View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

S M -8 7 -7
c
E
E

o
u
"D
C

.2
>

B A N K S T O C K V A L U A T IO N :
D O E S M A T U R IT Y G A P M A TTE R ?

Vefa Tarhan

73
>

r
—
70

m
<
/>
m

70
<

m
00
>

Z
*

n
z
n
>
n

0

Bank Stock Valuation:

Does Maturity Gap Matter?

Vefa Tarhan
Loyola University of Chicago

I have benefited from the comments of Herb Baer, Bulent Gultekln, John
Howell, George Kanatas, George Kaufman, Donald Ke1m, Nick Lash, Mike Smlrlock,
Paul Splndt, Paul Schultz, Steven Strongln and Timothy Thompson. The Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago provided support for this research. Don Wilson and
Linda Hunter provided excellent research assistance.




Bank Stock Valuation:
Does Maturity Gap Matter?

ABSTRACT
The relationship between unexpected interest rate movements and bank stock
returns is analyzed in the context of the nominal contracting hypothesis.
Unanticipated changes in interest rates should influence individual bank
profits and stock returns depending on the maturity characteristics of their
assets relative to their liabilities.

This hypothesis is investigated by

constructing portfolios on the basis of the nominal contracting positions of
banks.

The main conclusion of this paper is that the wealth redistribution

implications of the nominal contracting hypothesis is found to be unimportant
in the determination of bank stock returns.




1

The purpose of this study is to investigate the relationship between the
unanticipated movements in interest rates and bank stock prices.

As is

explained below the relationship in question can be considered a test of the
nominal contracting hypothesis for the banking industry.
The unexpected movements in interest rates are measured in two ways.

In

the first approach, money supply announcement induced interest rate movements
are examined.

During the last five years there has been an accumulation of

evidence pointing out that money announcement surprises cause unanticipated
movements in interest rates. 1

By and large, there seems to be a consensus in

the literature that there is no relation between the expected component of the
money figure announced and interest rates.

The response to the unanticipated

component, on the other hand, seems to be both prompt (thereby supporting the
efficient market hypothesis), and positive (e.g. when money is larger than
expected interest rates rise) . 2

Thus, examining, the response of bank stock

prices to money supply announcements may reveal the sensitivity of bank share
prices to unexpected interest rate changes.

Alternatively, the unanticipated

interest rate movements are captured by the residuals of an interest rate
forecasting equation.
This paper is organized as follows:

Section I presents the formulation of

the nominal contracting hypothesis for commercial banks.
the data used in this study.

Section II discusses

Model specifications as well as the empirical

results are covered in Section III.

Finally, Section IV summarizes the

conclusions of the paper.

I.

THE NOMINAL CONTRACTING HYPOTHESIS AND THE COMMERCIAL BANKS
The nominal contracting hypothesis (NCH) has been discussed in relation to

the wealth redistribution implications of unexpected inflation.




The

2

hypothesis states that a contract which requires a fixed dollar payment to be
made at a specified time will involve wealth redistribution amongest the
contracting parties in the event of unexpected inflation.

Alchian and Kessel

(1959), Bach and Ando (1957), Bach and Stephenson (1974) and Hong (1977),
analyze the differences in the stock returns of net debtor and net creditor
firms when operating under inflationary conditions.

However, these studies do

not differentiate between expected and unexpected inflation.

Under conditions

of market efficiency, only the unexpected component of inflation should
involve wealth redistribution amongst the contracting parties.

Recently two

studies rectified this situation by examining the nominal contracting
hypothesis in the context of unexpected inflation (French, Ruback, and Schwert
1983) and Bernard (1986).
In the case of financial intermediaries, the mechanism that triggers
wealth redistribution amongst the contracting parties is unexpected interest
rate movements.

The firms examined in this study are commercial banks.

Commercial banks are good candidates for an empirical investigation of the
issue at hand since most of their assets and liabilities are nominal in
nature.

Reasonably detailed data on individual bank balance sheet items is

available, which enables the construction of a measure that describes a bank's
nominal contracting position.

In its function as a financial intermediary, a

commercial bank enters into contractual agreements both with its depositors
and with the parties that borrow funds from the bank.
priced in terms of interest rates.

These contracts are

Therefore unexpected movements in interest

rates can potentially involve wealth redistribution between the bank and its
depositors and borrowers.

The movements in the unexpected component of

interest rates may be the result of revised expectations regarding inflation
or be caused by unexpected changes in the real rate of interest.




In terms of

3

the wealth redistribution issue, which of these two factors is the underlying
cause of a given unexpected change in the nominal interest rate is
unimportant.

Thus, while traditionally the nominal contracting hypothesis has

been tested in the context of unexpected inflation, when the firms involved
are financial intermediaries, unanticipated interest rate movements become the
appropriate focus.
Since the relation between money supply announcement surprises and
unanticipated changes in interest rates is well documented, one way to test
the NCH would be to examine how bank share prices respond to money supply
announcements.

The primary advantage of this approach is that it enables

testing the NCH in the context of an event study.

The event in question

(money announcements) has attracted substantial attention from the financial
markets.

Furthermore, the exact timing of the event as well as the market's

expectations regarding the figure to be announced is known.

The expectations

regarding the money figure to be announced is documented by the market
participants' response to a survey conducted prior to the announcement.
However, one possible problem associated with testing the NCH in the context
of money supply announcement induced interest rate changes needs to be pointed
out:

money supply announcement surprises are only one of the factors that

influence unexpected changes in interest rates.
introduces the possibility of measurement errors.

Thus, use of this proxy
To guard against potential

measurement errors, unanticipated interest rate movements are also measured
directly (as residuals for a daily interest rate forecasting equation), and
bank share price response to the residuals are examined.

It appears that the

results of this study are unaffected by the two different methods of measuring
unanticipated interest rates.




4

The high and volatile Interest rates that prevailed 1n the recent past
have fueled Interest 1 n the maturity structure of the assets and liabilities
of commercial banks.

One measure which has been developed to capture the

maturity profile of a bank's protfollo 1s called the maturity gap . 3

Ideally,

an Interest rate exposure measure should reflect the relative duration of
assets and liabilities.

