View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

orKing raper series



Bank Failures, Systemic Risk, and
Bank Regulation
George G. Kaufman

Working Papers Series
Issues in Financial Regulation
Research Department
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
January 1996 (WP-96-1)

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF CHICAGO

Bank Failures, Systemic Risk, and Bank Regulation

George G. Kaufman

Loyola University of Chicago
and
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

The views expressed in this paper are strictly those of the author. They do not necessarily
represent the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, or the Federal Reserve System.




Revised Draft
December 13, 1995

Bank Failures, Systemic Risk, and Bank Regulation
George G. Kaufman*

Bank (depository institutions) failures are widely perceived to have greater
adverse effects on the economy and thus are considered more important than the
failure of other types of business firms. In part, bank failures are viewed to be more
damaging than other failures because they are perceived to spread in domino fashion
throughout the banking system, felling solvent as well as insolvent banks.1 Thus, the
failure of an individual bank introduces the possibility of systemwide failures or systemic
risk. This perception is widespread.

It appears to exist in almost every country at

almost every point in time regardless of the existing economic or political structure. As
a result, bank failures have been and continue to be a major public policy concern in
all countries and a major reason that banks are regulated more rigorously than other
firms.2
Unfortunately, whether bank failures are or are not in fact more important than
other failures, and I will argue in this paper that they are not, the prudential regulations
imposed to prevent and/or mitigate the impact of such failures are frequently inefficient

* Loyola University of Chicago and consultant, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. This
paper was initially prepared for presentation ata conference on Public Regulation of
Depository Institutions, Koc University, Istanbul, Turkey, November 3,1995. lam
indebted to Douglas Evanoff for helpful comments.




2
and counterproductive. (See also Flannery, 1995.) They have often increased both the
probability of bank failure and the costs of such failures. In the process, the regulations
have tended to socialize the costs of failure by shifting them from private depositors of
the failed banks to general taxpayers.
In addition, the imposition of prudential regulations have identified banking as
"unique," and at times have involved potential government financial assistance. This
has often made it easier for governments to justify imposing other regulations that have
primarily social and political objectives and are often in conflict with the objectives of
the prudential regulations, e.g., credit allocation schemes.3 However, the bulk of the
evidence suggests that the greatest danger of systemic risk comes not from the
damage that may be imposed on the economy from a series of bank failures, but from
the damage that is imposed on the economy from the adverse effects of poor public
policies adopted to prevent systemic risk. As a result, it can be argued that the poor
performance of banking experienced in almost all countries in the last two decades
reflects primarily regulatory or government failures, rather than market failures.
Prevention of reoccurrences of the recent banking problems requires better developed
and more incentive compatible and market assisted prudential regulation and reduced
nonprudential regulations.

I Implications of Bank Failures
A bank fails economically when the market value of its assets declines below the
market value of its liabilities so that the market value of its capital (net worth) becomes
negative. At such times, the bank cannot expect to pay all of its depositors in full and




3
on time. The bank, or indeed any firm, should be resolved as quickly as possible in
order to treat all depositors (creditors) fairly and not allow a run by depositors holding
demand and short-dated deposits.

The longer an insolvent bank is permitted to

operate, the more time such informed depositors have to withdraw their funds at par
value and effectively strip the bank of its valuable assets. The entire loss will then be
borne by less informed depositors and holders of longer-dated deposits.
In most countries, the failure of an individual bank per se should be no more
important than the failure of any other firm of comparable size in the community. This
is particularly true today when most bank products are no longer unique and are being
provided in many countries by an ever growing number of nonbank firms that are
gaining market share at the expense of banks. Moreover, to the extent that bank or
branch office charters are not restricted, if the demand for banking services in the
community is sufficiently strong, a new bank or office should be expected to enter. In
the absence of deposit insurance, potential adverse effects to the community would be
minimized, the faster the insolvent bank is resolved and the smaller the losses to
depositors.
This is not to argue that bank failures are costless.

Losses accrue to

shareholders and most likely also to depositors, unsecured creditors, and the deposit
insurer. Small loan customers may be particularly inconvenienced by changes in their
loan officers, loan standards, and other aspects of their ongoing bank relationship. But
this is no different from the losses and disruptions in firm-customer relationships that
accompany the failure of almost any business entity of comparable size in the
community.




4

What makes, at least, the perception of bank failures more important, particularly
for public policy, is that the failure may spill over to other banks and possibly even
beyond the banking system to the financial system as a whole, the domestic
macroeconomy, and other countries. Similar fears are generally not perceived for the
failure of other firms. The failure of a steel mill, software manufacturer, or grocery store
is not widely perceived to spill over to other firms in the same industry.

Indeed, the

surviving firms are frequently thought to benefit from losing a competitor and being able
to expand their market shares (Lang and Stulz, 1992).
Whether or not bank failures are more serious than other failures, individual
banks are viewed as more susceptible to failure or more "fragile" than other firms and
the banking industry more susceptible to contagion than other industries. Banks are
viewed more fragile for three reasons. They have:
1.

low capital-to-assets ratios (high leverage), which provides little room for

2.

low cash-to-assets ratios (fractional reserve banking), which may require

losses,

the sale of earning assets to meet deposit obligations, and,
3.

high demand debt and short-term debt-to-total debt (deposits) ratios, which

may require hurried asset sales with potentially large fire-sale losses to pay off running
depositors.
The adverse implications of this fragility are intensified by the fear that depositors
may run "irrationally" on banks, forcing unnecessarily large fire-sale losses, and that
banks invest in assets that are opaque, illiquid and difficult to market, contain private
information, and can change in market value abruptly.



Thus, the greater fragility is

5

believed to lead to greater failure.
Moreover, because banks are closely intertwined financially with each other
through lending to and borrowing from each other, holding deposit balances with each
other, and the payments clearing system, a failure of any one bank is believed to be
more likely to spill over to other banks and to do so more quickly. Thus, the banking
system is seen as more susceptible to systemic risk, where systemic risk may be
defined as:
The probability that cumulative losses will occur from an event that ignites a
series of successive losses along a chain of institutions or markets comprising
a system (Kaufman, 1995b).4
A default by one bank on an obligation to another bank may adversely affect that
bank’s ability to meet its obligations to other banks and so on down the chain of banks
and beyond.
In a recent review of the literature on bank contagion, I identified five reasons
that have been cited for more serious contagion in banking than in other industries
(Kaufman, 1994). In banking, contagion is perceived to:
1.

occur faster,

2.

spread more widely within the industry,

3.

result in a larger number of failures,

4.

result in larger losses to creditors (depositors) at failed firms, and

5.

spread more beyond the banking industry to other sectors, the

macroeconomy, and other countries.
I concluded that the evidence suggests that, while contagion in banking may be
faster, be more likely to spread to a larger percent of the industry, lead to a larger




6
number of failures, and be more likely to spill over beyond banking, losses to depositors
at failed institutions -- the primary transmitter of systemic risk -- are smaller, and bank
runs -- which can increase the risk by increasing the losses -- tend to be informational
and bank specific.

At least marginal depositors are generally able to differentiate

solvent from insolvent banks, particularly when they are given the incentive to do so by
the fear of suffering losses.

