View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paper Series



Asset Price Fluctuation and Price Indices
Shigenori Shiratsuka

Working Papers Series
Research Department
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
June 1999 (WP-99-9)

Si

FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K
OF CHICAGO

Asset Price Fluctuation and Price Indices
Shigenori Shiratsuka
Bank of Japan and Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
shigenori.shiratsuka@boj .or.jp
June 1999
Abstract
Since the late 1980s, the Japanese economy has experienced tremendous rise and
fall of asset prices and large fluctuations of real economic activity, while general
price level has remained relatively stable. Such developments raised a question
of whether monetary policy should have targeted asset prices rather than
conventional price indices. This paper focuses on how to make use of
information inherent with asset price fluctuations in the monetary policy
judgement. To this end, it investigates the possibility of incorporating asset price
data into inflation measures by extending the conventional price index into a
dynamic framework. The main conclusion of this paper is as follows. Although
the concept of such extensions of the conventional price index is highly evaluated
from theoretical viewpoints, it is difficult for monetary policy makers to expect it
to be more than a supplementary indicator for monetary policy judgment This is
because (1) reliability of asset price statistics is quite low, compared with the
conventional price indices; and (2) asset price changes do not necessarily mean
that the future price changes because there are a lot of sources for asset price
fluctuation besides the private-sector expectation for inflation.
Keywords: Asset Price, Intertemporal cost of living index, Dynamic equilibrium
price index, Monetary policy, Information variable
JEL Classification Code: C43, E31,E52
This paper is an updated version of Shiratsuka (1996) written in Japanese. The author is a visiting
economist from the Bank of Japan at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. He is grateful to
Hiroshi Shibuya for his helpful comments to the earlier draft; to Michael Bryan, Ben Craig,
William T. Gavin, Ed Green, and seminar participants at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
Cleveland, and St. Louis for their useful comments and discussions; and to Laura Kutianski for
her assistance to. make this paper more readable. Opinions expressed are those of the author and
do not necessarily reflect those of the Bank of Japan or Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.




1. INTRODUCTION
Looking at Japan’s macroeconomic development since the late 1980s, so-called the
“bubble era,” asset prices rose and declined tremendously, and business conditions
fluctuated remarkably, while consumer and wholesale prices remained relatively stable.
Such developments raised questions of whether monetary policy should have targeted asset
prices rather than conventional price indices.1 In general, asset prices reflect market
participants’ expectations about the future, and market expectations seem to have played an
important role behind the scene of the bubble economy. Keeping this question in mind, I
examine the possibility of constructing a reliable inflation measure that includes asset price
information from the theoretical and practical viewpoints.2
As far as monetary policy tries to achieve the medium- to long-run sustainable price
stability, it is insufficient to monitor the fluctuation of the conventional price indices that
reflect only information on the current inflation.3 By contrast, asset prices provide
monetary policy makers with useful information in the sense that vividly reflects the

1 See, for example, Noguchi (1992), Suzuki (1995), Okina (1993). Matsushita (1995), the former Governor
of the Bank of Japan, stated the role of asset prices in conducting monetary policy as follows:
‘In pursuit of price stability, however, we believe that it is not appropriate to treat the stability of asset
prices, such as those of land and stocks, on the same basis as general price stability, and to include it in
the goal of monetary policy. As asset prices move in response to the private-sector expectations for
economic growth, it is impossible to establish any clear criteria, such as that zero inflation is desirable as
in the case of general prices.”
2
When we consider the problems on the relationship between asset prices and monetary policy, credit
channel is emphasized in the transmission mechanism that the fluctuation of asset prices affects the real
economic activity. In addition, it is also an important point of discussion that financial crisis often occurs as
an aftermath of significant drops in asset prices. For the issues such as the relationship between asset price
fluctuation and credit constraint, and the impact on financial system stability, see, for example, Hoshi (1996)
which surveys the recent researches on these issues.
3
See Shiratsuka (1997) for the discussion on the practical definition of price stability as an objective of
monetary policy.




I

private-sector expectation for inflation.4

Moreover, the dynamic extension of the

conventional price index concept indicates that asset prices are a desirable proxy for the
future inflation. Alchian and Klein (1973) first propose an intertemporal cost of living
index (ICLJ) to trace the intertemporal changes in the cost of living that is required to
achieve a given level of intertemporal utility. Then, Shibuya (1992) formulated the ICLI as
a practical index formula and named it the dynamic equilibrium price index (DEPI).
However, given the importance of asset price information, it difficult for monetary
policy makers to employ such inflation measures as one of the core indicators in monetary
policy judgment. This is because such inflation measures are hardly operational, since they
are too unreliable to be used in any formal assessment of the expected future course of
inflation. Therefore, monetary policy makers cannot expect asset prices to be more than
supplementary indicators of inflation pressures.5
In this context, the following two points are crucial: (1) policy implication of asset
price fluctuation differs in accordance with the sources of asset price changes; and (2)
acceptability of remarkably high weight for asset prices, suggested from the theoretical
foundation, is questionable. More precisely, asset price information is very difficult to be
interpreted as a monetary policy indicator due to the possibility of elements in asset prices

4 For the discussion on the role of asset prices as an information variable for monetary policy judgment, see
Borio et al. (1994). In addition, it should be noted the argument in Bemanke and Woodford (1997) that it is
not the case that monetary policy makers can respond mechanically to private-sector inflation forecasts, since
it leads to indeterminacy of rational expectation equilibria. However, taking conclusion of this paper in
advance, asset price information, while containing useful information on the future course of inflation and
other macroeconomic fluctuations, is too inaccurate to be adopted by monetary policy makers as a policy
target variable.
5 Goodhart (1995) and his discussants (Bockelmann, 1995; Bruni, 1995) raise a similar argument on the
feasibility of constructing a reliable inflation measure by combining the current price index and asset prices.




2

that reflect bubbles in the private-sector expectations and/or structural changes in the
economy. In addition, reliability of the current price indices is by far higher than that for
asset prices. While the current price indices are also affected by measurement errors, their
reliability is far higher than asset price statistics.6 Therefore, it seems quite difficult to
construct a reliable price index that includes asset price information.
The rest of the paper is constructed as follows. In Section 2 ,1 discuss the possibility
of incorporating asset price information into an inflation measure by extending the static
price index concept into a dynamic framework. Then, I compute the DEPI and empirically
examine the role of asset prices as an information variable for monetary policy in Section 3.
In Section 4 ,1 explore the difficulties monetary policy makers will be faced with, if such a
dynamic inflation measure that reflects the asset price fluctuations as well as the current
inflation is employed as the core indicator for monetary policy judgment In Section 5, I
discuss the optimal inflation measure for monetary policy makers. Finally, in Section 6 , 1
summarize the major results of this paper, and conclude it. In the appendices, I explain the
theoretical foundation of the dynamic price index concept, and estimate the observation
errors in the CPI with its disaggregated data.

6 Although it is true that the current price indices are also affected by measurement errors, their reliability is
far higher than asset price statistics. For the discussion on the measurement errors in the Japanese CPI, see
Shiratsuka (1998, 1999).




3

2. EXTENSION OF PRICE INDEX TO DYNAMIC F R A M E W O R K
In this section, I explore the possibility of constructing a price index that incorporates
asset price data from the theoretical viewpoints. Then, I extend the conventional price
index concept into the dynamic framework by taking into account the intertemporal
optimization of consumer behavior.
(1) Intertemporal Cost of Living index
When we discuss price indices as a measure of change in cost of living, we always
focus on the current consumption activity, and consider price indices as measures for
tracing price changes from the base period up to the current period.7 However, consumer
behavior possesses a dynamic nature so that current consumption depends closely on the
future path of consumption. Moreover, since monetary policy tries to achieve the mediumto long-run sustainable price stability, it is insufficient to monitor the fluctuation o f the
conventional price indices that reflect only information on the current inflation. Therefore,
it would be reasonable to extend the conventional price index concept into the dynamic
framework so as to trace intertemporal changes in the cost of living.

7 For the details of theoretical foundation of price indices, see, for example, Shiratsuka (1998, 1999), Poliak
(1989).




4

Alchian and Klein (1973) proposed the idea of the intertemporal cost of living index
(ICLI) that traces the intertemporal changes in the cost of living that are required to achieve
a given level of intertemporal utility.8 In this case, since price information for future goods
and services are not readily available from futures markets, an alternative measure to extract
such information must be devised. Considering the intertemporal maximization problem
for a household, its budget constraint is its lifetime income.9 If we take into account
intangible assets such as human capital as well as tangible assets, total amounts of assets
correspond to the claim to future consumption.
In this case, asset prices can be interpreted as prices of sources to purchase goods and
services in the future. In other words, we can take asset prices as a proxy for future prices
for goods and services.10 Based on such discussion, it might be the case that monetary
policy makers should take into account the fluctuation of asset prices as well as the current
price indices such as the GDP deflator and the CPI.

