View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Revised
March 1990

Are S o m e
M y t h




Banks Too

Large T o

Fail?

a n d Reality
George Kaufman*
That the world, or at least banking, as we know it today will end if we
permit large banks to fail is one of the great popular beliefs in banking and
a current favorite of many bank regulators. This belief may be called the
too large to fail or T L T F myth. Similar myths also exist in nonbanking,
for example, in industry with Chrysler, and in local government with New
York City. Moreover, these myths are not limited to the United States.
T L T F is frequently used by bank regulators to avoid taking actions that
could put them in conflict with powerful parties who would experience large
dollar losses, such as uninsured depositors or other creditors, management,
owners, and even large borrowers. In addition, the regulators frequently
believe that such actions would be an admission of failure not only of the
bank but also of their own agency, which is charged with bank safety and
evaluated by many on its ability to achieve this condition. In using TLTF,
the regulators play on the widespread public fears of the contagiousness of
bank failures, that is, on fears that individual bank failures may ignite a
domino or chain reaction that would tumble other “healthy” banks na­
tionwide, other financial institutions, and possibly even nonfmancial insti­
tutions and the aggregate macroeconomy.
The failure of large banks is viewed particularly likely to cause spillover
because of:
1. The large number of depositors;
2. The large number and dollar amounts of corresponding
balances from other banks:
3. The presence of foreign deposits, and
4. The important role such banks play in the payments system.
The economic justification for TLTF has been clearly stated by bank reg­
ulators. At the time of the Continental Illinois National Bank crisis in
1984, Comptroller of the Currency Todd Conover testified that if:

*John Smith Professor of Finance and Economics at Loyola University ofChicago and Con­
sultant, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. For presentation at the annual meeting of the
Eastern Finance Association, Charlestown, South Carolina, April 6, 1990. An earlierversion
ofthispaper was presented at“Behind theS&L Debacle: The Breakdown ofFederal Deposit
Insurance”,sponsored by the National Taxpayers Union Foundation and the Competitive
Enterprise Institute,Washington, D.C., April 19, 1989.

1




Continental had failed and been treated in a way in which depos­
itors and creditors were not made whole, we could very well have
seen a national, if not an international, financial crisis the dimen­
sions of which were difficult to imagine. None of us wanted to
find out. 1
In 1986, Irvine Sprague, who was a director of the FDIC at the time of the
Continental Illinois rescue, wrote in his book Bailout:
The problem was there was no way to project how many other
institutions would fail or how weakened the nation’s entire bank­
ing system might become. . .Various scenarios were laid out, and
they all signaled doomsday.2
More recently, FDIC Chairman William Seidman state that:
The bottom line [re TLTF]. . . is that nobody really knows what
might happen if a major bank were allowed to default, and the
opportunity to find out is not one likely to be appealing to those
in authority or to the public.3
These statements suggest that the regulators did not know what would
happen if a large bank fails and/or defaults; that they have done little, if
anything, since the Continental crisis in 1984 to find out; and that they have
acted in a way that reduced primarily their own risk exposure and that of
their agency.
Because it may be too severe a standard to expect bank regulators to have
a better understanding of the economics of the banking system than others,
one might have been able to excuse this attitude in 1984, when nearly ev­
eryone, including most academics, subscribed to the “Chicken Little
theory” of bank failures. But research since then has clearly shown that
although theoretically possible, nationwide contagion is highly unlikely,
particularly in today’s environment with credible federal deposit insurance
and a Federal Reserve that is wiser than the 1930’s. Because the federal
government guarantees the par value of deposits, deposits insurance dis­
courages smaller depositors from starting a flight from bank deposits to
currency. Even if deposit insurance does not discourage such a flight, the
Fed can intervene to offset the resulting decline in aggregate bank reserves
and money supply. Because it is impractical to conduct their financial op­
erations with currency, larger depositors do not flee from bank deposits to
currency but search for safe banks.
But despite this evidence, the regulatory agencies’ policies towards T L T F
have changed only moderately since 1984. It is almost as if they do not
want to hear the recently developed “good” news. In the meantime, the

?

cost of their policies of permitting economically insolvent large institutions
to continue in operation are now plainly evident:
1. Private market discipline is weakened and greater risk taking by
other banks is encouraged, when they learn that the penalties for
failure are not so severe. This has been a major contributor to
the large dollar size of the current FSLIC crisis.
2.

Smaller banks are discriminated against and put at a competitive
disadvantage.

Bank Runs




Underlying most economic T LTF arguments is the fear of bank runs. Runs
are viewed as the germs that spread contagion. Bank runs have two effects:
one, on the individual banks experiencing the run themselves; and two, a
potential effect on other banks and beyond. In a world with less than 100
percent deposit insurance, runs develop when a large number of depositors
believe, rightly or wrongly, that their bank is economically insolvent and
cannot repay all noninsured deposits in full and on time. These depositors
subscribe to the reasonable hypothesis that is better to be safe than sorry.
For an individual bank, a run causes liquidity problems from hurried
“fire-sale” losses. But theory and evidence both show that if the bank was
solvent at the time the run started— the depositors were wrong— the run will
not bring the bank down. That is, the liquidity problem will not expand
into a solvency problem. Solvent banks experience little difficulty in ob­
taining sufficient liquidity through liquid asset sales or borrowing from
other banks to meet deposit outflows.4 If the bank was economically insol­
vent to begin with— the depositors were right— the run will intensify the
liquidity problem, and fire-sale losses are likely to be larger. However, the
run was not the initial cause of the bank’s problems. If the bank had been
appropriately reorganized and recapitalized on a timely basis when it first
became insolvent, depositors would know they would not suffer losses, and
the run would have been unlikely. This conclusion is not new; it was
reached in a study for the American Bankers Association in 1929 and was
recently reconfirmed by a survey by Anna Schwartz for the American En­
terprise Institute.5
The implications of a run on an individual bank for other banks depend
on what the running depositors do. They have three options:1
1. If the depositors perceive other banks in their market areas to be
safe, they will shift their funds to those banks. This represents a
direct deposit. (This would include deposit transfers to overseas

3




banks. In such shifts, the foreign bank becomes the owner of the
deposit at the domestic bank.)
2.