As a result, contrary to folklore, bank contagion on a

nationwide scale has not been a common experience and, while large-scale banking
failures exacerbate economic downturns, they do not appear to start them.
Nevertheless, the perception of both great likelihood and great damage persists
and much extant prudential bank regulation is based on this perception. The remainder
of this paper examines the potential for systemic risk in banking more carefully and
recommends public policy initiatives that would greatly reduce, if not eliminate, this risk.

II Systemic Risk and Public Policy
Although banking may be more fragile than other industries, this does not imply
a higher breakage or failure rate. Rather, greater fragility implies "handle with greater
care," much as it does with glass and porcelain objects. And apparently that is what
the private market did in the U.S. when the proper incentives to encourage such
behavior were in place. Before the introduction of government safety nets, banks held
considerably higher capital ratios and assumed considerably less credit and interest
rate risks in their portfolios. The average annual failure rate for banks in the U.S. from
the end of the Civil War in 1865 to before the establishment of the Federal Reserve
System in 1914 was lower than for nonbank firms, although the annual variance was




7

greater.5 In addition, losses to depositors as a percent of deposits at failed banks
were lower than losses to creditors at failed nonbanks (Kaufman, 1994). Schwartz
(1988) argues that until the recent worldwide rash of bank failures (documented in Baer
and Klingebiel, 1995; Caprio and Klingebiel, 1995; Garcia,

1995; Goodhart, 1995,

particularly chapter 16; Nakajima and Taguchi, 1995), while banks failed, bank panics
and contagion had almost disappeared in developed countries, other than the U.S., by
the late 1920s.
Ironically, the introduction of government regulations and institutions in the U.S.
intended to provide protection against the fragility of banks has unintentionally
increased both the fragility of the banks and their breakage rate. By providing a safety
net under banks for depositors, first the Federal Reserve through its lender of last
resort operations and then the FDIC through its mispriced deposit guarantees have
reduced market discipline on banks and permitted, if not encouraged, banks to increase
their risk exposures both in their asset and liability portfolios and by reducing their
capital ratios.

This represents a classic and predictable moral hazard behavior

response (Kane, 1985, 1989, and 1992; Benston and Kaufman, 1995; Kaufman 1995a).
Public (taxpayer) capital has largely replaced private (shareholder) capital as the
ultimate protector of depositors.

For example, in its 1994 Annual Report, the FDIC

declared that "the FDIC remains today the symbol of banking confidence" (FDIC, 1995,
p. 35).6
But, in addition, the establishment of the Federal Reserve and FDIC in the U.S.
introduced severe principal-agent problems (Kane, 1995a and 1995b). The Federal
Reserve was charged with acting as the lender of last resort to the macroeconomy by,




8

among other things, offsetting the impact of losses of reserves from the banking system
for reasons such as a run to currency by depositors or gold outflows that threatened
to reduce the money supply below appropriate levels. But the Federal Reserve was
given discretion with respect to when and to what extent to do so. Unfortunately, when
the banking system experienced a run into currency during the Great Depression from
1929 to 1933, which dramatically reduced aggregate bank reserves, money supply, and
bank credit, the Federal Reserve failed to inject sufficient offsetting reserves (Friedman
and Schwartz, 1963). As a result, the simultaneous attempt by nearly all banks to
contract by selling assets led to large fire-sale losses and the largest number of bank
failures in U.S. history.
To prevent another misuse of discretionary power, the FDIC was established
to automatically guaranty a given dollar amount of deposits per bank account. Most
depositors would, therefore, have little, if any, reason to run on their banks regardless
of the bank’s financial condition. Rules were imposed to supplant discretion. But the
law of unintended consequences was not absent. The absence of runs removed a
major automatic mechanism by which troubled banks were previously closed and
resolved. Runs on troubled banks caused liquidity problems, which forced regulators
to suspend their operations until their solvency could be determined.

In this way,

depositors prevented insolvent institutions from remaining in operation for long and
thereby limited the ability of these banks to enlarge their losses.
In contrast, after deposit insurance ended most runs, the bank agencies were
able, for whatever reason, to permit insolvent banks to remain in operation and
continue to generate losses.




The failure of the late Federal Savings and Loan

9

Insurance Corporation (FSLIC) to promptly resolve insolvent savings and loan
associations in the 1980s, led to its own insolvency, the shifting of its approximate $150
billion negative net worth to the U.S. taxpayer, and a record number of thrift failures.
Capital forbearance was also practiced in this period by the FDIC for commercial banks
with high costs that were, however, able to be absorbed by the FDIC, primarily because
a sharp fall in interest rates, an equally sharp steepening in the yield curve, and new
federal legislation (discussed later) requiring recapitalization of banks abruptly improved
the economic health of the surviving banks (Kaufman, 1995a).
Paradoxically, the Federal Reserve and the FDIC/FSLIC used their discretionary
authority in opposite directions with equally adverse effects for the economy. In the
1930s, the Federal Reserve was overly restrictive. In the 1980s, after the government
had

introduced

a

system

that

would

prevent

overrestrictiveness

but

not

underrestrictiveness (which had not been a problem in the 1930s), both the FDIC and
FSLIC used their discretionary powers to be less restrictive on troubled insured
institutions than they should have been. In retrospect, both agencies were poor agents
for their principals -- the Congress and citizens of the U.S., and for the FDIC/FSLIC
also the healthy banks and thrifts that paid premiums to the insurance funds (Kane,
1989).

Ill The Causes of Systemic Risk
To design public policies that can efficiently prevent the fragility of banks to be
translated into a high failure rate, it is necessary to understand the causes of both
individual bank failures and systemic risk. The causes of individual bank failure have




10
been considered adequately elsewhere and need not be reconsidered here(e.g.,
O’Conner, 1938; Graham and Horner, 1988). The same is less true for systemic risk.7
Systemic risk occurs because all economic agents are interconnected.

This

interconnection provides a chain along which shocks to any one agent are transmitted
to others. The personal or institutional balance sheet of each agent includes assets
that are either liabilities of other agents or whose values depend on the behavior of
other agents.

Likewise, the liabilities of each agent are the assets of others.

If an

agent suffers a decline in the value of its assets, the value of its capital will decline.
This will likely reduce the spending behavior of the agent and thereby also the income
and asset values of other agents. Moreover, if the loss in asset values were sufficiently
large to exceed an agent’s capital (net worth), it would cause the agent to default on
its debt obligations. This, in turn, will reduce the values of assets on the balance sheet
of the agent’s creditors and ignite a chain reaction of either or both reduced spending
and/or defaults.
Losses to shareholders are generally viewed as less serious than losses to
creditors, who are assumed more risk averse and often consider themselves not fully
compensated for any losses they may experience.

This is particularly true for

depositors, who generally view these funds as the safest and most liquid component
of their wealth portfolios. Thus their "hurt" is greater and their response in rearranging
their portfolios to avoid further losses is more severe. It should be noted that defaults
lead primarily to redistributions in wealth rather than to aggregate reductions, as the
creditor’s loss is the debtor’s gain.
offsetting.




But the economic impacts are unlikely to be

The consequences of the losses outweigh those of the gains.

