View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

A N O T H E R L O O K AT T H E E V ID E N C E
O N M O N E Y -IN C O M E C A U S A L IT Y
Benjamin M. Friedman and Kenneth N. Kuttner

Working Paper Series
Macro Economic Issues
Research Department
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
October, 1990 (WP-90-17)

Another Look at the Evidence
on Money-Income Causality
Benjamin M. Friedman and Kenneth N. Kuttner*
Whether fluctuations in the stock of money anticipate fluctuations in income is
an important question, with implications for both economic theory and economic
policy. In a widely cited pdper, James Stock and Mark Watson (1989) offered
new evidence for the United States showing that money, as measured by the nar­
row Ml aggregate, does have statistically significant marginal predictive value for
real income, as measured by industrial production. Wholly apart from the use­
ful methodological contribution represented by the new testing strategy that they
proposed in their paper, Stock and Watson’s empirical findings were especially
noteworthy for two reasons: First, in contrast to the popular impression that fa­
miliar money-income relationships (and, for that matter, money-price relationships
too) had broken down in the 1980s, their results showed a continuing significant
relationship in a sample extending through 1985. Second, in contrast to earlier
researchers (most prominently, Christopher Sims) who had found a significant re­
lationship between money and real income in a bivariate context but not after also
allowing for fluctuations in interest rates, Stock and Watson’s results showed that
money had significant marginal predictive value for income even in the presence
of a short-term interest rate.
Evidence presented below shows, however, that Stock and Watson’s findings are
not robust in two ways, corresponding in turn to each of these aspects of their re­
sults that made them so interesting in the first place: First, merely extending the
sample period through 1988 renders money no longer significant in predicting in­
come, even within their chosen specification. Hence the widespread impression
that the money-income relationship has weakened, if not collapsed altogether, is
closer to the truth. Second, even for data through 1985 only, the Stock-Watson
finding turns out to depend on the use in the analysis of a particular interest rate,
the Treasury bill rate. Using instead the commercial paper rate, another short-term
interest rate which apparently is superior in capturing the information in finan­
cial prices that matters for the determination of real income, sharply weakens the
Stock-Watson result.
* Harvard University and The Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, respectively. The authors are grate­
ful for research support from the National Science Foundation, the General Electric Foundation and
the Harvard Program for Financial Research. The views presented here are the authors’; they do not
necessarily reflect the official position of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
October 1990, WP-1990-17




I

Applying the Stock-Watson Test to Different Samples

Following Sims (1980) and other researchers, Stock and Watson conducted their
investigation of the money-income relationship in the context of a four-variable
monthly vector autoregression system including not only money and real income
(proxied by industrial production) but also prices and a short-term interest rate.1
On the basis of a careful analysis of the univariate trend properties of these series,
in conjunction with the absence of evidence of co-integration among these four
variables, they selected as their preferred specification the first-differenced form
6

Ay, = a +

12

P, Am,-i +
i=1

12

y, Ay,_( +
i=l

12

8, A/> ,■+
,_
i'=l

9, A +/(0 + u,
r,_,-

(1)

i=l

where the regressors are as listed above,/(0 is a polynomial function of time, and
u is a standard disturbance term.
Stock and Watson argued for the inclusion of thef(t) regressor in (1) on the basis
of their finding that nominal money growth is well described as stationary about
a small but statistically significant trend term. Including/(r) in the regression is
equivalent to detrending each variable individually. Hence with the trend included,
the standard causality tests for the significance of lagged money focus on the pre­
dictive power of detrended money growth. Stock and Watson estimated each of
their causality-test equations in three forms: with no time trend, including a linear
trend, and including both linear and quadratic trends. At the methodological level,
the careful treatment of time trends and their implications is a major contribution
of the Stock-Watson paper.
Finally, while the choice of lag length 12 is standard in much of the vector autore­
gression literature based on monthly data, Stock and Watson estimated one version
of (1) including the standard 12 lags on all variables and another, as written above,
with only 6 lags on money and 12 lags on the other variables. They found that the
F-statistic for the joint significance of the coefficients on money falls off sharply
when the full 12 lags are included. Hence the use of lag length 6 for money, in the
results presented here, actually favors the conclusion that money has significant
marginal predictive power for income.
Table 1 presents sets of F-statistics, corresponding to three different sample peri­
ods, for the null hypothesis that all of the ft coefficients — that is, all of the coef­
ficient values on lagged values of money — are zero in (1). Following Stock and
Watson, for each sample period there are three variants of the equation, differing
only according to the time trends included. In addition, each of the four variables