However, the lack of sufficiently detailed data

(especially for liabilities), requires the use of a relative maturity
measure.

The gap measure 1n question 1s simply the dollar value of the

difference between short term assets and liabilities (where short term 1 s
typically defined as maturities less than a year).

To the extent that there

1 s a positive correlation between the maturity and duration structure of a

bank's assets and liabilities, the maturity gap measure will capture the
Interest rate exposure of one bank relative to another.

Thus, under these

conditions, ranking banks based on their maturity gaps should be similar to a
ranking obtained on the basis of the relative duration of their assets and
liabilities.
A bank with a positive gap has a protfollo where the dollar value of Its
short term assets exceed the dollar value of Its short term liabilities.
This, of course, means that at the long term end of the maturity spectrum, the
value of Its liabilities 1 s greater than Its assets, a bank with a negative
gap obviously has a maturity structure which Is the mirror Image of a bank
with a positive gap.
The activities of a bank can be thought of as a series of nominal
contracts between the bank and Its borrowers on the one hand, and the bank and
Its suppliers of funds on the other hand.

Two Important terms 1n these

contracts are price (Interest rate) and maturity.

However, as far as the

effect of unexpected changes In Interest rates on bank profitability, a more




5

Important characteristic than maturity is the frequency with which the assets
and liabilities are repriced.

A three year, fixed interest loan is a

substantially different asset than a three year loan, where the interest rate
is calculated daily in relation to the commercial paper rate.

Whether or not

there will be a wealth distribution between the bank and its customers (both
lenders of funds and borrowers of funds) in response to unexpected changes in
interest rates will be determined, to a great extent, by the repricing
frequency of the assets relative to the repricing frequency of the sources of
funds that the bank uses.

For example, if the interest rate on both the loan

and source of funds for the loan are tied to the commercial paper rate on a
daily basis, the bank will earn a spread on the loan, but will not experience
any wealth redistribution with either party (borrower and lender) when there
is an unexpected change in interest rates. 4

When the repricing terms of a

bank's assets and liabilities differ, unanticipated interest rate changes will
have wealth redistribution implications between the bank, the agents that
provide funds to the bank, and, those who borrow these funds.
Gap management techniques refer to the use of a bank's gap position as a
control variable in responding to anticipated interest rate movements.

In

this regard, a bank that expects interest rates to rise will attempt to
shorten the maturity (repricing period) of its assets and lengthen the
repricing period of its liabilities.

This way, when the expected interest

rate change is realized, the bank will be able to reprice its assets at the
higher interest rate, while enjoying a lower cost on its source of funds.
Thus, a bank with a positive gap should benefit when interest rates rise,
while a bank with negative gap (short term assets less than short term
liabilities) will experience a decline in profits.
Even though the impact of interest rate changes on the profitability of
both positive and negative gap banks is theoretically clear, the effect of



6

Interest rate changes on the share prices of banks with positive gaps 1 s
ambiguous.

This arises because of the fact that Interest rate changes affect

all share prices via the capitalization rate Investors use 1 n calculating the
present value associated with the expected dividend streams.

An unexpected

Increase 1 n Interest rates should cause the share prices of banks with
negative gaps to decline both because 1 t means a reduced level of expected
dividends, and also due to the fact that the stockholders will be discounting
the expected dividends at a higher discount rate.

For banks with positive

gaps on the other hand, higher Interest rates mean higher expected profits and
dividends, but since the expected dividend stream will be discounted at a
higher rate, the net effect on share prices can be determined only
empirically. 5
The banks 1n this study are classified according to a ranking procedure
based on the size (and not sign) of their gap positions.

The nominal

contracting hypothesis Implies that the smaller 1 s the size of a bank's gap
the more unfavorable will be the response of Its stock price to unanticipated
Interest rate Increases. 6
By way of preview, the tests conducted 1n this paper appear to support the
conclusion of French, Ruback and Schwert, 1n that, 1n the case of banks, the
nominal contracting effects are found to be unimportant.
contrary to the one reached by Flannery and James (1984).

This conclusion 1s
Their result

appears to Indicate that the gap position of a bank 1 s correlated with the
sensitivity of Its stock returns to unanticipated Interest rates.
approach taken 1n their study 1s a two stage procedure.

The

In the first stage, a

two factor market model 1 s estimated for Individual banks (the two factors are
the weekly returns on the NYSE composite Index and various measures of holding
period returns on an Index of constant maturity bonds).




In the second stage,

7

a cross-section regression Is estimated where the coefficient on the Interest
rate factor obtained from the market model 1 s the dependent variable and the
gap position of a bank 1s the Independent variable.

One Implication of a two

factor model 1 s that Interest rate exposure 1 s a nondlverslf1 able type of risk
which commands a premium.

In contrast, the approach taken 1n this paper does

not hinge on the Issue of whether or not Interest rate Is systematic or
unsystematic.

Instead, the methodology used 1n this study 1s agnostic with

respect to how Interest rate risk 1s priced.

The approach of this paper 1s

somewhat like an events study, 1 n that, portfolios are formed on the basis of
the degree of the maturity mismatch position of bank balance sheets, and the
response of these portfolios to unexpected Interest rate changes 1 s compared.
Ex-post, unanticipated Interest rates should cause a response 1n stock returns
regardless of whether the risk 1 n question 1 s considered to be systematic or
unsystematic.

In fact,the evidence presented 1n this paper shows that bank

stock returns are affected by unanticipated changes 1 n Interest rates 1 n a
statistically significant manner.

What 1s not supported by the results of

this paper 1 s the contention that the bank stock reaction to unanticipated
Interest rates 1 s related to the gap positions of banks.

II.

THE DATA AND THE MODELS
A.

The Data

The sample period for this study covers the period from February 2, 1979
to October 23, 1982.

The Information that banks provide 1n their quarterly

call reports 1s utilized to construct the gap positions.
was provided by the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.
banks In this study 1s 46.

The total number of

The asset and liability Items that enter the

calculation of the gap measure 1s exhibited In Table 1."*




The call report data

In examining the

8

relationship between Interest rates and bank stock prices, it is assumed that
the maturity structure of a bank's assets and liabilities does not change
significantly during a 13 week period.