8 See also Goodhart (1995), Shigehara (1990), and Carlson (1989) for the discussion on the incorporation of
dynamic elements into price indices. In addition, Shiller (1993) examine the possibility of constructing
dynamic price indices from the viewpoint of providing hedging instruments against the fluctuation of asset
prices, which might affect living standards of public. Santoni and Moehring (1994) pointed out that negative
correlation between real return on asset and expected inflation rates is caused by the exclusion of dynamic
elements in the price indices.
O
Necessary condition for this discussion is that there exists a perfect capital market, which makes it possible
to borrow money with collateral of all tangible and intangible assets.
10 See Appendix 1 for the details on the theoretical foundation of the ICLI.




5

(2) Dynamic Equilibrium Price Index
Although the ICLI has good features from the theoretical perspectives, it is too
abstract to base the practical price index on it. Shibuya (1992) proposed a practical index
formula based on the ICLI, and named it a dynamic equilibrium price index (DEPI), which
incorporates dynamic elements into a realistic price index formula. To this end, Shibuya
(1992) employs a one-good and time-separable Cobb-Douglas utility function, instead of
the general form of preference assumed in Alchian and Klein (1973), to derive the DEPI as
a weighted geometric mean of the current price index (the GDP deflator) and asset price
changes (changes in the value of the national wealth)11, as shown in equation (l):12
(
DEPI =

B Y*
Po_

(

X

B
<h>

\

J l«o J

I? *

(1)

where a 0 = p/(l + p ) , and a 0 and p represent the weight for the current goods and services,
and time preference, respectively.13

*1 In calculation of the DEPI, we should use asset prices for the value of overall asset, which covers all the
intangible assets such as human capital. Shibuya (1992) used the data on national wealth in the Annual Report
on National Accounts (Economic Planning Agency), which has the broadest coverage among the readily
available data sources. However, its coverage on intangible assets, which consists largely of households’
assets, is very limited. I will discuss this point in Section 4.
12 Shibuya (1992) assumed that marginal productivity is constant over the time, in the process of derivation of
equation (1). I will discuss problems associated with this assumption in Section 4.
a Q can be written as a t = (1 + p) / XJ=o(l + P) in general form, and are the normalized factors of time
preference, which add up to one. Thus, when we calculate the DEPI on a monthly and quarterly basis, we
have to use the rate of time preference transformed into a monthly and quarterly basis.




6

3. ASSET PRICES AS A LEADING INDICATOR OF INFLATION
In this section, I compute the DEPI by following the methodology in Shibuya (1992),
and examine the information content of asset price as a leading indicator of inflation.
(1) Calculation of DEPI
I calculate the DEPI by following the methodology described in the Appendix 2 of
Shibuya (1992), where the weights for the GDP deflator and National Wealth (hereafter,
aggregate asset price index) are assumed to be 0.03 and 0.97, respectively. Figure 1 plots
the movements of the DEPI from 1957 to 1997.14
This figure shows the large divergence between the DEPI and the GDP deflator
during the late 1960s, the early and late 1970s, and the early 1980s. Focusing on the
development since the mid 1980s, the DEPI rose sharply from 1986 to 1990, while the GDP
deflator remained relatively stable, and then the growth rate of the DEPI turned negative
since 1991. During this period, inflation rate in the GDP deflator accelerated until 1991,
and the inflation rate subdued since 1992.

Such development of the DEPI might be

interpreted as an understatement of the inflationary pressure in the late 1980s and the
deflationary pressure since the early 1990s.15

14 I will discuss the appropriateness of the DEPI weights estimated in Shibuya (1992) in Section 3.
15 Shibuya (1992, 1995) pointed out that the large fluctuation of the DEPI suggested a phenomenon of
disequilibriumdynamics in the economy.




7

(2) Statistical Relationship between Asset Prices and Inflation
Next, I statistically test the hypothesis that asset prices are a leading indicator of
inflation. To this end, I conduct two types of empirical exercises.

First, I check the

Granger causality among various macroeconomic indicators, including the GDP deflator
and aggregate asset price index, with various setups of VAR models. Second, I examine the
robustness of Granger causality from asset prices to the GDP deflator over the time with
rolling regression across the full sample period.
(a) Granger causality among various setups of VAR models
First, I check the Granger causality from asset prices to inflation in various setups of
VAR models.
The variable used in the VAR models are as follows: (1) first log difference of the
GDP deflator (DLCP); (2) first log difference of the aggregate asset price index (DLAP);
(3) first log difference of real GDP (DLRY); (4) long-term interest rate (long-term prime
lending rate, LR); and (5) first log difference of M2+CD (DLNM). All the series are annual
basis, since the aggregate asset price index is available in only annual basis, and the
estimation period is from 1957 to 1997.
Using these variables, I examine the robustness of Granger causality from the
aggregate asset price index to the GDP deflator in three setups of VAR models: (1) twovariable VAR model with only the GDP deflator and aggregate asset price index; (2) fourvariable VAR model with the GDP deflator, aggregate asset price index, real GDP, and
long-term interest rate; and (3) five-variable VAR model with all the above variables. In all
three VAR models, one-year lags are chosen by the criteria of maximizing the AIC.




8

Table 1 summarizes the results for Granger causality test in three setups of VAR
models. In all cases, the aggregate asset price index Granger causes the GDP deflator at
least five percent statistically significant level. On the contrary, the GDP deflator does not
Granger cause the aggregate asset price index, except for the five-variable VAR model at 20
percent significant.
These results indicate that asset price fluctuations contain specific information about
the future price movement, suggesting that the potential usefulness of asset prices as an
information variable in Japan.
(b) Granger causality from asset price to inflation over time
Next, I conduct the second empirical exercise to check the robustness of the Granger
causality from the asset prices to the inflation over time. To this end, I conduct three types
of rolling regressions on the aforementioned five-variable VAR model with 15-year, 20year, and 25-year sample periods.
Figure 2 shows the estimation results for the Granger causality from asset prices to
inflation over time. The Granger causality from the aggregate asset price index to the GDP
deflator is highly significant in the earlier sample periods. However, it is increasingly
insignificant in the sample periods beginning at mid-1960s and later on.
This result suggests that the usefulness of asset prices as an information variable for
inflation development depends on the macroeconomic environments.

As a result, it is

important to examine the factors behind the asset price fluctuations to extract a meaningful
policy implication.




9




4. PRACTICAL P R O B L E M S IN THE DEPI
In this section, I examine the practical problems inherent to the DEPI, which make it
less attractive to employ as a target indicator.
(1) Appropriateness of Weight for Asset Prices
The weight for the current price index in the DEPI (aft) is calculated from the time
preference (/>), based on the formula of Oft = p /(1+ p ) .

Shibuya (1992) employed the

modified golden-rule (equilibrium condition of neoclassical growth model with considering
the optimization behavior of households)16 to estimate this parameter value. To put more
detail, the rate of time preference is estimated as 0.03, deducted the rate of depreciation as
0.06, the growth rate of labor as 0.01, the rate of technological progress as 0.03 from the
real return on asset as 0.13, thus implying that the weight for the current price index and the
asset prices are equal to 0.03 and 0.97, respectively.
Although the price index formula for the DEPI is the weighted geometric mean of the
current price index and asset prices, the movement of the DEPI is almost identical to that of
asset prices, because the weight for asset prices is very close to one. As a result, if the
DEPI is employed to evaluate the inflation development, it is almost equivalent to look at
the asset price movement.

16For the details of modified golden rule, see, for example, Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995).
10

Moreover, the recent estimation results for consumption CAPM suggest the
possibility of overstatement of the current inflation, even if time preference is assumed as
0.03. For example, Hamori (1996) estimated the Euler equation by assuming the general
form of time-separable utility function, and obtained that time preference (p) is around
0.01.1718 If this parameter value is employed, the weights for current price and asset price are
0.01 and 0.99, respectively. Therefore, the weight for asset prices is likely to be much
larger, since this result holds regardless of the property of the production function.
Consider how the weights for the current price index and asset prices will be affected
when the planning horizon of economic agents varies.

Table 2 shows the simulation

results. It suggests that the weights for asset prices exceed 0.9 when the planning horizon
of economic agents becomes longer than ten years, thus indicating that the impact of asset
price fluctuation becomes dominant.
From the viewpoint of supporting the DEPI, it must be reasonable that the DEPI
allocate the very large (small) weight for the asset prices (the current prices), based on the
intertemporal optimization behavior of economic agents. However, such argument misses
the critical point that reliability of asset price statistics is very low. While the current price
indices are also affected by measurement errors, their reliability is by far higher than asset
*
* * 18
price
statistics.

17

In general, time preferences are estimated as an inverse number of gross rate of time preference (l/(l +p))
in the consumption Euler equation. Estimation results with monthly data shown in Hamori (1996) range from
0.985 to 0.995. These figures correspond to the time preference of 0.01 in annual basis.
18
See Section 3 (4) for more detailed discussion on the reliability of the DEPI.




11

Therefore, it seems quite difficult to construct a reliable price index that includes
asset price information. Putting large weight on the asset prices cannot be rationalized
without considering the large difference in the reliability of statistics. This point will be
examined in more detail below.
(2) Reliability of Asset Price Statistics
(a) Coverage of statistics
The ICLJ measures changes in the current and future prices of consumption flows
implied in the asset price fluctuations, while keeping the lifetime utility level constant. In
this case, it is crucial to emphasize that the ICLI must cover all assets, which are sources of
present and future consumption, such as tangible and intangible, financial and nonfinancial, and human and non-human assets.

