View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Assessing a Decade of Interstate Bank
Branching
Christian Johnson and Tara Rice

WP 2007-03

Assessing a Decade of Interstate Bank Branching

April 2007

Christian Johnson
Professor of Law
Loyola University Chicago School of Law
801-585-5073 or 801-842-8813
cjohns6@luc.edu
and
Tara Rice
Financial Economist
Economic Research Department
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
312-322-5274
trice@frbchi.org

The views expressed here are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago or the Federal Reserve System. We thank Erin Davis for her excellent research assistance, Gadi
Barlevy, Kristin Butcher, Jeff Campbell, Robert DeYoung, Gillian Garcia, George Kaufman, Edward J. Kane,
Spencer Krane, Anna Paulson, Dick Porter, Rich Rosen, Harvey Rosenbaum, Phil Strahan, legal counsel at various
state regulatory agencies and seminar participants at the 2005 Western Economic Association International Annual
Meeting, the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Working Paper Seminar, the University of Utah College of Law
Faculty Colloquium and the Thomas Jefferson School of Law Faculty Colloquium for comments and suggestions.
The authors also gratefully acknowledge the contribution made by Buz Gorman, General Counsel, of the Conference
of State Bank Supervisors through our many discussions on the topic.
1

Assessing a Decade of Interstate Bank Branching
Christian A. Johnson and Tara Rice
“One aspect of the American banking system that quickly impresses itself on the mind of a foreign
observer is its fragmented structure. . . . . [The] prospective developments in the payments mechanism –
electronic transfer of funds, direct deposit of payrolls, and wider use of pre-authorized credit – will
reduce the need for customers to visit their banks frequently and, though not resolving the branching
controversy, will make it academic.”1

I.

Introduction
While much has changed in the last 33 years, bank branching has not yet progressed from a

controversial issue to a purely academic one. Through its history, US banking regulation constrained
bank growth through prohibitions or restrictions on the means of direct and indirect bank expansion both
within states (termed intrastate banking and branching) and between states (interstate banking and
branching).2 Although restrictions on intrastate expansion were eliminated through piecemeal changes in
legislation over the past several decades, many restrictions remained with regard to interstate expansion.
The passage of the Riegle-Neal Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act (IBBEA) of
3

1994 removed remaining federal restrictions on interstate expansion, but allowed the states considerable
leeway in deciding the rules governing entry by out-of-state branches.4 As a result, states that were
opposed to entry used IBBEA to erect barriers to out-of-state branch entry.
IBBEA’s removal of Federal interstate branching barriers has resulted in staggering interstate
expansion. This growth, illustrated in Figure 1, was driven both by consolidation of bank subsidiaries
into branch offices and also establishment of de novo branches. In 1994, 62 out-of-state branches existed
1

Larry Mote, “The Perennial Issue: Branch Banking.” Business Conditions, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 323, (February 1974).
2
Means of geographic expansion are: (1) interstate banking (acquiring or establishing a charter in a state outside the
main bank's home state), (2) interstate branching (acquiring or establishing a branch office, an office which is not
separately chartered or capitalized, in a state outside the main bank's home state), (3) intrastate banking (acquiring or
establishing a charter within the main bank's home state) and (4) intrastate branching (acquiring or establishing a
branch office within the main bank's home state).
3
Pub. L. No. 103-328, 108 Stat. 2338 (1994) (codified in 12 U.S.C.).
4
Passage of IBBEA ignited a small flurry of commentary about the Act. See Indick, Murray A. & Satish M. Kini,
The Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act: New Options, New Problems, 112 Banking L.J. 100 (1995);
Mulloy, Patrick and Cynthia Lasker, The Riegle-Neal Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act of 1994:
Responding to Global Competition, 21 J. LEGIS 255 (1995). Rollinger, Mark D., Interstate Banking and Branching
Under the Riegle-Neal Act of 1994, 33 HARV. J. ON LEGIS. 183 (1996); Stritzel, Stacey, Note: The Riegle-Neal
Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act of 1994: Progress Toward A New Era in Financial Services
Regulation, 46 SYRACUSE L. REV. 161 (1995); Tart, Charlotte L., Expansion of the Banking Industry Under the
Riegle-Neal Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act of 1994: Is the Banking Industry Headed in the Right
Direction?, 30 WAKE FOREST L. REV. 915 (1995).
2

in a small number of states. By 2005, the number of out-of-state branches had grown to 24,728 or 40
percent of all domestic branches. 5

The number of de novo branches increased rapidly as well. Over our

sample period, 6,071 de novo out-of-state branches were started; that is, of the 15,296 total commercial
bank branch increase between 1994 and 2005, 39 percent of those were out-of-state de novo branches.
An examination of the impact of IBBEA and the effect of the state restrictions and limitations that
could be imposed on interstate branching is particularly topical today.

Banks recognize the state

anticompetitive regulatory burden permitted by IBBEA and have pressed agencies and Congress to
streamline banking law. A section contained in the “Financial Services Regulatory Relief Act”6 (which
was supported by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System) as passed by the House in 2006
would have eliminated remaining interstate branching barriers. As described in testimony before the U.S.
Senate by Federal Reserve Governor Donald Kohn, the interstate branching provisions originally
contained in the Act would remove the “last obstacle to full interstate branching for banks and level the
playing field between banks and thrifts.” 7 Although the final bill did not contain these provisions, the
issue is sure to be revisited in future bills and legislation.
Despite the recent growth in out-of-state branches, this article provides evidence that barriers to
out-of-state entry through branch banking still exist for commercial banks in the United States. Based
upon our empirical analysis, covering all 50 states plus the District of Columbia over 11 years, we find
certain state restrictions permitted by IBBEA to be associated with limited out-of-state branch growth in
some states.
The remainder of the article is organized as follows: Section II provides historical background on
the bank branching history in the United States. Section III details the changes in interstate branching law
since passage of IBBEA. Section IV discusses how initial (1994-1997) and evolving (1998-2004) state
interstate branching laws affect out-of-state branch growth in a state’s banking market. Section V presents
our index of state branching restrictions, while section VI employs that index in empirical analysis on the
effect of the individual state branching restrictions. Section VII concludes.

5

The branch banking figures are based on author’s calculations using data from the FDIC and the Federal Reserve
System. This figure represents domestic branches of domestic commercial-bank banking companies.
6
H.R. 3505 and S.2856. The House bill , passed March 2006, contains a section (401) titled “Easing the
restrictions on interstate branching and mergers,” which removes remaining restrictions on de novo interstate
branching and prohibits branching by commercially owned ILCs chartered after October 1, 2003. The Senate bill,
passed May 2006, contains no such section.
7
Before the Committee of Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs, United states Senate in March 2006. The
testimony is available online at www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/testimony/2006/20060301.
3

II.

Historical Background on Interstate Branching and IBBEA
Interstate branching has been an issue in the U.S. banking system since its inception. The issue,

however, did not become controversial until the establishment of the dual banking system during the Civil
War. These restrictions on branch banking are frequently attributed to the efforts of small banks and their
lobbies to stop large banking companies from entering into their markets. 8
Prior to the Civil War, interstate banking and branching was traditionally a state issue, with
federal law and policy typically deferring to state control. States historically have had control over
whether to permit banks chartered under their own chartering authority, state banks chartered by other
states, and national banking associations, to engage in intrastate and interstate banking and branching.
With such control, states have prevented both intrastate and interstate banking and branching up until the
recent past. As restrictions against interstate banking began to change on a piecemeal basis, Congress
removed the predominant interstate banking and branching restrictions with the passage of IBBEA,
subject, however, to a few important limitations.
With the exception of the Bank of the United States and the Second Bank of the United States,
chartered by Congress in 1791 and 1816, respectively, the chartering and regulation of banks prior to the
Civil War was almost entirely a state issue.

These two congressionally chartered banks were much

different from modern national banking associations, and were chartered essentially to assist the Federal
government with its banking needs and tax collections. Both of these banks also had a number of branch
offices, operating 8 and 27 branches respectively. Both banks, however, had limited lives; they lost their
Federal Charters in and 1811 and 1836 respectively.9
State chartered banks engaged in limited interstate branch banking prior to the Civil War.
Although both the form of branch banking and the volume of activities is quite different from today,
branch banking did occur in several regions. Limited decentralized interstate branch banking occurred in
Indiana, Ohio and Iowa. Although the different branches all shared the same charter, each branch was
“locally organized, had its own capital subscribed by its own stockholders, and paid its own dividends.”10
This model of branching was adopted by state banks in Illinois, Kentucky, Tennessee, Delaware and
8

For this study, we define the term banking company as an independent commercial bank, or a bank holding
company (BHC), or financial holding company (FHC) that controls one or more commercial banks. By definition,
a bank subsidiary of a BHC or FHC is a separately chartered institution controlled through partial or complete
ownership of its voting stock by a BHC or FHC whereas a branch office, a remote facility of a bank, requires no
separate charter. Prior to the establishment of BHCs, however, only independent banks existed. These retain the
term “bank”. A branch office is an office of a financial institution that is physically separated from its home office,
but that offers the same kinds of deposit taking, loan and other services conducted at the home office. This study
examines only domestic banking companies.
9
For a discussion of the Bank of the United States and the Second Bank of the United States, see Peter S. Rose,
Banking Across State Lines: Public and Private Consequences 25 (Quorum 1997); Robertson, supra note 4, at 2829; Macey, Miller & Carnell, Banking Law & Regulation (2001) 2-8.
4

Vermont.11
During this same period, a more centralized system of branch banking (similar to the modern
system we have today) developed primarily in the south, with branch banking occurring in Virginia,
North Carolina, South Carolina and Missouri.12

These branches, as opposed to those in the Midwest,

relied much more on capital raised in the head offices.13 This model was in substance much closer to
interstate banking than to interstate branching.
The ability to engage in interstate branching and banking was never as popular or considered to
be as important prior to the Civil War as it is today.

Because of limited interstate travel and

communication during this era, maintaining interstate branches was difficult if not impossible, with few
of the efficiencies and economies of scale possible today. With the advent of the telegraph, telephone and
better interstate travel, the ability to engage in interstate branching became more desirable.

More

recently, with advanced data processing, telecommunications, and the internet, combined with growing
overhead costs, branch banking has become a necessity (and perhaps question of survival) for most large
bank holding companies.
State control over banking became an issue during the Civil War as Congress provided for the
chartering and regulation of national banking associations through the Office of the Comptroller of the
Currency.14 Investors chartered national banks and they began to proliferate. In 1864, there were 1,089
state banks and 467 national banks in 1864. By 1865, however, the numbers had flipped; there were only
394 state banks and 1294 national banks.15
Although the National Bank Act provided directives on the regulation, supervision, and
examination of national banks, it did not provide direction on the issue of interstate and intrastate
branching regulation.16 Because of the absence of statutory guidance, the Comptroller of the Currency
provided direction. The Comptroller in 1865 ruled that sections 6 and 8 of the National Banking Act
prohibited branch banking.17 Based upon their reading of Section, every Comptroller in office until 1922
agreed that national banks could not open a bank in more than one location.18
10

Robertson, supra note 4, at 28.
Id.
12
Id. at 28-29; Macey, Miller & Carnell, supra note 9.
13
Robertson, supra note 4, at 28.
14
Act of February 25, 1863 (National Currency Act), ch. 58 (183); Act of June 3, 1864 (National Bank Act), ch.
106, (1864).
15
Eugene Nelson White, The Regulation and Reform of the American Banking System, Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press (1983) at 12.
16
Robertson, supra note 4, at 81 (“Examination of the legislative history . . . reveals no special concern about
branches”).
17
Id. at 82; Peter S. Rose, supra note 9, at 26-27.
18
Larry R. Mote, The Perennial Issue: Branch Banking, Business Conditions, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
(February 1974); Peter S. Rose, Banking Across State Lines: Public and Private Consequences 27 (Quorum 1997).
5
11