Furthermore, it is also assumed that

the information revealed in the quarterly call report is representative of a
bank's gap position for the 13 weeks centered around the seventh week of a
particular quarter.

The average market value of a banks equity is used to

scale the gap position. 8

In other words, the gap measure used in short term

assets minus short-term liabilities as a percent of the market value of a
bank's equity. 9
Table 2 depicts the mean, minimum, and maximum gap position of individual
banks for the sample period.

It is interesting to note that based on the mean

values there are more banks with negative gaps than positive gaps.

In fact,

there are 9 banks in the sample for which the maximum gap position is negative
(while there is only one bank whose minimum is positive).

Gap profiles of

individual banks over time (which are not reported here) reveal differences in
management styles.

While there are some banks which almost always have

negative gap positions and others with consistently positive gaps, there are
others which seem to change their gap positions from quarter to quarter. 18
The daily stock price and dividends, as well as daily interest rate data
used in this study, were provided by the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.

The

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago obtained the stock price and dividends data
from Chase Econometrics.

The money supply data used in this study consist of

weekly announcements to the changes in money supply, and the market's
expectations regarding this figure.

The announcements data were obtained from

the H6 release of the Federal Reserve System.
forms on Fridays at 4:10 PM EST.

The Fed releases the weekly

The money supply figure that the Fed

releases refers to the Ml definition of money prior to February 8 , 1980, and,




9

the M1B definition thereafter.

Thus, 1t 1s assumed that the changes 1n Ml and

M1B affect bank stock returns 1n a similar manner.

Furthermore, starting on

February 8 , 1980, the money supply announcement day has been changed from
Thursdays to Fridays (starting on February 16, 1984, the Fed switched Its
announcement day back to Thursdays).
times Irregular due to holidays.
1s not exactly one week.

Additionally, the announcements are at

Therefore, at times the observation Interval

To measure the response to money supply

announcements, bank stock returns are calculated for the business day
following the money supply announcements. 11
Weekly data on the market's expectations regarding the change 1n money
supply were provided by the Money Market Services of San Francisco. 12

Money

Market Services has been surveying group market participants on this Issue
since September 27, 1977.

Only the median forecast 1s released, and this 1s

used as the expected money supply variable.

III.

SPECIFICATION OF THE MODELS AND THE EMPIRICAL FINDINGS
Every quarter, the banks 1n this study are ranked according to the size of

their gap positions.

On the basis of these rankings, three equally weighted

portfolios are formed.

The first portfolio Includes the 15 banks with the

largest gaps, the second portfolio 1s comprised of the 15 banks that ranked
16-30, and the third portfolio consists of 16 banks ranked 31-46.

The ranking

process 1 s repeated every quarter and the portfolios 1 n question are revised.
The reaction of these portfolios to money supply announcements 1s
Investigated first.
Issue.

Three different tests are performed to analyze this

In the first test, the portfolio returns on the days following the

money supply announcements are compared to see whether or not the response 1 s
related to the gap positions.




The second test compares the returns of the

10

portfolios using a seemingly unrelated regression technique.

In the third

test, the relation between the reaction of bank stocks and gap positions of
banks 1 s Investigated by a non parametric approach.^
All of these tests are then repeated for the case where the residuals
obtained from an ARIMA model of dally Interest rates perform as the proxy
variable for unanticipated Interest rates.
1) Honey Supply Announcements
The relation Investigated 1n

this section can be specified as:

RPit - a 01 + a n (Mt - Mt) + a2l Mt + a 31 RETSP500t + UU

O)

Where RP^t measures the one day portfolio returns (the day after the money
A
E
announcement) Mt represents the announced change 1 n money and Mt 1 s the
market's expectation regarding the change 1n money.
unanticipated money.

Thus, Mt - m | measures

RETSP500t 1 s the one day return (the day after the money

announcement) of the S and P 500 Index.

This variable 1s Included 1n order to

control for the market movements.
The test for the nominal contracting effects amounts to the comparison of
the

coefficients for the three portfolios.

Furthermore, a statistically

Insignificant estimate for the a2^ coefficients will be consistent with the
efficient market hypothesis.

Market efficiency, 1n this case, Implies that

the expected component of the money supply should already be accounted for 1 n
the stock returns.
negative.

The sign of the a-j^ coefficients could be positive or

While, the expected sign of a ^ 1s amblglous for banks with

positive gaps, the expected relative magnitude of this coefficient for the
three portfolios 1s clear.
A

A

If the NCH 1s to hold 1t should be the case that

A

all > <*12 > a13* where portfolio 1 refers to those banks with the largest gap,




n

while portfolio 3 consists of those with the smallest gap (in fact negative
for the sample period used in this study).

In other words, since a positive

money surprise (the money announced exceeds expectations), results in an
upward (unexpected) movement in interest rates, those banks with primarily
long term liabilities (portfolio 3) should suffer the most.

Banks in

portfolio 1 (these banks have relatively more short term assets and long term
liabilities) should experience the least drop in their stock prices if the
nominal contracting effects are important.
The results from estimating (1) are presented in Table 4.

As can be seen

from the table, the a 2 i coefficients are statistically not different than zero
in all the portfolios, supporting the efficient market hypothesis.

The a-|^,

coefficients are negative and statistically significant in all the three
portfolios.

However, the relative magnitude of the estimated coefficients

does not seem to support the nominal contracting hypothesis.

The table

presents the F statistic on the 3 pairwise comparisons of the a-^,
coefficients.

The null hypothesis that the pairwise coefficients are the same

cannot be rejected in any of the cases.

It appears that when money supply

exceeds expectations all bank stocks suffer equally regardless of the maturity
structure of their assets relative to their liabilities. 13

The < 3 ^
*

coefficients are positive and highly significant in all the portfolios.

As

expected, the portfolio returns appear to be highly correlated with market
movements.
An alternative method to test the nominal contracting hypothesis can be
constructed by first examining (1 ).
The crucial relationship in (1) is the comovement of portfolio returns and
unanticipated money.




The relationship is captured by a ^ .