Nevertheless, even the National Wealth

Statistics, which has the broadest coverage among the asset price statistics and used in
compiling the DEPI, does not include the human capital.19
The reasons why no comprehensive asset price statistics, which cover human capital,
exists are as follows. First, human capital is never traded in the markets, and it is quite
difficult to estimate its market value.

Second, human capital investment has a long-

development period, and opportunity cost is an important factor for human capital
investment decision. Third, it is not available to make a bank loan contract with collateral
of human capital because of an imperfection in capital markets.

19

Ishikawa (1991) provides an extensive survey of the issues related with human capital.




12

Now we try to make some rough estimates on the human capital value, in order to
examine the coverage of currently available asset price statistics. The calculation is based
on the assumption that the value of human capital
discounted value of labor income

( Y l)

(W h)

is equivalent to the present

and estimate the value of human capital under the

following assumptions:20 (1) growth rate of future labor income
human capital

(d),

(g),

depreciation rate of

discount rate of future income (r) are all constant over time; (2) gross

growth rate of labor income is equal to the product of gross depreciation rate of human
capital and gross discount rate; and (3) population composition and human capital
investment pattern are constant over time.
In this case, value of human capital, which is calculated as the present discounted
value of labor income with average expected job tenure of n-year, is
(

V
W

—^

= Y

H

L (l+<f)(l+r)

+

y

----

(

la+dXl+r)

+ - yl
J

1+ 8

X

(l+ d )(l+ r)

(2)

= nYL

According to the System of National Account in Japan, the compensation of employees is
286 trillion-yen in 1997. If we assume that average expected job tenure is 25 years, the
value of human capital is calculated as 7,157 trillion of yen in 1997 from equation (2).21

20

The following estimation methodology is taken from Iwata (1992). In addition, there exist another type of
estimation method such as summation of human capital investment, and using estimated consumption function
based permanent income hypothesis.
21
Takayama (1992) applies individual data of National Survey o f Family Income and Expenditure to
estimate the value of households’ human capital in 1984 for 4,406 trillion yen. It corresponds to 5,146 trillion
yen in 1994-year basis after adjusting for inflation between 1984 and 1994. This figure is judged as
approximately equivalent to the estimates in this paper, because the estimates in Takayama (1992) do not
cover the one-person family.




13

When we sum up the above estimated value of human capital and the value of non­
human capital assets in the System of National Accounts, total net asset value of household
reaches 8,854 trillion yen in 1997 (Table 3). The Table also shows that the ratio of non­
human and human capitals is about one to three, and the relative importance of human
capital is high. This indicates that the coverage of the National Wealth Statistics is just
25% of the total assets in the household sector.
(b) Accuracy of price information
Another problem of asset price statistics is that their accuracy is insufficient for
quantitative analysis. For example, land as an asset, which is a typical tangible asset, is
characterized by its diversity and variety. In practice, there are various evaluations of land
prices, ranging from actual traded prices to the Officially Published Land Prices, and it is
quite difficult to say which price indicates fair prices. In this case, although it may be
possible to apply a hedonic approach to estimate quality-adjusted price changes, limited
data availability would make such research quite difficult22
(c) Changes in composition of asset holdings
In constructing an aggregated asset price indicator, it is also difficult to adjust the
changes in asset composition over time. Table 4 shows an asset and debt composition in
the consolidated balance sheet for Japan over time, and two points should be noted. First,
both the asset and debt sides of the national balance sheet for Japan expanded more rapidly
than the national wealth (deducted debts and equity from total assets). The ratio of total

22

See Suzuki and Ohta (1994) for an application of the hedonic approach to land price analysis. In addition,
there are estimates such as Ito and Hirono (1993), Kasuga (1996) for housing prices and rents.




14

assets (equal to sum of total debt and net worth) to the nominal GDP increased to 16.6 in
1990 from 8.1 in 1970, and declined to 14.6 in 1997. During the same time period, net
worth rose from 4.0 in 1970 to 8.2 in 1990 and declined to 6.4 in 1997. Second, looking at
the composition of asset and debt, weight of financial assets, and debt excluding equity
increased.
The DEPI focuses on the changes in net national wealth to trace the fluctuations in the
aggregated asset value as the sources of future consumption expenditure.

However, it

should be noted that changes in the net national wealth might reflect the impact of changes
in the composition of asset and debt.
(3) Policy Implications and Sources of Asset Price Fluctuation
(a) Dispersion from fundamentals
Based on the discounted present value formula, which is the basic theoretical
framework for asset pricing, asset price is equal to the present discounted value of future
flow of its income. Profit maximization of the firm indicates that its marginal revenue
corresponds to its marginal productivity of assets. Therefore, if we assume that marginal
productivity of capital (M P K ), nominal interest rate (r), and expected rate of inflation (^)
are all constant over time, real asset price iq /p ) is determined as,
q /p = M P K /(r-n ).

(3)

This equation implies that expected return on asset and expected nominal rate determine the
fluctuation of real asset price.
Figure 3 plots the time series of changes in real price of net national wealth, real GDP




15

growth,23 and changes in expected real interest to examine the relationship between asset
price and fundamentals. It shows that real asset price changes almost correspond to the
movements in fundamentals. The changes in real asset price have a positive correlation
with real GDP growth, and a negative correlation with expected changes in the real interest
rate.
However, it is also true that the degree of correlation between the real asset price and
fundamentals varies over time. For example, during the period since the late 1980s, Japan
experienced tremendous fluctuation of asset prices, which is much larger than the
fluctuation implied by the fundamental variables such as real GDP growth and expected
changes in the real interest rate.
Prolonged deviation of asset price from its fundamental value is often called the
bubble. Even if investors are perfectly rational, the actual stock price may contain a bubble
element and, therefore, there can be a divergence between the asset price and its
fundamental value.24 In general, asset prices reflect investors’ expectations about the
future, and such expectations seem to have played an important role in sustainability of
bubbles. In this case, it is impossible to extract information on future inflation rates of
goods and services from the asset prices.

23

Real GDP growth can be thought of as a proxy for profitability of assets in real basis.
In order to exclude bubble path, it is assumed that asset price will not diverge to infinity. See, for example,
Blanchard and Watson (1982), for the discussion on the asset price bubble.

24




16

However, negative impact on the economy in the case of the collapse of the bubble
will become larger, as the overvaluation of asset prices continues longer, thus resulting in
larger swings in business conditions. In this sense, it might be the case that the rise in the
DEPI due to the overvaluation of asset prices should be considered as a signal for monetary
tightening.
(b) Adjustment for changes in marginal productivity of assets
The above discussion assumes the static expectation on the marginal return on assets.
That is, it assumes that constant rates of economic growth or marginal return on assets
continue over time. Indeed, Shibuya (1992) assumes that marginal return on assets is
constant over time in order to compute the DEPI with readily available data.
However, the increases in land prices do not necessarily imply the increase in the
future prices of services that will be produced by land. The increases in land prices may
reflect the higher productivity of land in the future, which is the consequence of
technological innovations, such as advances in construction technology of the higher
skyscrapers and smart buildings.
Now suppose that the changes in the marginal productivity of assets occurs between
the economic conditions A and B. Then the DEPI defined equation (1) is modified as
follows:
f „b Y*° f _fi
DEPI -

q l/M P K

Po_

B

Y -0®

q Z /M P K A ^

\P°)

(4)

This equation implies that asset prices must be deflated by their marginal productivity to
convert them into the asset prices in efficiency unit when we try to extract information on




17

the future prices of products and services. For example, the changes in the marginal
productivity must be deducted from the changes in the unit price of land.
Figure 4 plots the year-to-year changes of land prices in Japan by usage. In general,
land prices show a similar trend across usage, and no significant changes in the relative
prices are observed. In this case, as mentioned above, it is necessary to detect the asset
price changes measured in the efficiency unit to extract meaningful information. However,
such changes in marginal productivity of assets are not directly observable, nor no readily
available proxy exists. Therefore, it is necessary to estimate an aggregate production
function to compute the marginal productivity in a rigorous way. Still, it is difficult to
estimate the marginal productivity for different assets, and accumulation of time series data
is required to deduct the structural breaks with econometric methodology.
In addition, even though the current marginal productivity can be traced properly, it
might be the case that deviation from the proxy for the fundamentals occurs under the
expectations on the higher marginal return on assets, reflecting the future innovations. In
this case, the difficult question arises to judge in advance whether such asset price increases
are phenomena of euphoria.
In summary of the above discussion, when we employ the DEPI as one of the core
economic indicators for monetary policy judgment, it is necessary for monetary policy
makers to access the possibility of unobserved structural breaks that provoke the substantial
changes in the marginal productivity of the economy.
In the monetary policy regime of the inflation targeting, which most clearly define the
policy objectives in terms of inflation measures, escape clauses are introduced to permit




18

central banks to temporally deviate from the targeted range of inflation rates in the case of
significant supply shocks, such as remarkable rises in oil prices and natural disasters.25 In
this context, the shift in the marginal productivity of assets, which is interpreted as the
structural change in the supply-side of the economy, should be included in the escape
clauses, if a central bank adopt an inflation target to the DEPI for its monetary policy
framework. In addition, validity of market expectations, such as the possibility of bubble
and euphoria, should be examined to extract the policy implication from the changes in the
DEPI properly.
Considering these limitations, it is inappropriate that monetary policy makers employ
the DEPI as one of the core indicators for monetary policy judgment.