Likewise, during the next 50 years, there was little if any branching of any kind occurring at the
state level. The National Monetary Commission noted in a study commissioned in 1911 that “[u]nder
none of the state banking laws has there been built up an important system of branch banks.”19 Most state
legislatures and regulators, however, resisted permitting interstate branching for several reasons. First, a
state regulatory agency received no compensation when an in-state bank branched out of state or when an
out-of-state bank branched or expanded into their state, which left them reluctant to facilitate interstate
activity. Second, state banks often put pressure on regulators to limit entry by larger banks chartered out
side of the state that may pose competitive problems.20 Accordingly, few states permitted interstate
branching. By 1900, branch banking “accounted for only 2 percent of the resources of American
commercial banks.”21
By the turn of the century, branch banking began on a very small scale. In the early 1900s, states
began to permit some in-state branch banking.22 In 1911, California, Delaware, Florida, Georgia, New
York, Rhode Island, Virginia and Washington permitted different degrees of intrastate branch banking.23
By 1915, “397 banks maintained branches; of this group, 12 were national banks and 385 were state
banks. The 397 institutions operated 785 branches; 832 offices were in the head-office city, and 350 were
outside the head-office city.”24
National banks continued to search for ways to get around the restrictions against branch banking,
particularly as it became more profitable to do so. National banks also believed that they were in a
substantial competitive disadvantage in those situations in which state banks could branch. In 1922, in an
attempt to put national banks on a more equal footing with state banks, the OCC, based upon an opinion
from the Attorney General of the United States, permitted national banks to establish branches within
their home city (and home city only); provided, however, that a state bank was permitted to operate
branches within that city.25 Between 1922 and 1926, national banks established 200 limited service
branch offices “within their city of location.”26 State banks and their supporters opposed national-bank
branching and challenged the Comptroller's ruling. The opposition eventually came to a head in 1924,
with the Supreme Court ruling against the Comptroller.27
19

George E. Barnett, State Banks and Trust Companies Since the Passage of the National-Bank Act (Washington:
Government Printing Office 1911), at 135.
20
White, supra note 14, at 14; Robertson, supra note 4, at 100.
21
Robertson, supra note 4, at 100.
22
Rollinger, supra note 4, at 190.
23
Barrett, supra note at 136. Macey, Miller & Carnell, supra note 9, at 19; Wilmarth, Arthur E. Jr., Too Big to Fail,
Too Few to Serve? The Potential Risks of Nationwide Banks, 77 IOWA L. REV. 957, at 1092.
24
Robertson, supra note 4, at 100.
25
Id. at 102.
26
Id. at 104.
27
First National Bank in St. Louis, v. Missouri, 263 U.S. 640 (1924), aff’g 249 S.W. 619 (Mo S.Ct 1923); Peter S.
6

Although the Supreme Court ruled in favor of the state banking industry, Congress responded in
1927 by permitting a national bank to branch with the passage of the McFadden Act.28 The statute first
provided that a national bank could “retain and operate” any branches that it had as of the date of the
statute.29 Second, it stated that if a state bank were converted into, or consolidated with, a national bank,
it could retain and operate its branches.30 Third, a national bank could “establish and maintain” new
branches within the city in which it was located if state banks were permitted under the laws of its state,
subject to certain population limitations.31 Although couched in positive statutory language, the effect of
the McFadden was to limit branch banking. By inference, branching outside of the city where the
national bank was situation was prohibited—thus restricting any intrastate and interstate branching.
Congress gave national banks additional branching authorization six years later. The GlassSteagall Act of 1933 allowed nationally chartered banks to branch in the same geographical areas as statechartered banks.32 Although this was intended to place national banks on an equal footing with state
chartered banks, it instead solidified the dominant position of state regulatory authorities by assigning the
determination of intrastate branching laws to each state regulatory authority.33 National Banks were
permitted to branch wherever state-chartered banks could branch statewide. However, national banks
could also not branch if state banks had no or limited city or state wide branching rights.34
Responding to pressure from state banks after the passage of the Glass-Steagall Act, state
regulation restricted intrastate branching in an attempt to prevent entry and growth of national banks in
their states. The McFadden Act was read as to stop interstate branching by national banks. After only a
few years, half of the states restricted or prohibited banks from setting up branch offices. In addition, not
one state permitted interstate branching.35 There was some attempt to permit national banks to branch
nationwide through Federal legislation. The bill, however, was defeated by the lobbying actions of
community banks.36 In contrast to the growth of interstate banking described below, prior to passage of
IBBEA, the vast majority of states did not permit interstate branching.
These regulatory constraints on interstate banking and branching spawned the multi-bank holding
company (MBHC), first formed in the early 1900s. The MBHC structure opened a loophole in branchbanking regulations that allowed a layered organizational framework of subsidiary organizations to
Rose, Banking Across State Lines: Public and Private Consequences 28 (Quorum 1997).
28
McFadden-Pepper Act, Feb. 25, 1927, Section 7, ch. 191, 44 Stat. 1224; Rose, supra note 9, at 28.
29
McFadden-Pepper Act, Feb. 25, 1927, Section 7, ch. 191, 44 Stat. 1224 (Section 5155(a)).
30
McFadden-Pepper Act, Feb. 25, 1927, Section 6, ch. 191, 44 Stat. 1224 (Section 5155(b)).
31
McFadden-Pepper Act, Feb. 25, 1927, Section 6, ch. 191, 44 Stat. 1224 (Section 5155(c) & (d)).
32
Glass-Steagall Act, Act of June 16, 1933, 48 Stat. 162, 189 (codified at 12 USC §36).
33
Rollinger, supra note 4, at 183.
34
Rose, supra note 9, at 28.
35
Id.; Rollinger, supra note 4, at 183.
7

substitute for a network of physical branch offices.37 Banks, therefore, used the MBHC organizational
form to effect interstate operations. Over time, additional restrictions on interstate branching further
encouraged use of the banking company loophole as a means of geographic expansion, leading more
banks to convert to a banking company structure. The Bank Holding Company Act of 1956 sought to
constrain the growth of the banking companies specifically through the Douglas Amendment,38 which
prohibited acquisition by a banking company of an out-of-state bank or banking company unless
statutorily authorized by the state in which the target resides. The Bank Holding Company Act did not
apply to one-bank bank holding companies (banking companies) and it was amended in 1970 to give the
Federal Reserve authority over formation and regulation of the one-bank bank holding companies. This
regulation was intended to further restrict the operations, organizational form and expansion ability of the
bank holding companies.
Despite branch banking prohibitions by state law, Federal law allowed some minor opportunities
for interstate branch banking. One such opportunity for geographic bank expansion, through the BHC
structure, was created with the 1982 Garn-St Germain Act. A provision of this Act authorized federal
banking agencies to arrange interstate acquisitions for failed banks with total assets of $500 million or
more.39

This policy innovation allowed interstate acquisitions under special circumstances even when

such acquisitions were not in accordance with state law. Because Federal savings and loan institutions had
been permitted to branch since 1933,40 banks welcomed the opportunity to acquire failed savings and loan
companies and their branch networks during the savings and loan crisis.
A national bank could also create an interstate branch through moving their main office to a
different state, leaving the former location as a branch of the new home office.41 The only limitation was
that the new office be located not more than 30 miles from the limits of the “city, town or village” where
the main office was previously located.42 Although such a method of branching was possible, it was
limited to national banks located near state borders.

36

Rollinger, supra note 4, at 192; Wilmarth, supra note 23, at 973-74.
By definition, a subsidiary is a separately chartered institution controlled through partial or complete ownership of
its voting stock by a Multibank Holding Company (MBHC), whereas a branch office, a remote facility of a bank,
requires no separate charter.
38
Bank Holding Act of 1956, Public Law 511, 84 Cong. Ch. 240, May 9, 1956, 70 Stat. 133, Section 3(d) (the
Douglas Amendment).
39
12 USC 1823(f)(4)(B).
40
Harding de C. Williams, Federal Banking Law and Regulation: A Handbook for Lawyers 102 (2006).
41
Id. at 102-103; Barton Crockett, BankAmerica Will Merge Washington and Idaho Units Using Thirty-Mile Rule,
The American Banker, Aug. 23, 1995.
42
12 USC 30; see also Ramapo Bank v Camp, 425 F.2d 333 (3rd Cir. 1970); OCC, Interpretations- Corporate
Decision #96-40 (Aug. 2, 1996); National Bank Allowed To Relocate Main Office And Retain Former Main Office
As A Branch, 88 Banking L.J. 704 (1971).
8
37

Although interstate branching was severely restricted, over time individual state laws permitted
the geographic expansion of commercial banks through interstate banking.43 Such laws had been relaxed
prior to IBBEA for 49 of the 50 states (plus the District of Columbia) for a variety of reasons: piecemeal
changes in legislation, outside events and competition among regulators.

All states except Hawaii

permitted some type of interstate banking operations either on a reciprocal or nonreciprocal basis.44
Regional pacts allowed out-of-state bank entry only from a specific geographic region, including the
Northeast, the West, the South (often including the Mid-Atlantic states) and the Midwest.45
By 1994, while most states allowed interstate banking in some form, only eight states allowed
any form of interstate branching.46 Of those eight, six allowed interstate branching only on a national
reciprocal basis. Any state wishing to allow its banks to branch into one of those six states must also
allow the banks headquartered in the six states to branch into their own state. One state, Nevada, allowed
interstate branching on a very limited, but nonreciprocal basis. It permitted interstate branching into
counties with a population less than 100,000. Utah was the only state that allowed national nonreciprocal
interstate branching before IBBEA, and it did so for just three years (as of July 1991) before IBBEA was
passed. Even though these rules were on the books, there was almost no interstate branch banking prior
to the passage of IBBEA in 1995.
Thus, very few banking organizations had an opportunity to branch across state lines due to the
preexisting legislation, and were restricted to expansion through only two means: (1) chartering a
subsidiary in the desired state (called a "de novo bank entry")47, or (2) acquiring an out-of-state bank to
convert to a subsidiary of the parent bank.
This changed dramatically with passage of IBBEA, which allows banks to expand though its
repeal of interstate banking and branching restrictions (subject, however, to the permitted state provisions
discussed below). The repeal of restrictions allows banking companies to merge either subsidiary or
branch banks across state lines in four ways:
(1) Interstate bank acquisitions (acquisitions of separately chartered institutions),
(2) Interstate agency operations (allows a bank subsidiary of a banking company to act as an
43

For a discussion of interstate banking, see Macey, Miller & Carnell, supra note 9, at 26-27, 32-33; Douglas
Ginsburg, Interstate Banking, 9 Hofstra Law Review 1133 (1981).
44
H.R. Rep. 103-448, 1994 U.S.C.C.A.N. 2039, 1994 WL 96120 (Leg. Hist.), at 2044.
45
See Northeast Bancorp v. Board of Governors, 472 U.S. 159 (1985) (upholding regional pacts); H. Rodgin Cohen,
State Interstate Banking Legislation, 597 PLI/Corp 375 (1988); Arnold G. Danielson, Tenth Anniversary of
Interstate Banking: The Southern Experience, 11 No. 9 Banking Pol’y Rep. 4 (May 4, 1992); Interstate Banking’s
Tenth Anniversary: The Midwest Experience, 11 No. 14 Banking Pol’y Rep. 6 (July 20, 1992).
46
Dean Amel, State Laws Affecting Geographic Expansion of Commercial Banks, unpublished manuscript, Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (1993). Those states are: Alaska, Massachusetts, New York, Oregon,
Rhode Island, Nevada, North Carolina and Utah.
47
A de novo bank is a newly chartered bank, as opposed to a bank that has been acquired or merged from an
9

agent of an affiliate of the banking company without being legally considered as a branch of that
affiliate),
(3) Interstate branching (consolidation of acquired banks or individual branches into branches of
the acquiring bank),
(4) De novo branching (establishment of a new branch office of a banking company across state
lines, into states which have passed a statute expressly allowing it.).48

Thus, the watershed event of IBBEA was not the allowance of interstate banking, but the explicit
permission of interstate branching. This gave banking companies the freedom to consolidate bank
subsidiaries into branch offices and to branch, under the provisions described below, across state lines.
States could "opt-in" early or "opt-out" of the IBBEA interstate branching provision by passing a
state law any time between the passage of IBBEA (September 1994) and the trigger date (June 1, 1997).
"Opting-in" required the state to pass a statute allowing interstate branching prior to June 1997. This
provision expressly permitted interstate consolidation and merger transactions prior to June 1, 1997,
provided that each MBHC or subsidiary involved in the transaction was located in a state which also
"opted-in" early. A state that "opted-out" of interstate branching prevented both the state and national
banks from branching across its borders. The provision, however, did not give banks complete freedom
to branch out of state. As discussed, from the time of enactment until the branching "trigger date" of June
1, 1997, IBBEA allowed states to determine many details related to this provision. Most states, in fact,
used this provision to impose conditions on the entry of out-of-state banks.
Although all fifty states and the District of Columbia have opted into interstate branching, there
was considerable debate and activity in many states over whether their state should opt out of interstate
branching. The pressure to opt out of interstate branching under IBBEA was based on the small bank
versus big bank special interest issues that had thwarted interstate branching in the past.49 Some argued
that interstate branching might imperil smaller communities by siphoning deposits out of the towns and
using them to make loans to larger clients in financial centers elsewhere.50
States that debated opting out included Texas, Colorado, Missouri, Oklahoma, Montana, New
Mexico, Nebraska and Kansas,51 with Texas and Montana opting out initially, though they later opted
existing institution.
48
Edward J. Kane, De Jure Interstate Banking: Why Only Now? Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 28 No. 2
(May 1996).
49
Joseph D. Hutnyan, States Start Considering Whether or When to Opt for Interstate Branching, 14 No. 5 Banking
Pol’y Rep. 7 (March 6, 1995); Carter H. Golembe, History Offers Some Clues on Signficancce of Interstate
Branching, 13 No. 15 Banking Pol’y Rep. 4 (Aug 15, 1994).
50
Barbara F. Bronstien, Opt-Out Pitch: Branching Imperials Small Towns, The American Banker, August 25, 1995.
51
Terrence O’Hara, Circling the Wagons to Fend Off Branching, The American Banker, Feb. 15, 1995; Barbara F.
10

in.52 The Colorado legislature also initially opted out, but the Governor later vetoed the legislation.53
Lobbyists for smaller banks such as the Independent Bankers Association of America, the California
Independent Bankers and the Independent Bankers Association of Texas all lobbied extensively to
persuade states to opt-out of interstate branching.54 We discuss in greater detail below the provisions
determined by Federal law and by the individual states.

