View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paper Series

Can the Benefits Principle Be Applied to
State-local Taxation of Business?
William H. Oakland and William A. Testa

Working Papers Series
Research Department
(WP-98-16)

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Can the Benefits Principle Be Applied to State-local Taxation
of Business?
William H. Oakland and William A. Testa

The opinions expressed in this paper are not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago and the Federal Reserve System.

Can the Benefits Principle Be Applied to State-local Taxation
of Business?1
William H. Oakland and William A. Testa

The benefits approach to taxation prescribes that taxes should fashioned so as to
mimic market prices. That is, much like user charges or user fees, a business firm=s tax
liability would accord with benefits received from the services provided by government--be
they roads, refuse disposal, law enforcement services etc.2 It has been argued by tax
analysts that the benefits principle is a much superior basis on which to fashion business
taxation, the competing principle being that tax liabilities should reflect individuals= Aability
to pay,@ much like personal income taxes which are often structured so that tax payments
are higher for those individuals with higher yearly income.3 The reasons for preferring a
benefits approach to taxing business are exactly because business firms are not individuals.
As the adage goes, Abusinesses do not pay taxes, people do,@ and, in the case of taxing
businesses on an ability to pay principle, we do not know which people are paying taxes, be
they rich or poor. The final incidence, that is, the burden after taxes are Ashifted@ forward
1

The authors thank Cuong Huynh and David Oppedahl for assistance. The authors
are Professor of Economics at Tulane University, and Economic Advisor and Vice
President, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.
2

A frequently asked question is, Awhy not directly apply user charges and fees?@ The
answer is that direct fees are not always possible because the usage is not directly and
strictly evident, or the administration of such payment may be too costly. For example,
gasoline taxes may be thought of as a benefits principle tax that corresponds to road usage
services rendered. Aside from controlled-access highways, however, it is not practical to
collect direct user fees.
3

For a recent treatment, and historical review of the literature, see William H.
Oakland, AHow Should Business Be Taxes?@ in Thomas F. Pogue, ed. State Taxation of
Business, Praeger, Westport, 1992.
2

or backward in the form of higher prices or lower input prices, has proven difficult if not
impossible to discern. For this, and other good reasons, a benefits approach to taxing
business is to be preferred.4 Such a system of implicit user fees carries along all the
advantages that we normally associate with private markets. Private market transactions
with agreed-upon prices tend to allocate resources where they are most highly valued, and
to maximize value creation more generally.
Despite the sound basis for fashioning business taxation on the basis of the benefits
principle, this practice has not been widely incorporated into state and local tax structures.
An oft-stated reason for its neglect is the criticism that it is unworkable because the service
costs and received by business entities from the state-local government sector are
impossible to measure.5 In the discussion to follow, we do create estimates of both
business taxes and of public service costs, which suggests that a benefits principle would be
practical. We estimate both the business-related expenditures and taxes of state-local
governments in U.S. states for the latest date for which comparable data are available,
1995. We believe that these measures are useful approximations, though greater accuracy
could surely be achieved if state-specific state-unique data sources were to be used in
constructing such estimates. However, our approach here has the advantage of a consistent
methodology across states. This is useful in observing what hypothetical “single business
taxes” in accordance with the benefits principle would look like in states of the U.S. We
4

Why not finance government by taxing individuals only, not business? One reason
is that businesses use government services generally, and many times it is out-of-state
businesses that use local government services. And so, business taxation may be the only
way for a state=s residents to be recompensed for services rendered.
5

See Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations, The Michigan Single
Business Tax, Washington D.C., 1978.
3

further examine whether our measures are useful in explaining interstate economic growth
differences from 1987 to 1996. In addition, we explore the extent to which states seem to
keep their business taxes and business services in alignment with those of neighboring
states. If neighboring states tend to match business taxes with expenditures to a similar
degree, this may indicate the degree to which states are already competing for growth and
development on a benefits principle basis of taxation.
The Context of the Debate: Why the Benefits Principle?
Discussion of the relation between regional growth and taxation has grown
increasingly contentious over the past 30-40 years. The reasons for this are quite evident.
First, the state-local government sector and business taxes have grown in importance.6
More importantly, state-local tax policies and tax systems have come to be crafted with an
eye toward regional growth and development. Specifically, states and localities have
adopted and customized selective tax incentives as policy tools to attract the attention of
would-be investors, even while states have increasingly sought to fine-tune their Atax
climates@ so as to be conducive to growth and investment. Most notably, as high-paying
manufacturing jobs have dispersed across regions, especially from the Northeast and

6

State-local direct expenditures as a fraction of U.S. GDP have grown from 8.8
percent in 1952 to 16.7 percent in 1995. State-local taxes have also grown rapidly,
although much of the state-local expansion has been financed by the growth of sales and
personal income taxes rather than by business-related tax sources. Oakland and. Testa
(1996) estimate that business taxes as a share of state-local tax collections have declined to
29 percent in 1992 from an estimate of 42 percent in 1957. See William H. Oakland and
William A. Testa, AState-local Taxation and the Benefits Principle,@ Economic Perspectives,
January/February 1996, pps. 2-19.
4

Midwest to the South and West, tax incentives and strategic structural changes to the tax
system have accompanied the shifts in investment geography.
The practice of fashioning tax policy toward the goals of growth and development,
especially the practice of selective tax incentives to individual firms, has been roundly
criticized by social scientists on the grounds of being costly and inefficient. With regard to
the location of industry itself, it is argued that tax-induced industrial location decisions tend
to lower national welfare by moving business investments off of their otherwise-preferred
locations. For example, such tax competition is said to distort business siting decisions,
resulting in fish processing plants located far from waterways, and to aircraft maintenance
facilities far from locations that are most suited by climate. In addition, tax competition
itself is characterized as a negative sum game with respect to financing public goods. That
is, local governments and firms themselves cannot refrain from tax competition, yet, in
doing so, revenues become insufficient to support intermediate goods (such as public
education) that are crucial to productivity, welfare, and growth. And so, corrective policies
have been proposed. At the most applied level, Burstein and Rolnick have suggested that
the federal government should circumscribe local tax policies or at least penalize those firms
that receive selective tax and public service abatements.7
Yet, the arguments of policy analysts on this issue have been far from one-sided.
Some analysts contend that sub-national tax policies may be quite helpful in Aclearing@