5. OPTIMAL INFLATION MEASURE IN PRACTICE
In this section, based on the above discussion, I will explore the question on what is
the optimal inflation measure for monetary policy in practice.
(1) Reliability of DEPI
In order to discuss the optimal inflation measures, it is important to obtain the
feasible combinations between the weight for asset prices and the observation errors in the
inflation measures. To this end, I perform a simulation on the observation errors in the
DEPI to analyze its reliability under the following conditions.
1) I assume the distributions of changes in price index and asset price follow the

See Bank of Japan (1995), Bemanke et al. (1999) and Leiderman and Svensson (1995) for the details of
inflation targeting.




19

normal distribution. This implies that price index and asset price levels follow the
lognormal distribution. As a result, the DEPI follows the lognormal distribution,
since the DEPI is defined as the geometric mean of price index and asset price.
2) I assume that observation errors in the GDP deflator is equal to that for the CPI,
estimated in the Appendix 2 at the level of 0.1% annually. In addition, I also
assume the three different levels of observation errors in asset prices, that is, ten,
100, and 1,000 times of that for the CPI.26
3) I assume the five different levels of correlation between the GDP deflator and
asset price fluctuations. The coefficient of correlation is 0.00, 0.10, 0.25, 0.50,
and 1.00, respectively.27
4) I assume six combinations of the -weights for the GDP deflator and asset price:
0.01:0.99,0.03:0.097,0.10:0.90,0.25:0.75,0.50:0.50, and 0.75:0.25, respectively.
5) Simulation results are compared with the benchmark of the estimated observation
errors in the CPI of the lowest aggregation level at 0.1 percent per annum.28

26 According to the estimated observation errors of the CPI in the Appendix 2, the observation errors increase
as the aggregation levels in data became high. The estimate of the highest aggregation data reaches 1.1
percent per annum, while that of the lowest aggregation data stays just 0.1 percent per annum. Therefore,
estimated observation errors vary in accordance with the data aggregation level, as large as 10 times between
the lowest and highest cases. This suggests that estimation with highly aggregated data enlarge the
observation errors because of the deterioration in the accuracy of price information. Since asset prices are
characterized by the diversity, their accuracy is far lower than that of the CPI price survey. Based on the
above consideration, the simulation in this paper assumes the three different levels of observation errors in the
asset prices: 10,100, and 1,000 times of the observation errors in the CPI.
27
Coefficients of correlation between the GDP deflator and asset price are 0.27 in 1970 to 1994, and 0.11 in
1980 to 1994.
28

This criteria means that 95 percent confidence range for the observed inflation rate is 0.2 percent in both
the upper and lower sides, when changes in the CPI follow the normal distribution process. For example,
when the year-to-year inflation rate is 2.0 percent, there will be a true value between 1.8 and 2.2 percent with
the probability of 95 percent.




20

Table 5 reports the simulation results, and shows the large observation errors, close to
that of asset prices, when the weights for asset prices exceed 0.9. Minimum value among
the simulated observation errors in the DEPI is 0.5 percent per annum, and it is ten times
larger than that of the G D P deflator. Considering the above examination on the accuracy of
the National Wealth Statistics, actual observation errors in the DEPI are expected to be far
larger than this minimum result. In addition, suppose that the achievement of monetary
policy objective is measured by the divergence from the targeted inflation rate, and required
confidence rage is 0.5 percent in both the upper and lower sides.29 All the simulation
results exceed the allowance.

(2) Optimal Weight Allocation to Asset Prices in Practice
Then, what is the optimal combination between the weight for asset prices and the
observation errors in the DEPI.
Figure 5 plots the changes in the estimated observation errors in the DEPI in response
to varying the weights between asset prices and the current price index.30 In this figure, the
vertical and horizontal axes correspond to the weight assigned to the asset prices and the
estimates of the observation errors in the DEPI, respectively.

29

Those countries that adopt inflation targeting as the monetary policy framework set an allowance range of
one percent around the targeted inflation rates. In general, the reason why such targeting ranges are set is that
there is a limitation in the controllability of inflation by monetary policy against the business cycle fluctuation
and external shocks. Therefore, we assume the maximum allowance level of the observation errors is half that
of the ordinary targeting rages.
30

In Figure 5, the simulation is conducted under the assumptions that (1) observation errors in the asset price
is 100 times more than that for the price index, and (2) there is no correlation between the fluctuation of asset
prices and the price index. It should be noted that simulation results shown in Table 5 suggest that simulation
results will not be influenced if there exists correlation between the fluctuation of asset prices and price index.




21

As the weight for asset prices increases, the observation errors in the DEPI
continuously rise. Therefore, their feasible combinations, “the inflation measures frontier,”
are downward-sloping and convex to the lower right In addition, the indifference curve for
the desirable inflation measures in terms of the weight for the asset prices and the
observation errors is also downward-sloping and convex to the lower right, since there
exists a trade-off between the weight for the asset prices and the observation errors (dashed
curve in the figure). On the one hand, increased weight for the asset prices is desirable
because the DEPI will reflect much more information on future inflation expectations. On
the other side, increased observation errors will deteriorate the credibility of inflation
measures.
Both the indifference curve and the inflation measure frontier are downward sloping
and convex to the lower right. Thus, if the indifference curve is tangent to the inflation
measure frontier from the inside, the tangency point will be the desirable combination of
weight for the asset price and observation errors. However, if the DEPI is employed as a
target indicator for monetary policy, the cost for the increase in the observation errors will
get larger, as the weight for the asset prices increases. This implies that the slope of the
indifference curve is steeper than that of the inflation measure frontier, thus producing the
comer solution shown in Figure 5. In this case, the desirable target indicator for the
monetary policy will be the conventional price index, which allocates the zero-weight for
asset prices in the DEPI. In other words, although there exists the reasonable theoretical
foundation that the DEPI allocates a large weight for asset prices, it is difficult to be
employed as one of the core indicators for the monetary policy judgment due to the




22

extremely low accuracy of the readily available data.

6. CONCLUSION
In this paper, I examined the possibility of constructing a reliable inflation measure
that reflects both the current inflation and asset prices from the theoretical and practical
viewpoints. Such an inflation measure, the dynamic equilibrium price index (DEPI), is the
extension of the conventional price index concept into the dynamic framework. Although
the concept of the DEPI is highly evaluated from the viewpoints of theoretical consistency,
it is difficult for monetary policy makers to expect the DEPI to be more than a
supplementary indicator for inflation pressures. This is because such modification of the
conventional price indices ishardly operational.
The first problem inherent in the DEPI is that asset price changes do not necessarily
mean the future price changes because there are a lot of sources for asset price fluctuations
besides the private-sector expectations for future course of inflation, such as bubble
elements of private-sector expectations and structural changes in the economy. Therefore,
if the DEPI is employed as one of the core indicators for monetary policy judgment,
monetary policy makers will be faced with the difficulty that the DEPI is very hard to
extract an appropriate policy implication in practice.
The second problem is the appropriateness of large weight for asset prices in the
DEPI. The DEPI is defined as the geometric weighted mean of current price index and
asset price, and its weight for asset price is almost equal to one, while that for current price
index is almost zero. From the theoretical viewpoints, it is reasonable to assign the large
(small) weight for the asset prices (the current price index), reflecting the dynamic




23

optimization of economic agents. However, such discussion misses the practical viewpoint
that reliabilityof asset price statistics is quite low. Although the conventional price indices
are also affected by measurement problems, their reliability is much higher than asset price
statistics, implying a difficulty in constructing a reliable price index that includes asset
prices.
The DEPI will be quite a similar indicator to asset prices, as far as one accepts the
theoretical weights for the current price index and asset prices. Ifasset prices are judged to
be inappropriate as a policy target indicator, and are limited as information variables for
monetary policy judgment, it is enough to monitor both the current price indices and the
asset prices separately.
In this context, itshould be noted that, as Kindleberger (1995) pointed out, there are
no cookbook rules for policyjudgement, and itis inevitable for monetary policy authority to
make a discretionaljudgement.31
The above conclusion implies that argument by Bemanke and Woodford (1997) is not
a serious problem for monetary policy makers in practice. They point out that it is not the
case that monetary policy makers can respond mechanically to private-sector inflation
forecasts, since itleads to indeterminacy of rational expectation equilibria. In this case, the
asset prices are one of the most likely indicators for monetary policy makers to extract the
information on the future course of inflation developments.

31 Kindleberger (1995) comments on this point as follows: “When speculation threatens substantial rises in
asset prices, with a possible collapse in asset markets later, and harm to the financial system, or if domestic
conditions call for one sort of policy, and international goals another, monetary authorities confront a dilemma
calling for judgment, not cookbook rules of the game.”