III.

IBBEA Interstate Banking and Branching Provisions Determined by Federal Law
The fundamental regulatory paradigm for interstate banking and branching changed dramatically

with the passage of IBBEA. The statute is effectively divided into two portions. Section 101 of IBBEA
deals with interstate banking while Sections 102 and 103 deals with interstate branching as summarized
below.

A.

IBBEA Provisions with regard to Interstate Banking

IBBEA allowed interstate bank acquisitions after September 29, 1995, and repealed the Douglas
Amendment of the 1956 Bank Holding Company Act.55 It expressly permits the Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System (the “Board”) to approve interstate bank acquisitions, regardless of whether
such acquisition would have been permitted under “the law of any state.” Unlike the interstate branching
provisions discussed below, the states were not permitted to opt out of the interstate banking rules.
IBBEA does impose certain Federal level restrictions on interstate banking. First, the bank
holding company acquiring the bank must be “adequately capitalized” and “adequately managed.”56
Second, the bank holding company after the acquisition may not exceed a nationwide deposit
concentration limitation of “more than 10 percent of the total amount of deposits of insured depository
institutions in the United States.”57 Third, the bank holding company may not exceed a statewide deposit
Bronstein, Focus on Kansas, The American Banker (Aug. 25, 1995) ; Barbara F. Bronstien, Iowa Group’s Departing
President Says “No” to Interstate Branching, The American Banker (July 21, 1995); Setback Puts Oklahoma Foes of
Interstate on Defensive, The American Banker, March 22, 1995; Terrence O’Hara, a Colorado Thumbs down for
Branching, The American Banker, Feb. 24, 1995.
52
Terrence O’Hara, Texas Governor to Sign Bill Letting State Opt Out of Branching Law, The American Banker,
April 28, 1995.
53
Terrence O’Hara, Colorado Governor’s Refusal to Slam Door to Out-of-State Banks Leads to Compromise, The
American Banker, April 25, 1995.
54
Hutnyan, supra note 49; Christopher Rhoads, Trade Group Wars, The American Banker (Sept. 21, 1995);
Terrence O’Hara, A Arsenal of Opt Out: $250,000 of Ammo from the IBAA, The American Banker, Feb. 15, 1995.
55
IBBEA, Section 101.
56
IBBEA, Section 101(a), codified at 12 USC §1842(d)(1)(A).
57
IBBEA, Section 101, codified at 12 USC §1842(d)(2)(A). The 10 percent limitation has already become
problematic for some bank holding companies. For example, Bank of America has already reached that limit after
its acquisition of FleetBoston. Effectively Bank of America will longer be unable to grow through the acquisition of
additional banks. Instead, Bank of America will need to grow its deposit base internally. Order of the Board of
11

concentration limitation, after the acquisition, of more than 30 percent.58 IBBEA, however, did not affect
the right of a state to impose a deposit cap that would limit the amount of deposits below 30 percent.59
In addition to preserving state deposit cap limitations, IBBEA also preserved state age laws,
subject to an important exception. An acquisition is not permitted if it does not does not comply with a
state’s age law that limits acquisitions of a “bank that has been in existence for a minimum period of
time” provided that the minimum age does not exceed five years.60 IBBEA also does not affect the
Board’s right to take into account the applicability of a state’s community reinvestment laws61 or a state’s
antitrust laws.62 In addition, IBBEA does not affect a state’s authority to tax the bank, the bank holding
company and any affiliates of a bank.63 Even given these limitations, the overall effect of IBBEA on
interstate banking was to eliminate the last vestiges of state interstate banking restrictions.

B.

IBBEA provisions with regard to Interstate Branching

IBBEA permits a national or state bank to engage in interstate branching, subject to certain
limitations. Essentially a bank may engage in interstate branching by (i) purchasing an out-of-state bank
and converting that bank into a branch, or (ii) subject to state banking law, either purchase the branch of
an out-of-state bank or open a “do novo” branch in a state other than its home state. As discussed above,
IBBEA did permit a state to “opt-out” of interstate branching and also to “opt-in” early. Finally, IBBEA
preserved a state’s deposit cap and minimum age laws with respect to interstate branching.

Interstate Bank Mergers. Beginning June 1, 1997, IBBEA permits a merger between insured
banks with different home states, without regard to whether such transaction is prohibited under the law
of any State.64 As part of the merger transaction, one bank would essentially be converted into an out-ofstate branch or branches of the surviving bank. IBBEA also permits, subject to state law, a bank to
acquire an out-of-state branch and substantively merge it into the bank.65
Although IBBEA was intended to apply to all states, it did permit a state to “expressly” prohibit
all “merger transactions involving out-of-state banks,”66 effectively preventing interstate branching for
Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Order Approving the Merger of Bank Holdings Companies (Bank of
America Corporation – FleetBoston Financial Corporation), March 8, 2004.
58
IBBEA, Section 101, codified at 12 USC §1842(d)(2)(B).
59
IBBEA, Section 101, codified at 12 USC §1842(d)(2)(C).
60
IBBEA, Section 101(a), codified at 12 USC §1842(d)(1)(B).
61
IBBEA, Section 101(a), codified at 12 USC § 1842(d)(3).
62
IBBEA, Section 101(a), codified at 12 USC §1842(d)(4).
63
IBBEA, Section 101(b), codified at 12 USC §1846(b).
64
IBBEA, Section 102(a), codified at 12 USC §1831u(a)(1).
65
IBBEA, Section 102(a), codified at 12 USC §1831u(a)(4).
66
IBBEA, Section 102(a), codified at 12 USC §1831u(a)(2).
12

that state. This was commonly referred to as a bank’s ability to “opt-out” of interstate branching. The
only requirements were that a state had (i) to opt-out of interstate branching after the enactment date of
IBBEA (September 29, 1994) and before June 1, 1997 and (ii) it had to apply “equally to all out-of-state
banks.”67 Only Texas and Montana elected to opt-out of interstate branching, although both states later
opted back in. IBBEA also permitted a state to “opt-in” early to interstate branching. An interstate
merger transaction (that resulted in out-of-state branches) could occur prior to June 1, 1997, provided that
the state had enacted a statute permitting such transaction.68
IBBEA imposes several Federal level limitations on interstate branching. First, both banks must
be adequately capitalized prior to the merger transaction and the resulting bank after the merger must also
be “adequately capitalized” and “adequately managed.”69 Second, the resulting bank after the merger
may not exceed a nationwide deposit concentration limitation of “more than 10 percent of the total
amount of deposits of insured depository institutions in the United States.”70 Third, for other than initial
entries, the resulting bank may not control 30 percent or more of the deposits in either its home state or in
any of its out-of-state branches host states, although a state is permitted to decrease or increase that
percentage as will be discussed below.71

C.

IBBEA Branching Provisions Determined by Individual States

While IBBEA opened the doors to nationwide branching, it allowed the states to have
considerable influence in the manner in which it was implemented, permitting states to effectively impose
anticompetitive obstacles to interstate branching.

It gave states the ability to set regulations on interstate

branching with regard to four important provisions: (1) the minimum age of the target institution to be
acquired and then merged into the acquirer, (2) de novo interstate branching, (3) acquisition of individual
branches, and (4) statewide deposit cap.

IBBEA does also not limit a state’s ability to apply reciprocity

conditions on those wanting to branch into the state. Over the past decade, some states have been
relaxing those restrictions.

Minimum Age of Target Institution
Although IBBEA expressly permits interstate branching through interstate bank mergers, IBBEA
preserves state age laws with respect to such acquisitions. Under IBBEA, states are allowed to set their
67

IBBEA, Section 102(a), codified at 12 USC §1831u(b)(2).
IBBEA, Section 102(a), codified at 12 USC §1831u(b)(3).
69
IBBEA, Section 102(a), codified at 12 USC§1831u(b)(4).
70
IBBEA, Section 102(a), codified at 12 USC §1831u(b)(2)(A). The 10 percent limitation has already become
problematic for some bank holding companies. See note 58.
71
IBBEA, Section 102(a), codified at 12 USC §1831u(b)(2)(B).
13
68

own minimum age requirements with respect to how long a bank has been in existence prior to its
acquisition in an interstate bank merger.72 The state law, however, cannot impose an age requirement of
more than five years.73
This rule applies to all banks, whether they are chartered by a state regulatory agency or the OCC.
If a newly established subsidiary office is located in a state which mandates a minimum age requirement,
then the banking company must wait to consolidate the subsidiary to a branch until the subsidiary has met
the necessary age requirement.
Many states set their age requirement at five years, but several states implemented a lower state
age requirement (three years or less) or required no minimum age limit at all. The age requirement of the
subsidiary office restricts entry of out-of-state banks that wish to establish branch offices, or slows
consolidation for banking companies with newly established subsidiaries located in states with such
requirements.
An age requirement serves two important functions for a state banking industry. First, it protects
older and established banks in the state. To branch into a state with an age requirement, the only mode of
entry is to buy an older institution and merge it into the bank. Second, it imposes significant costs on outof-state entry. Rather than simply opening a de novo branch office, a bank is required to purchase an
entire operating bank to enter a state. Separate bank charters are presumably more costly than a branch
office because they require separate charters, management, capital, and Board of Directors.

De novo Interstate Branching
While interstate branching done through an interstate bank merger (i.e. the purchase and
conversion of an existing bank to a branch office) is now permitted in every state, de novo interstate
branching is only permitted under IBBEA if a state explicitly “opts-in” to this provision; that is, a bank is
allowed to open an interstate branch if state law expressly permits it to do so.74
This provision applies only to initial entry, though this is not stated in many of the statutes. This
implies that, if a bank is able to enter a state through a loophole and establish one initial out-of-state
branch, it may then open other branches in that state. We discuss this important distinction and its
implications below.
De novo branching allows a bank to branch interstate without the costs of purchasing an
operating bank, discussed above. A de novo branching rule benefits all banking companies wishing to

72

IBBEA, Section 102(a), codified at 12 USC §1831u(a)(5)(A).
IBBEA, Section 102(a), codified at 12 USC §1231u(a)(5)(B).
74
IBBEA, Section 103, codified at12 USC §36(g) (national banks and state member banks pursuant to 12 USC
§321) and 12 USC §1828(d).
73

14

enter a state; but small banking companies may benefit more than large banking companies, since they
may be less able acquire an existing bank than to open a branch office.

Acquisition of Single Branches or Other Portions of an Institution
IBBEA states that an interstate merger transaction may involve the acquisition of a branch (or
number of branches) of a bank without the acquisition of the entire bank itself only if the state in which
the branch is located permits such a purchase.75 Again, states must explicitly “opt-in” to this provision.
In enacting such a provision, many states also subject a branch acquisition to an age requirement.
Such a provision makes it less costly and more efficient for a bank to engage in interstate
branching. Rather than being required to enter into an interstate merger of an entire bank in order to
interstate branch, a bank may now choose those interstate branches that it wishes to acquire. For
example, an Indiana bank wanting to interstate branch into Illinois may only want to acquire the Chicago
branches of an Illinois bank as opposed to acquiring the Peoria branches as well.