If the running depositors do not perceive other safe banks in their
market areas, they are likely to purchase safe nonbank securities,
such as Treasury securities. This represents a flight to quality. N o w
the question becomes, what do the sellers of the securities do with
the proceeds? It is likely that the sellers perceive some safe banks
in their market areas, because otherwise they would have been
unlikely to sell the securities. This scenario represents an indirect
redeposit.

3.

If neither the running depositors nor the sellers of the Treasury
securities perceive any bank in the country to be safe they will not
redeposit the funds in other banks. Rather, they will hold currency
outside the banks. This represents a flight to currency.

In both of the first two scenarios, there is little serious economic damage.
Reserves and deposits are not lost to the banking system as a whole, but
merely redistributed within the system. There is no decline in the money
supply, nor are there universal liquidity problems. The liquidity strains of
those banks losing deposits are offset by the liquidity surpluses of those
banks gaining deposits. Some depositor and borrower dislocation may oc­
cur and uncertainty will increase. In addition, in the case of a flight to
foreign currencies and banks overseas, a restructuring of exchange rates,
will occur and, in the case of a flight to quality, a restructuring of relative
interest rates will occur as prices on safe Treasury securities are bid up rel­
ative to those on risky bank deposits. The last two scenarios may adversely
affect the terms of trade, dampen private investment activity, and cause
abrupt changes in relative asset and goods prices. But, as there is no col­
lapse of the money supply, nationwide bank insolvencies or a significant
downturn in national business activity, which are the primary underlying
fears from a bank run and the primary justification for special protection
for large banks, will not occur. Runs on banks may spill-over on banks
that the public views as being beset by the same problems, such as regional
contagion, e.g., Texas in recent years. But this contagion is no different
than that which occurs when any visible business firm fails or with any
important frightening event, such as an act of terrorism or a “Tylenol”
scare.
The third type of bank run lies behind the public fear of bank runs and has
the most far-reaching effect. Because currency can only reach the public
from the banks, the currency outflow will reduce bank reserves in the ag­
gregate and thus also the money supply. Under fractional reserve banking,
a loss of reserves ignites a multiple contraction process that affects healthy
as well as insolvent banks. The attempts of all banks simultaneously to
meet their deposit outflows increases the amount of securities for sale,

4




fire-sale losses, and the likelihood of the banks’ liquidity problems ex­
panding into solvency problems. The feared spill-over effect becomes a
reality. The run on an individual bank is transformed into a run on the
banking system as a whole and may topple nonfinancial firms and the
macroeconomy as well. It is this scenario that makes bank failures uniquely
different from the failure of other business firms.
But U.S. history shows that a flight to currency is rare.6 Bank failures and
bank runs have not been very closely correlated. Although bank failure
have been relatively frequent throughout much of pre-1929 U.S. history,
runs on individual banks were not. Indeed, runs on individual banks were
negligible even during the prolonged period of frequent bank failures in the
1920s, when bank failures averaged more than 600 annually. Moreover, the
Comptroller of the Currency attributed few of the failures of national banks
in this period to runs.7 In part, the lack of runs in this period may be at­
tributed both to the relatively small size of the failed banks and to the
maintenance of reserves and money supply by the Federal Reserve .
Almost all bank runs have led to either direct or indirect redeposits. Before
the establishment of the Federal Reserve in 1913, private markets operated
reasonably successfully to reduce the probability of a type-one or type-two
bank run from developing into a type-three run. However, the cost was
not zero. At times, the process involved temporary suspensions of
convertibility and the issuance of “private” money in the form of clearing­
house certificates.9 But this cost was substantially lower than that of a
type-three run or, in retrospect lower than the policies used by the regula­
tory agencies today to prevent such a situation. (The SLA crises in Ohio
and Maryland in the early 1980s were the worst of all scenarios. There was
no private market at work and no credible government insurance) . 10
Only in 1893 and 1929-33, were flights to currency and nationwide
contagion likely to have occurred. But even in these periods it is not clear
that the bank runs were the cause of the concurrent depressions, rather than
vice-versa. Indeed, recent evidence suggests that the runs were as likely to
have been symptoms of the problems in the macroeconomy as originators
of these problems. 11 For example, Canada experienced approximately the
same percent declines in aggregate economic activity between 1929 and
1933 as did the United States-GNP declined by about 40 percent, prices
by some 25 percent, and M l by some 30 percent. But there was no banking
crisis in Canada. There were no runs either on individual banks or on the
banking system. The currency to money ratio increased only moderately,
compared to the U.S., where it more then doubled. Thus, in Canada, bank
runs could not have been a contributor to the macroeconomic difficulties.
The recent experience of savings and loan associations in Texas also points
to the high unlikelihood of national contagion and of spill-over beyond