In the context of

12

the nominal contracting hypothesis,

1 s related to the relative size of a

bank's assets and liabilities which are sensitive to Interest rates,
Thus,
al1

- T01

+ TH

GAP1 t

substituting (2 ) 1 n (1 ) results 1 n
RPit = “ 01 + Y01 (Mt - Mt) *

T\1

(HA - M*) GAPit +

T21 Mt + T31 RETSP500t + Uit

(3)

Equation (3) can be estimated as a system of equations using a seemingly
unrelated regression technique, which takes Into account the correlation of
the error terms across the equations.

The results from estimating (3) for the

three portfolios are presented 1n Table 5 . 14
Testing the nominal contracting hypothesis Involves comparison of the
estimates of a-j^ for the three portfolios.

The average response of the three

portfolios to unexpected money can be obtained by
_
<*11

___
= Y01

+ Y1 1

(4)

GAPi

where the bar above the GAP variable Indicates average values and the
coefficients 1n question are obtained from the estimation of (3).
coefficients are calculated and exhibited 1n Table 5.

These

It appears that the

response of the three portfolios to money surprises 1 s again negative and
statistically significant.

Based on the F-stat1st1cs, the null hypothesis

that each coefficient 1n question 1s equal to zero 1s rejected.
before, the prediction of the NCH 1s not fulfilled.

However, as

The F-stat1st1cs on the

pairwise comparison of the coefficients are small, making 1 t Impossible to
reject the null hypothesis that the coefficients 1 n question are not different
from one another.




13

Finally, a more direct method of testing for the nominal contracting
hypothesis Involves estimating (1) for each Individual bank separately.

The

hypothesis can then be tested by Investigating whether or not there 1 s a
systematic relation between the estimated a-^ coefficients for each Individual
bank (where a-j^ measure the reaction of the Individual banks' stock returns to
unanticipated money), and the average GAP position of each Individual bank
over the sample period (GAP1).
estimated

*\
-\

The Spearman rank correlation between the

and GAP1 shows whether or not the two series are related.

A

positive correlation coefficient would support the nominal contracting
hypothesis, since 1 t Indicates that the larger the gap position, the larger 1 s
the response of the stock returns to the unexpected component of the money
supply announcement.

The Spearman rank correlation was found to be negative

(-0.03) and statistically Insignificant (the tall area of the test 1s 0.84).
Thus, on the basis of this test also, 1t does not appear that the market takes
Into account the gap positions of Individual banks when 1 t revises Its
valuation of bank stocks 1 n response to money supply announcement surprises.
It 1s also Interesting to note that the 46 banks for which

1s

estimated, 39 have a negative sign for this coefficient (19 of these are
statistically significant at the 5 percent level).

Thus, 1n the case of only

7 banks does unanticipated money produce a positive response (none of these
coefficients are significant).
11) Residuals From and ARIMA Forecasting Procedure and Bank Stock Returns
As mentioned previously, money supply announcement Induced Interest rates
poses the possibility of a problem with measurement errors.

To guard against

this possibility, all three tests discussed above are repeated for the case




u

where the unanticipated daily interest rates are measured as the residuals
from an ARIMA equation.

ARIMA models were fitted on daily 3 month T-bill

rates, 6 months T-bill rates and 1 year T-bill rates.
here are only for the 90 day T-bill rates.

The results reported

However, it should be pointed out

that all the results obtained for the 90 day bill rate also hold for the other
two rates.
For the first test, (1) becomes
A

A

RPit = a0i + ali Rt + a2i RESt + <*3i RETSP500t + Ut

(5)

One major difference between (1) and (5) is that in (1) the daily returns
of the portfolios were calculated for the day following the money
announcements, whereas in (5) the daily returns are calculated for the entire
sample period.

Rt refers to the predicted value of the interest rate series

obtained from the fitted equation, while RESt refers to the residuals from the
same equation and thus is the proxy for unanticipated interest rates.^
The issue being tested again is whether or not the relative size of the
A

coefficients satisfy the following ordering:

A

A

a n > ai2 > ai3 - The results of

estimating (5) are reported in Table 6 . Notice, that the coefficients in
question are highly significant and negative as they were in the case of
response to money supply announcements.

But, more importantly, and as before,

the nominal contracting effects are not found.

Based on the F statistics, the

null hypotheses that the pairwise coefficients are not different cannot be
rejected for any of the portfolios.

Thus, the conclusion remains, that the

unexpected interest rate increases lead the market to revise the share prices
of banks downwards.




However, as before, in this revision process the market

15

does not appear to attach significance to the maturity structure of bank
assets and liabilities.16
Repeating the seemingly unrelated regression procedure for the case where
unanticipated interest rates are measured by the residuals transforms (3) to
the following equation:
A

A

Rpit = <*0i + T01 PESt * m

A

A

RESt GAPit + Y 2 i Rt + Uit

(6 )

The estimates of (6) for the 3 portfolios as well as the average response
of the portfolios is captured by:
A

A

“li = TOi + Tli GAPi
These coefficients along with the results obtained from the estimation of
(6) are reported in Table 7.
The a-|i coefficients appear to be highly significant on the basis of the
value of the F-statistics. In all cases the null hypothesis that a-j^ = 0 are
rejected.

However, the hypothesis that the response is not different amongst

the portfolios again cannot be rejected.
The non-parametric test leads to the same conclusion:
correlation between the

The Spearman rank

coefficients obtained from the estimation of (5)

for the individual banks and their average gap position is -0.013.

Based on

the tail area of the test (0.90), we cannot reject the hypothesis that there
is no relation between the response of bank share prices to unanticipated
interest rates and bank gap positions.^
iii)

Possible Reasons for the Empirical Findings

There are several possible explanations for the results in this paper.
One explanation for the fact that the returns of the three portfolios behave




16

similarly is that there is an industry factor associated with the banking
sector which dominates any firm specific factors.

It is conceivable that this

factor is related to the importance of interest rates for financial
institutions.

If so, then any event which affects interest rates (e.g. money

supply announcements) will result in the market reevaluating the banking
sector.

In this evaluation the industry factor in question may dominate bank

specific factors like the gap position of a bank.
Another possibility is that banks might be well hedged in terms of their
interest rate exposure.