Because

11
economies are systems, systemic risk is a constant and continuing problem in all
sectors of the economy.8
Because of their continuous lending to and borrowing from each other and their
need to pay other banks for third-party transfers, banks tend to be more tightly
financially interconnected with each other than are most other types of firms. Thus,
banks appear to be particularly susceptible to systemic risk, and shocks at any one
bank are likely to be quickly transmitted to other banks, which in turn will transmit the
shock down the remaining chain of banks. The adverse cumulative effects of the initial
shock are intensified because bank deposits make up the larger part of a country’s
money supply. Thus, ceteris paribus, losses to depositors from shocks that reduce
asset values sufficiently to drive banks into insolvency cause equivalent reductions in
the stock of money.

As a result, these depositors are likely to cut back on their

spending by more than they would for an equal dollar reduction in other, less liquid
forms of wealth. Such cutbacks will, in turn, reduce the income of other agents and
thereby also their spending.9
Absent deposit insurance protection, most bank depositors are well aware of the
unique fragility of banks.

If they perceive a shock to their bank or banks to be

sufficiently great to threaten the solvency of those banks, they are likely to withdraw
their deposits in anticipation of a default by the banks. Banks must sell assets quickly
to pay these depositors, so that such a run is likely to lead to liquidity problems and
fire-sale losses, which would both accelerate and intensify the transmission of the
shock. Of course, for a given adverse shock, the greater capital a bank has, the less
likely is it to default. In the absence of full deposit insurance, bank customers are thus




12
motivated to encourage their banks to hold sufficient capital to avoid default from
adverse shocks originating at other banks.
Runs occur in response to an actual or perceived default by a bank and, while
they may hasten the transmission to other banks, they generally do not ignite the initial
shock (Miskin, 1991). The poor financial state of the bank is unlikely to have started
with the run. Although popular in folklore, history provides little evidence that liquidity
problems caused by runs drove economically solvent banks into insolvency (Benston
and Kaufman, 1995; Calomiris and Gorton, 1991). The effects of a run on the bank,
other banks, and the macroeconomy will depend on the running depositors’ perception
of the financial solvency of other banks (Benston, Eisenbeis, et al, 1986).

If they

perceive some other banks in the system to be solvent and redeposit at those
institutions, the effect of the run in terms of aggregate impact will be relatively small.
There will be no or only little change in aggregate bank deposits or credit.

Some

adverse effects will be suffered by customers whose relationships with their banks
might be changed or terminated, but, as discussed earlier, this is no different from the
costly effects of any firm failure, and does not make bank failure a special public policy
concern.
However, if running depositors do not perceive any bank in their market area to
be safe, they may flee into safe nonbank securities, most likely those of the federal
government. Ownership of the deposit is transferred to the seller of the securities and
the implications depend on what he/she does with the deposit. If the seller perceives
a bank in his/her market area to be sufficiently financially secure, as is likely to be the
case for the seller to sell the safe security, the funds will be redeposited at that bank.




13
Again, there are no changes in either aggregate bank deposits or credit, only a
redistribution of the banks holding the deposits. Adverse effects, however, may be
somewhat greater than in the earlier direct redeposit scenario. Not only may some bank
customer relationships deteriorate, but the initial shift to government securities will bid
up the prices and lower the interest rates on public securities relative to private
securities. This may redirect investment from private to public sectors.
Moreover, if the perceived safe bank is located in a foreign country and the
deposit is denominated in domestic currency, the first country’s exchange rates will
depreciate if the running depositor or receiving bank do not wish to hold the funds in
that country’s currency.

The importance of this impact depends on the size and

international openness of the country. For large countries, neither effect is likely to be
sufficiently important to justify special public policy concern.

For smaller, open

countries, however, the percentage of deposits fleeing abroad is likely to be larger and
the depreciation in their exchange rates is likely to be more important.

If such a

country attempts to offset the decline, it will run down its holdings of foreign reserves.
To the extent the central bank cannot offset the impact of this loss on bank reserves,
the country will experience a contraction in its money supply.

Thus, for smaller

countries, a run or a threat of a run to banks in other countries is more likely to be a
special public policy concern. However, the magnitude of any exchange rate effect is
reduced to the extent that the fleeing deposits were denominated in foreign currency,
as is likely in many smaller countries.
If neither the running depositors nor the sellers of the government securities
perceive any bank in any country to be sufficiently sound to warrant a redeposit, then




14

there will be a flight to currency.

The increase in currency held by the public will,

unless offset by the central bank, reduce aggregate bank reserves and ignite a multiple
contraction in bank assets and deposits. In the process, fire-sale losses will be greater
and bank failures more frequent. Systemic problems are likely to occur. Indeed, it is
a depositor run to currency that enlarges fire-sale losses and is likely to produce the
major adverse effects generally perceived to result from widespread bank failures. In
this scenario, banking becomes a special public policy concern.

IV Public Policy Remedies
What can public policy do to mitigate the likelihood and severity of systemic risk
in banking?

There are three basic options.10

One, policy can be directed at

increasing macroeconomic stability and avoiding first abrupt increases and then
declines (bubbles) in asset values and defaults.

Such instability has been a major

cause of bank failures (Schwartz, 1988 and Goodhart, 1995, particularly chapter 14).
Unfortunately,

history has amply demonstrated that our current knowledge of

macroeconomics is far short of what is required to achieve such results consistently.
Two, discretionary powers can be delegated to bank regulatory agencies to provide a
safety net under banks to prevent both undue fire-sale losses from hurried asset sales
by banks from affecting depositors and runs on the banking system into currency that
exacerbate such losses. As noted earlier in this paper, it appears highly unlikely that
such agencies, e.g. the Federal Reserve and FDIC in the U.S., can do much better in
the future than they have in the past in avoiding serious agency problems for
themselves and moral hazard behavior by banks.




15

Three, policy can be directed at avoiding the pitfalls of excessively discretionary
and incentive incompatible prudential policies and focus directly on the cause of both
losses to depositors in bank insolvencies and depositor runs on banks, namely
economic insolvency with negative net worth at banks. Such a policy would attempt
to reduce, if not eliminate, both moral hazard behavior by banks and agency problems
by regulators by properly aligning the incentives of all parties in the same and
appropriate direction. The incentive for banks to engage in moral hazard behavior can
be reduced by requiring sufficient capital and imposing a series of sanctions in the form
of structured early intervention or prompt corrective action on troubled banks that mimic
the sanctions imposed by the private market on troubled noninsured bank competitors
in an attempt to have the banks reverse direction before insolvency.

The ability of

regulators to incur principal-agent problems is reduced by having them be required to
impose these sanctions on troubled institutions and to resolve a bank which was not
turned around by these sanctions through recapitalization by current shareholders, sale,
merger, or liquidation before its capital could be totally depleted and losses imposed
on depositors. The best way to reduce the costs of bank insolvencies to "innocent"
third parties is to restrict them solely to shareholders, who may be expected to be more
aware of the risks and be compensated for them more commensurately. Many of the
parts of such a structured early intervention and least cost resolution (SEIR) program
are included in the prudential prompt corrective action and least cost resolution
provisions of the FDIC Improvement Act (FDICIA) enacted in the U.S. atyearend 1991
(Benston and Kaufman, 1988, 1994a; Benston, Brumbaugh, etal, 1989; Carnell, 1992;
Shadow Financial Regulatory Committee, 1989).