7

For this view and for a range of views see AThe Economic War Among the States,@
The Region, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, June 1996.
5

stubbornly underemployed local labor markets.8 And from a practical standpoint of legal
administration, restrictions and penalties on state and local customization of tax liabilities
have been dismissed as unworkable. That is because central government regulation of
state-local tax practices for development may be very difficult to implement and enforce in
our federal system. In particular, as a ready substitute for circumscribed tax incentives,
more subtle expenditure subsidies and direct customized service provision could serve the
same purpose. Another concern is that what are de facto selective abatements can be easily
written directly into general tax codes. For example, this may include a general code
provision exempting a firm of a minimum size or in a specific industry or in a specified
location from tax liability, which is tantamount to a selective abatement. All of these
regulatory impracticalities lead us to search for an organization of fiscal affairs in which
economic development practitioners can follow their competitive instincts to more fruitful
societal outcomes.
The benefits principle approach to general business taxation offers resolution of
these contentious issues. Elsewhere, we have argued that the confusion and controversy
surrounding the proper approach to state-local general business taxation arises from a
failure to consider Afirst principles@ of how business should be taxed.9 First, on the grounds
of fairness to individuals with respect to their ability to pay, the current basis for business
taxation as a way to Aget at the rich@ should be abandoned because the actual incidence of
8

For example, see Tim Bartik, Who Benefits from State and Local Economic
Development Policies?, The Upjohn Institute for Employment Research, Kalamazoo, 1991;
For a more general treatment on subnational policies, see Edward M. Gramlich,
ASubnational Fiscal Policy,@ Perspectives on Local Public Finance and Fiscal Policy, Vol.
3, pps. 3-27.
9

Ibid. Oakland/Testa, 1996, p. 6.
6

business taxes remains unknown, and is likely far less regressive than popularly imagined.
Meanwhile, in considering neutrality and efficiency, a benefits principle approach to general
business taxation is far superior. The benefits principle prescribes that services rendered by
government to business entities should be financed by a proportionate tax system. This tax
system mimics a Auser charge@ system of financing those services that the state-local sector
provides to business. In doing so, business taxes becomes locationally neutral with respect
to where businesses are most productive, rather than having location decisions whipsawed
by capricious tax incentives. And with regard to business services provided by government
under a benefits approach, decision making of the electorate will be improved. That is
because households are likely to accede to government service provision to business insofar
as business is recognized as paying its own way under such a system. This is no small
matter insofar as public services to business are often found to significantly to growth and
development.10 Finally, if it is true that tax competition is ruinous or at least the folly of
politically-motivated elected officials under the current set of tax arrangements, competition
becomes value-creating under the benefits principle. Operating under a benefits principle,
regions and their development practitioners can continue to be quite active in promotion,
but they would now do so by providing the correct level and mix of public services to
business at a fair and least-cost price. Indeed, recognition that the benefits principle is
operable will encourage a better dialogue between the business community and its
government over the level and mix of public services to be provided. Having an alternative
10

The inclusion of services produced by state and local government for business is said to
be crucial in fashioning statistical appraisals of the impacts of fiscal affairs on growth and
development. For a comprehensive review and appraisal of the relevant empirical work, see
Ronald C. Fisher, AThe Effects of State and Local Services on Economic Development,@ New
England Economic Review, March/April 1997, pp. 53-66.
7

way to compete for investment, elected officials who pursue growth and development may
choose to curtail their use of selective abatements which are so objectionable to policy
analysts.
It should also be noted that improved public decision making is not confined to the
services provided to the business sector. In making decisions about household public
services, the voting population and their representatives are now less likely to mis-read the
true costs of public services. Such is the case whereby voters mis-perceive that Abusiness@
is paying for household services such as parks, recreation, and to some degree, education,
when, in fact, business taxation is a mere conduit for hidden tax shifting back onto
households themselves. Owing to high mobility of business capital and the many markets to
which sellers have access, the opportunities for tax exporting are generally much less than
that which is touted by elected officials.
Can the Benefits Principle Be Applied?
Our approach to measuring business taxes paid and the costs of services provided to
the business sector is to combine state with local government finances in each state. In
order to make interstate comparisons, such a combining of state with local is the only valid
approach because service delivery responsibilities between state and local government differ
from state to state, and so do tax sources and intergovernmental grant flows. Combining
state and local yields a combined system of accounts. This procedure is possible because
definitions and categories of expenditures and tax revenues are consistently collected in
available data by the Governments Division of the U.S. Census Bureau.

8

The methodology for estimating business taxes and business expenditures of state
and local governments follows that of Oakland and Testa (1996), which produced estimates
for the states of the Seventh Federal Reserve District for fiscal year 1992.11 Although still
problematic, it is somewhat more straightforward to categorize taxes as Abusiness@ versus
Ahousehold@ than to categorize expenditures. We define business taxes as any general tax
on business that, in the absence of tax shifting, would reduce the business=s bottom line.
These include taxes on business inputs such as labor and capital usage, business profits and
returns to capital, purchases of inputs that are presumably passed forward in the price of
inputs, such as excise taxes on energy utility sales to the business sector, a business=s right
to do business, and business=s property and assets. Individual sales and excise taxes on the
business sector=s products are excluded as being passed forward to consumers, such as
public utility excise taxes paid by on household electricity purchases. Narrow taxes such as
hotel and severance taxes are excluded as not being general business taxes, but rather as
targeted taxes on rents and on returns to special assets belonging to the state=s taxpayers
(e.g. locational rents and mineral assets). Similarly, environmental taxes are excluded as
11

Results for fiscal year 1992 are also reported in ADesigning State-Local Fiscal Policy
for Growth and Development,@ Conference Proceedings No. 5, held on July 17, 1995, Assessing
the Midwest Economy, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 1996.
A few methodological differences are important to note from earlier reports which
produced 1992 estimates. Property taxes levied on business property were collected directly
from state and, in a few instances, county revenue authorities in each state for the 1995
estimates. In the previous (1992) estimates, Census Bureau data were used. General sales tax
estimates on business taxable purchases were produced using results from Donald Ring Jr. for
1993 (no major base changes have occurred from 1993-1995 that would bias these estimates).
Ring estimates the in-state expenditures of residents on taxable consumer purchases using the
Consumer Expenditure Survey reports by income class for 1989. Sales taxes paid by consumers
are then estimated by applying the state-specific tax code and tax rates to these expenditures for
each state; the remainder of revenues are estimated sales taxes paid on business purchases.
These estimates are found to be very consistent with those conducted in individual states, often
using different methodologies.
9

special corrective taxes rather than as general business levies.
A tally of such taxes for the overall United States in 1995 suggests that general
business taxes levied by the state and local government sector amounted to over $255
billion for fiscal year 1995, amounting to over 38 percent of state-local tax collections.12
The property tax accounts for over 30 percent of such tax revenues. Most of such revenues
are levied on real property rather than on personal property, and the tax is largely imposed
and collected by local governments rather than by state governments. Surprisingly, sales
taxes are the next largest category, at almost 26 percent. This is surprising for two reasons.
First, many citizens tend to think of general sales taxes as final stage consumer taxes when,
in fact, many business purchases of intermediate inputs, and in some cases, capital
equipment, are included in the tax base.13 Of overall general sales tax collections, we
estimate that 41.2 percent is accounted for by business purchases. Together, property and
sales taxes account for two-thirds of state-local general business taxes. The second surprise
is that the tax that we normally associate with business taxation, the state corporate income
tax, amounts to a lesser 14.3 percent share, which is about the same share as unemployment
insurance tax collections.14 Excise taxes on intermediate business purchases of gasoline,
insurance, and utility services make up the rest, along with minor license and franchise fees.
12

See Appendix I for the taxes by category for U.S. and Midwest States.