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
October 1990, WP-1990-17




2

Table 1
F-Statistics for Effect of Money in Stock-Watson Tests

1960:2-1985:12

Sample:
1960:2-1979:9

1960:2-1988:12

None

2.187
(0.045)

2.493
(0.024)

1.084
(0.372)

Linear

2.774
(0.012)

1.427
(0.206)

1.356
(0.232)

Linear, Quadratic

2.181
(0.045)

1.339
(0.241)

1.019
(0.413)

Trends Included

Note: Numbers in parentheses are marginal significance levels.
in the equation is defined throughout as in Stock and Watson’s analysis: the in­
dex of industrial production (seasonally adjusted, 1987 = 100), Ml (seasonally
adjusted), the producer price index for all commodities (not seasonally adjusted,
1982 = 100), and the secondary market rate on three-month Treasury bills (not
seasonally adjusted).
The results shown in the first column of the table closely replicate Stock and Wat­
son’s findings for their 1960:2-1985:12 sample.2 Money has significant marginal
predictive value for income for all three renderings of/(/), and especially so for
the linear-trend case. Analogous results shown in the second column are for data
spanning 1960:2-1979:9 — that is, until just before the Federal Reserve System’s
adoption of new monetary policy procedures in October 1979. Stock and Watson,
who in their paper paid careful attention to questions of sub-sample stability, also
presented results for this sample, and the values shown in Table 1 again closely
replicate theirs.3 The point of including results for this sub-sample here is sim­
ply to highlight the sample-specific nature of Stock and Watson’s findings about
the role of time trends. Given the comparison between the first two columns of
the table, it is hardly surprising that the pre-1980s literature on the money-income
relationship did not emphasize inclusion of trends.
The third column of Table 1 shows analogous F-statistics based on data through
1988. Merely extending the sample for an additional three years into the 1980s
renders money not marginally significant in predicting real income, at any plausi­
ble significance level, regardless of whether the Stock-Watson trend terms are in­
cluded. Moreover, results (not shown) for the 1960:2-1988:12 sample but based
FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
October 1990, WP-1990-17




3

on other specifications that Stock and Watson proposed reconfirm these results
more broadly. Nor is the F-statistic for money significant in analogously specified
equations for prices, or for nominal income (proxied by the product of the producer
price index and the index of industrial production). Whatever these relationships
may have been before 1980, they have apparently deteriorated to such an extent
that they no longer appear in samples that include the 1980s.
The Treasury Bill Rate versus the Commerical Paper Rate

Following the work of Sims (1980), it has become customary in tests for effects of
money on real income to control for the effect of interest rates. A typical finding
in such work is that whether money has significant marginal predictive value for
income is highly sensitive to whether the analysis includes an interest rate. One
especially interesting feature of Stock and Watson’s findings, therefore, was the
limited nature of this sensitivity that they reported. True, deleting the interest rate
from their preferred specification for 1960:2-1985:12 raised the F-statistic for the
coefficients on lagged money from 3.04 to 3.50. But the more important point,
as emphasized above, is that even the smaller value, for the system including the
interest rate, was highly significant.
Although the inclusion of a short-term interest rate in empirical work of this kind
is now standard enough, there has been little discussion in the literature of just
which short-term rate is appropriate. Sims (1980) and Friedman (1983) both used
the commercial paper rate, while Litterman and Weiss (1985), Eichenbaum and
Singleton (1986) and Stock and Watson (1989) all used the Treasury bill rate.4
None of these authors, however, offered substantive arguments in support of the
selection made.
Just as different monetary aggregates correspond to different conceptual ways
of measuring financial market quantity information, different interest rates cor­
respond to different conceptual ways of measuring financial market price infor­
mation. As Friedman and Kuttner (1990) explained in some detail, in the case of
the commercial paper rate — that is, the interest rate on short-term unsecured bor­
rowing by corporations in nonfinancial lines of business — and the Treasury bill
rate — that is, the analogous unsecured borrowing rate for the U.S. Government
— there are substantive grounds on which to question which one provides the bet­
ter gauge of the financial prices that matter for the determination of real economic
activity. For purposes of this paper, however, what is of interest is the empirical
implication, for Stock and Watson’s results, of using one of these rates versus the
other.
Table 2 presents evidence that the use of one of these two short-term interest rates
versus the other has an important bearing on the Stock-Watson findings about the
FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
October 1990, WP-1990-17