In other words, it is conceivable that through use of

the futures market, interest rate swaps etc. banks offset their interest rate
exposure.

If so, they will in effect have a zero gap position.

The

possibility of all the banks being perfectly hedged however, can be questioned
on two accounts:

First, due to he ambiguity in the accounting treatment of

hedging transactions, some banks were reluctant to use the futures market
heavily during the sample period considered here. 18

Secondly, the argument

does not acknowledge the fact that banks at times actively position themselves
to profit from what they perceive to be expected future interest rate
movements.

Moreover, since there is no reason to think that individual bank

interest rate expectations are always homogeneous, their attempts to
restructure their balance sheets is likely to result in different degrees of
exposure across banks.
These possibly explanations notwithstanding, the evidence presented
appears to indicate that in evaluating the impact of unanticipated interest
rates, the stock market considers the differences in the maturity structure of
banks' assets and liabilities to be unimportant.




17

IV.

SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
This study Investigates the relationship between unanticipated interest

rates and bank stock returns.

The goal of the paper is to test whether or not

the statistical relationship observed between stock prices and unanticipated
interest rate can be explained in terms of the nominal contracting position of
the firms.

To this end, the behavior of bank stock returns is analyzed.

The

main conclusion is that the nominal contracting hypothesis does not appear to
be supported by the tests conducted in this study.
It should be pointed out that one would expect the nominal contracting
effects to be most important for the type of firms examined in this study,
since almost all their assets are nominal in nature.

French, Ruback and

Schwert (1983) report evidence indicating that the nominal contracting
hypothesis is unimportant in explaining the response of stock returns to
unexpected inflation. 19

While the disequilibrium condition analyzed here is

unexpected changes in interest rates, and not unexpected inflation, the
conclusion is similar, in the sense that the wealth redistribution
implications of the nominal contracting hypothesis are again found to be
unimportant in the determination of stock prices.
It should be pointed out that another study (Flannery and Tames (1984))
find evidence of nominal contracting effects in the context of the sensitivity
of bank stock returns to unanticipated interest rates.

The differences

between the approaches of the two studies were discussed in the first section
of this paper.

The contrast between the results of this study and theirs

points to the necessity that more work needs to be done in this area.

Such

future research should continue to examine the issue in the framework of the
financial sector, since the balance




18

sheets of Institutions in this industry consist of items which are nominal.
For the banking sector, it is found that nominal contracting hypothesis is not
supported by the data.

That is, while bank stock prices are affected by

unanticipated interest rate movements, their responses do not appear to be
related to the maturity structure of their assets and liabilities.




Footnotes

^During the last six years, the relation between money supply
announcements and various interest rates has generated a lot of interest
(Cornell (1979), Cornell (1983), Grossman (1981), Roley (1982), Urich and
Wachtel (1981). The impact of money supply announcements on the stock market
returns (Lynge (1981), Pearce and Roley (1982)) has also been investigated.
By and large these studies find that there is a significant relation between
unexpected money and the market rates in question. Another finding is that
the statistical relationship in question have become more pronounced since
October 6 , 1979, when the Fed switched to a policy of targeting monetary
aggregates.
2 T w o h y p o t h e s e s a r e a d v a n c e d in the l i t e r a t u r e to e x p l a i n th i s
the e x p e c t e d l i q u i d i t y e f f e c t , an d the i n f l a t i o n p r e m i u m e f f e c t .

relation:

Paradoxically, the implied behavior of the Fed is drastically different for
the two hypotheses in question. The basis for the former hypothesis is that
the Fed will abide by its monetary targets and thus offset the surprise
component of the announced money supply figure in future periods. The
rationale for the latter hypothesis, on the other hand, is that the Fed will
"give in" and adjust its monetary targets in the direction of the shock (e.g.
increase its targets when actual money supply exceeds the anticipated level).
3For alternative measures of the gap position of commercial banks see
Flannery and James (1984). the measure used here is same as the one that
Salomon Brothers publishes for selective banks.
^Maturity and repricing period mean the same thing when the interest rate
in question is fixed. However, when the interest rate is variable, the
repricing period is the appropriate concept in determining the wealth effects
associated with unanticipated interest rate changes.
3A decline in interest rates will benefit banks with negative gap
positions. The profits of banks in this category will increase since they
have long term assets and short term liabilities. This, combined with lower
discount rates will imply higher stock prices. The effect of lower interest
rates on banks positive gaps is again ambiguous.
^It should be pointed out that there is Another factor that reinforces the
repricing frequency argument which states that the returns from positive gap
bank stocks will be higher than negative gap bank stock returns in the event
of any unexpected rise in interest rates. This effect works through the
impact of interest rate changes on the market value of a bank's assets. A
bank with a positive gap has a smaller portion of its assets that are long
term, relative to a bank with a negative gap. Thus, when interest rates rise,
other things being equal, a bank with a positive gap will experience a smaller
decline in the value of its long term assets than a bank with a negative gap
position. Of course in the event of interest rate decreases, banks with a
negative gap position will benefit more than positive gap banks, both due to
the fact that their liabilities will be repriced at the lower rates, while
their assets will not, and also because they have relatively higher volume of
long term assets whose prices will increase.