13

Sales tax bases differ markedly on both consumer and business sectors from state to
state. For an overview on differences in administration and tax base, see John F. Due and John
L. Mikesell, Sales Taxation, State and Local Structure and Administration, The Urban Institute
Press, Washington D.C., 1995.
14

Many will argue that unemployment insurance is not a tax, but rather a perquisite that
may be capitalized into wages. We have decided to include it as a tax because, to varying
degrees across states, tax liabilities are not well assigned to those firms whose employees reap
the insurance payments.
10

With regard to expenditures for services benefitting business entities, the allocation
is much more uncertain. Following our previous work, we allocate some expenditure
categories wholly to the household sector--categories such as education, health and
hospitals, and parks and recreation; and some wholly to the business sector. The wholly
business sector categories are very few--water transport terminals, and agricultural
assistance. No doubt, working with individual state budgets, a much finer allocation to
business can be achieved. However, the Census expenditure categories are aggregated to a
degree that preclude accounting of services that are wholly benefitting to business.
(Appendix II displays the estimated results and assumptions behind Abusiness expenditure
costs@ for the United States as an example.) Other expenditure categories must be parsed
out to business and household sectors. For such categories as police, fire, judicial, and
corrections, a Ashared@ category of 50/50 split is assumed between the household and
business sectors. We believe that this errs on the side of parsing much benefit to the
business sector. A third category, that of overhead functions such as public buildings,
financial administration, and public debt, is allocated based on the business/household shares
of two previous categories.
The total of each expenditure category is reduced by netting out federal grants-inaid that are specific to that expenditure area, and also reduced by user fees that defray that
same category of expenditures. We do this so as to produce measures of Atax financed
expenditures,@ which can then be aggregated and compared to overall business taxes in each
state.

11

A tally of fiscal 1995 expenditures into these expenditure categories yields a
distribution wherein services to businesses account for only 16.0 percent of public sector
tax costs, or $123.6 billion for the aggregate state-local sector in the U.S. (figure 1). This
represents a tax-financed business expenditures that is slightly less than half of the business
taxes paid in that year.

Figure 1
Distribution of state and local expenditures, 1995
U.S.

Seventh District

Business
programs
(1.1%)

Business
programs
(0.9%)
Prorated
household
(10.7%)

Prorated
business
(2.2%)

Prorated
household
(9.4%)

Prorated
business
(1.7%)
Joint
household
programs
(12.0%)

Joint
household
programs
(12.7%)
Household programs
(60.7%)

Household programs
(64.0%)

Joint business
programs
(12.7%)

Source: Staff calculations based on data provided by state fiscal agencies and
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Government Division.

12

Joint business
programs
(12.0%)

The finding that business taxes exceed tax-financed service costs is universal across
states (Table 1). However, the variation is quite large, ranging from a over a 3:1 ratio to a
ratio modestly above one. A frequent criticism of our approach is in our categorizing
education as a public service within the household sector. We believe that this is very
defensible. Firms pay their employees for their product; accordingly, subsidies to
individuals for education will accrue to those individuals. Nonetheless, given the
proliferation of educational services that are being used as incentives to business location,
and which provide arguably firm-specific rather than general training, we run a sensitivity
analysis of our assumption. The remaining columns of Table 1 show the results on the
tax/expenditure ratio of assuming, respectively, that education service costs are allocated 10
percent to the business sector, and an unrealistic 25 percent to the business sector. Despite
the prominence of education in the state-local budgets, business taxes tend to lie well above
estimated service costs, with only minor changes in the rankings among states.
Existing studies of how closely governments approximate the benefits principle in
practice are quite consistent in showing that business taxes exceed the costs of services
rendered by significant proportions. At the local government level, H. Kitchen=s
examination of municipalities in Ontario, Canada, shows that the nonresidential payments of
taxes exceed the nonresidential share of expenditures by ratios of over two.15 This result
will not surprise those who are familiar with the literature concerning the fiscal impacts of
business property on local communities in the U.S., where a general result is that property
and other local taxes paid by businesses exceed business services rendered

13

15

See Harry M. Kitchen and Enid Slack, ABusiness Property Taxation,@ Discussion Paper
Series 93-24, Government and Competitiveness School of Public Policy, Queen=s University,
1993.
14

Table 1
Business Tax/Business Expenditures, 1995
0%
Maryland
Oregon
New Mexico
Alaska
New York
Colorado
Massachusetts
Florida
Vermont
Alabama
Nevada
North Carolina
California
Virginia
Kansas
District of
Wisconsin
Wyoming
Oklahoma
Louisiana
New Jersey
Kentucky
Utah
Rhode Island
Texas
South Dakota
Montana
Maine
Idaho
New Hampshire
Missouri
Connecticut
Georgia
North Dakota
Iowa
Mississippi
Minnesota
Illinois
Washington
Arizona
Nebraska
Ohio
Pennsylvania
Arkansas
Tennessee
Delaware
West Virginia
Michigan
Hawaii
South Carolina
Indiana

1.277
1.494
1.546
1.654
1.692
1.694
1.732
1.795
1.846
1.878
1.889
1.893
1.896
1.903
1.933
1.945
1.948
1.969
1.973
1.999
2.095
2.104
2.114
2.128
2.155
2.177
2.181
2.182
2.235
2.238
2.303
2.313
2.317
2.325
2.326
2.351
2.378
2.390
2.418
2.424
2.491
2.495
2.501
2.659
2.670
2.732
2.846
2.847
2.891
2.970
3.385

Assuming education as a business expenditure
10%
Maryland
Oregon
New Mexico
New York
Colorado
Alaska
Massachusetts
Vermont
North Carolina
Oklahoma
Alabama
Wyoming
Florida
Kansas
Virginia
Wisconsin
Idaho
Utah
Missouri
California
Nevada
Montana
New Jersey
Maine
Louisiana
Texas
Kentucky
New Hampshire
Rhode Island
South Dakota
Georgia
Mississippi
District of
Connecticut
Minnesota
Nebraska
Iowa
North Dakota
Pennsylvania
Illinois
Ohio
Washington
Arizona
West Virginia
Arkansas
Tennessee
Delaware
Michigan
South Carolina
Hawaii
Indiana

15

1.007
1.167
1.273
1.355
1.374
1.377
1.413
1.423
1.430
1.431
1.474
1.483
1.491
1.509
1.511
1.542
1.549
1.562
1.573
1.584
1.593
1.629
1.632
1.648
1.662
1.666
1.666
1.675
1.689
1.741
1.744
1.774
1.777
1.801
1.825
1.844
1.851
1.878
1.880
1.910
1.912
1.946
1.956
2.002
2.007
2.049
2.101
2.128
2.139
2.253
2.367