5




institutions perceived to be in the same boat. Texas SLAs, as well as the
industry as a whole, have experienced an outflow of deposits from mid-1988
through mid-1989. In large measure, the outflows reflected the sharp rise
in short-term interest rates, including those offered by money market funds.
Most SLAs did not match these rates on their deposits and voluntarily
permitted the consequent disintermediation.
But economically such
disintermediation does not represent a run.
At the same time, increasing publicity about FSLIC’s increasing problem
and the increasing insolvency of Texas SLAs increased uncertainty among
some depositors and some undoubtedly withdrew their deposits. But these
funds were redeposited at perceived solvent SLAs in other states, money
market funds, or FDIC insured commercial banks. They represented
type-one runs— direct redeposits. There has been no evidence whatsoever
that these depositors held their withdrawals in currency. Because of the
paucity of information about the financial condition of financial insti­
tutions and the natural tendency in times of uncertainty to avoid contact
with activities that may be similarly tainted (e.g., all airlines are effected
by a major skyjacking and all bottles of over-the-counter drugs are suspect
after a container poisoning scare), depositors may have avoided redeposit­
ing at healthy SLAs in Texas. More recently, the problems at large com­
mercial banks in Texas, e.g., First Republic and MCorp, have resulted in
flights to large banks elsewhere. This behavior represented a flight to
safety, but not a flight to currency. Although not good for healthy SLAs
and banks in the “contaminated” area, such a flight does not topple healthy
banks in other areas or destabilize the financial system as a whole.
Yet, in this instance, regulators have failed to distinguish both between
disintermediation and runs and between contagious and noncontagious
runs. Instead, they have publicized the Texas outflows as contagious runs,
at least partially, to build public support for the administration’s SLA res­
cue proposal. For example, Chairman Seidman has argued that
While depositor discipline may theoretically be desirable, placing
depositors at greater risk has not proven to be useful in practice.
The problem is that depositor discipline sometimes works too
well— taking the form of bank runs, which pose a threat to the
stability of the financial system. 12
Besides reflecting an implicit reversal from an earlier FDIC position that
market discipline was relatively ineffective, Seidman provides no evidence
that runs resulting from private market discipline pose any threat to finan­
cial stability.
Indeed, it is not private market discipline that appears to cause the worst
runs, but federal deposit insurance. No bank or association has lost suffi-

6

cient deposits in recent years to shrink from, say, $ 2 billion to $ 2 0 million
in a few months. But a number of SLAs have grown by this magnitude in
a not much longer time span. Federal deposit insurance has caused more
frequent and greater runs to bad banks, which offered higher deposit rates,
than private market discipline has caused runs from bad banks. 13
Moreover, even before federal deposit insurance, banking in the United
States was not as unstable as frequently described. Between the end of the
Civil War and the end of World War I, the annual bank failure rate was
lower than the failure rate among nonbank firms, although the variance
was greater. In addition, losses to depositors at failed banks were averaged
less than 0.2 percent of total bank deposits, annually. Moreover, even
losses to depositors at failed banks averaged less than losses suffered by
bond holders in defaults of nonfmancial firms. 14 Bank runs did not gener­
ally lead to bank failures and bank failures did not generally lead to bank
runs. Banks tended to fail when the economy they served weakened. In
this regard they are no different from grocery stores, automobile dealer­
ships, movie theaters, or any other business firms.

Resolving Large Bank Failures




Primarily because few large banks appeared threatened with failure before
the Continental Illinois National Bank crisis in 1984 the regulators gave
considerably more thought to procedures for resolving small- and
medium-size bank failures than large bank failures. The United States
National Bank of San Diego and the Franklin National Bank in the
mid-1970s were the only large bank exceptions and neither were money
center banks. From 1984 through the Continental crisis in mid-1983, the
FDIC experimented with imposing pro-rata losses, or “haircuts”, on
uninsured depositors at insolvent banks. This was done both through
modified payoffs, in which the insured deposits and the non-haircut portion
of the uninsured deposits are assumed by an acquiring bank in a purchase
and assumption (P&A) transaction, and through liquidation, such as in the
case of the Penn Square (Oklahoma) bank. But the FDIC backed away
from these policies in the Continental crisis because of fear and uncertainty
from at least three sources:
1.

Large bank size.
a. Large potential dollar losses.
b. Long resolution time.

2.

Large number and dollar volume of interbank balances with po­
tential large losses to a large number of banks. Over 2,000 banks
had correspondent balances and/or Fed funds loans with the Con­
tinental and 20 0 of these had balances that were greater than one-

7




half of their net worth.
3.

Substantial foreign deposits.

But none of these were legitimate fears.
1. Large bank size
a. The Continental Bank was not totaled. Depositor losses were
estimated at the time to be about 2 or 4 cents on the dollar.
Indeed, then-FDIC Chairman William Isaacs even denied that
the bank was insolvent. Currently, losses are estimated to be
near 5 cents per dollar.
b. The FDIC had authority to use longer resolution time under
conservatorship and deposit insurance national bank pro­
visions.
2.

Even if the losses had been as high as 10 percent, twice the largest
estimate, no correspondent bank would have suffered losses
greater than its capital and only two would have suffered losses
greater than 50 percent of their capital. 15

3.

Similar to deposit transfers by domestic depositors, transfers by
foreign depositors even to overseas banks do not change either
total reserves or deposits in the U.S. banking system. Unless
the withdrawals are in currency, which is highly unlikely for
large deposits the reserves are shifted among domestic banks,
although foreign banks may now own some of the deposits at
these banks. If the funds are transferred to overseas banks in
local currencies, exchange rates are likely to be affected.

In other words, the bank regulatory agencies did not thoroughly think
through the consequences of all available options.
In practice, T L T F is not the issue anymore. The FDIC has modified its
large bank nonliquidation failure resolution policies three times since the
Continental rescue to progressively increase the number of creditors whose
funds are risk. 16
1 . In 1984, the FDIC followed three policies with respect to the

Continental:
a. T L T F L — too large to fail legally, although the bank is econom­
ically insolvent,
b. TLTIL U B C - too large to impose losses on uninsured depos­
itors and other creditors of failed banks; and
c. T L T I L B H O C - too large to impose losses on creditors of in-

8




solvent bank holding companies.
In sum, this amounted to a policy of too large to fail legally and
impose losses on all uninsured creditors, or T L T F L I L A U C
2.

In 1986, the FDIC permitted the First Oklahoma Corporation to
default on its debt when its subsidiary First National Bank of
Oklahoma City became insolvent. However, it neither permitted
the bank to fail legally nor imposed losses on uninsured depositors
and creditors of the bank. A similar policy was followed in 1987
for the First City National Bank of Houston and First City Cor­
poration. The remaining policy may be described as too large to
fail legally and impose losses on all uninsured bank creditors or
TLTFLILAUBC.

