregate measure of rest-of-world GDP growth over the 3
years prior to filing, my analysis finds that higher frequency, annual fluctuations in the foreign
3

The final dumping determination takes place between 235 and 295 days after the filing of a petition in normal

cases, but can be delayed to a time range of 285 to 345 days in special circumstances. The final injury decision takes
place 280-340 days after the filing of a petition in normal cases and 330-390 days in special circumstances.

3

economy’s industry in the year prior to filing are an important determinant of filing.
Among theoretical models of dumping, the literature has developed into two strands that yield
opposing predictions about the relationship between economic fluctuations in the foreign economy
and the existence of dumping. Beginning with the seminal contribution of Ethier (1982), a number
of papers (Staiger and Wolak, 1992, 1994; Crowley, 2010) model a realization of weak foreign
demand as the driving force behind dumping. In contrast, Clarida (1993) develops a competitive
model of entry and firm learning about technology to show that dumping can arise during periods
of high worldwide demand. Similarly, Hartigan (1996) builds a duopoly model in which dumping
occurs when foreign demand is high. The contribution of the current paper is that provides empirical
support to models in which weak foreign demand drives dumping.
Previous empirical research on the determinants of antidumping filings and the outcomes in
investigations has emphasized political factors (Hansen, 1990; Moore, 1992; Hansen and Prusa,
1997), specific aspects of the legal/bureaucratic institutional framework (Hansen and Prusa, 1996;
Blonigen, 2006), trade policy retaliation (Blonigen and Bown, 20034 ; Prusa and Skeath, 2002;
Feinberg and Reynolds, 2006) or economic factors (Moore, 1992; Baldwin and Steagall, 1994;
Staiger and Wolak, 1994; and Knetter and Prusa, 2003). The approach here builds on the previous
empirical literature but utilizes a previously unexploited source of variation to identify a relationship
between foreign economic fluctuations and dumping.
Section 2 describes the antidumping process in the United States. Section 3 presents the
empirical model. Section 4 describes the data. Section 5 presents the empirical results and section
6 concludes.

2

Antidumping in the United States
This paper attempts to use information on the antidumping process in the United States over

the period 1980-2001 to identify the role that industry-level cyclical economic factors in foreign
economies play in dumping. In the course of an investigation that determines the existence and
4

Blonigen and Bown (2003) share a methodological similarity to this paper in that they exploit cross-country

variation in petition filing to identify the effect of the threat of retaliation measured as foreign market size on filing
decisions. Because their analysis utilizes cross-sectional data, they abstract away from the cyclical factors that theory
predicts could explain time-variation in dumping behavior by foreign firms.

4

domestic consequences of dumping, the US government collects and analyzes private business proprietary data on prices and costs of domestic firms who make accusations of dumping and foreign
firms accused of dumping. The government also analyzes a variety of publicly available data on
output, imports and domestic employment that inform its decision in antidumping cases. Unfortunately, the econometrician who is interested in testing the theories of cyclical dumping cannot
observe the business proprietary data on prices and costs that the government observes.
Nevertheless, I can observe industry and government decisions at several stages in the antidumping process. Furthermore, I have several measures that can proxy for the strength of demand in
a foreign country’s industry. The growth of employment and the growth of consumption in the
foreign country should all be highly correlated with the strength of demand in industry i in country j. According to cyclical dumping models, weakness in any of these variables in industry i,
country j in year t induces (1) pricing below average total cost and (2) injury to the domestic
import-competing industry (i.e., increased imports, lower domestic market share, lower domestic
capacity utilization). Because weakness in foreign demand precipitates conditions that satisfy the
legal definition of dumping, it should be associated with an increase in the probability of a petition
by the domestic industry and an increase in the probability of protection.
Figure 1 presents, by antidumping petition status, the mean growth of foreign industry-level
employment in the year before an antidumping petition is filed. This is the mean growth rate over
28 3 digit ISIC manufacturing industries for 49 countries between 1980-2001.5 Figure 2 presents
the mean growth of foreign industry-level consumption in the year prior to a filing. Beginning with
figure 1, it appears that negative employment growth in a foreign industry is correlated with an
antidumping case being filed and is also correlated with the imposition of a preliminary antidumping
duty. Figure 2 shows that cases tend to be filed and preliminary duties tend to be imposed against
foreign industries whose consumption growth is relatively weak. Somewhat surprisingly, the pattern
appears reversed for final antidumping duties. In brief, this simple figure suggests that foreign
economic conditions are relevant to antidumping protection. The empirical strategy in this paper
is to use cross-industry cross-country and inter-temporal variation in antidumping decisions to
identify if antidumping protection is induced by weak foreign demand and, if so, to quantify the
increase in the probability of protection associated with economic weakness in foreign countries.
Identification of the effect of foreign demand strength on filings and outcomes comes from three
sources of variation in the domestic-industry-foreign-country-year (ijt) panel data. First, within an
5

The data used in these graphs are described in detail in section 4.

5

industry i in year t, there is variation across countries j both in whether or not they are included
in an antidumping petition and in the government’s determination of injury and dumping. Second,
within a year t, there is variation across industries i in filing and protection decisions. Finally, there
is intertemporal variation for industry i and country j in the timing of petition-filing by industries
and the protection decisions by governments.
The US antidumping process can be broken into three distinct phases, each with its own data
requirements: 1. initiation of a case, 2. a preliminary phase with a determination as to whether
or not dumped imports are causing or threatening to cause injury to the domestic industry and a
preliminary determination about the existence and magnitude of dumping, and 3. a final phase with
determination about the existence and magnitude of dumping and a final injury determination.

6

In the first step, a domestic industry i that produces a product (also denoted i7 ) must initiate
or file a petition with the US Department of Commerce (DOC) and the US International Trade
Commission (USITC) that claims that the industry is being materially injured or threatened with
materially injury by reason of imports of good i at a price that is “less than fair value” from a single
country j or multiple countries j = 1, 2, 3.... Thus, the first margin of cross-country within-industry
and within-year variation comes in the filing decision.8
Table 1 presents the frequency of filing a petition in industry i against country j in year t for the
272,639 industry-country-year observations in the unbalanced panel of 439 industries, 49 countries
and 22 years used in this paper. The first important observation is that antidumping petitions are
6

A detailed description of the current antidumping process and a brief history of the evolution of US antidumping

law since 1916 can be found in the Antidumping and Countervailing Duty Handbook published by the US International
Trade Commission (2007). Although US trade law has been revised a number of times since the start of my data
sample in 1980, the antidumping process is largely unchanged with one important exception. Beginning in 1984, the
rule to cumulate imports from all countries listed in a petition during the injury investigation led to super-additivity
in USITC decisions and a 20-30% increase in the probability of protection (Hansen and Prusa, 1996). However, as
Hansen and Prusa (1996) note, “the ITC always makes its decisions on a country-by-country basis, even if imports
from a set of countries are cumulated.”
7
In practice, the definition of the domestic “like product” is part of the investigation process. In general, the
USITC definition of the “like product” is only a subset of the output of the 4 digit SIC 1987 industries that are the
most finely disaggregated units available for a cross-sectional analysis in the US.
8
Prusa (1997) and Benton (2001) exploit this variation to show that the country-specificity of antidumping protection leads to increased imports into the US (Prusa) and EU (Benton) from countries that are not specifically targeted
by the antidumping measure.

6

a rare event. The row “Country j exports i to the US at t and is accused of dumping” indicates
that the frequency of dumping accusations in the sample is less than 0.2% (545/272639). Second,
the row “Country j exports i to the US at t and is not accused” captures the high degree of crosscountry variation in petition filing. There are 8017 observations in the dataset in which a country
j with positive exports to the US in industry i year t was not listed in a antidumping petition filed
by the domestic US industry i in year t. Thus, while only 545 petitions were filed in the unbalanced
manufacturing panel, an additional 8017 petitions would have been filed if the domestic industry
had indiscriminately listed every country j that exported industry i’s output to the US in year t.
It thus appears that domestic industries are somewhat selective in their accusations of dumping.9
This selectivity is likely influenced by the economic and financial data which are included in
an industry’s antidumping petition. In addition to data on the domestic industry itself (capacity,
production, domestic sales, export sales, inventories, the number of production and non-supervisory
workers, and income and loss data), a petition must include data on the foreign firms and countries
accused of dumping. First, it must include the quantity and value of “less-than-fair-value” imports
from each supplying country for the most recent 3 years. Second, it must include data directly
related to the determination of dumping; i.e., the price charged by foreign firms in the US for
the “dumped” product and the domestic firms’ price for the same product for the most recent 5
quarters.10
If a petition contains all the necessary information, the preliminary phase of the investigation
begins. During the preliminary phase, the US International Trade Commission makes a preliminary determination of injury and/or threat of injury due to dumped imports for each country j
listed in the petition. In making its decision, the USITC relies on information obtained through
questionnaires sent to domestic producers, importers and foreign producers.11 If the preliminary
injury determination by the USITC is negative, the case ends with no antidumping duty. If the
preliminary injury determination is affirmative, then the case proceeds to the US Department of
9
10

Blonigen and Bown (2003) explain this selectivity as partially due to a US industry’s fear of foreign retaliation.
The International Trade Administration Form ITA-357P (OMB Control # 0625-0105) provides a detailed guide-

line of the price and cost information that must be included in a petition for antidumping protection.
11
Domestic producers’ questionnaires request economic data on capacity, production, inventories, commercial shipments, export shipments, internal consumption, company transfers, employment, hours worked, wages, as well as
financial data on income, losses, capital expenditures and sales prices. Importer questionnaires request data on the
quantity and value of imports and sales prices. Finally, foreign producers’ questionnaires inquire about the firm’s
capacity, production, home-market shipments, exports, and inventories.