25%
Maryland
Oregon
New Mexico
Oklahoma
New York
North Carolina
Vermont
Colorado
Alaska
Wyoming
Massachusetts
Alabama
Utah
Kansas
Virginia
Wisconsin
Montana
Florida
Maine
New Hampshire
New Jersey
Texas
Kentucky
California
Georgia
Missouri
Mississippi
Nevada
Rhode Island
Idaho
Nebraska
Louisiana
South Dakota
Connecticut
Minnesota
Pennsylvania
West Virginia
Ohio
Iowa
North Dakota
Illinois
Arkansas
South Carolina
Washington
Arizona
Tennessee
Michigan
Delaware
District of
Indiana
Hawaii

0.771
0.880
1.006
1.012
1.044
1.048
1.062
1.065
1.081
1.084
1.103
1.111
1.120
1.133
1.150
1.174
1.179
1.190
1.199
1.216
1.225
1.245
1.263
1.268
1.275
1.276
1.294
1.297
1.299
1.304
1.326
1.327
1.333
1.352
1.353
1.369
1.400
1.409
1.424
1.454
1.467
1.469
1.493
1.505
1.510
1.515
1.545
1.576
1.579
1.628
1.693

by an average ratio of three.16 Such findings are echoed at the state government level in the
U.S.; William Oakland=s 1988 study of Louisiana state government general fund spending
for fiscal year 1986 finds that business tax revenues exceeded the costs of services received
by 29 percent.17
What Would a Single Business Tax Look?
What would a general business tax system look like in contrast to the array of
individual business taxes that currently exists? Again, Abusiness activity@ generally defined
is proposed as the tax base of choice for a general business tax; it is business activity that
gives rise to government services. Among the alternative candidates for an indicator of
business activity; value added and not gross receipts is more indicative of business activity
as it avoids cascading or double counting of activity. More specifically, value added should
be computed on an origin basis because, almost universally, it is business activity within a
state rather than outside that consumes state and local government services.18 To its further

16

See Robert W. Burchell and David Listokin, The Development Impact Assessment
Handbook and Model, Urban Land Institute, Cambridge Mass, 1993.
17

See William H. Oakland, ABusiness Taxation in Louisiana: An Appraisal,@ in J.
Richardson ed., Louisiana=s Fiscal Alternatives, Louisiana State University Press, New Orleans,
1988, pps. 159-187.
18

Some analysts argue that by providing the foundations for a market, the government
provides a valuable benefit to firms who choose to sell in their jurisdiction, including those firms
who produce outside its boundaries but sell within them. While there is some validity to this
argument, the costs of government services to business arise much more from production
activities than from selling activities. Moreover, to the extent that selling activities give rise to
value added within a state, foreign based firms will become subject to the origin based value
added tax in appropriate measure.
Such value added can be measured as the difference between a firm's sales and its
purchase of materials and capital inputs (i.e. the subtraction method), or it can be measured by
adding payments to inputs--wages, profits, rents, and interest (i.e. adding up method). Because
multi-state and multi-national firms could manipulate intra-firm sales prices to reduce tax liability
16

credit, this tax base is neutral with respect to a firm's choice of input proportions, that is, its
use of capital versus labor or land in production. In contrast, most existing business taxes
fall disproportionately on capital intensive firms, e.g. consider corporate net income taxes,
sales taxes as applied to business machinery and equipment, and local property taxes.
In Table 2, column one, business tax collections in each state are expressed as a
share of gross state product, the latter being closely akin if not identical to value added.19
Here we see that, if we treat all business tax sources combined as a hypothetical single
business tax, the rates of such taxes would range from 2.7 percent to almost 7 percent.
These are the estimates at current levels of business taxation--that is, combining into one
revenue source the numerous individual taxes levied against business property, purchases,
assets, and right to do business, and assuming that the state-local government sector
collects revenue from a single business tax equal to actual collections from all business
taxes during fiscal year 1995.
In comparison to existing general business taxes, such a hypothetical single business
tax on value added would be very broad based, much like Michigan=s ASingle Business Tax@

(transfer pricing), the "adding up" approach may be the more practical. To avoid the problems
of transfer pricing, this means that capital earnings (interest and profits) of multi-jurisdictional
firms will have to be apportioned just as it is under the present state corporate income taxes;
however, the present practice of assigning disproportionate weight to the sales factor is
inconsistent with the origin approach as discussed herein.
19

The source of the value added data is the Bureau of Economic Analysis, U.S. Dept. of
Commerce. Since fiscal data runs 1994-95, the average of GSP for 1994 and 1995 is taken as
the tax base. Government sector GSP is netted out.
17

which is imposed by state government there.20 The broad basis of such a tax would also
have the salutary effect of extending to the growing service sector of the economy. In
contrast, the basis of taxation for the most prominent state level business tax,
the state corporate income tax, is narrow and it has been narrowing further. Business
income taxes usually apply only to those firms organized under the corporate legal
structure and, in addition, are often skewed in tax liability toward very large corporations.21
Increasingly, the corporate income tax base coverage is being further confined toward
those corporations that sell into the state from outside as states increasingly revise their
apportionment formula of the taxable incomes of multi-state firms toward the so-called
Asingle factor on sales.@ This formula defines the taxable base of any multi-state firm on the
basis of the firm=s sales within the geographic boundaries of a state. It therefore tends to
exempt firms that produce in the state yet sell outside its boundaries. In the Midwest, both
Iowa and now Illinois have adopted the single factor apportionment; Michigan is moving
closer to almost total weighting on sales, while the remainder of states weight sales more
heavily than the other two apportionment factors, payroll and property.

20

For a description and discussion, see Robin Barlow and Jack S. Connor Jr., AThe Single
Business Tax,@ in Harvey E. Brazer, ed., Michigan=s Fiscal and Economic Structure,
The University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor, 1982, and Advisory Commission on
Intergovernmental Relations, The Michigan Single Business Tax, Washington D.C., 1978.
21

Stemming from legal proceedings, the narrow base of New Hampshire=s Business
Profits Tax was an impetus behind that state=s adoption of a modest value added tax. See
Daphne A. Kenyon, AA New State VAT? Lessons from New Hampshire,@ National Tax
Journal, Vol XLIX, No. 3., pp. 381-399.
18

Table 2
Business Tax/Nongovernment Gross State Product Ratio, 1995
Business taxes minus business expenditures/non-government GSP
(assuming education as a business expenditure)
Ratios
Ascend
Ratios
Ascend
Ratios
education 0%
rank
education 10%
rank
education 25%