16

Briefly, SEIR focuses on:
1.

Explicit full government deposit insurance for "small" depositors.

Full

insurance would be provided up to a specified maximum amount per account and no
insurance would be provided above that amount. The precise amount at which to cap
the insurance is difficult to establish theoretically, but should be near the level that
depositors with larger amounts may be expected to have other investments that require
the ability, knowledge, and experience to evaluate credit worthiness and may be widely
expected to bear losses without much public sympathy and are unlikely to be able to
conduct their business in currency and therefore run into currency rather than to other
banks. These depositors would not only not be protected by deposit insurance, but
would be expected to monitor and discipline their banks through market forces and
thereby supplement regulatory discipline.

Explicit full deposit insurance for small

depositors is desirable, because a) social externalities exist in providing a safe
depository in the intermediation process for funds owned by agents for whom the costs
of financial analysis of private banks outweigh the benefits, b) these depositors are the
most likely to run into currency and threaten systemic problems, and c) insurance for
such depositors is a political reality in almost all countries and explicit guarantees are
more likely than implicit guarantees to avoid political battling when a failure does occur,
which generally will result in the government providing full coverage and signal the
willingness of the government to retreat in the face of pressure. (Kaufman, 1995c).
2.

Capital levels on banks that are equal to those that the private market

expects noninsured bank competitors to maintain in the particular country (Kaufman,
1992). Thus, banks would increase their self-insurance to more market determined




17

levels.11
3.

A system of graduated regulatory sanctions imposed on banks as their

performance deteriorates through a series of zones (tranches or tripwires) that
resemble the sanctions imposed by market forces on noninsured firms through bond
covenants

and creditor negotiation.12

These sanctions

are explicit,

publicly

announced, and become progressively harsher and more mandatory as the financial
condition of the bank deteriorates through the tranches. (The sanctions introduced
under FDICIA and the capital levels defining each tranche are shown in Table 1.)
4.

An explicit, publicly announced "closure rule" requiring the regulators to

promptly resolve troubled institutions before their net worths decline below some low
but positive critical level. The critical cutoff value of the capital-to-asset ratio should be
sufficiently high so that, in the absence of large-scale fraud and unusually abrupt
declines in market values on a diversified set of earning assets, no losses are suffered
by depositors or the deposit insurance agency. Losses from bank insolvencies are thus
effectively restricted to bank shareholders and deposit insurance becomes effectively
redundant.
5.

Risk-based deposit insurance premiums both to discourage banks from

assuming excessive risk and to prevent less risky banks from cross-subsidizing riskier
banks.

Because the closure rule should minimize losses to the insurance agency,

overall premiums to be charged insured banks would be low and necessary only to
cover these small losses and to finance operating costs.
6.

Market or current value accounting, so that economic values rather than

historical or book values are the basis for decisions by bank customers, bank




18
managers, and regulators.

This would also make for greater disclosure and

transparency and increase the accountability of both banks and their regulators.
Although all parts of the SEIR scheme contribute to its effectiveness, the key
provision is the firm and explicit "closure rule," which effectively makes deposit
insurance redundant.13

Indeed, no deposit insurance structure is effective in

minimizing the costs from failures unless it includes such a rule. The prompt corrective
actions increase the effectiveness of the closure rule by progressively increasing the
cost to financially deteriorating banks of "gambling for resurrection" as they approach
the closure capital ratio. The program must be compulsory for all banks in order that
no banks remain implicitly insured.
The scheme operates more effectively if capital were measured relative to total
assets -- the leverage ratio -- rather than to risk-based assets. This is not because the
amount of capital that a bank is required to maintain by the market is not related to its
riskiness, but because the necessary information appears to be too difficult to be
incorporated accurately in the risk classifications adopted by the regulators. The risk
classifications and weights adopted by the regulators to date have been arbitrary,
incomplete, insufficiently reflective of the riskiness of the bank as a whole as opposed
to individual activities, and modified to pursue political and social objectives.

As a

result, they provide distorted incentives, which differ significantly from those the market
imposes, and encourage arbitrage within risk classifications (Williams, 1995). Capital
should also be defined to include all bank liabilities that are subordinated to bank
depositors and the deposit insurance agency and are not in a position to run. Thus,
bank capital should give full weight to nonperpetual preferred stock and subordinated




19
debt with maturities of, say, one year or longer, as well as to equity.
The benefits of a system of SEIR are substantial.

In contrast to most

government-provided deposit insurance schemes, this structure is both incentive
compatible, so that all involved parties row in the same and appropriate direction, and
market oriented, so that regulatory discipline is reinforced by that of de facto as well as
de jure uninsured depositors.

No institution would be "too big to fail" in terms of

protecting uninsured depositors, shareholders, or senior management. By providing a
number of triggers for regulatory intervention rather than only one, the progressivity of
severity of the sanctions will be more moderate and both the likelihood and credibility
of intervention by the regulators increased. Moreover, because losses to the insurance
agency are no longer a major concern, banks could be permitted to engage in a wide
range of activities, at least with respect to prudential concerns. The permissibility of the
activities would be judged on the ability of the regulators to monitor their values
accurately and timely for purposes of prompt corrective action and resolution. It follows
that more difficult to monitor activities could be permitted banks with higher capital
ratios. This would provide incentives for banks to improve their capital positions and
introduce carrots as well as sticks in the structure. Banks would be risking their own
private capital rather than that of the insurance agency.
SEIR creates an environment that provides the best of both the insured and
uninsured worlds. It yields the benefits of government deposit insurance in preventing
runs on the banking system without its well known adverse moral hazard and agency
problems. SEIR deals effectively with the potential for banks to engage in moral hazard
behavior both by progressively increasing the cost to banks of declining to capital levels




20
that encourage such behavior and by resolving near-insolvent banks quickly so that
they do not get much time or second and third chances to gamble for resurrection. The
agency problem is reduced by requiring more mandatory sanctions to be imposed by
the regulators if the banks fail to respond to the discretionary sanctions that the
regulators may have imposed earlier when the bank’s financial condition first began to
deteriorate. The scheme also reduces the need for intrusive prudential regulation and
micro-management.

All that is required is a posting of the "rules of the game,"

including the discretionary and mandatory sanctions, effective and timely monitoring,
and timely imposition of the required sanctions by the regulators, including least cost
resolution.
If structured correctly, for any given degree of macroeconomic instability, SEIR
should reduce the probability of individual bank failure, the cost of failure to depositors,
other bank customers, and the community, and, by reducing if not eliminating depositor
losses and the need for depositors to run on their banks, also the likelihood of systemic
risk.14 The greater the macroeconomic instability in a country, the higher would have
to be the relevant capital ratios for prompt corrective action and resolution to achieve
these objectives.
policy.

By itself, SEIR is not a substitute for stabilizing macroeconomic

Although reducing the likelihood of failure, the scheme does not eliminate

failure, only the cost of failure to depositors and other creditors. Thus, the exit of poorly
performing banks, which is required in any efficient industry, is not affected.

Banks

would no longer be unique and different from other firms because of any perceived or
actual greater adverse impact of their failure and therefore no longer warrant specific
public policy concern for prudential reasons.