Statewide Deposit Cap
Under IBBEA, an interstate merger (other than with respect to initial entry) will not be approved
if the resulting bank (including any affiliated insured depository institutions) controlled 30 percent or
more of the insured deposits in the state.76

This limitation, however, is not to be construed to affect a

state’s authority to limit the percentage of deposits that may be controlled by a bank or holding
company.77 IBBEA preserves the right of a state to impose a deposit cap on an interstate bank merger
transaction below 30 percent and also to impose limitations with respect to initial entry. The provision
should also be read to preserve a state’s right to permit deposit concentration levels to exceed 30 percent.
The obvious impact of a deposit concentration limitation would be to prevent a bank from
entering into a larger interstate merger in such state. For example, if a state had set a deposit cap of 15
percent, a bank could not enter into an interstate merger transaction with any institution that held more
than 15 percent of the deposits in that particular state. A state could also try to encourage interstate
mergers by permitting concentration levels to exceed 30 percent in order to attract an out-of-state
acquirer.

75

IBBEA, Section 102(a), codified at 12 USC §1831u(a)(2).
IBBEA, Section 102(a), codified at 12 USC §1831.
77
IBBEA, Section 102, codified at 12 USC §1831u(b)(2)(C).
76

15

Reciprocity
Rather than specifically permitting or prohibiting de novo branching, acquisition of a branch or
portion of a bank, a set age requirement or deposit cap, many states chose to offer these four provisions
with reciprocity. In other words, the state would allow the particular action by an out-of-sate bank so
long as the laws of the state for that out-of-state bank were reciprocal, permitting the same level of
interstate branching. For example, a state could permit de novo entry into its state, provided that the state
in which the out-of-state bank is either chartered (or headquartered in the case of a national bank) also
permitted de novo entry into their state.

IV.

States’ Response to Interstate Branching Provisions
To collect information on each state’s initial IBBEA provisions and changes to those provisions

between 1994 and 2005, we surveyed individual state statues over the 11 year period.78 We collected all
state statutes that address interstate branching and interpreted the provisions, and changes to those
provisions.79 We discuss the states’ regulatory actions for each provision in turn below.
Table 1 details the changes to state interstate branching law. Since the 1997 “trigger date,” 13
states have eased their initial restrictions on interstate branching. Those states are: Georgia, Hawaii,
Illinois, Kentucky, Montana, New Hampshire, North Dakota, Oklahoma, Tennessee, Texas, Utah,
Washington and Vermont. Table 2 lists for 1997 and 2005 the number of states that allowed or prohibited
each of the four state-determined provisions. This table shows, generally, that over time, states eased
their interstate branching restrictions. Appendix A lists each of the states interstate branching laws from
1994-2005.

Minimum Age of Target Institution
As of the 1997 trigger date, 30 states had a five-year minimum age requirement.80 Five had a
three-year age requirement, 14 had no age requirement, three of which with an added reciprocity
condition, and two states (Montana and Texas) opt-ed out. By year end 2005, 24 states had a five-year
minimum age requirement, seven had a three-year minimum age requirement, 20 had no age requirement,
78

The Conference of State Bank Supervisors (CSBS) publishes a respected “Profile of State-Chartered Banking”
every two years. See Conference of State Bank Supervisors, A Profile of State-Chartered Banking. Washington,
DC: The Conference of State Bank Supervisors 2002. Although the information included on interstate branching is
useful, it is collected through voluntary surveys to the individual states. The state responses are not uniform, and
thus could not be used in our empirical analysis which covers, annually, the 50 states plus the District of Columbia
over the 11 year period studied.
79
We also contacted the individual state regulatory agencies when we found discrepancies, ambiguities or omissions
in the state statutes.
80
Oregon’s law (passed prior to the trigger date) was effective 07/01/1997. One state (Arizona) had a 5 year
16

six of which with reciprocity requirements. Most of the states that changed their statutes over the time
period generally moved from a five year requirement to no age requirement. One state, Indiana, added a
minimum age requirement. In 1997, it had no age requirement, but added a five year age requirement in
1998.

Statewide Deposit Cap on Branch Acquisition
In 1997, 33 states plus the District of Columbia imposed a 30 percent statewide deposit cap, the
standard set by IBBEA. Some states enacted legislation that explicitly enacted a state-wide deposit cap of
30 percent, while some states were silent on the deposit cap, in which case, the IBBEA state-wide cap
applies. 11 states imposed a statewide deposit cap less than 30 percent; more restrictive than IBBEA
dictates. Two states chose statewide deposit caps greater than 30 percent, and two states expressly
imposed no deposit cap. Only three states made changes to their statewide deposit caps over time; all
increased the cap.

De novo Interstate Branching
As of 1997, 12 states and the District of Columbia allowed de novo branching. Of those, eight
states allowed it with reciprocity, 36 states prohibited de novo branching, and two (Montana and Texas)
opted-out. By year end 2005, 22 states plus the District of Columbia allowed de novo branching, 16 of
the 22 states allowed it with reciprocity, and 28 states prohibited de novo branching. States that made
changes moved from prohibiting de novo branching to either allowing it unrestricted or with reciprocity.
All states that made changes over the time period eased restrictions.

Acquisition of Single Branches or Other Portions of an Institution
In 1997, 31 states prohibited acquisition of a branch or a portion of a bank. 18 states allowed it;
10 states plus the District of Columbia allowed unrestricted and seven states allowed it with reciprocity.
Again, the two states of Montana and Texas opted-out. By year end 2005, 24 states, 7 fewer than in 1997,
prohibited acquisition of branches or a portion of a bank. 27 allowed it, 13 unrestricted and 14 with
reciprocity. All states that changed restrictions over time eased those restrictions.

Reciprocity
By the end of 2005, 16 states allowed de novo branching with reciprocity. This means that an
out-of-state bank could enter into one of those 16 states through de novo branching as long as their home
minimum age requirement with reciprocity.
17

state also allowed it. Over time, the number of states permitting de novo branching or acquisition of a
branch or portion of a bank with reciprocity increased.

V.

Description of State Branching-Restriction Index
Using our information on state branching statutes, we create quantitative measures to assess the

relative restrictiveness of the state interstate branching law post-IBBEA. We do this in two ways. First,
we assign a value of one for each factor to the states which set more restrictive provisions than those set
by IBBEA for each of the provisions discussed above (minimum age for acquisition, de novo interstate
branching, interstate branching by acquisition of a single branch or other portions of an institution, and
statewide deposit cap).
Since states had to explicitly enact legislation if they chose to deviate from the interstate
branching provisions outlined in IBBEA (in Section III.b.), we implicitly assume that IBBEA is the
benchmark. We, therefore, define the state restriction variables as follows: Deposit Cap equals 1 if a state
enacted deposit cap of 30 percent or less; otherwise Deposit Cap equals zero. Minimum Age equals 1 if a
state enacted a 3 or 5 year minimum age for acquisition requirement, otherwise, it equals zero. De Novo
Branching equals 1 if a state prohibits it, otherwise it equals zero. Single Branch Acquisition equals 1 if a
state prohibits it, otherwise it equals zero.
Reciprocity equals 1 if the state instituted a reciprocity condition, otherwise it equals zero. It is
not evident how the reciprocity condition affects out-of-state branch growth. Generally, states that
imposed a reciprocity condition were more open (less restrictive) with regard to interstate branch
regulation. These states had lower barriers to entry than some others, yet banks in states that wished to
open branching in states with reciprocity had to be equally open.
We also create an index to proxy for a restrictive interstate branching regulatory environment.
We aggregate the four factors, to give a value for the index between zero and four, with zero being the
least restrictive and four being the most restrictive. Our index is equally weighted between the four
factors. Since we have collected the information on state statutes and changes to those statutes since
1994, we have a dynamic index that changes over time.

VI.

Data and Analysis
Data
Our data set consists of all banking companies that existed from 1994 (the year in which IBBEA

was enacted) through 2005. For each banking company, we also include its subsidiary bank and branch
data. The parent bank holding company consolidated financial data are collected from the Federal
18

Reserve Board's FR Y-9C reports. The bank-specific financial data are taken from the Federal Financial
Institutions Examination Council's Consolidated Reports of Condition and Income (call reports). The
branch data come from the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation's Summary of Deposits data.
The three data sets are merged by the top-tier entity (be it a bank or bank holding company), with
one observation for each bank and branch office owned by that top-tier entity. We then aggregate the
banking company information for each state and construct a panel set where each state plus the District of
Columbia has one observation per year for the entire sample period. The resulting panel has 612
observations. Finally, to this set, we add the state interstate branching variables representing each of the
four state provisions, the reciprocity condition and our state restriction index.

Empirical Analysis
Table 3 contains the summary statistics of our variables for the years 1994, 1997, 2000, and 2005.
The table shows that the restriction index has declined over time. This decline is consistent with Table 2
which shows that over time the state laws became, on average, less restrictive. The increasing number of
out-of-state branch offices and the proportion of out-of-state branches to total branches is consistent with
our hypothesis that as state regulations became less restrictive, more out-of-state branches would emerge.
The table suggests that the restrictive post-IBBEA state interstate branching laws may be
negatively associated with growth of out-of-state branches. We test this hypothesis within a simple
framework. Namely, we wish to examine whether these provisions, when more restrictive than the
provisions set by either IBBEA or neighboring states individually have affected the growth of out-of-state
branches between 1994 and 2005. We, therefore, model out-of-state branches at the state level as a
function of these four state restrictions, which limits competition from out-of-state banks, and a number
of controls.
The general form of the model is:
Out-of-state branchesit = ai + ß1it* state restrictions + ß2it*reciprocity + ei,

(1)

where the dependent variable, out-of-state branches, is the number of out-of-state branches to
total branches, state restrictions is, alternatively, each of the state branching variables or our interstate
branching index, reciprocity is an indicator variable for whether the states imposed a reciprocity
condition, i indexes the 50 states plus the District of Columbia and t indexes the years 1994-2005.81 We
include reciprocity because this condition directly affects whether the provision itself applies uniformly to
all out-of-state banks wishing to establish branch offices in a particular state.
81

This regression model is used to evaluate the linear relationship between the out-of-state branch growth (the
dependent variable) and the individual state restriction variables (the explanatory variables), the regression
coefficients are represented by a (the intercept) and B1 and B2.
19

Table 4 contains our regression results. Our model is estimated using ordinary least squares
(OLS) techniques with state and time fixed effects.

The superscripts *, **, and *** denote statistical

significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent and 1 percent levels, respectively. The regression R-squared
statistics are included in the last row.

The R-squared statistics for the 5 alternative regression

specifications, listed in Table 4, range between 0.29 and 0.32.
Each of the columns 1-4 includes one of the four provisions, time and state fixed effects, a
constant term and the reciprocity indicator variable. Column 5 contains regression results using the
restriction index, the sum of the four provisions, time and state fixed effects, a constant term and the
reciprocity indicator variable.
Our initial empirical results support our hypothesis. If higher interstate branching restrictions
were associated with fewer out-of-state branches then we would expect the coefficients (the ß1 estimates
of the dependent variables) to be negative and statistically significant. Our results indicate that two of the
four provisions are statistically significant (acquisition of single branches at the 5 percent level and the
statewide deposit cap at the 1 percent level). From this result we infer that these two provisions,
specifically, adversely affect out-of-state branch growth in states by prohibiting acquisition of single
branches and by having a lower statewide deposit cap. The estimated coefficients for de novo branching
and the minimum age requirement are not statistically significant, which suggests that these two
restrictions are not binding constraints; that is, banking companies were either able to circumvent the
minimum age requirement and prohibition on de novo branching or that the other restrictions were more
binding than these two restrictions.
The coefficient on the restriction index is negative and statistically significant at the 1 percent
level, suggesting that as a whole, the four provisions together, when more restrictive than the provisions
set by either IBBEA or neighboring states resulted in fewer out-of-state branches in those states. The
coefficient on reciprocity is not significant, suggesting that this condition did not affect out-of-state
branch growth.