Business taxes/GSP
Ascend
rank

Ascend
rank

North Carolina
Wyoming
Maryland
Oregon
New Hampshire
Alabama
Massachusetts
Missouri
Oklahoma
Colorado
Vermont
Texas
Georgia
Virginia
Kentucky
Tennessee
Arkansas
Pennsylvania
Delaware
Utah
California
South Dakota
Connecticut
Nevada
Ohio
Indiana
South Carolina
Louisiana
D.C.
Maine
New Mexico
Illinois
Mississippi
Kansas
Idaho
Nebraska
New Jersey
Wisconsin
New York
West Virginia
Montana
Minnesota
Florida
Iowa
Rhode Island
Michigan
North Dakota
Arizona
Washington
Hawaii
Alaska

Maryland
Oregon
North Carolina
Massachusetts
Colorado
Wyoming
New Mexico
Alabama
Vermont
Oklahoma
New Hampshire
Virginia
New York
Missouri
California
Nevada
Texas
Kentucky
District of
Utah
Louisiana
Georgia
Kansas
Florida
South Dakota
Wisconsin
Maine
Connecticut
Pennsylvania
New Jersey
Tennessee
Arkansas
Idaho
Ohio
Mississippi
Illinois
Delaware
Montana
Rhode Island
Nebraska
Minnesota
South Carolina
Iowa
Alaska
North Dakota
Indiana
West Virginia
Arizona
Michigan
Washington
Hawaii

0.0274
0.0288
0.0290
0.0304
0.0305
0.0318
0.0319
0.0323
0.0328
0.0331
0.0352
0.0356
0.0359
0.0360
0.0366
0.0376
0.0379
0.0382
0.0383
0.0383
0.0393
0.0395
0.0400
0.0401
0.0402
0.0403
0.0405
0.0407
0.0411
0.0414
0.0415
0.0417
0.0420
0.0423
0.0431
0.0435
0.0439
0.0441
0.0445
0.0452
0.0462
0.0463
0.0476
0.0479
0.0480
0.0494
0.0497
0.0534
0.0580
0.0650
0.0691

0.0063
0.0101
0.0129
0.0135
0.0136
0.0142
0.0147
0.0149
0.0161
0.0162
0.0169
0.0171
0.0182
0.0183
0.0186
0.0189
0.0191
0.0192
0.0200
0.0202
0.0204
0.0204
0.0204
0.0211
0.0214
0.0214
0.0224
0.0227
0.0229
0.0230
0.0235
0.0236
0.0238
0.0241
0.0241
0.0242
0.0243
0.0250
0.0254
0.0261
0.0268
0.0269
0.0273
0.0273
0.0283
0.0284
0.0293
0.0314
0.0321
0.0340
0.0425

19

Maryland
Oregon
North Carolina
New Mexico
Colorado
Massachusetts
Wyoming
Oklahoma
Alabama
Vermont
New York
Missouri
Virginia
New Hampshire
Utah
Texas
Kansas
California
Kentucky
Nevada
Idaho
Georgia
Wisconsin
Florida
Louisiana
Maine
South Dakota
New Jersey
Connecticut
Montana
Pennsylvania
District of
Mississippi
Alaska
Arkansas
Ohio
Tennessee
Rhode Island
Illinois
Nebraska
Delaware
Minnesota
South Carolina
Iowa
West Virginia
North Dakota
Indiana
Arizona
Michigan
Washington
Hawaii

0.0002
0.0043
0.0082
0.0089
0.0090
0.0093
0.0094
0.0099
0.0102
0.0105
0.0117
0.0118
0.0122
0.0123
0.0138
0.0142
0.0143
0.0145
0.0146
0.0149
0.0153
0.0153
0.0155
0.0157
0.0162
0.0163
0.0168
0.0170
0.0178
0.0178
0.0179
0.0180
0.0183
0.0189
0.0190
0.0192
0.0192
0.0196
0.0198
0.0199
0.0201
0.0209
0.0216
0.0220
0.0226
0.0232
0.0233
0.0261
0.0262
0.0282
0.0361

Maryland
Oregon
New Mexico
Oklahoma
North Carolina
New York
Colorado
Vermont
Wyoming
Massachusetts
Alabama
Utah
Virginia
Kansas
Alaska
New Hampshire
Wisconsin
Maine
Montana
Missouri
Texas
Florida
Kentucky
Georgia
New Jersey
California
Nevada
Mississippi
South Dakota
Louisiana
Idaho
Pennsylvania
Connecticut
Nebraska
Rhode Island
Ohio
Minnesota
Arkansas
Tennessee
West Virginia
Illinois
South Carolina
Delaware
Iowa
District of
North Dakota
Indiana
Michigan
Arizona
Washington
Hawaii

-0.0086
-0.0042
0.0002
0.0004
0.0013
0.0019
0.0020
0.0021
0.0022
0.0030
0.0032
0.0041
0.0047
0.0050
0.0052
0.0054
0.0065
0.0069
0.0070
0.0070
0.0070
0.0076
0.0076
0.0077
0.0081
0.0083
0.0092
0.0095
0.0099
0.0100
0.0100
0.0103
0.0104
0.0107
0.0111
0.0117
0.0121
0.0121
0.0128
0.0129
0.0133
0.0134
0.0140
0.0143
0.0151
0.0155
0.0155
0.0175
0.0180
0.0195
0.0266

While a hypothetical single business tax on value added by origin has the desirable
characteristics of being broad based and at a low rate, the rates would be lower still if
revenue collections were lowered to levels consistent with costs of business services
currently received. As measured against a hypothetical nongovernmental GSP tax base, the
rates of taxation under this scenario fall to a U.S. average of 2.1 percent for fiscal year 1995
(Table 3), ranging in Midwest from 1.3 percent in Indiana to 2.4 percent in Wisconsin.
Again, a perspective is needed to properly interpret these existing and hypothetical
state by state differences in benefits to taxes. Varying rates are and should be chosen by
states themselves so as to reflect differing preferences by their business community for
public services, and therefore need not reflect any tax climate advantage or disadvantage.
So too, over time, business service levels and tax rates would presumably change as a
benefits-based scheme was enacted. As the relation between business tax levels and
services was made more explicit, and it came to be articulated through a more formal
discussion/negotiation mechanism, businesses would be expected to respond to a changing
tax system by modifying its requests for public services.
Using Census Data to Evaluate Business Taxes and Benefits
In the previous section, we have used data from the Governments Division of the
Census Bureau to illustrate the nature of current state-local practices with respect to overall
business taxes in comparison to business service costs. Are these data and measures
accurate enough to serve as the basis for actual dialogues between service providers (state
and local governments) and the business sector in individual states?