7

Commerce for a preliminary dumping determination.12
During the second part of the preliminary phase, the US Department of Commerce makes a
preliminary determination of dumping against each country j listed in a petition.13 The dumping
margin for country j is calculated as the difference in the price charged by country j producers in
the US and country j,the US and a third market, or the difference between the price charged in
the US price and the average total cost of production of a firm in country j. Preliminary dumping
margins vary considerably across countries listed within a petition, with the USDOC occasionally
finding that there is no evidence of dumping by some countries that have been found guilty of
causing injury.14
To summarize the preliminary phase, a preliminary antidumping measure is imposed if both the
USITC and the USDOC come to affirmative preliminary determinations. Cross-country variation
in the application of a preliminary antidumping duty within a case can arise from cross-country
variation in the injury decision or in the dumping determination. Interestingly, when petitions
against individual countries are clustered into multicountry cases, we observe that roughly 73% of
multi-country cases have outcomes in which all countries were found guilty of dumping and injury
or no countries were found guilty of both dumping and injury. In the other 26% of cases, at least
one country had a preliminary outcome that differed from that of the other countries accused in
the multi-country case.
Table 2 provides evidence of this cross-country variation in preliminary outcomes for antidumping cases filed by US manufacturing industries between 1980 and 2001. The preliminary outcome is
defined as affirmative if the US ITC finds preliminary evidence of injury or threat of injury and the
USDOC finds preliminary evidence of dumping. The preliminary outcome is defined as negative if
either agency makes a negative determination. The first column reports the number of countries
12

Although it is uncommon, the USITC occasionally splits its preliminary decision across countries. For example,

in the 1993 case of phthalic anhydride (731-TA-664-668), only one of the five countries accused of dumping was found
to be injuring the domestic US industry during the preliminary investigation. Similarly, in the 1995 case of polyvinyl
alcohol (731-TA-726-729), only three of the four countries accused of dumping were found to be a cause of injury
during the preliminary investigation.
13
This determination is made within 115 days of the USITC’s preliminary determination. Therefore, the total
elapsed time from initiation to a preliminary measure is 160 days in normal cases.
14
See, for example, the splits in preliminary dumping determinations in oil country tubular goods in 1994 (731TA-711-717), stainless steel round wire in 1997 (731-TA-781-786), low enriched uranium in 2000 (731-TA-909-912),
and structural steel beams in 2001 (731-TA-935-942).

8

named in an antidumping case, the second column lists the number of multicountry-cases, the third
column lists the number cases in which all the accused countries faced a preliminary antidumping
measure, and column 4 lists the number of multicountry cases in which no accused country faced
a preliminary antidumping measure. Column 5 reports the number of cases in which some accused
countries faced preliminary measures and some did not. Overall, in about 26% of antidumping
cases at least one country had a preliminary outcome that was different from its accused peers.
If the preliminary injury investigation found evidence of injury caused by “dumped” imports,
the case proceeds to the final phase. In the final phase, the USITC again sends questionnaires
to the domestic firms, importers, and foreign firms that reported production and/or imports during the preliminary phase. Final questionnaires request generally the same data as preliminary
questionnaires, but are updated with more recent data. One difference with the preliminary investigation is that questionnaires are sent to purchasers of the product requesting data on the value of
purchases of the product manufactured domestically, by foreign firms accused of dumping and by
other foreign firms. Purchasers are also asked to compare foreign and domestic products in terms
of price, quality, service, delivery, etc. The US Department of Commerce makes a final dumping
determination according to the price and cost data available. As in the preliminary phase, there is
considerable variation across countries in the magnitude of the final duty with Commerce finding no
evidence of dumping in some cases. Differences in the magnitudes of preliminary and final dumping
margins can arise because more recent data on prices and costs have become available or because
data obtained in the final questionnaires may obtain revisions to data obtained in the preliminary
questionnaire.
To conclude the final phase of the investigation, the US ITC makes a final injury determination.15 The USITC generally groups all countries j that have proceeded to the final phase together
in its injury decision, but split decisions are possible if some countries are being investigated for
a threat of injury (as opposed to actual injury). If there is evidence of injury and dumping, the
government imposes a final antidumping duty.16 In summary, during the final phase of an inves15

This determination is made within 120 days of the US DOC’s preliminary dumping determination or 45 days of

its final dumping determination, whichever date is later. Consequently, the total elapsed time from initiation of a
petition to the final determination can range from 280 to 340 days in normal cases.
16
See Blonigen and Haynes (2002) and Blonigen and Park (2004) for a detailed discussion of the dynamics of
antidumping duties after imposition. Since 1995, GATT rules limit the duration of antidumping measures to 5 years.
However, Cadot, de Melo, and Tumurchudur (2007) find that US compliance with the WTO’s sunset review policy
is weak at best and likely has had no impact on the duration of US antidumping duties.

9

tigation, cross-country variation in which countries ultimately face antidumping duties can arise
from variation in the outcome of the dumping determination or the injury (or threat of injury)
determination.
Table 3 presents evidence on the cross-country variation in final determinations for antidumping
cases brought by US manufacturers between 1980 and 2001. The structure of the table is the same
as table 2. Again we observe that in the final stage of an antidumping investigation, the government
split its decision across countries accused of dumping in one quarter of multi-country cases.

3

Empirical Model
To evaluate if foreign economic fluctuations lead to cyclical dumping, I estimate a binary model

with selection (Van de Ven and Van Praag (1981)), specifically, a binary model of industry i
petitions for antidumping protection against countries j and a binary model of the government’s
decision to impose antidumping measures. The empirical model is a two stage process. In the first
stage, in every period t an industry i makes a binary decision to file for protection or not to file
against each foreign country j that exports i’s product to the US. In the second stage, if an industry
has filed for protection, the government makes a binary decision of whether or not to impose an
antidumping measure against each country j accused of dumping.
To simplify the analysis, in the second stage, I estimate a binary model of the government’s
decision to impose a preliminary antidumping measure in which the injury determination by the
USITC and the dumping determination by the USDOC are collapsed into a single outcome variable
which is affirmative if both agency decisions are affirmative. Similarly, the binary model of the final
decision is collapsed into a single outcome variable which is affirmative if there is evidence of both
dumping and injury.
In the second stage, the government’s latent measure of injury and dumping d∗ijt is unobserved,
but takes the form d∗ijt = β ′ xijt + εijt where i denotes the industry in which dumping is alleged to
occur, j denotes the foreign country accused of dumping, and t denotes the time period in which
the complaint is filed. The variables in xijt are described in detail in the next section. In brief,
this vector includes a measure of the state of industry demand in both the accused foreign country
and in the importing country and lagged measures of injury to the importing country’s industry.
Although I do not observe the latent measure of injury and dumping, I observe the importing

10

government’s decision of whether (dijt = 1) or not (dijt = 0) to impose antidumping protection
conditional on an industry filing for protection.

dijt =



1 if d∗ > 0
ijt

(1)


0 if d∗ ≤ 0
ijt
Assuming εijt ∽ N (0, 1), then the likelihood for the selected sub-sample is

L=

Yh
ijt

idijt Y h
i(1−dijt )
Φ(β ′ xijt )
1 − Φ(β ′ xijt )

(2)

ijt

where the CDF for a normal distribution is denoted by Φ.
An antidumping case is only considered by the government if a domestic industry chooses to
file a petition for protection. If an industry’s decision to apply for protection and the government’s
decision to grant protection are correlated, then estimates of β will be inconsistent.
∗ , is unobserved, but takes the
In the first stage, the industry’s latent measure of selection, yijt
∗ = γ ′ z +ν , where z
form yijt
ijt
ijt
ijt is a vector that includes a measure of the state of industry demand

in the foreign country and foreign and domestic industry characteristics that are predetermined at
time t; (νijt , εijt ) are assumed to be independent of (xijt , zijt ) and their joint distribution is given
by:



1 ρ 
  ∼ N 0, 

νijt
ρ 1
εijt







The industry’s decision to petition (yijt = 1) can be written

yijt =



1 if y ∗ > 0
ijt

(3)


0 if y ∗ ≤ 0
ijt
Given the preceding assumptions, the expectation of the government’s latent variable in the
second stage can be written:

∗
E(d∗ijt xijt , yijt
> 0) = E(β ′ xijt xijt , νijt > −γ ′ zijt ) + ρ

11

φ(−γ ′ zijt )
Φ(γ ′ zijt )

(4)

and the government’s latent variable is given by:
d∗ijt = β ′ xijt + ρ

φ(−γ ′ zijt )
+ ε̃ijt
Φ(γ ′ zijt )

(5)

∗ > 0) = 0 and E(ε̃2 y ∗ >
where ε̃ijt is normally distributed and independent of νijt , E(ε̃ijt yijt
ijt ijt

0) = 1 − ρ2 λijt (−γ ′ zijt − λijt ) and where λijt = φ(−γ ′ zijt )/Φ(γ ′ zijt ).
Renormalizing d∗ijt so that the variance of the censored error, ε̃ijt , is equal to one allows us to
derive the likelihood for the full model as:

L=

Yh
ijt

idijt yijt Y h
i(1−dijt )yijt Y h
i1−yijt
Φ(β ′ xijt , γ ′ zijt , ρ)
Φ(−β ′ xijt , γ ′ zijt , ρ)
Φ(−γ ′ zijt )
ijt

(6)

ijt

Identification of the effect of foreign demand strength on filings and outcomes comes from three
sources of variation in the ijt panel data. First, within an industry i in year t, there is variation
across countries j both in whether or not they are included in an antidumping petition and in
the government’s determination of injury and dumping. Second, within a year t, there is variation
across industries i in filing and protection decisions. Finally, there is intertemporal variation for
industry i and country j in the timing of petition-filing by industries and the protection decisions
by governments.
Marginal effects and predicted joint probabilities derived from coefficient estimates obtained
from maximizing the log of the likelihood (6) are reported in tables 6 - 11.

4

Data
I estimate the empirical model using a panel dataset constructed from three main data sources:

(1) the World Bank’s Trade, Production and Protection Data, (2) the NBER Trade and Manufacturing Databases, and (3) the Global Antidumping Database maintained by Chad Bown. Data on
US GDP growth come from the US Bureau of Economic Analysis. Annual bilateral real exchange
rates in foreign currency per US dollar come from the USDA Economic Research Service. Summary
statistics for all variables in the dataset are reported in table 5.
The focus of the empirical work is quantifying the role that foreign demand shocks play in
industry petitioning and the government’s decision to impose antidumping protection. The World
12

Bank’s Trade, Production and Protection Data compiled by Alessandro Nicita and Marcelo Olarreaga provides information on output, imports, exports and employment for 28 3 digit ISIC Rev.
2 manufacturing industries from 1980-2001 for 49 developed and developing economies.17 Because
US antidumping duties are imposed against countries and not customs unions or free trade areas,
the analysis treats each country of the EU as a separate observation with country-level, rather than
Union-level data used in the analysis.
Estimation of the model uses four different proxies for the strength of demand in country
j industry i: the growth of employment for ijt − 1, the growth of consumption (output plus
imports less exports) for ijt−1, detrended employment growth and detrended consumption growth.
Although foreign consumption growth would seem to be the best measure to capture fluctuations in
foreign demand, the rationale for focusing on foreign employment growth is that we might expect
the reported counts of workers to be a relatively high quality variable across a wide spectrum
of countries. Moreover, data on industry employment is available for more countries and years.
The two detrended growth measures are intended to better capture country and industry-specific
demand fluctuations. The detrended variable is defined as employment (consumption) growth in
country j industry i at t − 1 less the average annual growth rate of employment for country j
industry i from 1979 (or earliest year available) until 2001. The logged levels of employment and
consumption serve as proxies for the size of the foreign industry. Because the current value of these
variables could be endogenous to filing behavior by US industries, I use the first lag of all foreign
variables in estimating the model.
The NBER Trade and Manufacturing Databases provide data on imports, shipments, prices,
employment, real capital stock and value added for about 450 manufacturing industries. These
data were concorded to 439 1987 4 digit SIC codes using the industry concordance provided by the
NBER-CES Manufacturing Industry Database and the original data from 1979-1994 were extended
through 2001. Nominal values of imports and shipments (a measure of domestic output) were
17

Countries in the dataset include: Argentina, Australia, Austria, Bangladesh, Belgium, Brazil, Canada, Chile,

China, Columbia, Costa Rica, Denmark, Ecuador, Egypt, El Salvador, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hong Kong,
Hungary, India, Indonesia, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Japan, Kenya, South Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Netherlands, New
Zealand, Norway, Peru, Philippines, Poland, Portugal, Singapore, South Africa, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, Taiwan,
Thailand, Trinidad, Turkey, United Kingdom, and Venezuela. Twenty-two years of disaggregated manufacturing data
are available for almost all of the countries in the dataset. Important targets of US antidumping duties with fewer
than twenty-two years of available data include: the People’s Republic of China (1980-1998), Germany (1992-2001),
and Brazil (1993-1996).

13

deflated to real 1987 dollars using industry specific price indices.
Industry characteristics used to estimate the selection equation include political and economic
measures that may affect an industry’s propensity to file but are thought to be unrelated to the
government’s determination of dumping. Some industries may be more likely to file for protection
than others. For example, large industries may be better able to assume the large legal fixed cost of
filing a petition. Industries in which the level of imports relative to total domestic consumption is
high may be more familiar with trade protection policies and thus, more likely to file. The vertical
structure of an industry may matter; industries that are further downstream may file more petitions
because they are more sensitive to industry price changes. Thus, a measure of industry size, the
level of employment; the real import penetration ratio (real imports/(real imports + real domestic
shipments)); and a proxy for the vertical structure of an industry, the value-added to output ratio
are used to estimate the selection equation. The selection equation also includes three measures
of injury which US law suggests should be important to the government’s decision; the capacity
utilization rate (real shipments/real capital stock), the percent change in the import penetration
ratio and the change in employment. Because the current values of industry specific variables and
the choice of whether to petition for protection may be endogenous, I use lagged values of these
variables in zijt .
Data on antidumping cases from 1979 through 2001 come from Global Antidumping Database
Version 3.0 compiled by Chad Bown at Brandeis University. The US files in the database provide
detailed information on the date a petition was filed, the identity of the country accused of dumping, tariff line information on the products involved, various outcome dates, and the outcomes at
different stages of the investigation. The variable on petition filings takes on a value of one if the
US industry filed a petition. Using the detailed information on the case outcome, I construct two
binary measures of the government’s determination: preliminary decision and final decision. Following Hansen and Prusa (1995), the preliminary (final) decision is coded as affirmative if the US
government imposed a preliminary (final) antidumping duty or if he case resulted in a suspension
or termination agreement during the preliminary (final) phase.18
18

As a robustness check, I have re-estimated the basic specifications for preliminary duties and final duties after

re-coding suspension and termination agreements as negative (no-duty) outcomes. The estimated marginal effects of
foreign economic conditions are similar across coding schema although the magnitudes are larger when suspensions
and terminations are coded as no-duty outcomes. The robustness across coding schema is likely due to the rarity of
suspensions and terminations after the late 1980s.

14

The three datasets used in the paper provide information on industries at three different levels
of aggregation: 3 digit foreign industries, 4 digit US industries, and 5, 7, 8, or 10 digit antidumping
cases. In order to merge these three datasets together, the 439 4 digit SIC87 manufacturing
industries were mapped into 28 ISIC R. 2 manufacturing industries by the author. Similarly,
the tariff-line level antidumping case data were also mapped into 439 4 digit SIC87 industries by
the author. Because the US and foreign industry data used in the analysis are more aggregated
than the industries investigated in antidumping cases, we might expect parameter estimates based
on these aggregated variables to underestimate the true effect of domestic and foreign factors on
antidumping outcomes.

5

Empirical Results
The empirical results summarized in tables 8 and 11 indicate that a weakening of demand

in a foreign industry is associated with an increased probability of US antidumping protection.
According to the estimates of the empirical model, a one standard deviation fall in foreign demand
increases the joint probability that a US industry will seek and the US government will grant
a preliminary antidumping measure by a factor of two to three, depending on the measure of
foreign demand used. Similarly, a one standard deviation fall in foreign demand increases the joint
probability of a filing and a final antidumping measure by a factor of five to seven, depending upon
the precise measure. This suggests that the US government might be using antidumping protection
to shelter the US economy from cyclical dumping caused by economic weakness in a foreign trading
partner.
Tables 6 and 7 report the estimated marginal effects on the probability that an industry i
will file an antidumping petition against country j in year t and in the probability that the US
government will impose a preliminary antidumping measure. The predicted joint probability of a
petition filing and a preliminary antidumping measure associated with a one standard deviation
fall in foreign demand is presented in table 8.
Tables 9 and 10 present estimated marginal effects for petition filings and final antidumping
measures. Table 11 summarizes these results as the predicted joint probability of a petition filing
and a final antidumping measure in response to a one standard deviation fall in foreign demand.