VII. Summary and Conclusion
When implemented, it appeared that IBBEA allowed unrestricted interstate branching across all
states. But, in fact, it allowed states to create barriers to out-of-state branch entry. This study identifies
these restrictions and provides initial evidence that the provisions affected out-of-state branch growth.
We conclude that two of the four provisions granted the states by IBBEA (the state-wide deposit
cap and prohibition on the acquisition of single branches) restricted out-of-state branch growth when
those provisions were more restrictive than the provisions set by either IBBEA or neighboring states. We
20

find, however, that the minimum age requirement and de novo interstate branching did not materially
affect out-of-state branch growth. It is likely that banks were simply able to circumvent these restrictions
or that the other two provisions were more restrictive, or constraining, to out-of-state branch growth.
Our results suggest that the elimination of remaining interstate branching restrictions would likely
result in increased out-of-state branch growth by lowering the barriers (or costs) for out-of-state banks to
enter new banking markets.

21

Number of Banks/BHCs

4,400

4,600

4,800

5,000

5,200

5,400

5,600

5,800

6,000

1994

1995

1996
Banks

1997

BHCs

1998

1999

Branches

2000

2002
Out-of-state branches

2001

2003

2004

Figure 1
Number of Banks, Bank Holding Companies and Branches in the U.S.: 1994 - 2005

2005

0

10000

20000

30000

40000

50000

60000

70000

Number of Branches

22

North Carolina

New Hampshire

New Hampshire

Montana

Kentucky

Kentucky

Indiana

Illinois

Hawaii

Georgia

Arizona

State

Eliminated minimum age requirement.
Allowed de novo branching, branch acquisition, and changed state deposit cap from 20% to
30%.
Three statutes enacted between 1995 and 1999, but the last two contained no effective change.
The original act (1995) permitted de novo branching and branch acquisition with reciprocity
until 1997. In 1997, North Carolina extended the reciprocity condition until 1999. In 1999,
North Carolina made the reciprocity condition permanent by eliminating the clause that
reciprocity expire on 6/1/99.

Eliminated minimum age requirement.
Opted in. Allowed branch acquisition with 5 year minimum age requirement, increased state
deposit cap by 1% annually to a maximum of 22%.

Added reciprocity condition for minimum age requirement.

Added minimum age requirement.

Allowed de novo branching, branch acquisition and eliminated minimum age requirement.
Allowed de novo branching, branch acquisition and eliminated minimum age requirement.
Added reciprocity condition for minimum age requirement, de novo branching and branch
acquisition.

Reduced minimum age requirement from 5 to 3 years.

No effective changes in statute. Though it was enacted 9/1/1996, not until 8/31/01 could an
out of state bank acquire a single branch (with a minimum 5 year age requirement). Added
reciprocity condition for minimum age requirement and branch acquisition.

Post enactment changes

Table 1
States that Revised Interstate Branching Provisions between 1997 and 2005

7/1/1995

8/1/2000

1/1/2002

10/1/2001

3/17/2000

3/22/2004

7/1/1998

8/20/2004

1/1/2001

5/10/2002

8/31/2001

Effective Date

23

Washington

Vermont

Utah

Texas

Tennessee

Tennessee

Tennessee

Oklahoma

North Dakota

Allowed de novo branching. Added reciprocity condition.
Eliminated minimum age requirement, allowed de novo branching. Added reciprocity
condition for de novo branching.
Allowed de novo branching and branch acquisition. Added reciprocity condition for de novo
branching and branch acquisition.

Allowed branch acquisition. Added reciprocity condition for branch acquisition.
Allowed de novo branching and branch acquisition. Added reciprocity condition for de novo
branching and branch acquisition. No minimum age requirement for states with reciprocity, 5
year minimum age requirement for states with no reciprocity.

Allowed de novo branching. Added reciprocity condition for de novo branching.

Reduced minimum age requirement from 5 to 3 years in 2003.

Allowed de novo branching and branch acquisition. Added reciprocity condition for de novo
branching and branch acquisition.
Allowed de novo branching, branch acquisition, eliminated minimum age requirement, and
increased state deposit cap from 15% to 20% in 2000.

Table 1 (continued)
States that Revised Interstate Branching Provisions between 1997 and 2005

05/09/2005

01/01/2001

4/30/2001

9/1/1999

5/1/1998

7/1/2001

3/17/2003

5/17/2000

8/1/2003

24

35

2005

* Montana and Texas originally opted-out of IBBEA

34

1997

14

13

<30%

30%

Statewide Deposit Cap

7

24

2005

5

30

1997

Minimum Age Requirement

7

2005

5 years

5

1997

3 years

28

2

2

>30%

14

11

16

2

2

None

6

3

Reciprocity

0

2

N/A*

0

2

N/A*

0

2

N/A*

Allowed with
Reciprocity
8

0

2

N/A*

13

6

Allowed with
Reciprocity

No Minimum Age
Requirement

Allowed

36

Prohibited

14

2005

De novo Branches

24

12

31

Prohibited

1997

Acquisition of Branches

Allowed

Table 2
Number of States that Allowed or Prohibited each of the State-determined Provisions: 1997 and 2005

25

Table 3
Summary Statistics
The state restriction variables are defined as follows: Deposit Cap equals 1 if a state enacted deposit cap of 30
percent or less; otherwise Deposit Cap equals 0. Minimum Age equals 1 if a state enacted 3 or 5 year minimum
age for acquisition requirement, otherwise, it equals 0. De Novo Branching equals 1 if a state prohibits it, otherwise
it equals 0. Single Branch Acquisition equals 1 if a state prohibits it, else 0, and finally, Reciprocity equals 1 if the
state instituted a reciprocity condition, else 0.

1994

1997
Mean (Std. Dev)

2000

2005

Number of out-of-state
branches per state

1.22
(5.85)

161.20
(249.96)

323.47
(421.74)

484.86
(561.16)

Proportion of out-of-state
branches to total branches

0.0074
(0.0373)

0.1849
(0.2208)

0.2603
(0.2277)

0.3728
(0.2101)

Restriction Index

N/A

2.491
(1.461)

2.314
(1.378)

1.941
(1.489)

Minimum age dummy

N/A

0.745
(0.440)

0.706
(0.460)

0.627
(0.488)

De Novo Branching
dummy
Acquisition of Single
Branches
dummy

N/A

0.745
(0.440)

0.706
(0.460)

0.549
(0.503)

N/A

0.647
(0.482)

0.588
(0.497)

0.471
(0.504)

N/A

0.353
(0.483)

0.314
(0.469)

0.294
(0.460)

Deposit Cap
dummy

26

Table 4
Regression Results
Regression results for balance panel (N=612) of 50 states plus District of Columbia, aggregated from bank/branch
level data, 1994-2005. The dependent variable equals the number of out-of-state branches to total branches. All
variables are based on annual observations from year t. Equations are estimated with fixed time and state effects. The
superscripts *, **, and *** denote statistical significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent and 1 percent levels, respectively.
T-statistics are included in parentheses.

1
Acquisition of
single branches

2

3

4

5

-0.0460**
(-2.26)

Allows de novo
branches

-0.0242
(-1.19)
-0.0046
(-0.23)

Minimum age
requirement

-0.0776***
(-3.87)

Statewide
Deposit Cap

-0.0164**
(-2.47)

Restriction Index

Reciprocity

0.0210
(0.73)

0.0329
(1.15)

0.0436
(1.59)

0.0385
(1.45)

0.0219
(0.78)

constant

0.0525**
(2.07)

0.0317
(1.23)

0.0121
(0.47)

0.0835***
(3.33)

0.0722**
(2.36)

R-squared

0.295

0.290

0.287

0.318

0.297

27

1/1/1994

1993 Alaska Sess.
Laws 87

Alaska

8/31/2001

9/1/1996

6/1/1997

1996 Ariz. Sess.
Laws 81

1997 Ark. Acts
408

Arizona

Arkansas

Arizona

1996 Ariz. Sess.
Laws 81

No effective changes in
statute. Though it was
enacted 9/1/1996, not
until 8/31/01 could an out
of state bank acquire a
single branch (with a
minimum 5 year age
requirement). Added
reciprocity condition for
minimum age requirement
and branch acquisition.

5/31/1997

Effective Date

Alabama

Session Law
1995 Ala. Laws
115

State

Changes to State
Interstate Branching
Laws

No; Ariz. Rev.
Stat. §6-324

No; Ariz. Rev.
Stat. §6-324

No; Ark. Code
§23-48-904

5 years;
reciprocity
required; Ariz.
Rev. Stat. §6324
5 years; Ark.
Code §23-48903 - §23-45102(18)

Yes; Alaska
Stat.
§06.05.550(a)

No; Alaska
Stat.
§06.05.550(b)

No; Ark. Code
§23-48-904

No; Ariz. Rev.
Stat. §6322(E)

Yes;
reciprocity
required; Ariz.
Rev. Stat. §6322(E)

No; Ala. Code
§5-13B-23(e)

1831(u)(a)(4)
Interstate
Branching by
Acquisition of
Single
Branches or
Other
Portions of an
Institution

No; Ala. Code
§5-13B-23(d)

36(g)(1) &
1828(b)(4)
opt-in Allows
de novo
Interstate
Branching

5 years;
reciprocity
required; Ariz.
Rev. Stat. §6324

5 years; Ala.
Code §5-13B23(c)
3 years; Alaska
Stat.
§06.05.550 §06.05.990

1842(d)(1)(B)
1831u(a)(5)(A)
Minimum Age
of Institution
(Bank or
Branch) for
Acquisitions

Appendix A
Interstate Branching Laws
1994-2005

25%; Ark. Code
§23-48-406

30%; Ariz. Rev.
Stat. §6-328

30%; Ariz. Rev.
Stat. §6-328

50%; Alaska Stat.
§06.05.548

30%; Ala. Code
§5-13B-23(b)

1842(d)(2)(c)
1831u(b)(2)(B)(ii)
Statewide
Deposit Cap on
Branch
Acquisitions

No

Yes; Ariz.
Rev. Stat. §6327(B)

Yes; Ariz.
Rev. Stat. §6327(B)

No

No

28

Reciprocity
Required for
minimum age,
de novo &
branch
acquisition

6/1/1997

1996 Fla. Laws
168

DC

Florida

Georgia

6/1/1997

6/13/1996

1996 D.C. Stat.
11-142

Delaware

1996 Ga. Laws
279 §2

9/29/1995

1995 Del. Laws
112

Connecticut

5/10/2002

6/27/1995

1995 Conn. Acts
155

Colorado

Georgia

6/1/1997

1995 Colo. Sess.
Laws 1355

California

2002 Ga. Laws
670 §4

9/28/1995

1995 Cal. Stat.
480

Reduced minimum age
requirement from 5 to 3
years.

Effective Date

Session Law

State

Changes to State
Interstate Branching
Laws

5 years; Del.
Code tit. 5
§795(7);
§795E; §795F

3 years; Ga.
Code §7-1628.3(b)
5 years; Ga.
Code §7-1-608,
§7-1-622, §7-1628.3(b)

No; Ga. Code
§7-1-628.8

No; Ga. Code
§7-1-628.8

No; Fla. Stat.
§658.2953(5)

No; Del. Code
tit. 5 §795B(c)

5 years; Conn.
Gen. Stat. §36a412(a)(1)

3 years; Fla.
Stat.
§658.2953(7)(c)

No; Colo. Rev.
Stat. §11-104202(6)
Yes;
reciprocity
required;
Conn. Gen.
Stat. §36a412(a)(2)

5 years; Colo.
Rev. Stat. §11104-202(2)

Yes; D.C.
Code §26-734

No; Cal. Fin.
Code
§3824(b)(3)

5 years; Cal.
Fin. Code
§3825

No; D.C. Code
§26-737

36(g)(1) &
1828(b)(4)
opt-in Allows
de novo
Interstate
Branching

1842(d)(1)(B)
1831u(a)(5)(A)
Minimum Age
of Institution
(Bank or
Branch) for
Acquisitions

No; Ga. Code
§7-1-628.9

No; Ga. Code
§7-1-628.9

No

Yes; D.C.
Code §26-734

No; Del. Code
tit. 5 §795B(c)

No; Colo. Rev.
Stat. §11-104202(6); 11104-201
Yes;
reciprocity
required;
Conn. Gen.
Stat. §36a412(a)(1)

No; Cal. Fin.
Code
§3824(b)(2)

1831(u)(a)(4)
Interstate
Branching by
Acquisition of
Single
Branches or
Other
Portions of an
Institution

30%; Ga. Code
§7-1-628.3(a)(2)

30%; Ga. Code
§7-1-628.3(a)(2)

No

No

No

No
30%; Fla. Stat.
§658.2953(7)(b)

No
30% (per Riegle
Neal)

Yes; Conn.
Gen. Stat. §6a412(a)(2)

No

No

29

Reciprocity
Required for
minimum age,
de novo &
branch
acquisition

30%; Del. Code
tit. 5 §795H*****

30%; Conn. Gen.
Stat. §36a412(a)(1)

25%; Colo. Rev.
Stat. §11-104202(4)

30% (per Riegle
Neal)

1842(d)(2)(c)
1831u(b)(2)(B)(ii)
Statewide
Deposit Cap on
Branch
Acquisitions

Illinois

Illinois

8/20/2004

6/1/1997

2004 Ill. Laws
93-965

1997 Ill. Laws
90-226

9/29/1995*

1995 Idaho Sess.
Laws 99

Idaho

Allowed de novo
branching, branch
acquisition and eliminated
minimum age
requirement. Added
reciprocity condition for
minimum age
requirement, de novo
branching and branch
acquisition.