24

However, considering the limitation in asset prices discussed in this paper, it is
necessary to make a discretionary judgment to extract an appropriate policy implication
from the asset price fluctuations. Therefore, it is not practically feasible to assume a
mechanical rule to respond against the asset price fluctuations.32

APPENDIX 1. FORMULATION OF DYNAMICALLY EXPANDED PRICE INDEX
As an inflation measure of incorporating the dynamic elements of price fluctuation,
Alchian and Klein (1973) proposed the idea of an intertemporal cost of living index (ICLI)
that traces “the intertemporal changes in the cost of living that is required to achieve a given
level of intertemporal utility.”
Assuming that consumer preference depends on both the current and future
consumption expenditure as the following utilityfunction:
U = U ( x * ,...x * ,...,x

where

x£

(A-l)

*,...) fori = l,...,n;f= l,---°°,

represents the consumption expenditure for good

i

at time

t

with economic

condition of A.
The budget constraint of the consumer corresponds to the total assets (w A ) that cover
the tangible and intangible assets as follows:

32

Similar argument will be hold, if monetary policy makers employ a survey data on the private-sector
forecast for inflation as a targeted variable. This is because that such survey data is likely to reflects the
private-sector’s belief of unseen structural changes in the economy. In this case, it does not seem to be
practically feasible that monetary policy makers can mechanically react to the private-sector forecasts for
inflation.




25

w ‘ =

where

p

A, q A ,

(A-2)

l i p x
j=i

1=1 1=1

yA

represent the cuirent price of good i at time t under economic condition

A,33 and price and quantity of assetj at time t under economic condition A.
Suppose that the current price of the current or future goods change, and the new
economic condition B is realized. As a result, suppose also that the required asset value for
the consumer to achieve the same utilitylevel under the economic condition A becomes W 8.
The ICLI between the economic conditions A and B isdefined as

W B
I C L I AB

____

/=! i=l

n

W A

/=l i=I

(A-3)

m
y=l

Shibuya (1992) formulates the DEPI as a geometric mean of the current price index
and asset prices by assuming time separable utilityfunction in one good model and constant
marginal productivity of assets.

APPENDIX 2. APPLICATION OF OLS M E T H O D TO ESTIMATE OBSERVATION
E R R O R S IN PRICE INDEX
Appendix 2 shows the estimation procedure and results for the observation errors
in the price index, which are the basic data for the simulation on the observation errors in
the DEPI.

33

First, following Selvanathan and Prasada Rao (1994), I summarize the

This is the present value of the future product and service prices discounted by the discounted factor.




26

methodology to estimate the Laspeyres price index and its observation errors from the
disaggregated data. Then, I estimate the observation errors with four data sets with
different aggregation level of the CPI: ten major group index, subgroup index, item class
index, and item index.
N ow let p 0lx iQ and

p ux i0

be consumption expenditure to good i at the base period 0

and the current period t, respectively, and consider the regression equation as follows,
P u x io = J ,P o ,x io

where

y( is identical to allgood, and

+

1=

(A_4)

n

is random component. In addition, assuming

£[fj=0,

c o v ie ^ C j,

]= ^ P io X u S j j ,

(A-5)

where <$yis Kronecker’s delta.
By dividing equation (A-4) by Al p

i0x i0

,the following equation is derived
(A.-6)

P l = r , P m + u u^

where p‘ =

p u ^jxi0 / p i0 , u u = e j -J p i0x iQ

. From equation (A-5),

c o v K .«>] = cov[u u ,U j,] / ( p i0x iQ) = a f S v.

(A-7)

Therefore, the ordinary least square (OLS) estimation can be applied. The estimated
coefficient is

r, = 'Z

l'=I

p

I p 'o

/ 'Z ( p ' o ) 2 = Y j P i ,xt<0
/ 1=1
l=I
/ #=1

.

(A-8)

and coincide with the Laspeyres index formula. Thus, the standard error for the estimated
coefficient corresponds to the observation error for the price index.
Table A-l shows the estimation results for the item index, item class index, subgroup




27

index, and ten major group index in the Japanese CPL34 The estimated observation error
for the CPI isjust 0.1 percent per year for the item index, which has the lowest aggregation
level. However, the estimates become larger as the aggregation level get higher: 0.6, 0.8,
and 1.1 percent per year for the item class index, subgroup index, and ten major group
index, respectively. This implies that the observation errors expand as the accuracy of price
survey lowers.

REFFERENCES
Alchian, Armen A., and Benjamin Klein, “On A Correct Measure of Inflation,” J o u r n a l
M o n e y , C re d it , a n d B a n k in g

of

5(1), 1973, pp. 173-191.

Ball, Laurence, and N. Gregory Mankiw, “Relative-Price Changes as Aggregate Supply
Shocks,” Q u a r te r ly

J o u r n a l o f E c o n o m ic s

110(1), 1995, pp. 161-193..

Bank of Japan, “Inflation Targeting in Selected Countries,”
B u lle tin

B an k o f Ja p an

Q u a r t e r ly

3(2), 1995, pp. 39-52.

Barro, Robert J., and Xavier Sala-i-Martin, E c o n o m ic

G r o w th ,

McGrow-Hill, Inc., 1995.

Bemanke, Ben S., and Michael Woodford, “Inflation Forecasts and Monetary Policy,”
J o u r n a l o f M o n e y , C r e d it a n d B a n k in g ,

29 (4), 1997, pp. 654-684.

_____ ,Thomas Laubach, Fredric S. Mishkin, and Adam S. Posen,
L e s s o n s f r o m the I n te rn a tio n a l E v id e n c e ,

I n fla tio n T a r g e t in g :

Princeton University Press, 1999.

Blanchard, Olivier J., and Mark W. Watson, “Bubbles, Rational Expectations, and Financial

34 Estimation is conducted with the 1990-base CPI.




28

Markets,” in Paul Wachtel ed.

C r is e s

in

th e E c o n o m ic

and

F in a n c ia l S t r u c tu r e ,

Lexington Books, 1982, pp. 295-315.
Bockelmann, Horst, “Comments,” in Kuniho Sawamoto, Zenta Nakajima, and Hiroo
Taguchi eds., F in a n c ia l

S t a b ility in a C h a n g in g E n v iro n m e n t,

Macmillan Press, 1995,

pp. 498-500.
Borio, C. E. V., N. Kennedy, and S. D. Prowse, “Exploring Aggregate Asset Price
Fluctuations Across Countries: Measurement, Determinants and Monetary Policy
Implications”,B I S

E c o n o m ic P a p e r s

No. 40, 1994.

Bruni, Franco, “Comments” in Kuniho Sawamoto, Zenta Nakajima, and Hiroo Taguchi
eds., F in a n c ia l

S t a b ilit y in a C h a n g in g E n v iro n m e n t,

Macmillan Press, 1995, pp. 501-

505.
Carlson, Keith M., “Do Price Indices Tell Us about Inflation? A Review of the Issues,”
F e d e r a l R e s e rv e B a n k o f St. L o u is R e v ie w

71(6), 1989, pp. 12-30.

Goodhart, Charles A. E., “Price Stability and Financial Fragility,” in Kuniho Sawamoto,
Zenta Nakajima, and Hiroo Taguchi eds.,
E n v iro n m e n t,

F in a n c ia l

S t a b ilit y

in

a

C h a n g in g

Macmillan Press, 1995, pp. 439-497.

Hamori, Shigeyuki, S h o u h is h a
J a p a n e s e A s s e t M a rk e ts ) ,

K o u d o u to N ih o n n o S h is a n S h ijo ( C o n s u m e r B e h a v io r a n d

Toyo Keizai Shinpo Sha, 1996 (in Japanese).

Hoshi, Takeo, “Shihon Shijo no Hukanzen Sei to Kin’yu Seisaku no Hakyu Keiro: Saikin
no Kenkyu Seika no Tenbo” (Imperfection in Capital Markets and Transmission
Mechanism of Monetary Policy: Review of Recent Studies), I M E S

D is c u s s io n P a p e r

96-J-14, Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies, Bank of Japan, 1996.




29

Ishikawa, Tsuneo,

S h o to k u

to

Tom i

(In c o m e

and

W e a lth ),

Iwanami Shoten, 1991 (in

Japanese).
Ito, Takatoshi and Keiko Nosse Hirono (1993), “Efficiency of the Housing Market,” B a n k
o f J a p a n M o n e t a r y a n d E c o n o m ic S tu d ie s ,

11(1), 1993.

Iwata, Kazumasa, “Sutokku Keizai to Zeisei” (Stock Economy and Tax System), Takatoshi
Ito and Yukio Noguchi eds.,

B u n s e k i N ih o n

K e iz a i n o S u tto k u

Ka

(Analysis on

Advance in Stock Economy), Nihon Keizai Shinbunsha, 1992 (in Japanese).
Kasuga, Yoshiyuki, “Shutoken ni okeru Juutaku no Kousatsu: Mikuro Deita ni yoru Jutaku
Shijou no Kenshou,” (Housing Problems in Metropolitan Area: Examination of
Housing Market by Micro Data), C h o u s a No. 211, Japan Development Bank, 1996 (in
Japanese).
Kindleberger, Charles P., “Asset Inflation and Monetary Policy,” B N L

Q u a r t e r ly R e v ie w ,

no. 192, 1995, pp. 17-37.
Leiderman, Leonard, and Lars E. O. Svensson eds., I n fla tio n

T a rg e ts ,

CEPR, 1995.