15

5.1

Preliminary antidumping measures

Table 6 presents estimates of the two-stage model of the US industry’s filing decision and
government’s decision to impose a preliminary antidumping measure. The top panel of table 6
reports the marginal increase in the probability that a US industry will file an antidumping petition
associated with changes in measures of foreign demand and the size of the foreign industry. The
bottom panel reports the marginal increase in the probability of the US government imposing a
preliminary antidumping measure.
Column 1 reports results for the basic specification. A one unit increase in the lagged growth of
foreign employment is associated with a 1.2% decrease in the probability that a domestic industry
will file an antidumping petition. Evaluated at the sample mean, a one standard deviation fall in
lagged foreign employment growth increases the probability that that country’s industry will face
an antidumping petition by 0.23 percentage points. This roughly doubles the probability of a filing
relative to the unconditional mean filing rate in the sample of 0.20%.
Proceeding to the lower panel of the table, in column 1 a one-unit increase in the growth of
foreign employment is associated with a reduction in the probability of an preliminary antidumping
measure of 3.8% after controlling for other factors (the lagged employment of the foreign industry,
the lagged growth of country-specific import penetration, lagged US GDP growth, and the lagged
bilateral exchange rate) and the domestic industry’s first-stage decision to file an antidumping petition. The economic significance is moderate; a one standard deviation fall in foreign employment
growth translates into a 0.74 percentage point increase in the probability of an affirmative preliminary decision. Combining estimates from the two stages of the model, the predicted joint probability
of a petition filing and a preliminary measure being imposed associated with a one standard deviation fall in lagged foreign employment growth is 0.32%, roughly 2 times the mean joint probability
in the sample of 0.14%. Table 8 reports predicted joint probabilities for all specifications.
Moving across the columns of table 6, alternative measures of the strength of foreign demand are
employed. Column 2 substitutes the lagged growth of foreign consumption for the lagged growth
of employment. The results for the main variable of interest are of the same sign and similar
magnitude in the industry filing equation, even though the sample size is reduced by roughly
50,000 observations when this less-available measure of foreign demand is used. On this smaller
sample, the coefficient on lagged foreign consumption growth is not significantly different from zero
in the government’s decision equation. Table 8 reports that the predicted joint probability of a

16

petition and a preliminary measure is 0.44% in response to a one standard deviation fall in lagged
foreign consumption growth.
This raises a question: are the differences in the estimates presented in columns 1 and 2 due to
differences in the measures of foreign demand or due to differences in the estimation samples. The
results in column 3 attempt to resolve this. Column 3 repeats the specification 1 on the smaller
sample of observations for which the lagged foreign consumption growth variable is available. On
this smaller sample, the marginal effect of a change in foreign employment growth is larger in the
industry’s filing equation, and not significant in the government’s decision equation. To assess the
quantitative significance of these differences, table 8 reports that the predicted joint probability
of a petition and a preliminary measure conditional on a one standard deviation fall in the two
measures of foreign demand. For both specifications 2 and 3, the joint probability is 0.44%. This
suggests that the differences in estimates across specifications are likely due to the changing sample
size rather than in a fundamental difference in what the variables are measuring.
In specification 4, the measure of foreign demand is the actual growth of foreign employment
in the year before the antidumping petition was filed less the long-run trend growth of foreign
employment in country j’s industry i. This detrended measure of foreign employment growth might
better capture the country and industry-specific cyclicality of foreign demand. The results are close
in magnitude to those of the basic specification. In table 8 the predicted joint probability of an
antidumping measure for this specification is 0.29%, a hair smaller than the predicted probability
from specification 1 of 0.32%. Specification 5 repeats this type of analysis by using detrended foreign
consumption growth. Again, the estimates are quantitatively similar in size with a predicted joint
probability of 0.39% compared to 0.44% from specification 2. Together, columns 4 and 5 indicate
that the results are robust to different measures of foreign demand that might better capture
country and industry specific cycles.19
19

The coefficient estimates of US variables that are not reported (the growth of lagged import penetration, the

lagged level of import penetration, the lagged growth of employment in the domestic industry, the lagged level of
domestic employment, the lagged level of capacity utilization, the lagged growth of US GDP, and the lagged level of the
bilateral real exchange rate) are generally in line with previous research and are available upon request. Interestingly,
coefficient estimates on the lagged import penetration ratio and the lagged growth of import penetration in the
selection equation tell us that (1) consistent with Staiger and Wolak’s (1994) findings, industries with higher import
penetration ratios are more likely to seek protection and further, (2) countries with higher import penetration ratios
are more likely to be targets of antidumping activity than countries with lower import penetration ratios. However,
a shortcoming of the import penetration variable is that it cannot inform us as to whether industries seek (and the

17

The second to last line of table 6 reports estimates of ρ, the correlation of the errors from the first
and second stage. Estimates of ρ in table 6 are negative and of roughly the same magnitude across
all specifications. A negative selection bias is somewhat surprising. One possible interpretation
is that US industries only apply for protection if they are in poor health and think that they
might reasonably satisfy the injury criteria. Among this set of poorly-performing industries, the
government chooses to protect only the relatively healthy industries with an antidumping measure.
The last row of table 6 reports the loglikelihood. Because the inclusion of different variables
changes the estimation sample, it is not feasible to use the loglikelihood to compare fit across all
models. However, comparisons can be made between specifications 2 and 3, 1 and 4, and 3 and 5.
The differences in model fit, as shown by the loglikelihoods, are small.
Table 7 presents variations of the basic specification. In specification 6, the panel dataset is
restricted to the 4 digit SIC87 industries that have filed at least one antidumping petition against
any country j between 1980 and 2001. This specification relies heavily on time series variation
for frequent industry users of antidummping to obtain identification. In table 8, a one standard
deviation fall in foreign employment growth generates a predicted joint probability of a preliminary
antidumping measure of 0.64%, suggesting that cyclical variation in the foreign economy might
be even more important in industries that regularly seek antidumping protection. Specification 7
attempts to control for the fact that small exporters are not subject to antidumping duties.20 This
sample drops all country-product-year observations in which a country’s share of the US import
market is less than 1% of a 4 digit SIC87 industry. After omitting these smaller exporters, the joint
probability of a preliminary antidumping measure is 0.92% conditional on a one standard deviation
US government imposes) antidumping protection because US shipments have fallen or because foreign imports have
risen. Thus, the finding that antidumping protection is more likely against a country that is experiencing relatively
weak growth in its own industry after controlling for import penetration informs our understanding of why there is
variation in the government’s policy response to two different countries or industries with similar levels of import
penetration. Consistent with the findings of Knetter and Prusa (2003), Feinberg (2005) and Jallab, Sandretto and
Gbakou (2006) all of whom estimate negative binomial models of filing rates, a real appreciation of the dollar is
associated with an increase in the probability of antidumping filings.
20
The WTO’s antidumping code states that any country which is the source of less than 3% of the imports of a
product that is subject to an antidumping investigation is a “negligible” supplier and cannot be subject to antidumping
duties. Because my analysis uses industry definitions at the 4 digit SIC87 level which are more aggregated than the
product definitions used in antidumping cases, I restrict the “large exporter” sample to countries with an import
market share greater than 1% of the 4 digit industry. Results are robust to modest changes in this definition.

18

fall in foreign industry employment growth. This is more than twice as large as the joint probability
of a filing and preliminary measure in this “large exporter” sample of 0.44%. Finally, specification
8 seeks to identify if antidumping investigations that involve more than one country are more or
less likely to face a preliminary antidumping duty that single-country investigations. The estimate
on the multicountry case dummy is not statistically significant, suggesting that multicountry cases
are not more likely to result in preliminary antidumping measures than single country cases after
controlling for other factors. The marginal effect of a foreign demand shock has the same sign and
a slightly larger magnitude in both stages of the non-linear model. The predicted joint probability
of 0.41% is slightly larger than for the basic specification. Overall, table 7 validates the robustness
of the basic results while suggesting that the magnitude of foreign economic shocks is likely larger
for industries that regularly seek protection under antidumping law and for important exporting
countries.
In summary, weak growth in either employment or consumption in foreign industries is a powerful predictor of a preliminary antidumping measure. After controlling for other economic and
political factors including US GDP growth, a one standard deviation fall in the lagged growth of
foreign demand increases the probability of a preliminary antidumping measure by a factor of 2 to
3, depending on the precise measure of foreign demand used. In conclusion, temporary US trade
policies are applied counter-cyclically to foreign economic fluctuations.