F-2
^Starting 1n December 1982, Salomon Brothers has been calculating gap
statistics for selective banks 1n their publication titled "Bank Analysts'
Quarterly Handbook." Some of the banks used In this study overlap with the
banks 1n their sample. The Salomon Brothers' definition of the gap measure
has been revised a number of times during the last year. The gap measure used
In this study 1 s along the lines of their latest definition. I would like to
thank Thomas B. Drelles of Salomon Brothers for a detailed discussion on this
Issue. James and Flannery (JMCB, 1984) Investigate whether or not to Include
demand deposits, passbook accounts, cash assets and retail time deposits 1 n
their gap measure. They conclude that the Items 1n question are not truly
short term 1 n nature and thus should not be Included. I would like to
acknowledge the research assistance provided by Debbie Karlowskl 1n the
calculation of the gap measures for the sample banks.
8The average market value of a bank's equity 1 s defined as the number of
common shares outstanding times the average stock price for the 13 week period.
9In the case of multibank holding companies, the gap measures were
calculated for the lead bank. It 1s assumed that the gap measure which 1s
constructed for the lead bank 1 s representative of the banking operations of
the holding company. The banking assets constituted about 96 percent of the
assets of the bank holding companies used 1 n this study.
It should also be pointed out that due to the Irregularities 1n money
supply announcement days, there are not always 13 observations 1n a quarter.
10The average gap position for the equally weighted portfolio of banks In
the sample was graphed together with various Interest rates (3 mos and 1 year
Treasury bill rates and the 20 year constant maturity U.S. Government Bond
rate). It appeared that for the sample period 1n question high level of
Interest rates was correlated with negative gap positions. Reducing the
dollar value of short term assets and/or Increasing the dollar value of short
term liabilities when Interest rates Increase, 1 s consistent with the belief
that Interest rates follow a mean reverting process. However, without the
benefit of a model of bank Interest rate expectation formation, 1 t 1 s not
possible to test whether or not banks manager their gap positions 1 n this
manner. Nevertheless, this seems to be a plausible explanation as to why bank
gap positions became more negative as Interest rates rose.
^ T h e one day holding period return 1 s defined as
RPt =

P - P
+ D
t
t-1
t
Pt-1

Where p j _ | refers to the price of the stock on the day announcement (the
-.stock market 1 s already closed when the announcement 1 s made). Pt 1 s the
price of the stock on the first day following the announcement that the market
1s open, and D* refers to dividends paid on period t. Trading volume on the
stocks 1n question was not available. This poses a problem, since some of the
bank stocks 1n question had a large number of days with zero returns. One




F-3
possibility for zero returns would be no trades. While there was no way to
determine the extent of no trading or thin trading, due to the fact that some
of the banks 1 n question were relatively small, an attempt was made to
eliminate the problems associated with Infrequent trading: A particular stock
was excluded from the portfolios constructed if Its return on the day after
the announcement was zero. However, due to the possibility that the zero
returns are not the result of Infrequent trading, all the analysis 1 n this
study was repeated with the data where zero returns are not excluded. The
results reported are obtained using the data where zero returns are Included
1n the sample. However, repeating the analysis with data that does not
Include zero returns produced results which are remarkably similar. In fact
these results do not change the conclusions of this paper 1 n any stage of the
analysis.
12I would like to acknowledge Paul N1cho and K1m Rupert of Money Market
Services of San Francisco for making available the survey data 1n question.
13It 1 s conceivable that the quarter-to-quarter changes 1 n a bank's
Interest rate sensitive assets and liabilities do not reveal the management
philosophy of a bank regarding Its preferred maturity structure. It may be
the case that the market Ignores any quarter-to-quarter changes 1 n a bank's
gap position, relying Instead on the long run equilibrium gap positions in
determining banks' stock prices. To remove the potential ambiguity about
banks' gap structure, two portfolios were formed were only the banks which
have consistently negative or positive gaps were Included. The tests
conducted 1n this study were repeated for these portfolios. The results
obtained did not alter the conclusions of this appear In any significant
manner.
14The correlation coefficients across the equations ranged from 0.47 to
0.63. In light of the high correlation coefficients amongst the equations,
use of the seemingly unrelated regression method appears to be appropriate.
15The ARIMA model was estimated with nonzero AR terms at lags 5, 11 and
22, and moving average term at lag 1. ARIMA models were also fitted for the
dally 6 mos and 1 year Treasury bill rates. As Indicated above use of 6 mos
and 1 year bill rates did not change the conclusions of this study in any
manner.
16Even though the response of bank stock returns to the forecasted
Interest rates 1 s significant 1 n the case of two of the portfolios, this does
not imply that markets are inefficient. It should be noted that the relative
size of the estimated coefficients is something in the order of 1 /1 1 th to
1/15th of the response to the unexpected Interest rates. Thus, it appears
unlikely that investors can make excess profits by trading 1 n bank stocks on
the basis of an Interest rate forecasting scheme, even without transaction
costs considerations.
17The estimated <x-\} coefficients turned out to be negative for 38 of the
46 banks that comprise the sample. None of the 8 positive a-|^ coefficients
were statistically significant.




F-4
18The ambituity in question refers to the accounting treatment of the
fluctuations in the value of the futures contract versus fluctuations in the
value of the underlying cash position. Eventually it was ruled that the gains
or losses realized as a result of marking to market would be reported on a
current basis, while changes in the value of the offsetting cash positions
would be reported only when they are accrued.
It should also be pointed out that partially for this reason banks which
use the futures market seem to confine themselves to hedging their trading
account securities as opposed to their total assets and liabilities.
Additionally, it should be noted that the hedging activities for a bank is
likely to be asymmetric. When a bank is hedging the securities in its trading
account, it will only do so when it expects the interest rates to increase.
19Bernard (1984) reports that the relationship between unexpected
inflation and stock returns cannot simply be explained by nominal contracting
variables. He argues that unanticipated inflation affects firms through other
channels. From an empirical standpoint the most important channel appears to
be the systematic risk of firms. The parallel of Bernard's argument for this
study is the potential impact that unexpected interest rates may have on the
earnings of commercial banks via their effect on aggregate real activity. In
this study, market returns are included as an explanatory variable in the
specification of all the experiments conducted. Thus the differences amongst
banks regarding their sensitivities to aggregate real economic activity are
accounted for.




References
1. Alchian, Armen and Reuben Kessel "Redistribution of Wealth Through
Inflation: Science. 130 (September 4, 1959), 535-39.
2. Bach, George L. and Albert Ando "The Redistributional Effects of
Inflation." Review of Economics and Statistics. 39 (February 1957), 1-13.
3. Bach, George and James Stephenson "Inflation and the Redistribution of
Wealth," Review of Economics and Statistics. 56 (February 1974), 1-13.
4. Bernard, Victor L. "Unanticipated Inflation, Real Assets and the Value of
the Firm," Journal of Financial Economics. 15 (March 1986), 285-322.
5. Cornell, Bradford. "Do Money Supply Announcements Affect Short-Term
Interest Rates?" Journal of Money Credit and Banking. 11 (February
1979), 80-86.
6

. Cornell Bradford. "Money Supply Announcements and Interest Rates:
Another Vice," Journal of Business. 56 (January 1983), 1-24.