Restrictions on bank product and

21
geographic powers that may nave been imposed for prudential reasons may be
removed and banks subject only to those public policies applied to other industries
(Benston and Kaufman, 1996).

V Systemic Risk and the Payments System
As noted earlier, banks are closely interconnected not only by depositing funds
with each other and lending to and borrowing from each other (interbank balances), but
also by making and receiving funds transfers from each other in the process of clearing
payments due to or from other banks (interbank transfers). Because such transfers are
frequently in very large amounts, are processed almost immediately, and are highly
concentrated among a few large participating banks, the impact of defaults is more
likely to spread quickly to other banks participating in the clearing process and is
considered particularly disruptive as it may cause at least temporary gridlock in the
payments system.
Defaults in the payments clearing process can occur when the payment and
receipt of funds are not simultaneous, so that funds are disbursed before they are
received. As a result, credit is extended by one party to another. In generic modern
interbank clearing systems, payment for individual transactions may be made to other
banks, generally electronically by wire transfer, at the time delivery is made, but final
settling of net outstanding balances at each participating bank is not made until dayend.
Thus, for example, a bank may accept delivery of previously purchased securities,
either for themselves or their customers, in midday and pay for them at that time even
though it may not have the necessary funds on deposit at the clearing facility at the




22
time. An intraday or daylight overdraft occurs. The bank anticipates having sufficient
funds in its account at dayend through scheduled inflows to settle the overdraft, but
these inflows are not certain and may not occur. If they do not and the resulting losses
exceed a bank’s capital, the bank will default on its obligations to other banks.
Because the same funds may be transferred a number of times among banks before
dayend settlement, in case of default, these transfers must be reversed in order to
identify who owes whom what. This process is costly, time consuming, and disruptive.
Moreover, because the unwinding may result in losses that could cause other banks
to default, so that losses cascade through the banking system, the payments system
is commonly viewed as a source of systemic risk (Eisenbeis, 1995; Flannery, 1988;
Baer et al, 1991; Humphrey, 1987; Juncker et al, 1991; Summers, 1994).
To reduce the severity of such disruptions from default, some clearing systems
guarantee or provide finality for each individual funds transfer as it occurs. The costs
of later, dayend defaults are then borne by the sponsors of the clearing facility (house).
Such finality is more credible when the facility is operated by a government agency,
e.g., the central bank, than by private entities, e.g., private banks.

In the U.S., an

example of the first type of facility is Fedwire, operated by the Federal Reserve, and
of the second type is CHIPS, operated by large New York City banks. Clearings on
Fedwire are thus free of systemic risk.
Except for larger and more concentrated exposures, the credit risk assumed by
banks in the clearing process is little different from that assumed by them in any
transaction.

Thus, basically the same techniques for reducing this exposure apply.

The bank needs to know and monitor its counterparties, require margin when




23
necessary, impose maximum loan limits, and charge a commensurately high interest
rate on any credit extension. The bank’s own risk of default is reduced by maintaining
sufficient capital in light of its overdraft exposures.

The bank may also delegate some

of these decisions to the clearing house.
Until recently, the Federal Reserve did little to encourage banks to be greatly
concerned about daylight overdrafts in their use of Fedwire.

Because all payments

were guaranteed by the Fed when made, the risk of default was borne only by the Fed.
The Fed neither charged for daylight overdrafts nor applied bank limits on their use.
Since the early 1990s, the Fed has both charged for and limited the use of these
overdrafts, but it has been reluctant to impose market-based charges for fear of losing
business to competing payments systems. Thus, similar to the government guarantees
on bank deposits, as structured, the Federal Reserve guarantees on payments system
transfers in the U.S. appear to encourage risk taking by the banks.
Similarly to losses from bank failures for other reason, the probability of a default
by a bank and the magnitude of any resulting loss to other banks and parties from the
payment system is reduced greatly if not eliminated by an appropriately designed SEIR
structure. But, because of the large amounts, quick transfers, and high concentrations,
additional precautions may be warranted to protect both the payments system itself and
banks from defaults in the clearing process.

This may be done by permitting only

simultaneous payments and receipts, or payments only in "good funds." This would
eliminate the need for net settlement at dayend. Because almost all clearing facilities
now have the ability to monitor in real time, such clearings are likely to be neither
excessively costly nor disruptive relative either to the cost and disruption from defaults




24

or to the long-run cost of providing an inappropriately designed safety net. Alternatively,
market determined intraday interest rates may be charged for daylight overdrafts,
maximum loan limits established for each bank, collateral required against debit
positions, and participants in the clearing process subject to minimum capital
requirements determined by the clearing house (Benston, 1994). To the extent the
operator of the clearing facility is the government, the principal-agent problems
discussed earlier are likely to exist so that appropriate measures to deter private
defaults may not be imposed and resulting losses socialized.

This suggests that

economic welfare is enhanced if the clearing facility is private and its sponsoring banks
subject to the provisions of SEIR.
A similar but more difficult problem to solve arises if payments are settled in
different clearing facilities when settlement dayend is not at the same time at each
facility. This is particularly likely for clearing facilities in different countries in different
time zones. This problem was responsible for losses to some U.S. banks in 1974 when
the Herstatt Bank in Germany failed and was closed by the German authorities after
payment was made to it by U.S. banks at dayend in marks on the German clearing
house but before it could make payments to U.S. banks at dayend in dollars in New
York, which was later the same day.

Because this problem cuts across different

national sovereignties and thus laws, its solution is more difficult and requires
coordination among the clearing facilities and respective governments.

But as

international markets evolve towards 24-hour operations, clearing in only good funds
becomes increasingly feasible.




25

VI Conclusions
The evidence suggests that banks fail. But so do other firms. Bank failures are
costly to their owners, customers, and some third parties. But so are the failures of
other firms. To the extent that failures reflect market forces, public policies to prevent
exit harm other economic agents, such as competitors and those who will benefit from
entry, including consumers of banking services. Nevertheless, bank failures are widely
perceived to be more damaging to the economy because of the belief that they are
more likely to spill over to other banks and beyond. Thus, almost all countries have
imposed special prudential regulations on banks to prevent or mitigate such adverse
effects.
This paper argues that these policies (both regulations and institutions) have
frequently been incentive incompatible and counterproductive and have unintentionally
introduced both moral hazard behavior by the banks and principal-agent problems by
the regulators that have intensified the risk and costs of banking breakdowns. In the
absence of such anti-systemic risk regulations, the greater fragility of banks did not
often translate into greater failures nor did the payments system necessarily introduce
greater risk for the banks. Indeed, the two periods of by far the largest number and
greatest cost of bank failures in U.S. history occurred after the introduction of policies
intended specifically to reduce cascading failures. The first occurred in 1929-1933,
twenty years after the introduction of the Federal Reserve System.

The second

occurred in the 1980s, fifty years after the introduction of the FDIC to supplement the
Fed.

This suggests that bank instability is more a regulatory phenomenon than a

market phenomenon. As Schwartz (1995) has noted, omitting the government as a




26

cause of instability in banking in a play about systemic risk is like omitting the Prince
of Denmark from the first act of Hamlet
Although systemic risk may exist without government regulation, on net, the
probability of instability occurring in banking and the intensity of any resulting damage
are likely to be greatly increased by some government policies adopted in the name of
preventing systemic risk. This conclusion is not unique to banking. For example, just
as governments may reduce the monetary damage from floods by providing information
about water levels to threatened home owners, they may simultaneously increase the
damage by providing flood insurance and encouraging the home owners to build and
rebuild in flood plains.