6/1/1997

Hawaii

Hawaii

1996 Haw. Sess.
Laws 155

Effective Date

1/1/2001

Session Law

1999 Haw. Sess.
Laws 283 §2

State

Changes to State
Interstate Branching
Laws
Allowed de novo
branching, branch
acquisition and eliminated
minimum age
requirement.

Yes;
reciprocity
required; 205
Ill. Comp. Stat.
5/21-4

No; 205 Ill.
Comp. Stat.
5/21-4

5 years; 205 Ill.
Comp. Stat.
5/21-2

No

No age
requirement if
reciprocity; 5
years if no
reciprocity; 205
Ill. Comp. Stat.
5/21-2

5 years; Idaho
Code §26-1605

No

Yes;
reciprocity
required; 205
Ill. Comp. Stat.
5/21-4

30%; 205 Ill.
Comp. Stat. 5/213

30%; 205 Ill.
Comp. Stat. 5/213

No

Yes

Yes***

Statute explicitly
states no deposit
cap; Idaho Code
§26-1606**

No

No; Idaho
Code §261604(2)

No; Haw. Rev.
Stat. §412-105

5 years; Haw.
Rev. Stat. §41212-104

30%; Haw. Rev.
Stat. §412-12106*****

30

Reciprocity
Required for
minimum age,
de novo &
branch
acquisition

No

Yes; Haw.
Rev. Stat.
§412-12105(a)

No; Haw. Rev.
Stat. §412-12104

1842(d)(2)(c)
1831u(b)(2)(B)(ii)
Statewide
Deposit Cap on
Branch
Acquisitions

30% (per Riegle
Neal); Haw. Rev.
Stat. §412-12-106

Yes; Haw.
Rev. Stat.
§412-12105(b)

36(g)(1) &
1828(b)(4)
opt-in Allows
de novo
Interstate
Branching

1842(d)(1)(B)
1831u(a)(5)(A)
Minimum Age
of Institution
(Bank or
Branch) for
Acquisitions

No; Haw. Rev.
Stat. §412-12105

1831(u)(a)(4)
Interstate
Branching by
Acquisition of
Single
Branches or
Other
Portions of an
Institution

6/1/1997

1996. Ky. Acts
338

Kentucky

3/17/2000

2000 Ky. Acts
135

Eliminated minimum age
requirement.

Kentucky

Kansas

3/22/2004

9/29/1995

1995 Kan. Sess.
Laws 79

Iowa

2004 Ky. Acts 13

4/4/1996

1996 Iowa Acts
1056

Indiana

Kentucky

6/1/1997

1996 Ind. Acts
171

Indiana

Added reciprocity
condition for minimum
age requirement.

7/1/1998

1998 Ind. Acts 11

Added minimum age
requirement.

State

Effective Date

Session Law

Changes to State
Interstate Branching
Laws

No; Iowa Code
§524.1205(4)

No

No

No

No

5 years; Kan.
Stat. Ann. §9541(a)
No; reciprocity
required; Ky.
Rev. Stat.
§287.920
No; reciprocity
not required;
Ky. Rev. Stat.
§287.920
5 years; Ky.
Rev. Stat.
§287.920

36(g)(1) &
1828(b)(4)
opt-in Allows
de novo
Interstate
Branching
Yes;
reciprocity
required; Ind.
Code §28-218-20
Yes;
reciprocity
required; Ind.
Code §28-218-20

5 years; Iowa
Code
§524.1805(1)

No

5 years; Ind.
Code §28-2-1720.1(b)

1842(d)(1)(B)
1831u(a)(5)(A)
Minimum Age
of Institution
(Bank or
Branch) for
Acquisitions

No

No

No

No

No

1831(u)(a)(4)
Interstate
Branching by
Acquisition of
Single
Branches or
Other
Portions of an
Institution
Yes;
reciprocity
required; Ind.
Code §28-218-21
Yes;
reciprocity
required; Ind.
Code §28-218-21

15%; Ky. Rev.
Stat. §287.920

15%; Ky. Rev.
Stat. §287.920

15%; Ky. Rev.
Stat. §287.920

15%; Kan. Stat.
Ann. §9-520

No

No

Yes

No

No

Yes; Ind. Code
§28-2-18-29

30% (per Riegle
Neal)
15%; Iowa Code
§524.1802(7)

Yes; Ind. Code
§28-2-18-29

31

Reciprocity
Required for
minimum age,
de novo &
branch
acquisition

30% (per Riegle
Neal)

1842(d)(2)(c)
1831u(b)(2)(B)(ii)
Statewide
Deposit Cap on
Branch
Acquisitions

Effective Date

6/1/1997

1/1/1997

9/29/1995

8/2/1996

11/29/1995
6/1/1997

6/1/1997

9/29/1995*

Session Law
1995 La. Acts
1249

1996 Me. Laws
628
1995 Md. Laws
213

1996 Mass. Acts
238

1995 Mich. Pub.
Acts 202
1997 Minn. Laws
117
1995 Miss. Laws
304
1995 Mo. Laws
34

Louisiana

Maine

Maryland

Massachusetts

Michigan

Minnesota

Mississippi

Missouri

State

Changes to State
Interstate Branching
Laws

Yes;
reciprocity
required;
Mich. Comp.
Laws
§487.14107(1)

Yes;
reciprocity
required;
Mich. Comp.
Laws
§487.13711(7)

3 years; Mass.
Gen. Laws
ch.167 §39B

No; Mich.
Comp. Laws
§487.13702
5 years; Minn.
Stat. §49.411(4)
5 years; Miss.
Code Ann. §817-8(1)
5 years; Mo.
Rev. Stat.
§362.077

No

No

No

No

No

Yes; Mass.
Gen. Laws
ch.167 §39C

Yes; Mass.
Gen. Laws
ch.167 §39C

No

No

Yes; Md. Code
Ann. Fin Inst.
§5-1003(2)

Yes; Md. Code
Ann. Fin Inst.
§5-1003

No

No; La. Rev.
Stat. Ann.
§6:536(c)
Yes;
reciprocity
required; Me.
Rev. Stat. Ann.
tit. 9B §373(1)

36(g)(1) &
1828(b)(4)
opt-in Allows
de novo
Interstate
Branching
No; La. Rev.
Stat. Ann.
§6:536(c)
Yes;
reciprocity
required; Me.
Rev. Stat. Ann.
tit. 9B §373(1)

5 years; La.
Rev. Stat. Ann.
§6:532(11)

1842(d)(1)(B)
1831u(a)(5)(A)
Minimum Age
of Institution
(Bank or
Branch) for
Acquisitions

1831(u)(a)(4)
Interstate
Branching by
Acquisition of
Single
Branches or
Other
Portions of an
Institution

No

No

25%; Miss. Code
Ann. §81-7-8(2)
13%; Mo. Rev.
Stat. §362.915

No

Yes; Mich.
Comp. Laws
§487.13711(7)
and
§487.14107(1)
30% (per Riegle
Neal)

Statue explicitly
states no deposit
cap. Mich. Comp.
Laws
§487.11104(8) **

30%; Mass. Gen.
Laws ch.167
§39B

No
Yes; Mass.
Gen. Laws
ch.167 §39B
and ch.167
§39C

Yes; Me. Rev.
Stat. Ann. tit.
9B §373(1)

30%; Me. Rev.
Stat. Ann. tit. 9B
§241(10)
30%; Md. Code
Ann. Fin Inst. §51013

No

32

Reciprocity
Required for
minimum age,
de novo &
branch
acquisition

30% (per Riegle
Neal)

1842(d)(2)(c)
1831u(b)(2)(B)(ii)
Statewide
Deposit Cap on
Branch
Acquisitions

2000 N.H. Laws
236

Allowed de novo
branching, branch
acquisition, and changed
state deposit cap from
20% to 30%.

New Hampshire

8/1/2000

1/1/2002

Nevada

New Hampshire

9/29/1995*

1995 Nev. Stat.
1555

Nebraska

2001 N.H. Laws
269

5/31/1997

1997 Neb. Laws
351

Eliminated minimum age
requirement.

9/29/1995

1995 Mont. Laws
265 §5

Opted out

Montana

10/1/2001
(enacted 1997)

2001 Mont. Laws
36

Montana

Effective Date

Session Law

State

Changes to State
Interstate Branching
Laws
Opted in. Allowed
branch acquisition with 5
year minimum age
requirement, increased
state deposit cap by 1%
annually to a maximum of
22%.

5 years; N.H.
Rev. Stat.
§384:59

No

5 years; Nev.
Rev. Stat.
§666.405(1)

5 years; Neb.
Rev. Stat. §82104

Yes;
reciprocity
required; N.H.
Rev. Stat.
§384:60

Yes;
reciprocity
required; N.H.
Rev. Stat.
§384:60

Yes;
reciprocity
required; N.H.
Rev. Stat.
§384.60
Yes;
reciprocity
required; N.H.
Rev. Stat.
§384.60

No; Neb. Rev.
Stat. §8-2105
No; Nev. Rev.
Stat. §666.410
(Exception for
counties of
100,000 or
less)

N/A

No

No; Neb. Rev.
Stat. §8-2105
No; Nev. Rev.
Stat. §666.410
(Exception for
counties of
100,000 or
less)

N/A

No

5 years; Mont.
Code Ann. §321-370

N/A

36(g)(1) &
1828(b)(4)
opt-in Allows
de novo
Interstate
Branching

1842(d)(1)(B)
1831u(a)(5)(A)
Minimum Age
of Institution
(Bank or
Branch) for
Acquisitions

1831(u)(a)(4)
Interstate
Branching by
Acquisition of
Single
Branches or
Other
Portions of an
Institution

30%; N.H. Rev.
Stat. §384-B:2,
§384-B:3,
§383:59

30%; N.H. Rev.
Stat. §384-B:2,
§384-B:3

30% (per Riegle
Neal)

Yes; N.H.
Rev. Stat.
§384:59,
§384:60

Yes; N.H.
Rev. Stat.
§384:60

No

No

No

18%; increases
1% per year up to
22%; Mont. Code
Ann. §32-1383(3)
14%; Neb. Rev.
Stat. §8-2106

No

33

Reciprocity
Required for
minimum age,
de novo &
branch
acquisition

22%; Mont. Code
Ann. §32-1-383

1842(d)(2)(c)
1831u(b)(2)(B)(ii)
Statewide
Deposit Cap on
Branch
Acquisitions

New York

7/1/1995

6/1/1997

1996 N.Y. Laws
9

New Mexico

North Carolina

6/1/1996

1996 N.M. Laws
2

New Jersey

1995 N.C. Sess.
Laws 322

4/17/1996

1996 N.J. Laws
17 §16

Three statutes enacted
between 1995 and 1999,
but the last two contained
no effective change. The
original act (1995)
permitted de novo
branching and branch
acquisition with
reciprocity until 1997. In
1997, North Carolina
extended the reciprocity
condition until 1999. In
1999, North Carolina
made the reciprocity
condition permanent by
eliminating the clause that
reciprocity expire on
6/1/99.