7. Cornell, Bradford. "The Money Supply Announcements Puzzle: Review and
Interpretation," American Economic Review. 73 (September 1983), 644-57.
8.

Flannery Mark J. and Christopher M. James. "Effect of Interest Rate
Charges On the Common Stock Returns of Financial Institutions," Journal of
Finance. 39 (September 1984) 1141-53.

9. Flannery Mark J. and Christopher M. James. “Market Evidence on the
Effective Maturity of Bank Assets and Liabilities," Journal of Money
Credit and Banking. (November 1984), 435-45.
10. French, Kenneth R. "Stock Returns and the Weekend Effect," Journal of
Financial Economics. 8 (March 1980), 55-69.
11. Grossman, Jacob "The Rationality of Money Supply Expectations and the
Short-Run Response of Interest Rates of Monetary Surprises," Journal of
Money Credit and Banking. 13 (November 1981), 409-24.
12. Hong, Hai. "Inflation and the Market Value of the Firm: Theory and
Tests." Journal of Finance. 32 (September 1970), 1031-48.
13. Lynge, Morgan J. "Money Supply Announcements and Stock Prices ," Journal
of Portfolio Management. 8 (Fall 1981).
14. Pearce, D. Douglas and Vance Roley. "The Reaction of Stock Prices to
Unanticipated Changes in Money," Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City,
Research Working Paper 1982.




R-2

15. Roley, Vance. "Weekly Money Supply Announcements and the Volatility of
Short-Term Interest Rates" Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Economic
Review. (February 1983), 3-15.
16. Urlch, T. J. and P. Wachtel. "Market Responses to Weekly Money Supply
Announcements 1n the 1970's," Journal of Finance. 36 (December 1981),
1063-72.







TABLE 1
Variables Used 1n Calculating the GAP Positions
Rate Sensitive Assets (RSA)
Federal Funds Sold
Fixed Rate Loans with Remaining Maturity Less Than One Year.
Investments With Remaining Maturity Less Than One Year.
Loans With Floating Interest Rate
Interest Bearing Overseas Placement (less than one year)
Trading Account Securities
Customers Acceptances
Interest Bearing Balances
Time and Savings Balances With Commercial Banks 1n U.S.
Rate Sensitive Liabilities (RSL)
Domestic Certificate of Deposits (less than one year maturity)
Foreign Certificate of Deposits (less than one year maturity)
Other Large Time Deposits
Federal Funds Purchased
Banks Liabilities on Acceptances (Domestic)
Banks Liabilities on Acceptances (Foreign)
Interest Bearing Demand Notes Issued on U.S. Treasury
Money Market Time Deposits
Dollar Value GAP=RSA-RSL
Percent GAP=(RSA-RSL)/Market Value of Equity

TABLE 2
DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS ON INDIVIDUAL BANK GAPs
MEAN
1
2

3
4
5
6

7
8

9
10
11
12

13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22

23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42




0.0061
0.0018
-0.0061
-0.0064
0 .0 0 0 2

-0.0003
-0.0018
0.0006
0.0053
-0 . 0 0 0 0
-0.0055
-0.0007
-0.0031
-0 . 0 0 2 0
-0.0074
0.0003
-0.0016

STANDARD
DEVIATION

MINIMUM
VALUE

MAXIMUM
VALUE

0.0046

-0.0009
-0 . 0 0 2 2
-0.0132
-0.0132
-0.0039
-0.0017
-0.0046
-0.0041
-0.0075
-0.0038
-0.0037
-0 . 0 0 2 1
-0.0061
-0.0081
-0.0115
-0.0038
-0.0133
0.0008
-0 . 0 2 1 1
-0.0004
-0.0008
-0.0062
-0.0739
-0.0053
-0.0105
-0.0014
-0.0054
-0.0080
-0.0007
-0.0105
-0 . 0 0 1 1
-0 . 0 1 2 2
-0.0181
-0.0105
-0.0019
-0.0137
-0.0016
-0.0248
-0.0052
-0.0043
-0.0347
-0.0026
-0.0027
-0 . 0 0 2 0
-0 . 0 1 0 1
-0 . 0 0 1 2

0.0153
0.0062
0.0034
0.0014
0.0092

0 .0 0 2 2

0.0047
0.0046
0.0039
0.0009
0.0018
0.0032
0.0106
0 .0 0 1 2

0.0025
0.0007
0.0015
0.0032
0.0035
0 .0 0 2 0

0.0052

0 .0 0 2 2

0.0010

-0.0090
0.0005
0.0023
-0.0037
-0.0440
-0.0024
-0.0048

0.0047
0.0006
0.0013

0 .0 0 0 2

-0 . 0 0 2 2
-0.0031
0.0011

-0.0043
0.0004
-0.0062
-0.0098
-0.0031
-0.0005
-0.0062
0.0014
-0.0133
-0 . 0 0 2 1
-0 . 0 0 0 1
-0.0157
-0 . 0 0 0 0
-0.0016
-0.0013
-0.0054
-0 . 0 0 0 1

0 .0 0 2 2

0.0304
0.0014
0.0023
0.0016
0.0027
0.0034
0.0014
0.0054
0.0011
0 .0 0 2 2

0.0034
0.0031
0.0009
0.0049
0.0028
0.0074
0.0021

0.0032
0.0137
0.0014
0.0006
0.0006
0.0027
0.0006

0.0011

0.0023
0.0085
0.0330
0.0016
0.0031
0.0004
0 .0 0 0 0

0.0035
-0.0026
0.0036
0.0065
0.0044
-0.0019
0.0017
0.0041
0.0005
0.0101

-0.0007
-0.0008
0.0036
0.0033
0.0037
0.0041
0.0084
0.0029
-0.0037
-0.0032
0.0021

0.0008
0.0023
0.0077
-0.0008
0.0025
0.0056
0 .0 2 0 0

0.0019
-0.0004
0.0005
-0.0004
0 .0 0 1 0

TABLE 3
Selected Statistics from the Portfolios
Portfolio 1

Portfolio 2

Portfolio 3

SP500

Mean Return

0.00090

0.00074

0.00062

0.00055

Standard deviation of returns

0.00737

0.00744

0.00773

0.00923

Minimum Return

-0.03532

-0.04318

Maximum Return

0.07495

0.02859

0.04316

Mean GAP

0.00248

-0.00133

-0.01024

Standard Deviation of GAP

0.00135

0.00106

0.00331

Minimum GAP

0.00029

-0.00659

-0.0144

Maximum GAP

0.00505

0.00073

-0.00410

Number of Banks




15

15

-0.0451

16

-0.0305
0.0465

TABLE 4
The Effects of Expected and Unexpected
Money on Bank Returns3

A
E
E
RP1t = <*01 + “ 11 (Mt " Mt) + <*21 Mt * <*31 RETSP500t + U^t
No. of
Observation