20

Table 3
Hypothetical Tax Rates for a Single Business Tax Levied on
the Basis of Value Added by Origin, Fiscal Year 1995

Tax Rate Assuming
Current Collections
(percent)

Tax Rate Assuming Collections
Equal to Current Service Costs
(percent)

Difference

Illinois

4.4

1.9

2.5

Indiana

4.3

1.3

3.0

Iowa

4.9

2.2

2.8

Michigan

5.2

1.9

3.3

Minnesota

4.9

2.1

2.8

Ohio

4.1

1.8

2.4

Wisconsin

4.6

2.4

2.2

Midwest

4.5

1.9

2.7

United States

4.3

2.1

2.2

21

To explore this question, we experiment with benefit/tax estimates in two ways.
First, the estimates of service costs versus taxes are used as independent variables in
ordinary least squares regression equations of interstate manufacturing growth differences.
Specifically, using our measure of benefits in relation to business taxes for individual states,
does an imbalances of taxes over expenditures have the expected dampening effects on
business investment and location? Second, we explore whether neighboring states act Aas
if@ their business taxes and benefits provided matter to growth and development. Do
neighboring states tend to adjust their business service costs and business taxes so as to
avoid getting out of line with neighboring states with whom they (presumably) compete in
attracting manufacturing investment?
Beginning with the interstate growth experiments, we estimate equations explaining
variation in interstate manufacturing growth using the two most general frameworks. In
both frameworks, business investment and location are assumed to follow regional
variations in state=s underlying cost conditions, such as wages and taxes, and in its product
demand, such as changes in federal spending for manufactured products used for national
defense. The first framework is the so-called Aequilibrium@ framework wherein it is
assumed that any point in time represents an equilibrium such that existing business activity
has fully adjusted to current cost and on demand conditions. In particular, changes in
manufacturing activity between two points in time is regressed on changes in cost and on
demand parameters. This approach has the statistical advantage of avoiding coefficient bias
that may arise from omitted (unknown and state-specific) influences on growth. The

22

second approach assumes that regions adjust to conditions with a long lag, so that we tend
to observe a region=s change in activity as a partial adjustment to past conditions.22
If we examine the results of such growth equations (Table 4), it is apparent that the
census-based benefit/tax measures reveal no apparent relation with state-by-state variation
in the growth of manufacturing, as measured by either growth in gross state product in
manufacturing or growth in manufacturing employment from 1989 to 1996.23 The

22

Tim Bartik summarizes the commonly-used “disequilibrium” functional forms as

follows:
Supposing that business activity in area i at time t, Ait , partially adjusted to its long run
optimal level, Ait* , from its previous level, Ai ,t − 1 ,
(1)

Ait

= λAit*

+ ( 1 − λ) Ait

− 1

+ µ it

where µ is a random disturbance term. Further, suppose that Ait* depends on the current
period’s level of observed variables, X it , which usually reflect cost and demand conditions.
(2)

Ait*

= β′
Xit

+ e it

where eit is a random disturbance term. Substituting into (1),
(3)

Ait

= λB ′
X it

+ ( 1 − λ) Ai , t

− 1

+ z it

where zit = λeit + µit , the disturbance term. Subtraction of Ai ,t − 1 from both sides yields the
functional form:
(4)

Ait

− Ai , t

− 1

X it
= λβ′

− λAi , t − 1 + z it

See Timothy J. Bartik, “The Effects of Property Taxes and Other Local Public Policies on the
Intrametropolitan Pattern of Business Location,” in Industry Location and Public Policy, Henry
W. Herzog, Jr., and Alan M. Schlottmann, eds., The University of Tennessee Pres? , Knoxvi[le,
ñ98? .
23

T? e ceoice`to exam? ne growt• the ma? ufacturi g is ap? ropriate<for
two? reasons.
The se? tor is l cationa ? ly footl:ose. S? condly, úuch of ? ach statu=s busi? ess tax >tructur?
is skew0d towar? s capita -intens? ve indus.ries su? h as manufacturing. In particular,
property taxes and state corporate income taxes can, if not shifted, fall on returns to capital.
23

Table 4
OLS Estimates of State Manufacturing Growth: 1989-1996

Percent
Change in
Mfg.
Employment

Dependent
Variable
Intercept

Change
Mfg.
Employment

.09
(.59)

-82.8
(1.02)

Percent
Change in
Mfg.
GSP

Change
Mfg.
GSP

.62
(1.00)

-479.2
(.07)

Mfg. (1989)

.04
(.82)

.40
(5.83)

Hourly Earnings (1989)

7.56
(.99)

10.35
(.01)

Percent Change Hourly Earnings

-.60
(1.18)

Avg. Low. Temp. (Jan.)

-.009
(4.38)

.24
(.11)
.67
(.89)

Direct Fed. Spending (1989)

-.009
(1.14)

63.7
(1.03)

-.003
(2.67)

-21
(-2.50)

Percent Change Fed. Spending

.38
(2.13)

(Business Tax Less Bus.
Benefits)/GSP

.033
(.009)

-78.2
(.06)

-13.8
(.98)

6,850.6
(.06)

Right to Work Law

.23
(5.51)

43.0
(2.35)

.23
(1.40)

1,896.3
(1.30)

48

48

48

48

.45

.40

-.02

.67

n

R

2

.40
(.60)

Note: t-statistics in parentheses.
Mean value n=48
MFGGSP89

Gross state product in manufacturing, 1989
($ millions)

21,035.4

MFGEMP89

Total employment in manufacturing, 1989
(thousands)

395.7

HERN89

Avg. Hourly earnings of payroll workers in mfg., 1989
(nominal dollars)

10.30

TEMPJANLO

Average daily low temperature in January degrees centigrade

RTW

Existence of “right to work law”(zero or one)

FEDTOT89

Direct federal spending, 1989 ($ millions)

BTEGSP0

Estimated state and local business taxes less costs of
business-related government expenditures, fiscal year 1995,
divided by nongovernment gross state product (1995)

22.1

18,364.7

.00577

PCMFGGSP

.4736

PCMFGEMP

.0517

PCWAGE

.2161

PCFED

.4983

(PC = % change in same DIVIDED BY 100)

24

independent variable is specified as the excess of business taxes over business servicerelated public expenditures in the base period. This excess of taxes over services is further
scaled by the size of each state=s gross state product. Therefore, the explanatory variable is
structured much like a net tax rate on productive activity. The resulting absence of partial
correlation between net business tax and growth holds for both the empirical Aequilibrium@
specification as well as the Adisequilibrium@ specification.
It is of passing interest to note the statistical significance of two explanatory
variables, direct federal spending and right-to-work laws. Federal spending on national
defense fell 23 percent in real terms over the sample period, selectively impacting those
states with high concentrations and cutbacks of defense-related manufacturing (Warf and
Glasmeier, 1993). Right-to-work laws are also commonly implicated in the literature as
significantly attracting manufacturing activity (Holmes 1995 and Moore and Newman
1985).
While we find little evidence that those states that have overtaxed their business
communities in relation to services rendered have experienced slower manufacturing
growth, one might further hypothesize that states act Aas if@ services matter, and that they
act to keep their business tax/business services aligned with neighbor. However, if we
regress a state=s net business tax on those of its neighbors, we again find no relationship
(results not reported).24 It may be that states do not act as if business taxes and business
service levels matter to growth and development; or it may be that the measure itself is too
aggregative to reveal such behavior.
24