5.2

Final antidumping measures

Table 9 presents marginal effects for the model of industry filing and the government’s decision to
impose final antidumping measures. A one standard deviation fall in foreign employment growth has
a significant positive effect on the probability that a petition will be filed, but is not a statistically
significant determinant of the government’s decision to impose final (long-lasting) antidumping
measures. Quantitatively, the predicted joint probability of a petition and a final antidumping
measure evaluated at the sample mean is 0.52% in response to a one standard deviation fall in foreign
employment growth. This is a more than five-fold increase above the underlying joint probability
in the sample of 0.09%. See table 11. Substituting in foreign consumption growth (specification
10), using a smaller sample (specification 11), or using detrended employment (specification 12) or
consumption growth (specification 13) as the measure of foreign demand generate broadly consistent
results. The strength of foreign demand is an important determinant of filing behavior, but not of
the government’s decision. In table 11, the predicted joint probabilities of a petition and a final
19

measure are 0.69%, 0.56%, 0.48% and 0.49% for specifications 10-13, respectively.21
It is not clear why the measures of foreign demand are not significant determinants in the
government’s final decision. One possibility is that new data might become available to policy
makers between the time of the preliminary and final decision. However, because the overwhelming
majority of preliminary and final decisions are made within the same calendar year, there is not
enough variation in the sample to examine this with annual data.22
Table 10 reports three addition specifications. Column 14 presents estimates obtained from a
sample restricted to 4 digit SIC87 industries that filed at least one antidumping petition during the
sample period. Again, the sign of the marginal effect of foreign employment growth is the same as
that of the basic specification 9 reported in table 9. Quantitatively, table 11 reports a one standard
deviation fall in lagged foreign employment growth increases the joint probability of a filing and a
final measure to 0.71%. Specification 15 restricts the sample to large exporters as defined above.
Within this sample of large exporters, a one standard deviation fall in lagged foreign employment
growth increases the joint probability of a filing and a final measure to 0.45% from a mean in this
sample of 0.27%. Specification 16 adds a multicountry case dummy to the government’s decision
rule and yields an estimate of the joint probability of a filing and a final measure associated with
a one standard deviation fall in lagged foreign employment growth of 0.55%.
To summarize tables 9 and 10, economic weakness in foreign industries is a strong predictor of
final antidumping measures. However, the mechanism by which these variables influence the outcome is different for final (long-lasting) antidumping duties and preliminary (temporary) measures.
While measures of economic weakness in a foreign industry directly impact both the government’s
preliminary antidumping decision rule and the domestic industry’s filing rule, for final antidumping
duties, measures of foreign demand only affect the ultimate outcome through the domestic industry’s filing decision. Depending on the exact specification of the model, a one standard deviation
fall in foreign demand can increase by a factor of 10 the joint probability that an industry will file
an antidumping petition and the US government will impose a final antidumping duty.
21

As with preliminary measures, the coefficient estimates for other variables are generally in line with previous

research. The estimated correlation coefficient is negative in all specifications.
22
Estimating the model with the data lagged from the date of the final decision rather than the petition filing
yielded no notable changes. Because most cases are completed in one calendar year, this alternative lagging structure
yielded few changes relative to the basic data sample.

20

6

Conclusion
This paper exploits cross-country, cross-industry and intertemporal variation in manufacturing

employment and consumption growth to identify the relationship between economic weakness in
a foreign economy and the probability of antidumping protection. After controlling for other economic and political variables including US GDP growth, I find that a one standard deviation fall in
the growth of employment (consumption) in a foreign economy’s manufacturing industry doubles
(triples) the joint probability that the US industry will file an antidumping petition and the US
government will impose a preliminary (temporary) antidumping measure. Further, a one standard
deviation fall in foreign employment (consumption) growth increases the joint probability that a
petition will be filed and a final (long-lasting) antidumping measure will be imposed by a factor
of five (seven). While earlier research by Knetter and Prusa (2003) showed that antidumping protection is applied counter-cyclically with regard to the domestic business cycle, this paper provides
the first evidence that I am aware of that US trade policy is applied counter-cyclically to foreign
economic fluctuations.

21

Figure 1: Mean employment growth in industry i country j in the year before an antidumping
petition is filed

1.5%

1.2%

1.0%
0.3%

0.5%

0.2%

0.0%
!0.5%

!0.7%

!1.0%

!1.1%

!1.3%

!1.5%

Figure 2: Mean consumption growth in industry i country j in the year before an antidumping
petition is filed

6.0%

5.4%

5.0%
3.8%

4.0%
3.0%

3.2%
2.7%

2.6%
1.8%

2.0%
1.0%
0.0%

22

Table 1: Accusations of dumping: US Manufacturing 1980-2001
Industry i makes accusation of dumping at t
Country j exports i to US at t and is...
accused of dumping

545

not accused

8017

Industry i makes no accusation of dumping at t
Country j exports i to US at t and is...
not accused

264,077

23

Table 2: Cross-country variation in prelim. antidumping outcome: 1980-2001
No. of countries

Number

Affirm.

Negative

Split

named in case

of cases

Cases

Cases

Cases

1

186

138

48

0

2

65

43

10

12

3

18

8

5

5

4

14

8

5

1

5

8

5

0

3

6

4

3

0

1

7

5

2

1

2

8

1

0

0

1

12

1

0

1

0

Total

302

207

70

25

24

Table 3: Cross-country variation in final antidumping outcome: 1980-2001
No. of countries

Number

Affirm.

Negative

Split

named in case

of cases

Cases

Cases

Cases

1

186

80

106

0

2

65

28

25

12

3

18

7

6

5

4

14

5

4

4

5

8

4

2

2

6

4

2

1

1

7

5

0

4

1

8

1

0

1

0

12

1

0

1

0

Total

302

126

150

25

Table 4: 49 countries included in the dataset
Argentina

Costa Rica

Hungary

Mexico

Spain

Australia

Denmark

India

Netherlands

Sweden

Austria

Ecuador

Indonesia

New Zealand

Switzerland

Bangladesh

Egypt

Ireland

Norway

Taiwan

Belgium

El Salvador

Israel

Peru

Thailand

Brazil

Finland

Italy

Philippines

Trinidad

Canada

France

Japan

Poland

Turkey

Chile

Germany

Kenya

Portugal

U. Kingdom

China

Greece

South Korea

Singapore

Venezuela

Columbia

Hong Kong

Malaysia

South Africa

25

Table 5: Summary Statistics
Mean

Std. Dev.

Preliminary Measure= 1|petition filed

0.739

0.439

Final Measure= 1|petition filed

0.459

0.499

0.0020

0.0447

Growth Foreign Employmentijt−1

0.003

0.195

Growth Foreign Consumptionijt−1

0.053

0.283

Growth Foreign Employijt−1 - Trendij

0.001

0.188

Growth Foreign Consumpijt−1 - Trendij

0.003

0.275

Ln Level of Foreign Employmentijt−1

10.572

1.703

Ln Level of Foreign Consumptionijt−1

14.867

1.778

-0.014

0.095

Ln US Employmentit−1

3.202

1.031

Capacity Utilizationit−1

2.765

1.743

ValueAdded/Outputit−1

0.505

0.119

Growth Import Penetrationijt−1

0.088

1.118

Import Penetrationijt−1

0.006

0.026

Dependent Variables

Petition Filed
Measures of foreign industry demand

Measures of foreign market size

Domestic Industry Variables
Growth US Employmentit−1

Foreign*Domestic Industry Variables

Number of Observations

272639

26

Table 6: Estimates of marginal effects for preliminary decisions

Stage 1: Industry's filing decision
Measures of foreign demand
Growth of foreign employment_ijt!1

Basic specific.

Substitute
foreign
consump.
growth

(1)

(2)

!0.012***
(0.004)

Detrended foreign Detrended foreign
consumption
Basic spec. on employment growth
col. (2) sample as foreign demand growth as foreign
demand shock
shock
(3)

(4)

!0.023***
(0.004)

Growth of foreign consumption_ijt!1

!0.014**
(0.006)

Detrended growth of foreign employment_ijt!1

!0.010**
(0.004)

Detrended growth of foreign consumption_ijt!1
Measures of foreign market size
Ln foreign employment_ijt!1

!0.012**
(0.006)
0.008***
(0.001)

0.009***
(0.001)

Ln foreign consumption_ijt!1

Other control variables

Stage 2: Government's preliminary decision
Measures of foreign demand
Growth of foreign employment_ijt!1

0.007***
(0.000)

0.009***
(0.001)
yes

yes

!0.038*
(0.023)

0.009***
(0.001)
yes

yes

yes

!0.040
(0.031)

Growth of foreign consumption_ijt!1

0.000
(0.015)

Detrended growth of foreign employment_ijt!1

!0.042*
(0.022)

Detrended growth of foreign consumption_ijt!1
Measures of foreign market size
Ln foreign employment_ijt!1

(5)

!0.003
(0.015)
0.003
(0.003)

0.004
(0.003)

Ln foreign consumption_ijt!1

0.003
(0.002)

0.002
(0.004)

0.002
(0.004)

Other control variables

yes

yes

yes

yes

yes

Number of uncensored observations

545

443

441

545

443

Number of Observations

272639

228830

227849

272639

228830

Rho

!0.025**
(0.012)

!0.027*
(0.015)

!0.029*
(0.015)

!0.024**
(0.011)

!0.027*
(0.015)

Log Likelihood

!3616.14

!2952.25

!2937.34

!3616.09

!2953.45

Notes: Huber!White robust std errors in parentheses with ***,**, and * indicating statistical significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels. Other
control variables in the stage 2: government decision include: the growth of import penetration_ijt!1, the growth of domestic employment_it!1,
capacity utilization_it!1, the growth of US GDP_t!1, and the bilateral real exchange rate between the dollar and country j's currency_t!1. Other
control variables in the stage 1: Industry filing decision include all controls in the stage 2 decison plus import penetration_ijt!1, the logged level
of domestic employment_it!1, and value added/output_it!1.