3.

In 1988, the FDIC both declared the First Republic National Bank
of Dallas to have failed legally as well as being economically in­
solvent and imposed losses on creditors of its parent holding
company, First Republic Corporation. The remaining policy was
too large to impose losses on all uninsured bank creditors, or
TLTILAUBC.

4.

In 1989, the FDIC imposed pro-rata losses on fed funds sales and
the uninsured portion of interbank deposits of solvent MCorp
subsidiary banks at other insolvent MCorp (Texas) subsidiary
banks. Indeed, these losses drove some of the former banks into
insolvency. Because similar losses were not imposed on other
uninsured creditors at these banks, the FDIC’s action is being
challenged in the courts. Special authority for the FDIC to impose
such haircuts on interbank deposits of affiliated banks was explic­
itly authorized in the recent Financial Institutions Reform, Re­
covery, and Enforcement Act (FIRREA) of 1989.

Thus, only a policy of too large to impose losses on most uninsured bank
creditors, or T L T I L M U B C remains Importantly, no spill-over or other
adverse effects occurred when the other three safeguards were removed one
at a time, despite predications of such consequences.
Resolution procedures for large-bank failures do differ from small-bank
failures, but primarily because their large size makes them more complex
and lengthens the time required to develop optimal solutions. In the
Competitive Equality Banking Act of 1987, Congress specifically provided
the FDIC with more time in which to resolve large bank failures by au­
thorizing the establishment of FDIC operated “bridge” banks for up to two
years, later extended to three years by the Financial Institutions Reform,
Recovery, and Enforcement Act (FIRREA) of 1989. The FDIC can apply
its market-tested modified payoff technology. The FDIC encountered no
significant problems with it at smaller banks, and should not encounter any

9




such problems at larger banks. At the close of business on the day the
FDIC assumes control of the bank, it estimates the economic loss or nega­
tive net worth and pro-rates it among insured and noninsured deposits. 17
A loss estimate has already been made by necessity when the FDIC decided
to take control of the bank. The FDIC assumes the loss on insured deposits
and chamges the loss on uninsured deposits to the appropriate depositors.
This haircut is deducted from the uninsured deposits. Overnight (or, more
frequently, over a weekend), the bank is sold, merged, or rechartered as a
bridge bank. At the opening of business the next day, insured depositors
have full use of all their deposits and uninsured depositors have full use of
the non-haircut portion of their deposits. There is no interruption in busi­
ness.
Immediate estimates of the negative net worth of a bank and, therefore, of
the loss allocated to uninsured depositors, are likely to differ from the ac­
tual loss, which can only be determined much later. What if the FDIC’s
preliminary estimates are incorrect? In both its modified payoff and liqui­
dation resolutions, the FDIC pays out additional funds through time to
reimburse the uninsured depositors if its original estimate of loss was
greater than the later determined actual loss and absorbs all additional
losses if its original estimate turns out to have been to optimistic. The
FDIC’s recent treatment of the MCorp and later of Texas American
(Dallas) intersubsidiary bank deposits appears to have followed this proce­
dure
To minimize possible disruption from a sudden change in ground rules, this
process could be phased in over time, say, a maximum haircut of 1 percent
in the first year of operation, 3 percent the second year, 5 percent the third
year, and no limit the fourth and following years. Such a policy was floated
in the mid-1980s by some officials of the American Bankers Association,
which represents those who may be expected to have the most to lose. 18
More recently, this proposal was revived by some bankers. Interestingly
enough, when first proposed, it was rejected most strongly by the bank
regulators. More recently, the American Bankers Association has published
a reform program that argues that:
The single most important goal of deposit insurance reform should
be to require investors on uninsured deposits to share in the risk
of failure of the institutions to which they commit their funds. 19
The report rejects 100 percent deposit protection as unacceptable and re­
commends that marked discipline be enhanced. When a bank's equity
capital falls to zero, the bank should be declared insolvent, uninsured
depositors and creditors be assessed a loss equal to the average loss the
FDIC has experienced in recent years, and the bank be re-opened the next
business day as part of another bank or as a bridge bank.20 Abandonment

10




of T L T F was also recently recommended by the members of the New York
Clearing House Association, who are among the country's very largest
banks.21 This suggests that TLTF is as much a political as an economic is­
sue.
Resolution of large bank failures by modified payoff technology will sig­
nificantly increase private market discipline by uninsured depositors and
creditors. Contrary to the belief of Seidman and many other bank regula­
tors, such discipline works well and in a stabilizing fashion by encouraging
banks to increase their capital and reduce the risk exposure of their port­
folios.22 It did so before the FDIC and should operate even more efficiently
now, because information about individual banks is quicker and cheaper
to obtain than earlier. The threat of a run is a powerful force in inducing
banks to err on the side of conservatism. Seidman appears to confuse the
ex-ante incentives of banks under market-discipline and no-marketdiscipline scenarios.23
Under the first scenario, bankers will already have acted to reduce the
probability of a run on their banks by maintaining higher capital-to-asset
ratios and incurring less risk exposure in their asset-liability portfolio mix.
As discussed earlier, in this setting, runs are unlikely to topple banks. U n ­
der the second scenario, bankers will be less prepared as they have less at
stake. In the absence of federal deposit insurance, runs are more likely to
occur and bankers will be less able to prevent a bank failure when they do
occur. This point has been recognized as far back as Walter Bagehot, more
then 100 years ago.24 Any change in regimes that may increase the likeli­
hood of runs in the short-run needs to be phased-in slowly to give bankers
sufficient time both to revise their operating strategies and to achieve their
new equilibrium positions.
Of course, the threat of runs on and failures of all banks can be reduced
further by adopting a program for more timely and mandatory regulatory
intervention and recapitalization before a bank’s economic net worth turns
negative. This has been proposed by the author and George Benston, the
Shadow Financial Regulatory Committee, and, in measure, recently
adopted by the Federal Home Loan Bank Board.25
In sum, a cost-benefit analysis of “too large to fail,” even in its current less
extreme form of “too large to impose losses on most uninsured bank cred­
itors,” clearly indicates that the cost of perpetuating the myth that this
policy is necessary to preserve the world as we know it today is too great.
This truth was recently recognized by none less than William Issac, who as
Chairman of the FDIC during the Continental Illinois Bank crisis led the
forces in favor of making everyone whole and defended his actions vigor­
ously for many years. Recently, however, he recanted and admitted that:

77




With the benefit of five-years’hindsight, I am beginning to believe
that Carter [Golembe] may be right [in arguing against my action].
Many (though not all) of the larger banks about which I was con­
cerned have failed anyway and have almost certainly lost the FDIC
more money than if they had failed earlier. And there can be no
doubt that the thrift industry ran up far greater losses over the
ensuing five years than would have been the case had we been
forced to deal with the problems in 198426
Unless accompanied by a major breakdown in Federal Reserve policy,
bank failures, even of large banks, do not lead to bank runs on noncontaminated banks and bank runs do not lead to the failure of economically
solvent banks. Public policy makers should start tomorrow to remove the
last vestiges of T L T F and impose pro-rata haircuts on uninsured depositors
and creditors at even the largest economically insolvent bank, just as policy
makers now do at all insolvent bank holding companies, regardless of size.
Too large to fail should be left to college basketball coaches and college
presidents to fight over!

72

Footnotes




1C. Todd Conover, Testimony in the U.S. Congress, Subcommittee on Financial
Institutions Supervision, Regulation, and Insurance, Committee on Banking, Fi­
nance and Urban Affairs, I n q u i r y i n t o C o n t i n e n t a l I l l i n o i s C o r p o r a t i o n a n d C o n t i ­
n e n ta l Illin o is N a tio n a l B a n k :
H e a r i n g s , 98th Cong., 2nd Sess., September 18-19
and October 4, 1984, pp. 287-88.
2 Irvine H. Sprague, B a i l o u t , New York: Basic Books, 1986, p. 155.
3 L. William Seidman, “Remarks Before Garn Institute Deposit Insurance
Forum,” Washington, D.C.: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, November
14, 1988, p. 9. Basically the same statement was made in Seidman’s remarks,
“‘Too Big’— Revisited,” before The Annual Southeastern Banking Law Confer­
ence, February 16, 1990.

4 George G. Kaufman, “The Truth About Bank Runs” in C. England and T.
Huerras, eds., T h e F i n a n c i a l S e r v i c e s R e v o l u t i o n : P o l i c y D i r e c t i o n s f o r t h e F u t u r e ,
Boston: Kluwer, 1988, pp. 9-40; George G. Kaufman, “Bank Runs: Causes,
Benefits and Costs,” C a t o J o u r n a l , Winter 1988, pp. 559-587; and George J.
Benston et al., P e r s p e c t i v e s o n S a f e a n d S o u n d B a n k i n g , Cambridge, MA: MIT
Press, 1986.

5 George G. Kaufman, “Banking Risk in Historical Perspective,” P r o c e e d i n g s

o f

Chicago: Federal Reserve Bank
of Chicago, 1986, pp. 231-49; and Anna J. Schwartz, “Financial Stability and the
Federal Safety Net” in W. Haraf and R. Kushmeider, eds., R e s t r u c t u r i n g B a n k i n g
a n d F i n a n c i a l S e r v i c e s i n A m e r i c a , Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise In­
stitute, 1988, pp. 34-62.
a

C o n fe re n ce on

B a n k S t r u c t u r e a n d C o m p e titio n ,

6 The history of bank failures is analyzed in Benston et al. Chapter 2.
7 Anna J. Schwartz, pp. 34, 55-56.
8 Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz, A M o n e t a r y H i s t o r y o f
S ta te s, 1 8 6 7 -1 9 6 0

th e

U n ite d

(Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1971), pp. 353-357.

9 Gary Gorton, “Clearinghouses and the Origin of Central Banking in the United
States,” J o u r n a l o f E c o n o m i c H i s t o r y \ June 1985, pp. 227-83; and Richard H.
Timberlake, Jr., “The Central Banking Rule of Clearinghouse Association,”
J o u r n a l o f M o n e y , C r e d i t a n d B a n k i n g , February 1984, pp. 1-15.

10 Edward J. Kane, T h e S & L I n s u r a n c e M e s s : H o w D i d I t H a p p e n ? Washington,
D.C.: Urban Institute, 1989; and Edward J. Kane, “How Incentive-Incompatible
Deposit Insurance Funds Fail,” Prochnow Report No. PR-014, Madison,
Wisconsin: The Prochnow Educational Foundation, 1988.
11 Gary Gorton, “Banking Panics and Business Cycles,” O x f o r d E c o n o m i c P a p e r s ,
December 1988, pp. 751-81; and Phillip Cagan. D e t e r m i n a n t s a n d E f f e c t s o f
C h a n g e s i n t h e S t o c k o f M o n e y , 1875-1960: New York: Columbia University
Press, 1965.
12 L. William Seidman, “Deposit Insurance For the Nineties-Remarks Before The
National Press Club,” Washington, D.C.: Federal Deposit Insurance Corpo­
ration, November 30, 1988, p. 9. See also the account of the FDIC’s takeover
of the Broadview Savings Bank (Ohio) in Kathleen Day, “Under New Manage-

13




ment - The Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation,”
W e e k l y E d i t i o n , May 1-7, 1989, pp. 20-21.