Matsushita, Yasuo, “Role of Capital Market and its Confronting Problems,” B a n k
Q u a r t e r ly B u lle tin ,

Noguchi, Yukio,

o f Ja p an

1995.

B a b u ru

no

K e iz a ig a k u

(E c o n o m ic s

on

B u b b le s ) ,

Nihon Keizai

Shinbunsha, 1992 (in Japanese).
Okina, Kunio, K it a i

to T o u k i n o K e iz a i B u n s e k i

—

‘B a b u r u ’ G e n s h o u to K a w a s e R e it o

( E c o n o m ic A n a ly s is o f E x p e c ta tio n s a n d S p e c u la tio n s

E x c h a n g e R a te s

_______ , K in ’yu




—

‘B u b b le ' P h e n o m e n a a n d

— ),Toyo Keizai Shinpo Sha, 1985 (in Japanese).

Seisaku ( M onetary P o lic y ), Toyo Keizai Shinpo Sha, 1993 (in Japanese).

30

—

Poliak, Robert A., T h e

T h e o ry o f th e C o s t - o f- U v in g In d e x ,

Oxford University Press, 1989.

Santoni, G. J., and H. Brian Moehring, “Asset Return and Measured Inflation,” J o u r n a l
M o n e y , C re d it , a n d B a n k in g

of

26(2), 1994, pp. 232-248.

Selvanathan, E. A., and D. S. Prasada Rao,

In d e x N u m b e rs : A

S t o c h a s t ic A p p r o a c h ,

Macmillan, 1994.
Shibuya, Hiroshi, “Dynamic Equilibrium Price Index: Asset Price and Inflation” B a n k
J a p a n M o n e t a r y a n d E c o n o m ic S tu d ie s ,

of

Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies,

Bank of Japan, 10(1), 1992, pp. 95-109.
_____ ,“Monetary Policy, Banking Crisis, and Disequilibrium Dynamics: Business Cycles
with Capital Price Overshooting,” Mimeo, 1995.
Shigehara, Kumiharu, “Shisan Kakaku no Hendo to Infureishon ni tsuite” (Asset Price
Fluctuation and Inflation), K i n ’y u

K enkyu,

9(2), Institute for Monetary and Economic

Studies, Bank of Japan, 1990.
Shiller, Robert J.,M a c r o

M a rk e ts ,

Oxford University Press, 1993.

Shiratsuka, Shigenori, “Shisan Kakaku Hendo to Bukka Shisu (Asset Price Fluctuations and
Price Index),” K in y u

K enkyu,

Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies, Bank of

Japan, 14 (4), 1996, pp. 45-72 (in Japanese).
_____ , “Inflation Measures for Monetary Policy: Measuring the Underlying Inflation
Trend and Its Implication for Monetary Policy Implementation,”
M o n e t a r y a n d E c o n o m ic S tu d ie s ,

_____ ,B u k k a

o f Ja p an

15(2), 1997, pp. 1-26.

n o K e iz a i B u n s e k i (E c o n o m ic A n a ly s is o f I n fla tio n M e a s u r e s ) ,

T okyo Press, 1998 (in Japanese).




Bank

31

University of

_____ , “Measurement Errors in the Japanese Consumer Price Index,”
B a n k o f C h ic a g o W o rk in g P a p e r ,

F e d e r a l R e s e rv e

1999 (forthcoming).

Suzuki, Kenji, and Makoto Ohta, “A Hedonic Analysis of Land Prices and Rents in the
Bubble: Kanagawa Prefecture in Japan for 1986-1988,” E c o n o m ic

S t u d ie s Q u a r t e r ly ,

45(1), 1994.
Suzuki, Yoshio,

E n D e fu r e to D o r u I n ju re ( Y e n D e fla t io n a n d D o lla r I n fla t io n ) ,

Toyo

Keizai Shinpo sha, 1995 (in Japanese).
Takayama, Noriyuki, S u to k k u

E k o n o m i (S to c k E c o n o m y ) ,

Japanese).




32

Toyo Keizai Shinpo sha, 1992 (in

Table 1. Granger Causality Test with Different Setup of V A R Models
A: Two-variable V A R estimation
Depend. Independent var.
Variable DLCP
DLAP
21.024
15.749
DLCP
(0.000) (0.000)
0.171 29.893
DL A P
(0.682) (0.000)
B: Four-variable V A R estimation
Independent variables
Depend.
Variable DLCP
LR
DLAP
DLRY
0.519
7.282
0.598
10.549
DLCP
(0.011) (0.003) (0.444) (0.476)
0.982
0.353
0.798
16.529
DL A P
(0.378) (0.000) (0.556) (0.328)
2.850
0.807
0.256 20.835
DLRY
(0.375) (0.616) (0.000) (0.100)
11.326
0.068 133.663
0.435
LR
(0.514) (0.002) (0.796) (0.000)
C: Five-variable V A R estimation
Independent variables
Depend.
variable
DLNM
DLRY
LR
DLCP
DLAP
0.033
0.956
0.000
5.620
4.959
DLCP
(0.024) (0.033) (0.998) (0.857) (0.335)
3.130
0.386
0.006
1.768
6.773
DL A P
(0.193) (0.014) (0.539) (0.937) (0.086)
3.152
5.234
6.116
2.385
0.201
DLRY
(0.132) (0.085) (0.028) (0.657) (0.019)
0.274
6.671
0.005 98.183
0.191
LR
(0.604) (0.014) (0.944) (0.000) (0.665)
0.702 23.310
0.988
0.055
0.000
DLNM
(0.327) (0.816) (1.000) (0.408) (0.000)

\

Sources: Bank of Japan, Econom ic S ta tistics A nnual;
Economic Planning Agency, Annual R eport on
N a tio n a l A ccounts .
Note: M2+CD is connected series of the following two
series: (1) annual average of outstanding at the end of
each month in 1956-69: (2) annual average of average
outstanding of each month in 1970-1997.




33

DLCP

DLAP

DLCP

DLAP

DLRY

LR

LR
T "
i
DLCP

◄ H

DLAP

V
DLRY

Granger’s causality
significant at 1%
significant at 5 %
significant at 10%
significant at 20%

4

- DLNM

level:
level:
level:
level:

lead-----► lag
lead— «► lag
lead------ > lag
lead— $> lag

T a b le 2 . P la n n in g H o riz o n and W e ig h t fo r D E P I

ining
izon
2
4
6
8
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100
oo




discount factor=0.03
Current price asset price
0.493
0.507
0.261
0.739
0.821
0.179
0.862
0.138
0.114
0.886
0.935
0.065
0.950
0.050
0.042
0.958
0.962
0.038
0.035
0.965
0.967
0.033
0.032
0.968
0.031
0.969
0.031
0.969
0.971
0.029

34

discount factor=0.01
current price
asset price
0.502
0.498
0.254
0.746
0.171
0.829
0.129
0.871
0.105
0.895
0.055
0.945
0.038
0.962
0.030
0.970
0.025
0.975
0.022
0.978
0.020
0.980
0.018
0.982
0.017
0.983
0.016
0.984
0.010
0.990




T a b le 3 . B a la n c e -S h e e t fo r H o u se h o ld s in 1 997

Unit: Trillion Yen, %
2,654

(

28.4)

303

(

3.2)

Land

1,068

(

11.4)

Financial Assets

1,222

(

13.1)

61

(

0.6)

401

(

4.3)

Net Worth

2,187

(

23.4)

Human Capital

7,157

(

76.6)

Net Total Assets

9,344

( 100.0)

National Wealth

3,241

Non-Human Capital
Net Fixed Assets

Others
Debts

Source: Economic Planning Agency, A n n u a l R e p o r t o n N a t io n a l A c c o u n t s .
Notes: 1. Figures on Human Capital are author’s estimation.
2. Net total assets are sum of net worth and human capital.
3. National wealth covers non-financial incorporated enterprises,
financial institutions, and general government, in addition to
households.

35

T a b le 4 . C o n so lid a te d A cc o u n ts fo r Jap an

1980

1970

1990

1997

Reproducible Tangible Assets

121 ( 20.5)

592 ( 22.4)

1,053 ( 14.8)

1,387 ( 18.7)

Non-reproducible Tangible Assets

174 ( 29.4)

745 ( 28.2)

2,420 ( 33.9)

1,729 ( 23.3)

Financial Assets

296 ( 50.1)

1,305 ( 49.4)

3,663 ( 51.3)

4,306 ( 58.0)

Total Assets

591 (100.0)

2,642 (100.0)

7,137 (100.0)

7,422 (100.0)

Debts (excluding Equity)

266 ( 45.1)

1,177 ( 44.6)

3,008 ( 42.1)

3,810 (5 1 .3 )

Equity

28 ( 4.7)

125 ( 4.7)

National Wealth

296 ( 50.2)

1,340 ( 50.7)

Ratio to Nominal GDP
Total Debts and National Wealth
Ratio to Nominal GDP

4.0

5.6

591 (100.0)

Source: Economic Planning Agency, A n n u a l R e p o rt o n




36

8.5)

371 (

3,522 ( 49.4)

7,137 (100.0)

5.0)

3,241 ( 43.7)

8.2

2,642 (100.0)
11.0

8.1

607 (

6.4
7,422 (100.0)

16.6

N a t io n a l A c c o u n t s .