27

Table 7: Estimates of marginal effects for preliminary decisions: Additional specifications
Restrict col. (1) sample to Restrict col. (1)
industries with
sample
antidumping filers
to large exporters
(6)
(7)
Stage 1: Industry's filing decision
Measures of foreign demand
Growth of foreign employment_ijt!1

Add a multi!country
case dummy to basic
specif. in col. (1)
(8)

!0.010***
(0.003)

!0.111***
(0.034)

!0.018***
(0.006)

0.006***
(0.000)
yes

0.025***
(0.005)
yes

0.012***
(0.001)
yes

!0.022
(0.016)

!0.361**
(0.183)

!0.057*
(0.034)

0.001
(0.002)

0.032
(0.021)

0.005
(0.004)

Other control variables

yes

yes

yes

Number of uncensored observations

545

379

545

82905

62850

272639

Rho

!0.025**
(0.012)

0.034
(0.196)

!0.037**
(0.018)

Log Likelihood

!3217.43

!2239.96

!3615.84

Measures of foreign market size
Ln foreign employment_ijt!1
Other control variables

Stage 2: Government's preliminary decision
Measures of foreign demand
Growth of foreign employment_ijt!1
Measures of foreign market size
Ln foreign employment_ijt!1

Number of Observations

Notes: Huber!White robust std errors in parentheses with ***,**, and * indicating statistical significance at the 1%, 5% and
10% levels. Other control variables in the stage 2: government decision include: the growth of import penetration_ijt!1,
the growth of domestic employment_it!1, capacity utilization_it!1, the growth of US GDP_t!1, and the bilateral real
exchange rate between the dollar and country j's currency_t!1. Other control variables in the stage 1: Industry filing
decision include all controls in the stage 2 decison plus import penetration_ijt!1, the logged level of domestic
employment_it!1, and value added/output_it!1.

28

Table 8: Predicted joint probability of a petition filing and a preliminary antidumping measure for
a one s.d. fall in foreign demand

Spec. Measure of foreign demand

Description

Predicted joint probability of a
filing and a preliminary
measure conditional on a one
std. dev. fall in foreign demand
0.32%

(1)

Employment growth

Basic specification

(2)

Consumption growth

Basic specification

0.44%

(3)

Employment growth

Basic on spec . (2) sample

0.44%

(4)

Detrended employ. growth

Basic specification

0.29%

(5)

Detrended consump. growth

Basic specification

0.39%

(6)

Employment growth

0.64%

(7)

Employment growth

(8)

Employment growth

Restrict spec. (1) sample to
industries with
antidumping filers
Restrict spec. (1) sample
to large exporters
Add a multi!country case
dummy to spec. (1)

29

0.92%
0.41%

Table 9: Estimates of marginal effects for final decisions

Stage 1: Industry's filing decision
Measures of foreign demand
Growth of foreign employment_ijt!1

Basic specific.

Substitute
foreign
consump.
growth

(9)

(10)

!0.048***
(0.017)

Detrended
Detrended
foreign
foreign
Basic spec. on employment consumption
growth as
growth as
col. (10)
foreign
foreign
sample
demand
demand
shock
shock
(11)

(12)

!0.059***
(0.011)

Growth of foreign consumption_ijt!1

!0.046**
(0.019)

Detrended growth of foreign employment_ijt!1

!0.045**
(0.019)

Detrended growth of foreign consumption_ijt!1
Measures of foreign market size
Ln foreign employment_ijt!1

!0.039**
(0.02)
0.032***
(0.002)

0.024***
(0.002)

Ln foreign consumption_ijt!1

Other control variables

Stage 2: Government's preliminary decision
Measures of foreign demand
Growth of foreign employment_ijt!1

0.032***
(0.002)

0.031***
(0.002)
yes

yes

0.017
(0.073)

0.031***
(0.002)
yes

yes

yes

0.033
(0.063)

Growth of foreign consumption_ijt!1

0.036
(0.055)

Detrended growth of foreign employment_ijt!1

!0.008
(0.077)

Detrended growth of foreign consumption_ijt!1
Measures of foreign market size
Ln foreign employment_ijt!1

(13)

0.027
(0.058)
0.016
(0.01)

0.007
(0.008)

Ln foreign consumption_ijt!1

0.016*
(0.01)

0.010
(0.012)

0.011
(0.012)

Other control variables

yes

yes

yes

yes

yes

Number of uncensored observations

545

443

441

545

443

Number of Observations

272639

228830

227849

272639

228830

Rho

!0.095**
(0.042)

!0.089*
(0.048)

!0.084**
(0.035)

!0.095**
(0.042)

!0.090*
(0.048)

Log Likelihood

!3678.159

!2987.146

!2973.175

!3678.728

!2988.404

Notes: Huber!White robust std errors in parentheses with ***,**, and * indicating statistical significance at the 1%, 5% and 10%
levels. Other control variables in the stage 2: government decision include: the growth of import penetration_ijt!1, the growth of
domestic employment_it!1, capacity utilization_it!1, the growth of US GDP_t!1, and the bilateral real exchange rate between the
dollar and country j's currency_t!1. Other control variables in the stage 1: Industry filing decision include all controls in the stage 2
decison plus import penetration_ijt!1, the logged level of domestic employment_it!1, and value added/output_it!1.

30

Table 10: Estimates of marginal effects for final decisions: Additional specifications
Restrict col. (9) sample to Restrict col. (9)
industries with
sample
antidumping filers
to large exporters
(14)
(15)
Stage 1: Industry's filing decision
Measures of foreign demand
Growth of foreign employment_ijt!1

Add a multi!country
case dummy to basic
specif. in col. (9)
(16)

!0.045***
(0.015)

!0.023***
(0.007)

!0.051***
(0.018)

0.028***
(0.002)
yes

0.005***
(0.001)
yes

0.034***
(0.002)
yes

0.021
(0.059)

0.017
(0.026)

0.017
(0.079)

0.008
(0.009)

0.004
(0.004)

0.019*
(0.011)

Other control variables

yes

yes

yes

Number of uncensored observations

545

379

545

82905

62850

272639

Rho

!0.103**
(0.048)

!0.061*
(0.033)

!0.101**
(0.045)

Log Likelihood

!3279.807

!2290.329

!3676.879

Measures of foreign market size
Ln foreign employment_ijt!1
Other control variables

Stage 2: Government's preliminary decision
Measures of foreign demand
Growth of foreign employment_ijt!1
Measures of foreign market size
Ln foreign employment_ijt!1

Number of Observations

"Notes: Huber!White robust std errors in parentheses with ***,**, and * indicating statistical significance at the 1%, 5%
and 10% levels. Other control variables in the stage 2: government decision include: the growth of import penetration_ijt!
1, the growth of domestic employment_it!1, capacity utilization_it!1, the growth of US GDP_t!1, and the bilateral real
exchange rate between the dollar and country j's currency_t!1. Other control variables in the stage 1: Industry filing
decision include all controls in the stage 2 decison plus import penetration_ijt!1, the logged level of domestic
employment_it!1, and value added/output_it!1.