The latter adverse affect is likely to dominate the former

beneficial effect.15 A similar conclusion was reached by the late Fischer Black, who
noted that:
When you hear the government talking about systemic risk, hold on to
your wallet! It means they want you to pay more taxes to pay for more
regulations, which are likely to create systemic risk by interfering with private
contracting....ln sum, when you think about systemic risks, you’ll be close to the
truth if you think of the government as causing them rather than protecting us
from them. (Black, 1995, p.8).

Governments appear to face a tradeoff between two types of banking problems—
systemic risk from the failure of one or more banks and non-systemic bank failures from
excessive risk-taking and inadequate regulatory discipline. They first problem may be
solved by introducing a safety net in the form of government deposit insurance and/or
central bank lender of last resort. But, if poorly designed or implemented, this solution
is likely to exacerbate the second problem. Thus, the governments appear to have a
no-win choice.




But the evidence, at least for the U.S., is quite clear.

The cost of

27
systemic risk before the introduction of the safety net under banking in 1914 was far
smaller than the cost of bank failures since then.
The counterproductive prudential policies have been imposed more in response
to perceptions of systemic risk and "horror stories" in the popular press than in
response to empirical evidence by public policy-makers, who were responding to public
outcries and were highly risk-averse.

Similar to nuclear plant accidents, even if the

probability of systemic risk in banking was very low, if it ever did occur, the expected
losses would be very great, and reflect poorly on government officials and regulators.
Moreover, through time, the regulators have developed a vested interest in maintaining
and even expanding prudential regulations designed to combat systemic risk as they
have become aware of the public prestige and power these regulations bestowed on
them as protectors of society from financial collapse. In recent years, regulators have
been among the most vociferous expositors and prophets of the dangers of systemic
risk.16
The best protection against widespread bank failures and systemic risk is
macroeconomic policies that achieve stability and avoid price bubbles which leave
banks highly vulnerable to failure.

But since the success of such policies is highly

questionable, backup prudential policy is desirable.

This paper argues that it is

possible to reduce both the likelihood and costs of future bank failures as well as any
resulting systemic problems without suffering the undesirable side-effects of moral
hazard and agency problems that plague many prudential policies.

This can be

achieved by introducing an effective system of structured early intervention and
resolution (SEIR). This system is both incentive compatible and market oriented. Bank




failures would be reduced but not eliminated, so that inefficient institutions can exit the
industry. The key feature of the scheme is a "closure rule" that resolves banks before
their own capital is fully depleted and thereby effectively restricts losses only to
shareholders. Explicit full deposit insurance is provided for smaller accounts to prevent
systemic risk, but becomes effectively redundant. Because uninsured depositors suffer
only small if any losses in bank insolvencies, the major transmission process of
systemic risk is not activated and failures of individual banks will not spill over to others.
Bank runs, even on individual banks, are far less likely than in a system without a
closure rule. A system of SEIR, although in weakened form, has been included in the
U.S. in the prompt corrective action and least cost resolution provisions of FDICIA.
Whether it will prevent repeats of the bank holocausts of the 1930s and 1980s for the
same degree of macroeconomic instability depends on how closely the regulators
enforce the intent of the provisions.




29
ENDNOTES
1.

Some argue that not only banks but all financial firms are potential sources of
systemic risk. For example, in their study of capital requirements for securities
firms, Dimson and Marsh (1994, p. 3) note that
Implicitly, competition between non-financial firms is assumed to generate
an appropriate set of capital structures, and the costs of financial distress
are an integral part of their decision process. Most countries take a
different line when it comes to financial businesses, however. The
systemic costs of default...have persuaded regulatory authorities to
impose minimum capital requirements.
See also Davis (1992).

2.

Gerald Corrigan, former President of the New York Federal Reserve Bank, has
noted that
More than anything else, it is the systemic risk phenomenon associated
with banking and financial institutions that makes them different from gas
stations and furniture stores. It is this factor —more than any other -- that
constitutes the fundamental rationale for the safety net arrangements that
have evolved in this and other countries (Corrigan, 1991, p.3).

3.

Although not the subject of this paper, credit allocation schemes, which have
been a major cause of bank insolvencies, particularly at state banks, in many
developing and traditional economies, are not possible without a government
safety net that removes the concern of depositors. Indeed, credit allocation in
favor of residential housing in the form of encouraging long-term fixed rate
mortgage loans funded by short-term deposits was a major cause of the savings
and loan debacle in the U.S. in the 1980s (Kane, 1989; Kaufman, 1995a).

4.

Alternative definitions are developed in Bartholomew and Whalen, 1995. The
importance of defining systemic risk accurately has recently been emphasized
by Alan Greenspan, Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, when he noted that




It would be useful to central banks to be able to measure systemic risk
accurately, but its very definition is still somewhat unsettled.
It is
generally agreed that systemic risk represents a propensity for some sort
of significant financial system disruption. Nevertheless, after the fact, one
observer might use the term "market failure" to describe what another
would deem to have been a market outcome that was natural and healthy,
even if harsh....Until we have a common theoretical paradigm for the
causes of systemic stress, any consensus of how to measure systemic
risk will be difficult to achieve (Greenspan, 1995, p. 7).

30

5.

The bank failure rate and losses may be somewhat understated as brief
suspensions of convertibility are not included in either calculation.

6.

Much of the general public qonsiders the government to be the ultimate
guarantor of nearly all financial transactions, regardless of the size or type of
transaction. In his analysis of the Daiwa Bank’s problems in the U.S., a wellknown U.S. economic columnist, writing in the Washington Post, has noted that
Financial markets (banking, the trading of securities) depend upon trust
and confidence. Hundreds of billions of dollars of daily transactions occur
on nothing more than a phone call or a computer key....In part, trust rests
on faith that government regulators will supervise the complex payments
system and police for fraud and financial failure (Samuelson, 1995).
Likewise, another Washington Post columnist ended his column on deposit
insurance, the troubled Bank of New England (which failed shortly thereafter)
and why he did not join the "irrational" run, by noting
So my account is still at the Bank of New England. And my money is still
at the FDIC (Kuttner, 1991).
Even some bankers do not believe that depositors should look only to their
banks for safety.
In criticizing the banking agencies’ proposed capital
requirements for market risk, the American Banker reported that Jill Considine,
President of the New York Clearing House Association, argued that
These
standards
are "unnecessarily
rigid and
extremely
conservative"....The market risk rules should be used to "protect banks
against normal market risks in their portfolios, [not] as a tool to protect the
banking system against systemic risk" (Fox, 1995).

7.

An exception is Davis (1992).

8.

A more complete listing of alternative paths along which systemic risk may travel
appears in Schwartz (1995).

9.

The impact of the reduced money supply may be offset by deposit expansion by
solvent banks that now have excess reserves or by the central bank through the
injection of additional reserves.

10.