<q ^
*

a-|^

a2 ^

<3 ^
*

R2

Portfolio 1

171

0.00025
(0 .6 6 )

-0.00047
(-2.69)

0.00027
(1.04)

0.39269
(11.13)

0.48

Portfolio 2

171

0.00064
(1.62)

-0.00078
(-4.24)

-0.00008
(-0.28)

0.48992
(13.20)

0.57

Portfolio 3

171

0.00016
(0.38)

-0.00055
(-2.73)

-0.00038
(-1.30)

0.53998
(13.27)

0.55

Null Hypothesis
A




parenthesis.

0.22

0.093

0.76

0.698

0.40

A

all = al 2

3 t-stat 1 st1 cs 1 n

.488

1

A

all = al 2
A

Tall Area of the Test

A

all = al 2
A

F-Stat1st1c

TABLE 5
Seemingly Unrelated Regression Results of the Response
of Bank Stock Returns to the Money Supply Announcements3

A
E
A
E
E
Rpit = a0i + YOi (Mt - Mt + Yli (Mt - Mt) GAP^t + Y 2 i Mt + T3i
a

RETSP500t

2

Oi

T0 i

rn

T2 i

T3i

Portfolio 1

0.00025
(0 .6 6 )

-0.00045
(-1.35)

-0.00671
(-0.05)

0.00027
(1.04)

0.39285
(11.06)

0.48

Portfolio 2

0.00065
(1.63)

-0.00065
(-1.79)

0.08094
(0.42)

-0.00008
(-0.29)

0.49014
(13.17)

0.57

Portfolio 3

0.00016
(0.37)

-0.00055
(-0.73)

0.00009
(0 .0 0 )

-0.00038
(-1.29)

0.53990
(13.22)

R

0.55

The weighted R--square for the system = 0.38b
The Average Response
to Unexpected Money

F-statistic
(Null Hyp:ali=0)

Tail area
of the test

Portfolio 1

all = -0.00045 + (-0.00671)(0.00248) = -0.00045

7.07

Portfolio 2

all = -0.00065 + (0.08094)(-0.00133) = -0.00076

15.37

0.0001

Portfolio 3

511 = -0.00055 + (0.00009H-0.01024) = -0.00055

6.71

0.009

Null Hypothesis

F-statistics

0.008

Tail area of the test

511 = 512:

0.14

511 = 513:

0.21

0.65

511 = 513:
3 t-statistics

2.19

0.98

0.32

in parenthesis.
bThis is the R-square that corresponds to the approximate F test on all non-intercept
parmeters in the system.




TABLE 6
The Effects of Forecasted and Unexpected
Interest Rates on Bank Stock Returns3

RP^-j- = < ^ + a j ^ RES^ + a 2 ^ R^ +
xq
No. of
Observation

a0 i

RETSP500^- + U ^

al i

a2 i

R2

a3i

Portfolio 1

876

0.00267
(2.59)

-0.00241
(-2.83)

-0.00016
(-1.89)

0.39887
(16.54)

0.29

Portfolio 2

876

0.003
(3.14)

-0.00232
(-2.93)

-0 . 0 0 0 2
(-2.59)

0.45454
(20.27)

0.37

Portfolio 3

876

0.00223
(2.26)

-0.00176
(-2.15)

-0.00016
(-1.96)

0.50449
(21.77)

0.39

Null Hypothesis
A




in parenthesis.

0.92

0.303

0.58

0.238

0.63

A

all = al3:
3 t-statistics

0.007

A

all = al3:
A

Tail area of the test

A

all = al 2 :
A

F-statistics

TABLE 7
Seemingly Unrelated Regression Results of the Response
of Bank Stock Returns to the Unexpected and Forecasted Interest Rates3
Rpit = t 0 i * YOi RESt * rii RESt
t

a

y

0i

GAP1t + Y 2 i Rt + T3i

Y

Oi

li

y

RETSP500t * uit

.

2i

y

3i

R

2

Portfolio 1

0.00267
(2.60)

-0.00141
(-0 .8 6 )

-0.48689
(-0.71)

-0.00016
(-1.90)

0.39834
(16.51)

0.29

Portfolio 2

0.00301
(3.15)

-0.00333
(-2.38)

-0.58509
(-0 .8 8 )

-0 . 0 0 0 2 1
(-2.61)

0.45375
(20.28)

0.38

Portfolio 3

0.00228
(2.31)

-0.00475
-(1.49)

-0.25679
(-0.97)

-0.00016
(-1.99)

0.50325
(21 .72)

0.40

The weighted R-square for the system = 0.21^
The Average Response
to Unexpected Money

Portfolio 1

ill = -0.00141

Portfolio 2
Portfolio 3

F-statistic
(Null Hyp:all=0)

(-0.48689)(0.00248) = -0.00262

Tail area
of the test

8.50

0.003

£11 = -0.00333 * (-0.58509K-0.00133) = -0.00255

9.41

0.002

£11 = -0.00475 + (-0.25679H-0.01074) = -0 . 0 0 2 1 2

5.62

0.018

Null Hypothesis

F-statlstics

Tail area of the test

£11

= £1 2 :

0.004

0.947

£11

= £13:

0.301

0 .0 0 2

£11

= £13:

0.287

0.592

at-statistics in parenthesis.
&This is the R-square that corresponds to the approximate F test on all non-intercept
parmeters in the system.