31

Table 11: Predicted joint probability of a petition filing and a final antidumping measure for a one
s.d. fall in foreign demand

Spec. Measure of foreign demand

Description

Predicted joint probability of a
filing and a final measure
conditional on a one std. dev.
fall in foreign demand
0.52%

(9)

Employment growth

Basic specification

(10)

Consumption growth

Basic specification

0.69%

(11)

Employment growth

Basic on spec . (9) sample

0.56%

(12)

Detrended employ. growth

Basic specification

0.48%

(13)

Detrended consump. growth

Basic specification

0.49%

(14)

Employment growth

0.71%

(15)

Employment growth

(16)

Employment growth

Restrict spec. (9) sample to
industries with
antidumping filers
Restrict spec. (9) sample
to large exporters
Add a multi!country case
dummy to spec. (9)

32

0.45%
0.55%

References
[1] Bown, Chad P. and Meredith A. Crowley. 2007. ”Trade Deflection and Trade Depression,” Journal of International Economics 72(1): 176-201.
[2] Baldwin, Robert and Steagall, Jeffrey W. 1994. “An Analysis of ITC Decisions in Antidumping, Countervailing Duty and Safeguard Cases.” Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 130:290307.
[3] Blonigen, Bruce A. 2006. “Evolving Discretionary Practices of US Antidumping Activity.”
Canadian Journal of Economics, 39: 874-900.
[4] Blonigen, Bruce A. and Bown, Chad P. 2003. “Antidumping and Retaliation Threats.”
Journal of International Economics, 60: 249-273.
[5] Blonigen, Bruce A. and Haynes, Stephen E. 2002. “Antidumping Investigations and the
Pass-Through of Antidumping Duties and Exchange Rates.” American Economic Review, 92:
1044-1061.
[6] Blonigen, Bruce A. and Park, Jee-Hyeong 2004. “Dynamic Pricing in the Presence of
Antidumping Policy: Theory and Evidence.” American Economic Review, 94: 134-154.
[7] Bown, Chad and Crowley, Meredith. November 2010. “China’s Export Growth and the
China Safeguard: Threats to the World Trading System?” Canadian Journal of Economics,
43: 4.
[8] Cadot, Olivier; de Melo, Jaime; and Tumurchudur, Bolormaa 2007. “Anti-dumping
Sunset Reviews: The Uneven Reach of WTO Disciplines.” unpublished mimeo.
[9] Crowley, Meredith A. 2010. “Split Decisions in Antidumping Cases.” The B.E. Journal of
Economic Analysis and Policy, 10, Iss. 1, Article 68.
[10] Ethier, Wilfred J. 1982. “Dumping.”Journal of Political Economy, 90:487-506.
[11] Feinberg, Robert M. 2005. “U.S. Antidumping Enforcement and Macroeconomic Indicators
Revisited: Do Petitioners Learn?” Review of World Economics, 141: 612-622.
33

[12] Feinberg, Robert M. and Reynolds, Kara M. 2006. “The Spread of Antidumping
Regimes and the Role of Retaliation in Filings.” Southern Economic Journal.
[13] Hansen, Wendy L. 1990. “The International Trade Commission and the Politics of Protectionism.” American Political Science Review, 84: 21-46.
[14] Hansen, Wendy L. and Prusa, Thomas J. 1996. “Cumulation and ITC Decision Making:
The Sum of the Parts is Greater than the Whole.” Economic Inquiry, 34: 746-69.
[15] Hansen, Wendy L. and Prusa, Thomas J. 1997. “The Economics and Politics of Trade
Policy: An Empirical Analysis of ITC Decision Making.” Review of International Economics,
5: 230-45.
[16] Hartigan, James C. 1996. “Predatory dumping.” Canadian Journal of Economics, 29: 228239.
[17] Jallab, Mustapha Sadni; Sandretto, Rene; and Gbakou, Monnet Benoit Patrick
2006. “Antdiumping Procedures and Macroeconomic Factors: A Comparison between the
United States and the European Union.” Global Economy Journal, 6: Article 5.
[18] Knetter, Michael M. and Prusa, Thomas J. 2003. “Macroeconomic Factors and Antidumping Filings: Evidence from Four Countries.” Journal of International Economics, 61:117.
[19] Miranda, Jorge; Torres, Raul A.; and Ruiz, Mario. 1998. “The international use of
antidumping: 1987-1999.” Journal of World Trade, 32: 5-71.
[20] Moore, Michael O. 1992. “Rules or Politics? An Empirical Analysis of ITC Anti-dumping
Decisions.” Economic Inquiry, 30: 449-66.
[21] Prusa, Thomas J. 1997. “The Trade Effects of U.S. Antidumping Actions,” in The Effects
of U.S. Trade Protection and Promotion Policies Robert C. Feenstra, ed. Chicago: University
of Chicago Press.

34

[22] Prusa, Thomas J. and Skeath, Susan 2002. “The economic and strategic motives for
antidumping filings.” Review of World Economics, 138: 389-413.
[23] Staiger, Robert W. and Wolak, Frank A. 1992. “The effect of domestic antidumping law
in the presence of foreign monopoly.” Journal of International Economics, 32:265-287.
[24] Staiger, Robert W. and Wolak, Frank A. 1994. “Measuring Industry-Specific Protection:
Antidumping in the United States.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics,
51-118.
[25] Van de Ven, P.M.M. and Van Praag, Bernard M.S. 1981. “The Demand for Deductibles
in Private Health Insurance: A Probit Model with Sample Selection.” Journal of Econometrics,
17:229-252.

35

Working Paper Series
A series of research studies on regional economic issues relating to the Seventh Federal
Reserve District, and on financial and economic topics.
Standing Facilities and Interbank Borrowing: Evidence from the Federal Reserve’s
New Discount Window
Craig Furfine

WP-04-01

Netting, Financial Contracts, and Banks: The Economic Implications
William J. Bergman, Robert R. Bliss, Christian A. Johnson and George G. Kaufman

WP-04-02

Real Effects of Bank Competition
Nicola Cetorelli

WP-04-03

Finance as a Barrier To Entry: Bank Competition and Industry Structure in
Local U.S. Markets?
Nicola Cetorelli and Philip E. Strahan

WP-04-04

The Dynamics of Work and Debt
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-04-05

Fiscal Policy in the Aftermath of 9/11
Jonas Fisher and Martin Eichenbaum

WP-04-06

Merger Momentum and Investor Sentiment: The Stock Market Reaction
To Merger Announcements
Richard J. Rosen

WP-04-07

Earnings Inequality and the Business Cycle
Gadi Barlevy and Daniel Tsiddon

WP-04-08

Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets: The Case of Payment Networks
Sujit Chakravorti and Roberto Roson

WP-04-09

Nominal Debt as a Burden on Monetary Policy
Javier Díaz-Giménez, Giorgia Giovannetti, Ramon Marimon, and Pedro Teles

WP-04-10

On the Timing of Innovation in Stochastic Schumpeterian Growth Models
Gadi Barlevy

WP-04-11

Policy Externalities: How US Antidumping Affects Japanese Exports to the EU
Chad P. Bown and Meredith A. Crowley

WP-04-12

Sibling Similarities, Differences and Economic Inequality
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-04-13

Determinants of Business Cycle Comovement: A Robust Analysis
Marianne Baxter and Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-04-14

The Occupational Assimilation of Hispanics in the U.S.: Evidence from Panel Data
Maude Toussaint-Comeau

WP-04-15

1

Working Paper Series (continued)
Reading, Writing, and Raisinets1: Are School Finances Contributing to Children’s Obesity?
Patricia M. Anderson and Kristin F. Butcher

WP-04-16

Learning by Observing: Information Spillovers in the Execution and Valuation
of Commercial Bank M&As
Gayle DeLong and Robert DeYoung

WP-04-17

Prospects for Immigrant-Native Wealth Assimilation:
Evidence from Financial Market Participation
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-04-18

Individuals and Institutions: Evidence from International Migrants in the U.S.
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-04-19

Are Technology Improvements Contractionary?
Susanto Basu, John Fernald and Miles Kimball

WP-04-20

The Minimum Wage, Restaurant Prices and Labor Market Structure
Daniel Aaronson, Eric French and James MacDonald

WP-04-21

Betcha can’t acquire just one: merger programs and compensation
Richard J. Rosen

WP-04-22

Not Working: Demographic Changes, Policy Changes,
and the Distribution of Weeks (Not) Worked
Lisa Barrow and Kristin F. Butcher

WP-04-23

The Role of Collateralized Household Debt in Macroeconomic Stabilization
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-04-24

Advertising and Pricing at Multiple-Output Firms: Evidence from U.S. Thrift Institutions
Robert DeYoung and Evren Örs

WP-04-25

Monetary Policy with State Contingent Interest Rates
Bernardino Adão, Isabel Correia and Pedro Teles

WP-04-26

Comparing location decisions of domestic and foreign auto supplier plants
Thomas Klier, Paul Ma and Daniel P. McMillen

WP-04-27

China’s export growth and US trade policy
Chad P. Bown and Meredith A. Crowley

WP-04-28

Where do manufacturing firms locate their Headquarters?
J. Vernon Henderson and Yukako Ono

WP-04-29

Monetary Policy with Single Instrument Feedback Rules
Bernardino Adão, Isabel Correia and Pedro Teles

WP-04-30

2

Working Paper Series (continued)
Firm-Specific Capital, Nominal Rigidities and the Business Cycle
David Altig, Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum and Jesper Linde