6/1/1997

Effective Date

New Hampshire

Session Law
1996 N.H. Laws
288

State

Changes to State
Interstate Branching
Laws

No
No; N.M. Stat.
§58-1C-6
No; N.Y.
Banking Law
§224

No; N.J. Stat.
Ann. §17:9A133.1
5 years; N.M.
Stat. §58-1C5(C)
5 years; N.Y.
Banking Law
§223-a

Yes;
reciprocity
required; N.C.
Gen. Stat. §53224.12

No

5 years; N.H.
Rev. Stat.
§384:59

No; reciprocity
required; N.C.
Gen. Stat. §53224.19

36(g)(1) &
1828(b)(4)
opt-in Allows
de novo
Interstate
Branching

1842(d)(1)(B)
1831u(a)(5)(A)
Minimum Age
of Institution
(Bank or
Branch) for
Acquisitions

Yes;
reciprocity
required; N.C.
Gen. Stat. §53224.13

Yes; N.Y.
Banking Law
§223

No; N.M. Stat.
§58-1C-6

Yes; N.J. Stat.
Ann.§ 17:9A133.1(e)

No

1831(u)(a)(4)
Interstate
Branching by
Acquisition of
Single
Branches or
Other
Portions of an
Institution

30% (per Riegle
Neal)

30% (per Riegle
Neal)

40%; N.M. Stat.
§58-1C-5(B)

30%; N.J. Stat.
Ann. §17:9A133.1(b)

20%; N.H. Rev.
Stat. §384:59

1842(d)(2)(c)
1831u(b)(2)(B)(ii)
Statewide
Deposit Cap on
Branch
Acquisitions

34

Yes; N.C. Gen.
Stat. §53224.14(c)

No

No

No

No

Reciprocity
Required for
minimum age,
de novo &
branch
acquisition

Oregon

Oregon

Oklahoma

Oklahoma

Prohibited branch
acquisition.

7/1/1997

2/27/1995

1995 Or. Laws 6
§3

5/31/1997

1997 Okla. Sess.
Laws 120 §1
1997 Or. Laws
631 §284

5/17/2000

Ohio

2000 Okla. Sess.
Laws 205 §18

5/21/1997

1997 Ohio Laws
22

Allowed de novo
branching, branch
acquisition, eliminated
minimum age
requirement, and
increased state deposit
cap from 15% to 20% in
2000.

5/31/1997

North Dakota

North Dakota

1997 N.D. Laws
79 §19

Effective Date

8/1/2003

Session Law

2003 N.D. Laws
75 §4

State

Changes to State
Interstate Branching
Laws
Allowed de novo
branching and branch
acquisition. Added
reciprocity condition for
de novo branching and
branch acquisition.

No
Yes; Ohio
Rev. Code
Ann. §1117.01

No; reciprocity
required; N.D.
Cent. Code
§6.08.3-13
No; Ohio Rev.
Code Ann.
§1115.05(B)

5 years; Okla.
Stat. tit. 6
§501.1(K)
3 years; Or.
Rev. Stat.
§713.270
3 years; Or.
Rev. Stat.
§711.017

No

No

No

Yes; Okla.
Stat. tit. 6
§501.1

Yes;
reciprocity
required; N.D.
Cent. Code §608.4-04

No; reciprocity
required; N.D.
Cent. Code
§6.08.4-04

No; Okla. Stat.
tit. 6 §501.1(K)

Yes;
reciprocity
required; N.D.
Cent. Code §608.4-04

36(g)(1) &
1828(b)(4)
opt-in Allows
de novo
Interstate
Branching

1842(d)(1)(B)
1831u(a)(5)(A)
Minimum Age
of Institution
(Bank or
Branch) for
Acquisitions

Yes

No

No

Yes; Okla.
Stat. tit. 6
§501.1

Yes; Ohio
Rev. Code
Ann. §1117.01

No

1831(u)(a)(4)
Interstate
Branching by
Acquisition of
Single
Branches or
Other
Portions of an
Institution

No

No

30% (per Riegle
Neal)

No

Yes; Okla.
Stat. tit. 6
§501.1

No

35

Yes; N.D.
Cent. Code §608.4-06.1

Yes; N.D.
Cent. Code §608.4-06.1

Reciprocity
Required for
minimum age,
de novo &
branch
acquisition

30% (per Riegle
Neal)

15%; Okla. Stat.
tit. 6 §501.1

20%; Okla. Stat.
tit. 6 §501.1

30%; Ohio Rev.
Code Ann.
§1115.05(B)(1)(a)

25%; N.D. Cent.
Code §6-08.303.1

25%; N.D. Cent.
Code §6-08.303.1

1842(d)(2)(c)
1831u(b)(2)(B)(ii)
Statewide
Deposit Cap on
Branch
Acquisitions

2001 Tenn. Pub.
Acts 140

1998 Tenn. Pub.
Acts 742

Allowed de novo
branching. Added
reciprocity condition for
de novo branching.

Allowed branch
acquisition. Added
reciprocity condition for
branch acquisition.

Tennessee

Tennessee

South Dakota

5/1/1998

7/1/2001

3/17/2003

3/9/1996

1996 S.D. Laws
280

South Carolina

Tennessee

7/1/1996

1996 S.C. Acts
310 (H.B. 4790)

2003 Tenn Pub.
Acts 32

6/20/1995

1995 R.I. Pub.
Laws 82 §45

Rhode Island

Reduced minimum age
requirement from 5 to 3
years in 2003.

7/6/1995

Effective Date

1995 Pa. Laws 39

Session Law

Pennsylvania

State

Changes to State
Interstate Branching
Laws

5 years; Tenn.
Code Ann. §452-1403

5 years; Tenn.
Code Ann. §452-1403

3 years; Tenn.
Code Ann. §452-1403

5 years; S.D.
Codified Laws
§51A-7-16

No

No
Yes;
reciprocity
required;
Tenn. Code
Ann. §45-21412
Yes;
reciprocity
required;
Tenn. Code
Ann. §45-21402

No

5 years; S.C.
Code Ann. §3425-240(c)

No; 7 Pa. Stat.
Ann. §1602
Yes; R.I. Gen.
Laws §19-7-9

Yes;
reciprocity
required; 7 Pa.
Stat. Ann.
§904(b)

No; R.I. Gen.
Laws §19-7-3

36(g)(1) &
1828(b)(4)
opt-in Allows
de novo
Interstate
Branching

1842(d)(1)(B)
1831u(a)(5)(A)
Minimum Age
of Institution
(Bank or
Branch) for
Acquisitions

No
Yes;
reciprocity
required;
Tenn. Code
Ann. §45-21402(1)
Yes;
reciprocity
required;
Tenn. Code
Ann. §45-21412(1)
Yes;
reciprocity
required;
Tenn. Code
Ann. §45-21412(1)

No

Yes; R.I. Gen.
Laws §19-7-9

1831(u)(a)(4)
Interstate
Branching by
Acquisition of
Single
Branches or
Other
Portions of an
Institution
Yes;
reciprocity
required; 7 Pa.
Stat. Ann.
§904 & Pa.
Stat. Chap. 16

30%; Tenn. Code
Ann. §45-2-1404

30%; Tenn. Code
Ann. §45-2-1404

30%; Tenn. Code
Ann. §45-2-1404

30% (per Riegle
Neal)

30%; S.C. Code
Ann. §34-25-240

30% (per Riegle
Neal)

30% (per Riegle
Neal)

1842(d)(2)(c)
1831u(b)(2)(B)(ii)
Statewide
Deposit Cap on
Branch
Acquisitions

Yes; Tenn.
Code Ann.
§45-2-1412(b)

Yes; Tenn.
Code Ann.
§45-2-1412(b)

Yes; Tenn.
Code Ann.
§45-2-1412(b)

No

No

Yes; R.I. Gen.
Laws §19-7-9

36

Yes; 7 Pa. Stat.
Ann. §904(b)

Reciprocity
Required for
minimum age,
de novo &
branch
acquisition

Vermont

Utah

1999 Vt. Acts &
Resolves 153 §2

1/1/2001

6/1/1995

1995 Utah Laws
49

Eliminated minimum age
requirement, allowed de
novo branching. Added
reciprocity condition for
de novo branching.

4/30/2001

2001 Utah Laws
211

Allowed de novo
branching. Added
reciprocity condition.

Utah

8/28/1995

1995 Tex. Gen.
Laws ch. 58

Opted out

Texas

6/1/1997

Effective Date

9/1/1999

Texas

1996 Tenn. Pub.
Acts 768

Session Law

1999 Tex. Gen.
Laws 344

Allowed de novo
branching and branch
acquisition. Added
reciprocity condition for
de novo branching and
branch acquisition. No
minimum age requirement
for states with reciprocity,
5 year minimum age
requirement for states
with no reciprocity.

Tennessee

State

Changes to State
Interstate Branching
Laws

5 years; Utah
Code Ann. §71-703(7)

No; 8 Vt. Stat.
Ann. tit. 205
§15202

No; Utah Code
Ann. §7-1702(5)(b)

5 years; Utah
Code Ann. §71-703(7)

Yes;
reciprocity
required; 8 Vt.
Stat. Ann.
§15202(b)(2)

N/A
Yes;
reciprocity
required; Utah
Code Ann. §71-702(5)(b) &
5(c)

N/A

Yes;
reciprocity
required; Tex.
Fin. Code
Ann. §203.002
(a)

No

5 years; Tenn.
Code Ann. §452-1403

No, if
reciprocity; 5
years if no
reciprocity for
de novo; Tex.
Fin. Code Ann.
§203.005

36(g)(1) &
1828(b)(4)
opt-in Allows
de novo
Interstate
Branching

1842(d)(1)(B)
1831u(a)(5)(A)
Minimum Age
of Institution
(Bank or
Branch) for
Acquisitions

Yes; 8 Vt. Stat.
Ann.
§15202(b)(1)

N/A
Yes; Utah
Code Ann. §
7-1-702(4)(a);
Utah Code
Ann. §7-1703(7).
Yes; Utah
Code Ann. §
7-1-702(4)(a);
Utah Code
Ann. §7-1703(7).

Yes;
reciprocity
required; Tex.
Fin. Code
Ann.
§203.002(c)

No.

1831(u)(a)(4)
Interstate
Branching by
Acquisition of
Single
Branches or
Other
Portions of an
Institution

30%; 8 Vt. Stat.
Ann. §14108

30% (per Riegle
Neal)

30% (per Riegle
Neal)

20%

20%; Tex. Fin.
Code Ann.
§203.004

30%; Tenn. Code
Ann. §45-2-1404

1842(d)(2)(c)
1831u(b)(2)(B)(ii)
Statewide
Deposit Cap on
Branch
Acquisitions

37

Yes; 8 Vt. Stat.
Ann.
§15202(b)(2)
and 8 Vt. Stat.
Ann.
§15202(b)(1)

No

Yes; Utah
Code Ann. §71-702(5)(b) &
5(c)

N/A

Yes; Tex. Fin.
Code Ann.
§203.002

Yes; Tenn.
Code Ann.
§45-2-1412(b)

Reciprocity
Required for
minimum age,
de novo &
branch
acquisition

9/29/1995*

1995 Va. Laws
301

Virginia

5/9/2005

6/6/1996

5/31/1997

5/1/1996

5/31/1997

1996 Wash. Laws
2

1996 W. Va. Acts
72
1995 Wis. Laws
336
1997 Wyo. Sess.
Laws

Washington

West Virginia

Wisconsin

Wyoming

Washington

2005 Wash. Laws
348

Allowed de novo
branching and branch
acquisition. Added
reciprocity condition for
de novo branching and
branch acquisition.