All these options assume that the banks in the country start with a positive net
worth or if not have, at minimum, a schedule for regaining positive net worth.
These policy options do not deal with the issue of who pays for any negative net
worth that banks may have -- depositors, positively capitalized banks, taxpayers,
or some other party. This is as much a political problem as an economic
problem and the basis for much poor macroeconomic policy as many




31

governments assume responsibility for the negative net worths and monetize this
addition to their deficits.
11.

Merton (1995) identifies three ways for banks to reduce their risk exposures; 1)
hedging, 2) insuring with others, and 3) capital cushion. SEIR is not well
designed for banking systems in countries in which a large number of banks
have large negative capital and are not on a specific and meaningful schedule
for recapitalization to positive capital levels or in which state-owned banks are
subject to different regulation than private banks (Kaufman, 1995c).

12.

The effectiveness of private market sanctions in reducing moral hazard behavior
on non-insured nonbank firms is examined by DeAngelo and DeAngelo (1990).

13.

The need to maintain some government deposit insurance but to prevent its
associated adverse effects through capital requirements, increased monitoring,
and so on is also the conclusion reached by Davis, 1992. See also Flannery,
1995.

14.

Unfortunately, the prompt corrective action and least cost resolution provisions
of FDICIA as well as the implementing regulations were weakened by Congress
and, particularly, the regulators both before and after the Act was enacted so
that failure and losses will be larger than necessary. In particular, the numerical
values for the capital tripwires are set too low (Benston and Kaufman, 1994b).

15.

This example is motivated by that of Merton (1995, p.37).

16.

For example, John LaWare, former Governor of the Federal Reserve System,
testified before Congress when he was Governor that
It is systemic risk that failed to be controlled and stopped at the inception
that is a nightmare condition, unfair to everybody. The only analogy that
I can think of for the failure of a major international institution of great size
is a meltdown of a nuclear generating plant like Chernobyl.
The ramifications of that kind of failure are so broad and happen with
such lightning speed that you cannot after the fact control them. It runs
the risk of bringing down other banks, corporations, disrupting markets,
bringing down investment banks along with it.... We are talking about the
failure that could disrupt the whole system. (La Ware, 1991, p.34).
Similarly, C.T. Conover, who was Comptroller of the Currency at the time of the
Continental Illinois National Bank failure in 1984, testified in Congress at the time
that




[H]ad Continental failed and been treated in a way in which depositors
and creditors were not made whole, we could very well have seen a




32

national, if not an international, financial crisis, the dimensions of which
were difficult to imagine. None of us wanted to find out. (Conover, 1991,
p.288).

33

REFEREN CES
Baer, Herbert L. et al, in George G. Kaufman, ed., Research in Financial Services. Vol.
3, Greenwich, Ct.: JAI Press, 1991. (Four articles on the U.S. and Swiss clearing
systems.)
Baer, Herbert L. and Daniela Klingebiel, "Systemic Risk When Depositors Bear Losses"
in George G. Kaufman, Ed., Research in Financial Services. Vol. 7, Greenwich, Ct.:
JAI Press, 1995 (forthcoming).
Bartholomew, Philip F. and Gary W. Whalen, "Fundamentals of Systemic Risk" in
George G. Kaufman, ed., Research in Financial Services. Vol. 7, Greenwich, CT:
JAI Press, 1995 (forthcoming).
Benston, George J., "International Harmonization of Banking Regulations," Journal of
Financial Services Research. September 1994, pp. 205-225.
Benston, George J., R. Dan Brumbaugh, Jr., Jack M. Guttentag, Richard J. Herring,
George G. Kaufman, Robert E. Litan, and Kenneth E. Scott, Blueprint for
Restructuring America’s Financial Institutions. Washington, D.C.:
Brookings
Institution, 1989.
Benston, George J., Robert A. Eisenbeis, Paul M. Horvitz, Edward J. Kane, and
George G. Kaufman, Perspectives on Safe and Sound Banking. Cambridge, Ma.:
MIT Press, 1986.
Benston, George J. and George G. Kaufman, Risk and Solvency Regulation of
Depository Institutions: Past Policies and Current Options. New York; Salomon
Brothers Center, Graduate School of Business, New York University, 1988.
Benston, George J. and George G. Kaufman, "The Intellectual History of the Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act of 1991," in George G. Kaufman,
ed., Reforming financial Institutions and Markets in the United States. Boston:
Kluwer, 1994a, pp. 1-17.
Benston, George J. and George G. Kaufman, "Improving the FDIC Improvement Act"
in George G. Kaufman, ed., Reforming Financial Institutions and Markets in the
United States. Boston: Kluwer, 1994b., pp. 99-120.
Benston, George J. and George G. Kaufman, "Is the Banking and Payments System
Fragile," Journal of Financial Services Research. September/December 1995
(forthcoming).




34

Benston, George J. and George G. Kaufman, "The Appropriate Role of Bank
Regulation," Economic Journal. May 1996 (forthcoming).
Black, Fischer, "Hedging, Speculation, and Systemic Risk," Journal of Derivatives.
Summer 1995, pp. 6-8.
Calomiris, Charles W. and Gary Gorton, "The Origins of Banking Panics" in R. Glenn
Hubbard, ed., Financial Markets and Financial Crises. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 1991, pp. 109-173.
Caprio, Gerard, Jr. and Daniela Klingebiel, "Dealing with Bank Insolvencies:
Country Experience," Working Paper, World Bank, 1995.

Cross

Carnell, Richard S., "A Partial Antidote to Perverse Incentives: Implementing the FDIC
Improvement Act of 1991," Rebuilding Public Confidence Through Financial Reform.
Columbus, Oh.: College of Business, Ohio State University, June 1992, pp. 31-51.
Conover, C.T., "Testimony" in Inouirv Into the Continental Illinois Corp. and Continental
Illinois National Bank: Hearing Before the Subcommittee on Financial Institutions
Supervision. Regulation, and Insurance of the Committee on Banking. Finance and
Urban Affairs (98-111), U.S. House of Representatives, 98th Cong., 2nd Sess.,
September 18, 19 and October 4, 1984.
Corrigan, Gerald E., "The Banking-Commerce Controversy Revisited," Quarterly
Review. (Federal Reserve Bank of New York), Spring 1991, pp.1-13.
Davis, E.P., Debt. Financial Fragility, and Systemic Risk. Oxford: Oxford University
Press, 1992.
DeAngelo, Harry and Linda DeAngelo, "Dividend Policy and Financial Distress" Journal
of Finance. December 1990, pp. 1415-1431.
Dimson, Elroy and Paul Marsh, The Debate on International Capital Reouirements (City
Research Project Working Paper), London: London Business School, February
1994.
Eisenbeis, Robert A., "Private Sector Solutions to Payment System Fragility," Journal
of Financial Services Research. September/December 1995 (forthcoming).
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, 1994 Annual Report. Washington, D.C., 1995.
Flannery, Mark J., "Payments System Risk and Public Policy," in William S. Haraf and
Rose Marie Kushmeider, eds., Restructuring Banking and Financial Services in
America. Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute, 1988, pp. 261-287.