W a s h in g to n

P o st

N a tio n a l

13See, for example, Paul Duke, Jr., “How Texas S&L Grew Into A Lending Giant
and Lost $1.4 billion,” W a l l S t r e e t J o u r n a l ,April 27, 1989, pp. A I, A 10.
14 George G. Kaufman, “Banking Risk in Historical Perspective”.
15

C o n tin e n ta l

Illin o is

N a tio n a l B a n k

F a ilu r e

and

its

P o te n tia l Im p a c t

on

C o rre ­

Staff Report to Subcommittee on Financial Institutions, Super­
vision, Regulation, and Insurance, Committee on Banking, Finance, and Urban
Affairs, October 6, 1984, pp. 16-18; and George G. Kaufman, “Implications of
Large Bank Problems and Insolvencies for the Banking System and Economic
Policy,” S t a f f M e m o r a n d a , 85-3; Chicago, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
March 1985.

sp o n d en t

B a n k s,

16 Few large insolvent banks, similar to any other large insolvent firm, are liqui­
dated and depositors paid off. The FDIC will resort to such a policy only ifit is
unable to quantify the bank’s assets and the contingencies are sufficiently
undeterminable to make a sale too costly. Since 1934, the FDIC has liquidated
only two reasonably large banks, the Penn Square Bank (Oklahoma) in 1982 and
the Guradian Bank (New York) in 1989. Both banks had under $0.5 billion in
deposits. Tax considerations played a part in the FDIC’s decisions in some cases.
17 A description of the modified payoff procedure appears in Federal Deposit In­
surance Corporation, D e p o s i t I n s u r a n c e i n a C h a n g i n g E n v i r o n m e n t , Washington,
D.C.: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, 1983, pp. III-4-6; and Jonathan
R. Macey and Geoffrey P. Miller, “Bank Failures, Risk Monitoring, and the
Market for Bank Control,” C o l u m b i a L a w R e v i e w , October 1988, pp. 1153-1226.
18 P.Michael Laub, “Benefits of a Deposit Insurance System with Modified
Payoffs,” Washington, D.C.: American Bankers Association, February 28, 1986
(unpublished).
19 American Bankers Association, F e d e r a l
fo rm ,

D e p o s it In s u r a n c e :

A

P ro g ra m f o r

R e ­

Washington, D.C., March 1990, p. 7.

20 American Bankers Association, pp. 15-17.
21 Jed Horowitz, “Banks in New York Clearing House Vote to Oppose Too Big
to Fail' Credo”,A m

e ric a n

B a n k e r,

January 26, 1990, pp. 1,13.

22 George J. Benston, et al., and George G. Kaufman, “Banking Risk in Histor­
ical Perspective”.

23 George G. Kaufman, “Bank Runs: Causes, Benefits and Costs.”
24 Thomas M. Humphrey, “Lender of Last Resort: The Concept in History,”
E c o n o m ic

R e v ie w ,

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, March/April 1989, pp.

8-16.

25 Federal Home Loan Bank Board, “Required Capital Levels for Insured Insti­
tutions: Regulatory Intervention,” (Advance Notice of Proposed Rulemaking.)
No. 88-1565, December 30, 1988. In April 1989, the Federal Home Loan Bank
Board assumed control of three associations that were solvent by Regulatory
Accounting Principles (RAP) but not by Generally Accepted Accounting Princi­
ples (GAAP)— Gibraltar Savings of Beverly Hills, CA; Gibraltar Savings of
Bellevue, Wash; and Lincoln Savings and Loan, Irvine, CA. See also George S.

74




Benston and George G. Kaufman,

R is e

and

S o lv e n c y

R e g u la tio n

o f D e p o s ito ry

New York: Salomon Brothers
Center for the Study of Financial Institutions, New York University, 1988; and
Shadow Financial Regulatory Committee, “An Outline of a Program for Deposit
Insurance and Regulatory Reform,” P o l i c y S t a t e m e n t N o . 4 1 , February 13, 1989.

In s titu tio n s :

P a st

P o lic ie s

and

C u rren t

O p tio n s ,

26 William M. Isaac, “Deposit Insurance Reform: Banking’s Top Priority,”

The

(Washington, D.C.: C H G Consulting), June 1989, p. 5. Re­
cently, itappeared that Seidman had also had a change of mind. The W a l l S t r e e t
J o u r n a l quoted him during the demise of Drexel Burnham as saying:
G o le m b e

R e p o rts

If the market floats through all this, then we have greater stability than
we had hoped... If this goes through, they may say the too-big-to-fail
doctrine is gone for everyone. It could have that kind of influence.
(Allan Murray and Kevin G. Salwen, “Fed SEC Officials Decided Hands-Off
Policy Was Best”, W a l l S t r e e t J o u r n a l ,February 14, 1990, p. A6.) But he denied
making this remark the next day in an interview with the A m e r i c a n B a n k e r .
(Robert M. Garsson, “Regulators Not Likely To Treat A Big Bank Failure Same
Way,” A m e r i c a n B a n k e r ,February 15, 1990, pp. 1, 7.)

75

References




American Bankers Association,
R e f o r m : e ita l,
B e n sto n ,

G eo rg e

J .,

D e p o s ito ry
S a lo m o n

Fe d era l

D e p o s it

W a s h in g to n , D .C ., M a r c h
and

G e o rg e

In s titu tio n s :

B ro th e rs

G .

K a u fm a n .

P a st

P o lic ie s

C e n te r f o r

th e

R is e
and

S tu d y

In s u ra n c e :

A

P ro g ra m

fo r

1990.
and

S o lv e n c y

C u rren t

R e g u la tio n

O p tio n s .

N ew

o f F in a n c ia l In s titu tio n s ,

o f

Y o rk :

N ew

Y o rk

U n iv e rs ity , 1 9 8 8 .
B e n sto n ,

G e o rg e

M A :
C agan ,

M

J .,

IT

et

P ress,

P h illip .

C .

P e rs p e c tiv e s

Todd.