5/30/1996

Effective Date

1995 Vt. Acts &
Resolves 142 §4

Session Law

Vermont

State

Changes to State
Interstate Branching
Laws

No

No

No; W.Va.
Code §31A-8D4
5 years; Wis.
Stat.
§221.0901(8)
3 years; Wyo.
Stat. Ann. §132-804(c)

No
Yes;
reciprocity
required; Va.
Code Ann.
§6.1- 44.4
Yes;
reciprocity
required;
Wash. Rev.
Code
§30.38.015

36(g)(1) &
1828(b)(4)
opt-in Allows
de novo
Interstate
Branching

No
Yes;
reciprocity
required;
W.Va. Code
§31A-8E-4

5 years; Wash.
Rev. Code
§30.04.232

5 years; Wash.
Rev. Code
§30.04.232

No; Va. Code
Ann. §6.144.18

5 years; 8 Vt.
Stat. Ann. §654

1842(d)(1)(B)
1831u(a)(5)(A)
Minimum Age
of Institution
(Bank or
Branch) for
Acquisitions

No

No

No
Yes;
reciprocity
required;
W.Va. Code
§31A-8E-4

Yes; Va. Code
Ann. §6.1-44.5
Yes;
reciprocity
required;
Wash. Rev.
Code
§30.38.015

1831(u)(a)(4)
Interstate
Branching by
Acquisition of
Single
Branches or
Other
Portions of an
Institution
Yes; 8 Vt. Stat.
Ann.
§654(b)(2)

30%; Wyo. Stat.
Ann. §13-2804(b)

30%; Wis. Stat.
§221.0901(7)
****

No

No

Yes; W.Va.
Code §31A8E-4

No

30% (per Riegle
Neal); Wash. Rev.
Code
§30.49.125****

25%; W.Va. Code
§31A-2-12a

Yes; Wash.
Rev. Code
§30.38.015

30% (per Riegle
Neal); Wash. Rev.
Code
§30.49.125****

38

Yes; Va. Code
Ann. §6.1-44.7

No

30%; 8 Vt. Stat.
Ann. §1015

30% (per Riegle
Neal)

Reciprocity
Required for
minimum age,
de novo &
branch
acquisition

1842(d)(2)(c)
1831u(b)(2)(B)(ii)
Statewide
Deposit Cap on
Branch
Acquisitions

*** Idaho requires reciprocity, but it does not allow de novo branching, acquisition of a branch and has a five year minimum age requirement to buy a bank, making it one of the most
restrictive states. Thus, the reciprocity requirement has little value.
**** Statute expressly references IBBEA deposit cap.
***** Statute states 30% statewide deposit cap per IBBEA, but State Banking Commissioner may waive the cap.

NOTES:
* No precise date is listed in statute, only the year. We assume for each of these states that the effective date is 09/29/1995.
** Statute states no deposit cap -- which implicitly implies 100%

39

Working Paper Series
A series of research studies on regional economic issues relating to the Seventh Federal
Reserve District, and on financial and economic topics.
Standing Facilities and Interbank Borrowing: Evidence from the Federal Reserve’s
New Discount Window
Craig Furfine

WP-04-01

Netting, Financial Contracts, and Banks: The Economic Implications
William J. Bergman, Robert R. Bliss, Christian A. Johnson and George G. Kaufman

WP-04-02

Real Effects of Bank Competition
Nicola Cetorelli

WP-04-03

Finance as a Barrier To Entry: Bank Competition and Industry Structure in
Local U.S. Markets?
Nicola Cetorelli and Philip E. Strahan

WP-04-04

The Dynamics of Work and Debt
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-04-05

Fiscal Policy in the Aftermath of 9/11
Jonas Fisher and Martin Eichenbaum

WP-04-06

Merger Momentum and Investor Sentiment: The Stock Market Reaction
To Merger Announcements
Richard J. Rosen

WP-04-07

Earnings Inequality and the Business Cycle
Gadi Barlevy and Daniel Tsiddon

WP-04-08

Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets: The Case of Payment Networks
Sujit Chakravorti and Roberto Roson

WP-04-09

Nominal Debt as a Burden on Monetary Policy
Javier Díaz-Giménez, Giorgia Giovannetti, Ramon Marimon, and Pedro Teles

WP-04-10

On the Timing of Innovation in Stochastic Schumpeterian Growth Models
Gadi Barlevy

WP-04-11

Policy Externalities: How US Antidumping Affects Japanese Exports to the EU
Chad P. Bown and Meredith A. Crowley

WP-04-12

Sibling Similarities, Differences and Economic Inequality
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-04-13

Determinants of Business Cycle Comovement: A Robust Analysis
Marianne Baxter and Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-04-14

The Occupational Assimilation of Hispanics in the U.S.: Evidence from Panel Data
Maude Toussaint-Comeau

WP-04-15

1

Working Paper Series (continued)
Reading, Writing, and Raisinets1: Are School Finances Contributing to Children’s Obesity?
Patricia M. Anderson and Kristin F. Butcher

WP-04-16

Learning by Observing: Information Spillovers in the Execution and Valuation
of Commercial Bank M&As
Gayle DeLong and Robert DeYoung

WP-04-17

Prospects for Immigrant-Native Wealth Assimilation:
Evidence from Financial Market Participation
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-04-18

Individuals and Institutions: Evidence from International Migrants in the U.S.
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-04-19

Are Technology Improvements Contractionary?
Susanto Basu, John Fernald and Miles Kimball

WP-04-20

The Minimum Wage, Restaurant Prices and Labor Market Structure
Daniel Aaronson, Eric French and James MacDonald

WP-04-21

Betcha can’t acquire just one: merger programs and compensation
Richard J. Rosen

WP-04-22

Not Working: Demographic Changes, Policy Changes,
and the Distribution of Weeks (Not) Worked
Lisa Barrow and Kristin F. Butcher

WP-04-23

The Role of Collateralized Household Debt in Macroeconomic Stabilization
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-04-24

Advertising and Pricing at Multiple-Output Firms: Evidence from U.S. Thrift Institutions
Robert DeYoung and Evren Örs

WP-04-25

Monetary Policy with State Contingent Interest Rates
Bernardino Adão, Isabel Correia and Pedro Teles

WP-04-26

Comparing location decisions of domestic and foreign auto supplier plants
Thomas Klier, Paul Ma and Daniel P. McMillen

WP-04-27

China’s export growth and US trade policy
Chad P. Bown and Meredith A. Crowley

WP-04-28

Where do manufacturing firms locate their Headquarters?
J. Vernon Henderson and Yukako Ono

WP-04-29

Monetary Policy with Single Instrument Feedback Rules
Bernardino Adão, Isabel Correia and Pedro Teles

WP-04-30

2

Working Paper Series (continued)
Firm-Specific Capital, Nominal Rigidities and the Business Cycle
David Altig, Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum and Jesper Linde

WP-05-01

Do Returns to Schooling Differ by Race and Ethnicity?
Lisa Barrow and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP-05-02

Derivatives and Systemic Risk: Netting, Collateral, and Closeout
Robert R. Bliss and George G. Kaufman

WP-05-03

Risk Overhang and Loan Portfolio Decisions
Robert DeYoung, Anne Gron and Andrew Winton

WP-05-04

Characterizations in a random record model with a non-identically distributed initial record
Gadi Barlevy and H. N. Nagaraja

WP-05-05

Price discovery in a market under stress: the U.S. Treasury market in fall 1998
Craig H. Furfine and Eli M. Remolona

WP-05-06

Politics and Efficiency of Separating Capital and Ordinary Government Budgets
Marco Bassetto with Thomas J. Sargent

WP-05-07

Rigid Prices: Evidence from U.S. Scanner Data
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Benjamin Eden

WP-05-08

Entrepreneurship, Frictions, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-05-09

Wealth inequality: data and models
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-05-10

What Determines Bilateral Trade Flows?
Marianne Baxter and Michael A. Kouparitsas

WP-05-11

Intergenerational Economic Mobility in the U.S., 1940 to 2000
Daniel Aaronson and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-05-12

Differential Mortality, Uncertain Medical Expenses, and the Saving of Elderly Singles
Mariacristina De Nardi, Eric French, and John Bailey Jones

WP-05-13

Fixed Term Employment Contracts in an Equilibrium Search Model
Fernando Alvarez and Marcelo Veracierto

WP-05-14

Causality, Causality, Causality: The View of Education Inputs and Outputs from Economics
Lisa Barrow and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP-05-15

3

Working Paper Series (continued)
Competition in Large Markets
Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-05-16

Why Do Firms Go Public? Evidence from the Banking Industry
Richard J. Rosen, Scott B. Smart and Chad J. Zutter

WP-05-17

Clustering of Auto Supplier Plants in the U.S.: GMM Spatial Logit for Large Samples
Thomas Klier and Daniel P. McMillen

WP-05-18

Why are Immigrants’ Incarceration Rates So Low?
Evidence on Selective Immigration, Deterrence, and Deportation
Kristin F. Butcher and Anne Morrison Piehl

WP-05-19

Constructing the Chicago Fed Income Based Economic Index – Consumer Price Index:
Inflation Experiences by Demographic Group: 1983-2005
Leslie McGranahan and Anna Paulson

WP-05-20

Universal Access, Cost Recovery, and Payment Services
Sujit Chakravorti, Jeffery W. Gunther, and Robert R. Moore

WP-05-21

Supplier Switching and Outsourcing
Yukako Ono and Victor Stango

WP-05-22

Do Enclaves Matter in Immigrants’ Self-Employment Decision?
Maude Toussaint-Comeau

WP-05-23

The Changing Pattern of Wage Growth for Low Skilled Workers
Eric French, Bhashkar Mazumder and Christopher Taber

WP-05-24

U.S. Corporate and Bank Insolvency Regimes: An Economic Comparison and Evaluation
Robert R. Bliss and George G. Kaufman

WP-06-01

Redistribution, Taxes, and the Median Voter
Marco Bassetto and Jess Benhabib

WP-06-02

Identification of Search Models with Initial Condition Problems
Gadi Barlevy and H. N. Nagaraja

WP-06-03

Tax Riots
Marco Bassetto and Christopher Phelan

WP-06-04

The Tradeoff between Mortgage Prepayments and Tax-Deferred Retirement Savings
Gene Amromin, Jennifer Huang,and Clemens Sialm

WP-06-05

Why are safeguards needed in a trade agreement?
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-06-06

4

Working Paper Series (continued)
Taxation, Entrepreneurship, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-06-07

A New Social Compact: How University Engagement Can Fuel Innovation
Laura Melle, Larry Isaak, and Richard Mattoon

WP-06-08

Mergers and Risk
Craig H. Furfine and Richard J. Rosen

WP-06-09

Two Flaws in Business Cycle Accounting
Lawrence J. Christiano and Joshua M. Davis

WP-06-10

Do Consumers Choose the Right Credit Contracts?
Sumit Agarwal, Souphala Chomsisengphet, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles

WP-06-11

Chronicles of a Deflation Unforetold
François R. Velde

WP-06-12

Female Offenders Use of Social Welfare Programs Before and After Jail and Prison:
Does Prison Cause Welfare Dependency?
Kristin F. Butcher and Robert J. LaLonde
Eat or Be Eaten: A Theory of Mergers and Firm Size
Gary Gorton, Matthias Kahl, and Richard Rosen
Do Bonds Span Volatility Risk in the U.S. Treasury Market?
A Specification Test for Affine Term Structure Models
Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

WP-06-13

WP-06-14

WP-06-15

Transforming Payment Choices by Doubling Fees on the Illinois Tollway
Gene Amromin, Carrie Jankowski, and Richard D. Porter

WP-06-16

How Did the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut Affect Stock Prices?
Gene Amromin, Paul Harrison, and Steven Sharpe

WP-06-17

Will Writing and Bequest Motives: Early 20th Century Irish Evidence
Leslie McGranahan

WP-06-18

How Professional Forecasters View Shocks to GDP
Spencer D. Krane

WP-06-19

Evolving Agglomeration in the U.S. auto supplier industry
Thomas Klier and Daniel P. McMillen

WP-06-20

Mortality, Mass-Layoffs, and Career Outcomes: An Analysis using Administrative Data
Daniel Sullivan and Till von Wachter

WP-06-21

5

Working Paper Series (continued)
The Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures:
Tying One’s Hand through the WTO.
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-06-22

How Did Schooling Laws Improve Long-Term Health and Lower Mortality?
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-06-23

Manufacturing Plants’ Use of Temporary Workers: An Analysis Using Census Micro Data
Yukako Ono and Daniel Sullivan

WP-06-24

What Can We Learn about Financial Access from U.S. Immigrants?
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-06-25

Bank Imputed Interest Rates: Unbiased Estimates of Offered Rates?
Evren Ors and Tara Rice

WP-06-26

Welfare Implications of the Transition to High Household Debt
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-06-27

Last-In First-Out Oligopoly Dynamics
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-06-28

Oligopoly Dynamics with Barriers to Entry
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-06-29

Risk Taking and the Quality of Informal Insurance: Gambling and Remittances in Thailand
Douglas L. Miller and Anna L. Paulson

WP-07-01

Fast Micro and Slow Macro: Can Aggregation Explain the Persistence of Inflation?
Filippo Altissimo, Benoît Mojon, and Paolo Zaffaroni

WP-07-02

Assessing a Decade of Interstate Bank Branching
Christian Johnson and Tara Rice

WP-07-03

Debit Card and Cash Usage: A Cross-Country Analysis
Gene Amromin and Sujit Chakravorti

WP-07-04

6