35

Flannery, Mark J., "Prudential Regulation for Banks" in Kuniho Sawamoto, Zenta
Nakajima, and Hiroo Taguichi, eds., Financial Stability in a Changing Environment.
New York: St. Martin’s Pres.s 1995, pp. 281-318.
Friedman, Milton and Anna J. Schwartz, A Monetary History of the United States. 19671960. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1963.
Fox, Justin, "Banks Say Too Much Capital Required by Market Risk Rules," American
Banker. September 22, 1995, p. 3.
Goodhart, C.A.E., The Central Bank and the Financial System. Cambridge, Ma: MIT
Press, 1995.
Garcia, Gillian, "Comparing and Confronting Recent Banking Problems in Foreign
Countries," Working Paper, IMF, 1995.
Graham, Fred C. and James E. Horner, "Bank Failure: An Evaluation of the Factors
Contributing to the Failure of National Banks" in Proceedings of a Conference on
Bank Structure and Competition. Chicago: Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 1988,
pp. 406-435.
Greenspan, Alan, "Remarks at a Conference on Risk Measurement and Systemic
Risk," Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, November
16, 1995.
Humphrey, David B., "Payments System Risk, Market Failure, and Public Policy" in
Elinor Solomon, ed., Electronic Funds Transfers and Payments. Boston: Kluwer,
1987, pp. 83-110.
Juncker, George G., Bruce J. Summers, and Florence M. Young, "A Primer on the
Settlement of Payments in the United States," Federal Reserve Bulletin. November
1991, pp.847-858.
Kane, Edward J., The Gathering Crises in Federal Deposit Insurance. Cambridge, Ma.:
MIT Press, 1985.
Kane, Edward J., The S&L Mess. Washington, D.C.: Urban Institute, 1989.
Kane, Edward J., "How Incentive-Incompatible Deposit Insurance Plans Fail," in George
G. Kaufman, ed., Research in Financial Services. Vol. 4, Greenwich, Ct.: JAI Press,
1992, pp. 51-92.




36

Kane, Edward J., "Three Paradigms for the Role of Capitalization Requirements in
Insured Financial Institutions," Journal of Banking and Finance. June 1995, pp. 431459.
Kane, Edward J., "Why and How Should Depository Institutions Be Regulated," Paper
prepared for conference at Koc University (Turkey), October 1995.
Kaufman, George G., "Capital in Banking: Past, Present and Future," Journal of
Financial Services Research. April 1992, pp. 385-402.
Kaufman, George G., "Bank Contagion: A Review of the Theory and Evidence,"
Journal of Financial Services Research. April 1994, pp. 123-150.
Kaufman, George G., "The U.S. Banking Debacle of the 1980s: An Overview and
Lessons," Financier. May 1995a, pp.9-26.
Kaufman, George G., "Comment on Systemic Risk," in George G. Kaufman, ed.,
Research in Financial Services. Vol. 7, Greenwich, Ct.: JAI Press, 1995b
(forthcoming).
Kaufman, George G., "Introducing Efficient Incentive Compatible, and Market Assigned,
Government-Provided Deposit Insurance in Less Developed Countries," Working
Paper, Loyola University, 1995c.
Lang, Larry H.D. and Rene M. Stulz, "Contagion and Competitive Inter-Industry Effects
of Bankruptcy Announcements," Journal of Financial Economics. August 1992, pp
45-60.
Kuttner, Robert, "Deposit Insurance-Now More Than Ever," Washington Post National
Weekly Edition. January 14-20, 1991, p. 29.
La Ware, John, "Testimony" in Economic Implications of the "Too Big to Fail" Policy:
Hearing Before the Subcommittee on Economic Stabilization of the Committee on
Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs. U.S. House of Representatives, 102nd Cong.,
1st Sess., May 9, 1991.
Merton, Robert C., "A Functional Perspective of Financial Intermediation," Financial
Management. Summer 1995, pp. 23-41.
Miskin, Frederic S, "Asymmetric Information and Financial Crises" in R. Glenn Hubbard,
ed., Financial Markets and Financial Crises. Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
1991, pp. 69-108.




37

Nakajima, Zenta and Hiroo Taguchi, "Toward a More Stable Financial Framework: An
Overview of Recent Bank Disruption Worldwide," in Kunito Sawamoto, Zenta
Nakajima, and Hiroo Taguchi, eds., Financial Stability in a Changing Environment.
New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1995, pp. 41-98.
O’Conner, J.F.T., Banking Crisis and Recovery Under the Roosevelt Administration.
Chicago: Callaghan and Co., 1938.
Samuelson, Robert J., "Daiwa’s Deeper Lesson," Washington Post National Weekly
Edition. November 13-19, 1995, p. 5
Schwartz, Anna J., "Financial Stability and the Federal Safety Net," in William S. Haraf
and Rose Marie Kushmeider, eds., Restructuring Banking and Financial Services
in America. Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute, 1988, pp. 34-62.
Schwartz, Anna J., "Systemic Risk and the Macroeconomy" in George G. Kaufman,
ed., Research in Financial Services. Vol. 7, Greenwich, Ct.: JAI Press, 1995
(forthcoming).
Shadow Financial Regulatory Committee, "An Outline of a Program for Deposit
Insurance and Regulatory Reform," Statement No. 41, February 13,1989 in Journal
of Financial Services Research. August 1992 supplement, pp. 578-582.
Summers, Bruce J., ed., The Payment System:
Design. Management, and
Supervision. Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund, 1994.
Williams, Michael G., "The Efficacy of Accounting-Based Bank Regulation: The Case
of the Basle Accord ," Working Paper (95-5), Milken Institute, May 1995.




Table 1
S U M M A R Y OF PROMPT CORRECTIVE ACTION PROVISIONS OF THE
FEDERAL DEPOSIT INSURANCE CORPORATION IMPROVEMENT ACT OF 1991
Capital Ratios (percent)
Risk Based
Zone

Mandatory Provisions

Discretionary Provisions

1. Well capitalized
2. Adequately capitalized

1. No brokered deposits, except with FDIC
approval

1. Suspend dividends and management
fees
2. Require capital restoration plan
3. Restrict asset growth
4. Approval required for acquisitions,
branching, and new activities
____________________________________ 5. No brokered deposits________________
3. Undercapitalized

4. Significantly undercapitalized

5. Critically undercapitalized

1. Same as for Zone 3
2. Order recapitalization*
3. Restrict inter-affiliate transactions*
4. Restrict deposit interest rates*
5. Pay of officers restricted

1.
2.
3.
4.
5.

Order recapitalization
Restrict inter-affiliate transactions
Restrict deposit interest rates
Restrict certain other activities
Any other action that would better
carry out prompt corrective action

1. Any Zone 3 discretionary actions

Leverage

Total

Tie r 1

Tie r 1

>10

>6

>5

>8

>4

>4

<8

<4

<4

<6

<3

<3

2. Conservatorship or receivership if
fails to submit or implement plan
or recapitalize pursuant to order
3. Any other Zone 5 provision, if
such action is necessary to carry
out prompt corrective action

1. Same as for Zone 4
2. Receiver/conservator within 90 days*
3. Receiver if still in Zone 5 four quarters
after becoming critically under­
capitalized
4. Suspend payments on subordinated
debt*
5. Restrict certain other activities

* Not required if primary supervisor determines action would not serve purpose of prompt corrective action or if certain other conditions are
met.
SOURCE:




Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

<2

U>
00