WP-05-01

Do Returns to Schooling Differ by Race and Ethnicity?
Lisa Barrow and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP-05-02

Derivatives and Systemic Risk: Netting, Collateral, and Closeout
Robert R. Bliss and George G. Kaufman

WP-05-03

Risk Overhang and Loan Portfolio Decisions
Robert DeYoung, Anne Gron and Andrew Winton

WP-05-04

Characterizations in a random record model with a non-identically distributed initial record
Gadi Barlevy and H. N. Nagaraja

WP-05-05

Price discovery in a market under stress: the U.S. Treasury market in fall 1998
Craig H. Furfine and Eli M. Remolona

WP-05-06

Politics and Efficiency of Separating Capital and Ordinary Government Budgets
Marco Bassetto with Thomas J. Sargent

WP-05-07

Rigid Prices: Evidence from U.S. Scanner Data
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Benjamin Eden

WP-05-08

Entrepreneurship, Frictions, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-05-09

Wealth inequality: data and models
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-05-10

What Determines Bilateral Trade Flows?
Marianne Baxter and Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-05-11

Intergenerational Economic Mobility in the U.S., 1940 to 2000
Daniel Aaronson and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-05-12

Differential Mortality, Uncertain Medical Expenses, and the Saving of Elderly Singles
Mariacristina De Nardi, Eric French, and John Bailey Jones

WP-05-13

Fixed Term Employment Contracts in an Equilibrium Search Model
Fernando Alvarez and Marcelo Veracierto

WP-05-14

Causality, Causality, Causality: The View of Education Inputs and Outputs from Economics
Lisa Barrow and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP-05-15

3

Working Paper Series (continued)
Competition in Large Markets
Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-05-16

Why Do Firms Go Public? Evidence from the Banking Industry
Richard J. Rosen, Scott B. Smart and Chad J. Zutter

WP-05-17

Clustering of Auto Supplier Plants in the U.S.: GMM Spatial Logit for Large Samples
Thomas Klier and Daniel P. McMillen

WP-05-18

Why are Immigrants’ Incarceration Rates So Low?
Evidence on Selective Immigration, Deterrence, and Deportation
Kristin F. Butcher and Anne Morrison Piehl

WP-05-19

Constructing the Chicago Fed Income Based Economic Index – Consumer Price Index:
Inflation Experiences by Demographic Group: 1983-2005
Leslie McGranahan and Anna Paulson

WP-05-20

Universal Access, Cost Recovery, and Payment Services
Sujit Chakravorti, Jeffery W. Gunther, and Robert R. Moore

WP-05-21

Supplier Switching and Outsourcing
Yukako Ono and Victor Stango

WP-05-22

Do Enclaves Matter in Immigrants’ Self-Employment Decision?
Maude Toussaint-Comeau

WP-05-23

The Changing Pattern of Wage Growth for Low Skilled Workers
Eric French, Bhashkar Mazumder and Christopher Taber

WP-05-24

U.S. Corporate and Bank Insolvency Regimes: An Economic Comparison and Evaluation
Robert R. Bliss and George G. Kaufman

WP-06-01

Redistribution, Taxes, and the Median Voter
Marco Bassetto and Jess Benhabib

WP-06-02

Identification of Search Models with Initial Condition Problems
Gadi Barlevy and H. N. Nagaraja

WP-06-03

Tax Riots
Marco Bassetto and Christopher Phelan

WP-06-04

The Tradeoff between Mortgage Prepayments and Tax-Deferred Retirement Savings
Gene Amromin, Jennifer Huang,and Clemens Sialm

WP-06-05

Why are safeguards needed in a trade agreement?
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-06-06

4

Working Paper Series (continued)
Taxation, Entrepreneurship, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-06-07

A New Social Compact: How University Engagement Can Fuel Innovation
Laura Melle, Larry Isaak, and Richard Mattoon

WP-06-08

Mergers and Risk
Craig H. Furfine and Richard J. Rosen

WP-06-09

Two Flaws in Business Cycle Accounting
Lawrence J. Christiano and Joshua M. Davis

WP-06-10

Do Consumers Choose the Right Credit Contracts?
Sumit Agarwal, Souphala Chomsisengphet, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles

WP-06-11

Chronicles of a Deflation Unforetold
François R. Velde

WP-06-12

Female Offenders Use of Social Welfare Programs Before and After Jail and Prison:
Does Prison Cause Welfare Dependency?
Kristin F. Butcher and Robert J. LaLonde
Eat or Be Eaten: A Theory of Mergers and Firm Size
Gary Gorton, Matthias Kahl, and Richard Rosen
Do Bonds Span Volatility Risk in the U.S. Treasury Market?
A Specification Test for Affine Term Structure Models
Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

WP-06-13

WP-06-14

WP-06-15

Transforming Payment Choices by Doubling Fees on the Illinois Tollway
Gene Amromin, Carrie Jankowski, and Richard D. Porter

WP-06-16

How Did the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut Affect Stock Prices?
Gene Amromin, Paul Harrison, and Steven Sharpe

WP-06-17

Will Writing and Bequest Motives: Early 20th Century Irish Evidence
Leslie McGranahan

WP-06-18

How Professional Forecasters View Shocks to GDP
Spencer D. Krane

WP-06-19

Evolving Agglomeration in the U.S. auto supplier industry
Thomas Klier and Daniel P. McMillen

WP-06-20

Mortality, Mass-Layoffs, and Career Outcomes: An Analysis using Administrative Data
Daniel Sullivan and Till von Wachter

WP-06-21

5

Working Paper Series (continued)
The Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures:
Tying One’s Hand through the WTO.
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-06-22

How Did Schooling Laws Improve Long-Term Health and Lower Mortality?
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-06-23

Manufacturing Plants’ Use of Temporary Workers: An Analysis Using Census Micro Data
Yukako Ono and Daniel Sullivan

WP-06-24

What Can We Learn about Financial Access from U.S. Immigrants?
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-06-25

Bank Imputed Interest Rates: Unbiased Estimates of Offered Rates?
Evren Ors and Tara Rice

WP-06-26

Welfare Implications of the Transition to High Household Debt
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-06-27

Last-In First-Out Oligopoly Dynamics
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-06-28

Oligopoly Dynamics with Barriers to Entry
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-06-29

Risk Taking and the Quality of Informal Insurance: Gambling and Remittances in Thailand
Douglas L. Miller and Anna L. Paulson

WP-07-01

Fast Micro and Slow Macro: Can Aggregation Explain the Persistence of Inflation?
Filippo Altissimo, Benoît Mojon, and Paolo Zaffaroni

WP-07-02

Assessing a Decade of Interstate Bank Branching
Christian Johnson and Tara Rice

WP-07-03

Debit Card and Cash Usage: A Cross-Country Analysis
Gene Amromin and Sujit Chakravorti

WP-07-04

The Age of Reason: Financial Decisions Over the Lifecycle
Sumit Agarwal, John C. Driscoll, Xavier Gabaix, and David Laibson

WP-07-05

Information Acquisition in Financial Markets: a Correction
Gadi Barlevy and Pietro Veronesi

WP-07-06

Monetary Policy, Output Composition and the Great Moderation
Benoît Mojon

WP-07-07

Estate Taxation, Entrepreneurship, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-07-08

6

Working Paper Series (continued)
Conflict of Interest and Certification in the U.S. IPO Market
Luca Benzoni and Carola Schenone
The Reaction of Consumer Spending and Debt to Tax Rebates –
Evidence from Consumer Credit Data
Sumit Agarwal, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles

WP-07-09

WP-07-10

Portfolio Choice over the Life-Cycle when the Stock and Labor Markets are Cointegrated
Luca Benzoni, Pierre Collin-Dufresne, and Robert S. Goldstein

WP-07-11

Nonparametric Analysis of Intergenerational Income Mobility
with Application to the United States
Debopam Bhattacharya and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-07-12

How the Credit Channel Works: Differentiating the Bank Lending Channel
and the Balance Sheet Channel
Lamont K. Black and Richard J. Rosen

WP-07-13

Labor Market Transitions and Self-Employment
Ellen R. Rissman

WP-07-14

First-Time Home Buyers and Residential Investment Volatility
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Martin Gervais

WP-07-15

Establishments Dynamics and Matching Frictions in Classical Competitive Equilibrium
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-07-16

Technology’s Edge: The Educational Benefits of Computer-Aided Instruction
Lisa Barrow, Lisa Markman, and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP-07-17

The Widow’s Offering: Inheritance, Family Structure, and the Charitable Gifts of Women
Leslie McGranahan

WP-07-18

Demand Volatility and the Lag between the Growth of Temporary
and Permanent Employment
Sainan Jin, Yukako Ono, and Qinghua Zhang

WP-07-19

A Conversation with 590 Nascent Entrepreneurs
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-07-20

Cyclical Dumping and US Antidumping Protection: 1980-2001
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-07-21

7