The border measure is a vector of identical weights between zero and one, with the
weights being the inverse of a state=s number of neighboring states (having significant stretches
of border).
25

The upshot of these empirical explorations is open to interpretation. It may be that
business taxes in relation to services rendered are not important to regional growth and
development. If so, this runs contrary to many studies which have explored such impacts of
individual business services such as public infrastructure on regional growth. Alternatively,
the census data may be too aggregated in constructing business tax and service costs to
reveal the relationship. Further explorations of this nature may do well to focus on more
refined interstate measures, perhaps using finer accountings of business-related services
such as those that can be obtained from individual state and local financial and budgetary
documents. The Census data appear useful only in illustrating the approximate dimensions
of what an overall single business tax would look like if fashioned on the benefits principle.
Conclusions
All too often, tax structures emerge without much thoughtful planning and design.
No doubt, this occurs over many decades under the pressures of the immediate needs of
revenue urgency, administrative feasibility, and political expediency. In the case of statelocal business taxation, such evolution has given rise to much confusion with regard to
optimal tax policy. For example, current debates over the efficacy of selective tax
abatements to lure new investment appear to be nowhere near consensus, and long-standing
business taxes such as state corporate net income taxes continue to be revised and amended
without a clear conceptual underpinning of how business entities ought to be taxed. In both
these instances, the overarching goal as publicly stated appears to be the promotion of
regional growth and development. Yet, in thinking over the strongest foundation on which
to construct a system of business taxation, it is clear that the benefits principle would be a

26

substantial improvement over the current array of state-local business taxes. The benefits
principle prescribes that general business taxes should be fashioned so as to align with the
costs of services provided by the state-local government sector to business entities. This
allows a healthy competition among regions so as to provide the correct level of services to
business at maximum cost efficiency. It also allows state and local governments, with the
blessing of the local electorate, to reach out of state businesses and to charge them for
services rendered. At the same time, it does not distort the Aprices@ that the local household
sector should view and use in evaluating and articulating their own preferences for services
from state and local government. If followed, such as system of business taxation can only
promote growth and welfare.
In practical application, insofar as the government sector provides services to a very
wide array of business, business taxes themselves should be broad-based and closely
correlated with the extent of each business= activity. We have suggested that the basis of
such taxation should be something closely akin to the value added activity of each business
within a state=s boundaries. Such a system implies that all general costs of services to
business entities in Midwest states might be financed by a tax rate varying from 2-3 percent
annually of business activity.

27

References
Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations, AThe Michigan single business tax: A
different approach to state business taxation,@ Washington, DC: ACIR, 1978.
_______________, AState-local taxes with an initial impact on business,@ Regional Growth:
Interstate Tax Competition, Washington, DC, March 1981, pp. 61-77.
Bartik, T., AThe effects of property taxes and other local public policies on the intrametropolitan
pattern of business location,@ in Industry Location and Public Policy, Henry Herzog and Alan
Schlottman (eds.), Knoxville, TN: Univ. of Tennessee Press, 1991, pp. 57B80.
DeBoer, L., AShares of major Indiana taxes paid by businesses and individuals, 1991,@ Report
prepared for the Commission on State Tax and Financing Policy, 1992.
Due, John, and J. Mikesell, Sales Taxation: State and Local Structure and Administration, 2nd
ed., Washington, DC: Urban Institute Press, 1995, pp. 1B106.
Ebel, Robert D., The Michigan Business Activities Tax, Value-Added in a Subnational
Economy, East Lansing, MI: Michigan State University Business Studies, 1972.
Edison Electric Institute, Statistical Yearbook of the Electric Utility Industry 1992, Washington,
DC, 1992.
Holmes, Thomas J., “The Effects of State Policies on the Location of Industry: Evidence from
State Borders,” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Staff Working Paper No. 205, 1995.
Insurance Information Institute, 1992 Property/Casualty Insurance Facts, 1993, pp. 34B40.
Moore, William J. and Robert J. Newman, “The Effects of Right-to-Work Laws: A Review of
the Literature,” Industrial and Labor Relations Review, vol. 38, no. 4, July pp. 571-85.
Oakland, W. H., AHow should business be taxed?@ in State Taxation of Business: Issues and
Policy Options, Thomas Pogue (ed.), National Tax Association, 1992.
Ring, R., AThe proportion of consumers’and producers’goods in the general sales tax,@ National
Tax Journal, Vol. 42, No. 2, 1989, pp. 167B179.
_______________, AConsumers’share and producers’share of the general sales tax,@ Presented
to the National Tax Association Annual Conference on Taxation, St. Paul, MN, mimeo, 1993.
Studenski, Paul, AToward a Theory of Business Taxation,@ Journal of Political Economy, Vol.
68, October 1940, pp. 621B654.
28

Tax Policy League, Inc., How Shall Business Be Taxed? Proceedings from a symposium
conducted by the Tax Policy League, 1936.
Warf, Barney, and Amy Glasmeier, eds. “Theme Issue: Defense Spending and Regional
Development” Economic Geography, Vol. 69, no. 2, April, 1993.
Wheaton, W., AInterstate differences in the level of business taxation,@ National Tax Journal,
Vol. 36, No. 1, March 1983, pp. 83-94.

29

Appendix I
Business Taxes: Fiscal Year 1995
($ millions)

Total

Property

Sales

Corporate
Income

Insurance

Utility &
Business
Licenses

Unemployment
Insurance

Motor
Fuel

Illinois

13,012.8

5,782.7

1,511.6

1,630.1

60.3

705.0

2,227.3

1,095.9

Indiana

5,257.5

2,331.7

1,083.9

918.9

54.3

2.6

485.0

381.1

Iowa

2,906.4

1,394.8

518.2

312.9

48.0

12.9

298.7

321.0

Michigan

10,696.7

3,540.1

1,994.4

2,265.9

76.9

48.9

2,047.4

723.1

Minnesota

5,211.1

2,042.0

1,047.7

827.1

61.3

26.0

701.9

505.1

Ohio

9,869.7

3,937.3

1,401.6

1,455.1

100.7

434.9

1,601.5

938.6

Wisconsin

5.041.5

1,902.0

868.6

807.6

50.8

162.8

801.2

448.5

51,995.6

20,930.6

8,426.0

8,217.5

452.3

1,393.0

8,163.0

4,413.2

255,504.9

78,196.5

65,998.3

36,423.4

3,304.4

13,933.0

37,224.7

20,424.7

Midwest
United States

Source: Staff calculations based on data from the U.S. Department of Commerce. Bureau of the Census, Governments Division,
and from state revenue departments.