14.6

T a b le 5 . S im u la tio n R e su lts fo r O b se rv a tio n E rro rs in th e D E P I

Weights
Asset
Current
Price
Price

Assumption on correlation
0.10

0.00

0.25

0.50

1.00

Case 1: Observation errors in Asset Price = 10 times of Current Price
0.995
0.995
0.995
0.996
0.01
0.99
0.985
0.986
0.985
0.987
0.97
0.03
0.952
0.950
0.954
0.90
0.949
0.10
0.870
0.873
0.867
0.878
0.75
0.25
0.714
0.719
0.50
0.711
0.728
0.50
0.511
0.517
0.507
0.526
0.25
0.75

0.996
0.988
0.959
0.889
0.745
0.543

in Asset Price = 100 times of Current Price
Case 2: Observation errors :
9.950
9.950
9.950
0.99
9.950
0.01
9.849
9.850
0.03
0.97
9.849
9.850
9.487
9.488
0.90
9.489
9.492
0.10
8.660
8.663
8.666
0.25
0.75
8.671
7.071
7.075
7.080
0.50
0.50
7.089
5.004
5.001
5.010
0.75
0.25
5.019

9.951
9.852
9.496
8.682
7.107
5.038

1,000 times of Current Price
99.499
99.499
99.499
98.490
98.489
98.489
94.871
94.873
94.869
86.605
86.608
86.613
70.714
70.720
70.728
50.004
50.009
50.019

99.500
98.492
94.878
86.624
70.746
50.038

Case 3: Observation errors in Asset Price =
0.01
99.499
0.99
0.03
0.97
98.489
94.868
0.10
0.90
0.25
86.603
0.75
0.50
70.711
0.50
50.000
0.75
0.25




37

F ig u re 1. D E P I an d G D P d e fla to r

(Changes from the previous year, % )

Sources:
Notes:




Economic Planning Agency, A n n u a l R e p o rt o n N a t io n a l A c c o u n t s
For the details of calculation method of DEPI, see Shibuya (1992).

38

F ig u re 2. G ra n g e r C a u s a lity fro m A s s e t P ric e to G D P d e fla to r o v e r T im e

A. 15-year rolling regressions

58 59 60 61 62 63 64 65 66 67 68 69 70 71 72 73 74 75 76 77 78 79 80 81 82 83
(beginning of sample period)

B. 20-year rolling regressions
(f-value)

58

59

60

61

62 63

64 65 66 67 68 69 70 71
(beginning of sample period)

72

73

74

75

76

77

78

C. 25-year rolling regressions

58




59

60

61

62

63
64
65
66
67
(beginning of sample period)

39

68

69

70

71

72

73

F ig u re 3 . A ss e t P ric e F lu ctu a tio n and Fu n d a m e n ta ls

(%)

Source: Economic Planning Agency, A n n u a l R e p o rt o n N a t io n a l A c c o u n t s .
Note: Ex post long-term real interest rates correspond to the long-term
prime-lending rate deducted by the changes of the G D P deflator.




40

F ig u re 4 . L a n d P ric e s b y U s e

70

72

74

76

78

80

82

84

Source: Japan Real Estate Institute, U r b a n




41

86

88

90

L a n d P r ic e In d e x .

92

94

96

(Weight for Asset Prices)

F ig u re 5 . D E P I W e ig h t an d O b se rv a tio n E rro rs




0

2

4
6
(Observation Errors, %)

42

8

10

12

Table A-l. Estimation of Observation Errors in the CPI

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

Average

Estimation by item index
Coeff.

1.033

1.050

1.064

1.071

1.070

S.E.

0.002

0.002

0.003

0.004

0.005

R2

0.996

0.992

0.987

0.978

0.971

0.001

Estimation by item class index
Coeff.

1.032

1.050

1.063

1.071

1.070

S.E.

0.003

0.005

0.006

0.007

0.009

R2

0.997

0.994

0.992

0.986

0.981

0.006

Estimation by subgroup index
Coeff.

1.032

1.050

1.064

1.071

1.070

S.E.

0.005

0.006

0.008

0.011

0.013

R2

0.995

0.994

0.990

0.981

0.975

0.008

Estimation by ten major group index
Coeff.

1.033

1.050

1.063

1.071

1.070

S.E.

0.005

0.007

0.010

0.014

0.017

R2

0.998

0.997

0.994

0.988

0.982




43

0.011

W o r k i n g P a p e r Series

A series ofresearch studies on regional economic issues relating to the Seventh Federal
Reserve District,and on financial and economic topics.

B an k F ailures, S y stem ic R isk, and B ank R egulation

W P -96-1

F orecastin g Structural C hange w ith a R egion al E conom etric Input-Output M o d el

W P -9 6 -2

O n B ia se s in T ests o f the E xpectations H ypothesis
o f the Term Structure o f Interest Rates

W P -9 6 -3

T h e E q u ity Prem ium P u zzle and the R isk-Free Rate P u zzle at L ong H orizons

W P -9 6 -4

E xpectation Traps and D iscretion
K

W P -9 6 -5

A lligato rs in the Sw am p: T he Impact o f D erivatives o n the Financial
P erform an ce o f D ep ository Institutions

W P -9 6 -6

Strategic R esp on ses to B ank Regulation: E vidence from H M D A D ata

W P -9 6 -7

D ep o sit Insurance, Bank Capital Structures and the D em and for L iquidity

W P -9 6 -8

N orth -S ou th B u sin ess C y cles

W P -9 6 -9

N orth -S ou th Financial Integration and B u sin ess C ycles

W P -9 6 -1 0

M acro eco n o m ic E ffects o f E m ploym ent R eallocation

W P -9 6 -1 1

GeorgeG.Kaufman

PhillipR.Israilevich,GeoffreyHewings,MichaelSonis
andGrahamR.Schindler
GeertBekaert,RobertJ.HodrickandDavidMarshall

KentDanielandDavidMarshall

V.Chari,LawrenceJ.ChristianoandMartinEichenbaum

ElijahBrewerIII,WilliamE.JacksonIII,andJamesT.Moser
DougEvanoffandLewisM.Segal

AlbertoM.Ramos

MichaelKouparitsas

MichaelKouparitsas

KenKuttnerandJeffreyCampbell
AM ix e d Bag: A ssessm en t o f Market Perform ance and Firm Trading
B eh a v io r in the N O x R ECLAIM Program
MichaelAriPrager,ThomasH.KlierandRichardH.Mattoon
Interest-R ate D erivatives and Bank Lending

ElijahBrewerIII,BernadetteA.MintonandJamesT.Moser
APrice T arget for U .S. M onetary Policy? L essons from the E xperience
w ith M o n e y Growth Targets?
BenjaminM.FriedmanandKennethN.Kuttner




W P -9 6 -1 2

W P -9 6 -1 3

W P -9 6 -1 4

/

W o r k i n g P a p e r Series (continued)

C atching up w ith the K eynesians

WP-96-15

C h aos, Sunspots, and A utom atic Stabilizers

W P -9 6 -1 6

A ggreg a te E m ploym ent F luctuations w ith M icroecon om ic A sym m etries

W P -9 6 -1 7

B ank Fragility: Perception and H istorical E vid en ce

W P -9 6 -1 8

LarsLjungqvistandHaroldUhlig
LawrenceJ.ChristianoandSharonG.Harrison
JeffreyR.CampbellandJonasD.M.Fisher
GeorgeG.Kaufman

U sin g S ib lin g D ata to Estim ate the Im pact o f N eigh b orh ood s
o n C hildren’s Educational O utcom es

W P -9 6 -1 9

H o w Shou ld Financial Institutions and M arkets B e Structured?
A n a ly sis and O ptions for Financial System D esig n

W P -9 6 -2 0

C h an ges in Trading A ctiv ity F o llo w in g S tock Sp lits and T heir Im pact
o n V o la tility and the A d verse Information C om ponent o f the B id -A sk Spread

W P -96-21

F inancial D istress and the R o le o f Capital C ontributions b y the O w ner M anager

W P -9 6 -2 2

C redit M arket Im perfections and the H eterogeneous R esp on se o f Firms
to M o n eta iy Sh ock s

W P -9 6 -2 3

DanielAaronson

GeorgeG.KaufmanandRandallS.Kroszner

A.S.Desai,M.NimalendranandS.Venkataraman
S.Venkataraman

JonasD.M.Fisher
(S,s)Inventory P olicies in G eneral Equilibrium
JonasD.M.FisherandAndreasHornstein

W P -9 6 -2 4

N o n -C o n v e x C osts and Capital Utilization: A Study o f Production and
Inventories at A u tom ob ile A ssem b ly Plants

W P -9 6 -2 5

T h e G row th o f Tem porary S ervices Work

W P -9 6 -2 6

T h e S ecurity Issue D ecision : E vidence from S m all B u sin ess Investm ent C om p an ies