F in a n c ia l

Y o rk :

and

S a fe

T e s tim o n y .

U rb a n

E ffe cts

C o lu m b ia

In s titu tio n s ,

F in a n c e , a n d

on

and

Sou n d

B a n k in g ,

C a m b rid g e ,

1986.

D e te rm in a n ts

1 8 7 5 -1 9 6 0 . N e w
C o n o v er,

a l.

In

o f

th e

U n ite d

S u p e rv is io n ,

and

N a tio n a l

in

B a n k:

S ta te s

th e

S to ck

o f

M on ey,

1965.

C o n g ress

In s u ra n c e ,

A f f a ir s , In q u iry In to

C o n tin e n ta l Illin o is

Changes

U n iv e rs ity P r e s s ,

S u b c o m m itte e

C o m m itte e

on

on

B a n k in g ,

C o n tin e n ta l Illin o is C o r p o r a tio n

H e a rin g s ,

9 8 th

C o n g .,

2nd

S e s s .,

and
Sep ­

te m b e r 1 8 -1 9 a n d O c to b e r 4 , 1 9 8 4 .
D a y , K a th le e n .

“ U nder N ew

C o r p o r a tio n .”
D u ke,

P a u l Jr.
L o st

Fe d era l

“ H ow

1 .4 B ,”

D e p o s it

Fe d era l

H om e

Lo a n

F rie d m a n , M ilt o n

B a n k

M .

G o rto n ,

G a ry .

“ R e q u ire d

Jed ,

F a il'
H u m p h rey ,
n o m ic
Is a a c ,

P a n ic s

Thom as

and

and

K a n e,

in

N ew

A m e ric a n
M .

Ed w a rd
P ro ch n o w

M .

J.

“ D e p o s it

To

B u s in e s s

L e v e ls

T rea t A

G ia n t

and

C h a n g in g

E n v i­

F o r

In s u re d

N o tic e

o f

In s ti­

P ro p o se d

U n ite d S ta te s ,

B ig

B a n k

1971.
F a ilu r e

Sam e

1, 7.

C y c le s ,”

th e

O r ig in

O x fo rd

E c o n o m ic

Y o rk

C le a rin g

o f La st

o f C e n tra l B a n k in g

(Ju n e

P a p ers

th e

U n ite d

to

The

O p p o se

'T o o

B ig

to

1 ,1 3 .

C on cept

in

H is t o r y ,”

E c o ­

B a n k o f R ic h m o n d , M a r c h ) A p r il 1 9 8 9 .

In s u r a n c e

P R - 0 1 4 ..

V o te

26, 1990, pp.

R e so rt:

in

1 9 8 5 ), p p . 2 2 7 -8 3 .

H o u se

R e fo rm :
C H G

In c e n tiv e - In c o m p a tib le

N o.

a

U n iv e rs ity P r e s s ,

15, 1990, pp .

W a s h in g to n , D . C . :

“ H ow

R e p o rt

in

M o n e ta r y H is t o r y o f th e

B a n k e r, Ja n u a ry

“ Len d er

R e p o rts.

A

H is to ry

R e v ie w , F e d e r a l R e s e rv e

W illia m

L e a d in g

7 5 1 -8 1 .

“ C le a rin g h o u s e s

“ B a n ks

C a p ita l

(A d v a n ce d

N o t L ik e ly

B a n k er, Fe b ru a ry

1 9 8 8 ), p p .

C red o ”

G o le m b e

a

In s u ra n c e

J e r s e y : P rin c e to n

S t a t e s ,” J o u r n a l o f E c o n o m ic
H o ro w itz

In to

W a s h in g to n , D . C . , D e c e m b e r 3 0 , 1 9 8 8 .

“ R e g u la tio n s

“ B a n k in g

D e p o s it

In t e r v e n t io n ,”

N o . 8 8 -1 6 5 .

W a y ,” A m e r ic a n
G a ry .

B o a rd .

P rin c e to n , N e w

(D e ce m b e r

G rew

1 -7 , 1 9 8 9 .

1983.

a n d A n n a J . S ch w a rtz.

1 8 6 7 -1 9 6 0 .
R o b ert

Lo a n s

C o rp o ra tio n .

R e g u la to ry

R u le m a k in g )

G o rto n ,

S a v in g s a n d

W a s h in g to n , D .C .,

tu tio n s :

G a rsso n ,

T exas

P o s t N a t io n a l W e e k ly E d it io n . M a y

W a ll S t r e e t J o u r n a l, A p r il 2 7 , 1 9 8 9 .
In s u ra n c e

ro n m e n t.

M a n a g e m e n t — T h e F e d e ra l R e s e rv e D e p o s it In s u ra n c e

W a s h in g to n

M a d is o n ,

B a n k in g s

Top

P r io r it y ,”

C o n s u ltin g , J u n e
D e p o s it

W is c o n s in :

In s u ra n c e
The

The

1989.
Fu n d s

P ro ch n o w

F a il,”
E d u ca ­

tio n a l F o u n d a tio n , 1 9 8 8 .

76




K a n e, Ed w a rd J.
D .C .:
K a u fm a n ,

The

U rb a n

G e o rg e

S a v in g s a n d L o a n

M e ss:

H ow

D id It H a p p e n ?

G .

“ B a n k in g

R is k

in

H is t o r ic a l P e r s p e c t iv e ,"

C o n fe r e n c e o n B a n k in g S t r u c t u r e a n d C o m p e titio n .
B a n k

o f C h ic a g o , 1 9 8 6 , p p . 2 3 1 -4 9

F in a n c ia l S e rv ic e s
K a u fm a n ,

G eo rg e

(W in te r
K a u fm a n ,

G .