30

Appendix II
State-Local Tax Financed Expenditures on Households and Businesses
United States, FY 1995
(in millions of dollars)

Spending Category

Households

Prorated
Households

Higher Education
42,111
Elem./Sec. Education
240,555
Libraries
5,284.7
Welfare
77,310.4
Health & Hospital
47,864.2
Veteran Affairs
204.4
Fish & Forestry
2,696
Parks & Recreation
13,260.6
Hous./Comm. Devel.
2,734.2
Unemploy. Insurance
37,224.7
Water Transport/Terminals
Natural Resources— Agriculture
Natural Resources— N.E.C.
Air Transportation
Transportation Subsidies
Highways
Parking
Fire Protection
Police Protection
Corrections
Judicial
Protective Inspection & Regulation
Sewerage
Solid Waste
Legislative
Financial Administration
General Public Buildings
General Interest on Debt
All Other and Unallocable

1,465.6
18,575.3
5,869.8
47,285.2
9,510.8

Total

82,706.7

469,245

Shares
Households

Business

Prorated
Business

Shared
Business

386.1
3,080.8
5,115.1
-72.4
7,519.4
25,902.4
-146.3
8,504.7
20,527.3
17,928.4
9,584.1
3,618.2
1,581.4
3,176.7

-72.4
7,519.5
25,902.4
-146.3
8,504.7
20,527.3
17,928.4
9,584.1
3,618.2
1,581.4
3,176.7
300.2
3,804.6
1,202.2
9,684.9
1,948

98,123.9

Source: U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Governments Division.

31

8,582

16,939.9

98,123.9

Total

42,111
240,555
5,284.7
77,310.4
47,864.2
204.4
2,696
13,260.6
2,734.2
37,224.7
386.1
3,080.8
5,115.1
-144.8
15,039.0
51,804.8
-292.7
17,009.5
41,054.5
35,856.9
19,168.2
7,236.3
3,162.7
6,353.4
1,765.7
22,379.9
7,072.0
56,970.1
11,458.8
773,722

Appendix III: Methodology for Business Taxes and Expenditures
Taxes:
1. Unemployment insurance tax— Taxes are imposed by both the federal and state
governments on the basis of payroll of those workers covered by unemployment
insurance. We report state collections only, as reported by the Governments Division,
Bureau of the Census, U.S. Department of Commerce.
2. General sales taxes collected from businesses— The hybrid nature of the sales tax as
consumer-business tax presents formidable obstacles in distinguishing the business
sector’s share of revenues from that of consumers. State revenue departments typically
report data by type of store or vendor from which the sale take place, with no information
about the buyer. The existence and variety of exemptions and partial exemptions for
business purchases further complicates the matter, as does the varying exemption and
coverage of certain consumer items, such as food, clothing, and prescription drugs. We
apply sales tax rate to government-reported data of consumer expenditures; the residual
represents an estimate of business and tourist payments of the sales tax (Ring, 1989;
Blume, 1983). For example, Illinois consumers’share of sales tax is 71.6%. We subtract
71.6% from 100% to find the business’s share of sales tax. The difference is 28.4%. We
use the business percentage to multiply to the government-reported overall sales tax
revenue data. Estimates of the business sector’s share of state sales tax revenue
collections are applied to the Census Bureau figures of general sales tax collections at the
state-local level for fiscal year 1994-1995 to arrive at estimates of sales paid by
businesses.
3. Corporate income tax— These collections figures are reported by the Census Bureau for
fiscal year 1994-1995 and, within the Midwest states, all collections derive from state
government taxes.
4. Property tax— Beginning with a 1963 study, the U.S. Advisory Commission on
Intergovernmental Relations (ACIR) began estimating property taxes paid by commercial,
industrial, and agricultural enterprises. These estimates are based on tables of assessment
and collections valued reported at five-year intervals by the Census of Governments. We
depart from that practice and instead use property tax collections as reported by
individual state fiscal agencies for business classes of property.
5. Business licenses and fees— We follow the ACIR practice of including fees and taxes
imposed on the right to do business, at the state or local level. These data are collected
and grouped by the Governments Division of the Bureau of the Census.

32

6. Taxes on broad-based inputs to production— We exclude selective taxes such as those
levied on tobacco, alcohol, and amusement. Presumably, these are intended to be shifted
forward to consumers, or their taxation is intended to discourage the activity rather than
to act as a broad-based payment for government services rendered. Likewise, taxes on
specific industries, such as motel/hotel or severance taxes, are not broad-based business
taxes but are intended to discourage or compensate for damages imposed on the state or
local community. In contrast, we do include the following selective sales taxation of
items which are broadly purchased as intermediate inputs by the business community:
Insurance— Most states tax the premiums on insurance sold in the state. Since
businesses broadly purchase insurance, we estimate the business sector’s share of
such purchases in allocating total insurance premium tax collections. The sector’s
share is calculated for reported premiums sold by in-state companies to other
businesses in each of the respective states. Using The Fact Book 1996
Property/Casualty Insurance Facts (published by Insurance Information Institute), we
sum all the categories that deal with businesses and divide by direct written premiums
by state; thereby producing a ratio. We multiply that ratio to the governmentreported data to estimate the insurance business taxes.
Motor fuels tax— Following DeBoer (1992), we estimate motor fuel purchases by the
business sector as opposed to households in allocating revenues collected. These data
are collected and grouped by the Governments Division of the Bureau of the Census.
Public utility gross receipts tax— The business portion of revenues is allocated using
data on investor-owned public utilities. The Statistical Yearbook of the Electric
Utility Industry reports gross receipts derived by sector, household vs. commercial
and industrial sectors. These data are grouped and collected by the Governments
Division of the Bureau of the Census.

Expenditures:
Expenditures by function are reported annually by the Governments Division of the Bureau of
the Census, U.S. Department of Commerce. Total direct expenditures by function include all
payments to employees, suppliers, contractors, beneficiaries, and all other final recipients of
government payments. Intergovernmental expenditures— payments and grants to other
governments between state and local— are excluded. Such expenditures become
expenditures of those governments where the funds come to rest. Since we are interested
only in those expenditures made by state-local government, federal grant monies by function
are netted out of these same functional expenditures. Similarly, revenues derived from user
charges and fees (such as college tuition and roadway tolls) are netted out of appropriate
expenditures made by state-local government. The remainder represents those direct
33

expenditures by function that are funded by state-local own-source tax revenues. When a
negative remainder of the direct expenditures exists, it means that federal intergovernmental
grants and/or user charges are greater than the total direct expenditures.
Two categories of expenditures must be allocated. “Shared” expenditures are those for
which little information on benefits to business vs. households are available, for example,
police, fire, transit, sewerage, sanitation, and parking. For these, a liberal 50 percent is
allocated to the business sector.
Those expenditures representing general government overhead, such as all financial
administration services, all general public buildings, all other miscellaneous government,
interest on general debt, all legislative, and other-unallocable, are assigned to the business
sector on a prorated basis. The proration reflects the share of business expenditures, plus
shared business expenditures to total direct expenditures (net of prorated expenditures).
Other categories of spending are allocated directly to business or to the household sector.

34