W P -9 6 -2 7

S tick y Price and Lim ited Participation M odels o f M oney: A C om parison

W P -9 6 -2 8

T h e E ffect o f State Fiscal Reform on Population H eterogeneity

WP-96-29

GeorgeJ\Hall

LewisSegalandDanielSullivan

ElijahBrewerIII,HesnaGenay,WilliamE.Jackson,andPaulaR.Worthington
LawrenceJ.Christiano,MartinEichenbaumandCharlesL.Evans
DanielAaronson




2

W o r k i n g P a p e r Series (continued)

F D IC IA A fter F iv e Years: A R eview and Evaluation

WP-97-1

MichaelD.BordotChristopherJ,ErcegandCharlesL.Evans

M o n ey , S tick y W ages, and the Great D ep ression

W P -9 7 -2

P rice Pass-T hrough and M inim um W ages

W P -9 7 -3

H abit P ersisten ce and A sse t Returns in an E xchange E co n o m y

W P -9 7 -4

N orth -S ou th Term s o f Trade: A n E m pirical Investigation

W P -9 7 -5

Interactions B etw een the Seasonal and B u sin ess C ycles
in P roduction and Inventories

W P -9 7 -6

“ P eso P roblem ” E xplanations for Term Structure A n o m a lies

W P -9 7 -7

T h e B ig Problem o f Sm all C hange

W P -9 7 -8

B ank C apital Standards for Market Risk: A W elfare A n a ly sis

W P -9 7 -9

M onetary P o licy and the Term Structure o f N o m in al Interest Rates:
E v id en ce and Theory

W P -9 7 -1 0

E m p loyer Learning and Statistical D iscrim ination

W P -9 7 -1 1

A M o d el o f C om m odity M on ey, With A p p lication s to G resham ’s L aw
and the D eb asem en t P uzzle

W P -9 7 -1 2

T h e E volu tion o f Sm all C hange

W P -9 7 -1 3

T he R o le o f Credit M arket C om petition on L ending Strategies
and on C apital A ccum ulation

W P -9 7 -1 4

A lgorith m s for S olv in g D ynam ic M odels w ith O ccasion ally B inding C onstraints

W P -9 7 -1 5

T he Return from C om m unity C ollege S ch o o lin g for D isp laced W orkers

W P -9 7 -1 6

GeorgeJ.BenstonandGeorgeG.Kaufman

DanielAaronson

MicheleBoldrin,LawrenceJ.ChristianoandJonasD.M.Fisher
MichaelA.Kouparitsas

StevenG.Cecchetti,AnilK KashyapandDavidW.Wilcox
GeertBekaert,RobertJ.HodrickandDavidA.Marshall
ThomasJ.Sargent,FrancoisR Velde

DavidMarshallandSubuVenkataraman
CharlesL.EvansandDavidA.Marshall
JosephG.AltonjiandCharlesR Pierret

FrancoisR Velde,WarrenE,WeberandRandallWright
ThomasJ.SargentandFrancoisR Velde

NicolaCetorelli

LawrenceJ.ChristianoandJonasFisher

LouisS.JacobsonRobertJ.LaLondeandDanielG.Sullivan



3

W o r k i n g P a p e r Series (continued)

Modeling Money

W P -9 7 -1 7

Monetary Policy Shocks: What Have We Learned and to What End?

W P -9 7 -1 8

Volunteer Labor Sorting Across Industries

W P -9 7 -1 9

Would Freetrade Have Emerged in North America without NAFTA?

W P -9 7 -2 0

The Role o f the Financial Services Industry in the Local Economy

W P -97-21

The Trojan Horse or the Golden Fleece? Small Business Investment
Companies and Government Guarantees

W P -97-22

Temporary Services Employment Durations: Evidence from State UI Data

W P -9 7 -2 3

The Determinants o f State Food Manufacturing Growth: 1982-92

W P -9 7 -2 4

Requiem for a Market Maker: The Case o f Drexel Burnham Lambert
and Below-Investment-Grade Bonds

W P -9 7 -2 5

Plant Level Irreversible Investment and Equilibrium Business Cycles

W P -98-1

Search, Self-Insurance and Job-Security Provisions

W P -9 8 -2

Could Prometheus Be Bound Again? A Contribution to the Convergence Controversy

W P -9 8 -3

The Informational Advantage o f Specialized Monitors:
The Case o f Bank Examiners

W P -9 8 -4

Prospective Deficits and the Asian Currency Crisis

W P -9 8 -5

Stock Market and Investment Good Prices: Implications o f Microeconomics

W P -9 8 -6

Understanding the Effects o f a Shock to Government Purchases

WP-98-7

LawrenceJ.Christiano,MartinEichenbaumandCharlesL.Evans
LawrenceJ.Christiano,MartinEichenbaumandCharlesL.Evans
LewisM.Segal,ElizabethMauserandBurtonA.Weisbrod
MichaelA.Kouparitsas

DouglasD.Evanojf,PhilipR IsrailevichandGrahamR Schindler

ElijahBrewerIII,HesnaGenay,WilliamE.JacksonIIIandPaulaR Worthington
LewisM.SegalandDanielG.Sullivan
MikeSinger

ElijahBrewerIIIandWilliamE.JacksonIII
MarceloVeracierto

FernandoAlvarezandMarceloVeracierto
NicolaCetorelli

RobertDeYoung,MarkJ.Flannery,WilliamW LangandSorinM.Sorescu

CraigBurnside,MartinEichenbaumandSergioRebelo
LawrenceJ.ChristianoandJonasD.M.Fisher

WendyEdelberg,MartinEichenbaumandJonasD.M.Fisher




4

W o r k i n g P a p e r Series (continued)

A Model o f Bimetallism

WP-98-8

An Analysis o f Women’s Retum-to-Work Decisions Following First Birth

W P -9 8 -9

The Quest for the Natural Rate: Evidence from a Measure o f Labor Market Turbulence

W P -9 8 -1 0

School Finance Reform and School District Income Sorting

W P -9 8 -1 1

Central Banks, Asset Bubbles, and Financial Stability

W P -9 8 -1 2

Bank Time Deposit Rates and Market Discipline in Poland:
The Impact o f State Ownership and Deposit Insurance Reform

W P -9 8 -1 3

Projected U.S. Demographics and Social Security

W P -9 8 -1 4

Dynamic Trade Liberalization Analysis: Steady State, Transitional and
Inter-industry Effects

W P -9 8 -1 5

Can the Benefits Principle Be Applied to State-local Taxation o f Business?

W P -9 8 -1 6

Geographic Concentration in U.S. Manufacturing: Evidence from the U.S.
Auto Supplier Industry

W P -9 8 -1 7

Consumption-Based Modeling o f Long-Horizon Returns

W P -9 8 -1 8

Can VARs Describe Monetaiy Policy?

W P -9 8 -1 9

Neighborhood Dynamics

W P -9 8 -2 0

Inventories and output volatility

W P -9 8 -2 1

Lending to troubled thrifts: the case o f FHLBanks

W P -9 8 -2 2

Wage Differentials for Temporary Services Work:
Evidence from Administrative Data

WP-98-23

FrancoisR.Velde,andWarrenE.Weber
LisaBarrow

EllenR.Rissman
DanielAaronson

GeorgeG.Kaufman

ThomasS.MondscheanandTimothyP.Opiela

MariacristinaDeNardi,SelahattinImrohorogluandThomasJ.Sargent
MichaelKouparitsas

WilliamH.OaklandandWilliamA.Testa

ThomasH.Klier

KentD.DanielandDavidA.Marshall

CharlesL.EvansandKennethN.Kuttner

DanielAaronson

PaulaR.Worthington

LisaK.AshleyandElijahBrewerIII

LewisM.SegalandDanielG.Sullivan



5

W o r k i n g P a p e r Series (continued)

Organizational Flexibility and Employment Dynamics at
Young and Old Plants

WP-98-24

Extracting Market Expectations from Option Prices:
Case Studies in Japanese Option Markets

W P -99-1

Measurement Errors in Japanese Consumer Price Index

W P -9 9 -2

Taylor Rules in a Limited Participation Model

W P -9 9 -3

Maximum Likelihood in the Frequency Domain: A Time to Build Example

W P -9 9 -4

Unskilled Workers in an Economy with Skill-Biased Technology

W P -9 9 -5

Product Mix and Earnings Volatility at Commercial Banks:
Evidence from a Degree o f Leverage Model

W P -9 9 -6

School Choice Through Relocation: Evidence from the Washington D.C. Area

W P -9 9 -7

Banking Market Structure, Financial Dependence and Growth:
International Evidence from Industry Data

W P -9 9 -8

Asset Price Fluctuation and Price Indices

W P -9 9 -9

Jeffrey& CampbellandJonasD.M.Fisher

HisashiNakamuraandShigenoriShiratsuka
ShigenoriShiratsuka

LawrenceJ.ChristianoandChristopherJ.Gust
LawrenceJ.ChristianoandRobertJ\Vigfusson
ShouyongShi

RobertDeYoungandKarinP.Roland
LisaBarrow

NicolaCetorelliandMicheleGambera
ShigenoriShiratsuka




6