(V o l. I ) ,

“ B a n k

a n d in

G e o rg e

C a u ses,

o f a

K a u f m a n , e d ., R e s e a r c h

G re e n w ic h , C o n n e c tic u t :

R u n s:

P ro c e e d in g s

C h ic a g o : F e d e r a l R e se rv e

B e n e fits ,

in

J A I P ress, 1989.

and

C o s t s ,"

C a to

Jo u rn a l

1 9 8 8 ), p p . 5 5 9 -5 8 7 .

G eo rg e

G .

“ Im p lic a tio n s

th e B a n k in g S y s te m
F e d e ra l R e serv e
K a u fm a n , G e o rg e
e d s .,

W a s h in g to n ,

I n s t i t u t e , 1 9 8 9 .s

The

G .

o f La rg e

B ank

P ro b le m s

and

In s o lv e n c ie s f o r

a n d E c o n o m i c P o l i c y ." S t a f f M e m o r a n d a , 8 5 - 3 ; C h i c a g o ,

B a n k o f C h ic a g o , M a r c h
“ The

T ru th

F in a n c ia l

1985.

A b o u t B a n k R u n s ,"

S e rv ic e s

R e s o lu tio n :

in C . E n g l a n d a n d T H u e r r a s ,

P o lic y

D ire c tio n s f o r

th e

F u tu re .

B o s to n : K lu w e r, 1 9 8 8 .
La u b ,

P .

M ic h a e l.

P a y o f f s ."
Fe b ru a ry

pp.

th e

R . an d

G e o ffre y P .

M a rk e t fo r

a n d K e v in

W a s B e s t ,"

an d

a

D e p o s it

In s u r a n c e

D .C .:

S y ste m

A m e ric a n

W ith

M o d ifie d

B a n k ers

A s s o c ia tio n ,

B a n k

M ille r .

C o n t r o l,"

“ B a n k in g F a ilu r e s , R i s k

M o n ito rin g ,

C o lu m b ia

La w

R e v ie w

(O cto b e r

1 9 8 8 ),

1 1 5 3 -1 2 2 6 .

M u r r a y , A la n

S ch w a rtz,

o f

W a s h in g to n

28, 1986.

M a c e y , Jo n a th a n
and

“ B e n e fits

P ro ce sse d .

A nna
R .

tio n a l

J

“ F in a n c ia l S ta b ility

K u s h m e id e r,

A m e ric a ,
S e id m a n , L .

G . S a lw e n , “ F e d , S E C

O ffic ia ls D e c id e d H a n d s - O f f P o lic y

W a ll S t r e e t J o u r n a l, F e b r u a r y

e d s .,

and

th e

R e s tru c tu rin g

W a s h in g to n , D . C . :

A m e ric a n

C lu b ,"

W a s h in g to n ,

F e d e ra l S a fe ty
B a n k in g

and

E n te rp ris e

W illia m . “ D e p o s it In s u r a n c e f o r
P ress

14, 19 90 , p . A 6 .
N e t ,"

in

F in a n c ia l

In s titu te ,

W .

Fe d era l

D e p o s it

in

1988.

th e N in e t ie s - R e m a r k s B e f o r e

D .C .:

H a ra f

S e rv ic e s

th e N a ­

In s u ra n c e

C o rp o ­

ra tio n , N o v e m b e r 3 0 , 1 9 8 8 .
S e id m a n ,

L .

W illia m .

W a s h in g to n ,

“ R e m a rk s B e fo re

D .C .:

Fe d era l

G am

D e p o s it

In s titu te

D e p o s it In s u ra n c e

In s u ra n c e

C o rp o ra tio n ,

F o r u m ,”

N ovem ber

14,

1988.
S e id m a n ,

L .

e a ste rn

W illia m ,

“ <T o o - B i g >— R e v i s i t e d , "

B a n k in g

La w

e r a l D e p o s it In s u ra n c e
S e id m a n ,

L .

U rb a n

W illia m ,
A ffa irs ,

“ T e s tim o n y

F in a n c ia l R e g u la to ry

In s u ra n c e

and

B efo re

U n ite d S ta te s H o u s e

R e fo r m ,"

C o m m it te e

on

“ An

A n n u a l S o u th ­

B a n k in g ,

o f R e p re s e n ta tiv e s " ;

P o lic y

th e

W a s h in g to n , D . C . :

F e d ­

16, 1990.

C o rp o ra tio n , F e b ru a ry

C o m m it t e e .

R e g u la to ry

th e

B e fo re

G e o rg ia ;

C o rp o ra tio n , F e b ru a ry

F e d e r a l D e p o s it In s u ra n c e
Shadow

R e m a rk s

C o n fe r e n c e , A tla n ta ,

O u t lin e

F in a n c e

W a s h in g to n ,

and

D .C .:

21, 1990.
o f a

S ta te m e n t

P ro g ra m
N o.

41,

fo r

D e p o s it

Fe b ru a ry

13,

1989.
S p r a g u e , Ir v in e
T im b e r la k e ,

H .

R ic h rd

B a ilo u t. N e w
H .

Jr.

“ The

Y o rk .

B a s ic

C e n tra l

B o o k s,

B a n k in g

1986.

R u le

a t io n ,” J o u r n a l o f M o n e y , C r e d it, a n d B a n k in g ,

o f

C le a rin g h o u s e

(F e b ru a ry

1 9 8 4 ), p p .

A s s o c i­
1 -1 5 .

17




U .S .

C o n g ress.
and

S u b c o m m itte e

In s u ra n c e ,

n e n ta l

Illin o is

on

C o m m it te e
N a tio n a l

sp o n d en t B a n k s.

F in a n c ia l In s titu tio n s ,

on

B an k

B a n k in g , F in a n c e ,
F a ilu r e

S ta ff R e p o r t , 9 8 th

and

Its

S u p e rv is io n ,

and

U rb a n

P o te n tia l

R e g u la tio n ,

A ffa irs .

Im p a c t

O n

C o n ti­
C o rre ­

C o n g ., 2 n d S e s s . O c t o b e r 6 , 1 9 8 4 .

18