marginal predictive value of money for real income. The table shows F-statistics
for tests of the null hypothesis that all of the coefficients on money are zero, and
also for (separate) tests of the null hypothesis that all of the coefficients on the
interest rate are zero in (1) estimated for the 1960:2-1985:12 sample. The table
shows results based on using the three month Treasury bill rate as the model’s
short-term interest rate, as in Stock and Watson’s work, and alternative results
based on using the rate on six-month dealer-placed prime commercial paper (also
not seasonally adjusted).
Although the F-statistics for the effect of the interest rate on income are uniformly
larger for the commercial paper rate than for the Treasury bill rate, in no case does
the change render this effect significant at any plausible level. By contrast, which
short-term interest rate the model includes does affect the significance of the effect
of money on income. In no case is the effect of money significant even at the .10
level in the presence of the commercial paper rate.
Hence even within their own 1960-85 sample, Stock and Watson’s strongly pos­
itive findings hinge crucially on the use of the Treasury bill rate rather than the
commercial paper rate to represent financial market price information. Not sur­
prisingly, as Table 3 shows, simultaneously extending the sample and substituting
the commercial paper rate for the Treasury bill rate overwhelms Stock and Wat­
son’s positive results altogether.
Although it may be tempting to interpret these results as a straightforward indi­
cation that the commercial paper rate is simply superior to the Treasury bill rate
in capturing information about financial effects on nonfinancial economic activ­
ity, further investigation shows that the relevant interactions may in fact be more
subtle. Table 4 presents F-statistics for several tests of an expanded version of (1)
in which the Treasury bill rate is replaced by both the commercial paper rate and
the spread between the commercial paper rate and the Treasury bill rate. The table
shows results for both the 1960-85 and the 1960-88 sample periods, but only for
Stock and Watson’s preferred specification including the linear time trend. (Cor­
responding results for the variants with no trend and with both linear and quadratic
trends are highly similar.)
Neither the F-statistic testing the effect of money nor that testing the effect of the
commercial paper rate is significant, at any plausible level, in either sample. By
contrast, what is startling is that the paper-bill spread is significant at the .0001
level or better in both sample periods. At the same time, the F-statistic for the (sep­
arate) null hypothesis that the respective pairs of coefficients on the commercial
paper rate and the paper-bill spread are each equal in magnitude and opposite in
sign (so that the net result is equivalent to simply including the Treasury bill rate,

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
October 1990, WP-1990-17




5

Table 2

Implications of Alternative Interest Rates
in Stock-Watson Tests, 1960-1985

Treasury Bills

Commercial Paper

F-Statistic for Money

2.187
(0.045)

1.085
(0.372)

F-Statistic for Interest Rate

0.829
(0.620)

1.288
(0.225)

F-Statistic for Money

2.774
(0.012)

1.498
(0.179)

F-Statistic for Interest Rate

0.811
(0.639)

1.154
(0.316)

F-Statistic for Money

2.181
(0.045)

1.189
(0.312)

F-Statistic for Interest Rate

0.847
(0.602)

1.157
(0.314)

Trends Included
No Time Trend

Linear Time Trend

Linear, Quadratic Time Trends

Note: Numbers in parentheses are marginal significance levels.
The sample period is 1960:2-1985:12.

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
October 1990, WP-1990-17




6

Table 3

Implications of Alternative Interest Rates
in Stock-Watson Tests, 1960-1988

Treasury Bills

Commercial Paper

F-Statistic for Money

1.084
(0.372)

0.573
(0.752)

F-Statistic for Interest Rate

0.842
(0.607)

1.603
(0.090)

F-Statistic for Money

1.356
(0.232)

0.700
(0.650)

F-Statistic for Interest Rate

0.813
(0.637)

1.499
(0.123)

F-Statistic for Money

1.019
(0.413)

0.591
(0.737)

F-Statistic for Interest Rate

0.884
(0.563)

1.498
(0.123)

Trends Included
No Time Trend

Linear Time Trend

Linear, Quadratic Time Trends

Note: Numbers in parentheses are marginal significance levels.
The sample period is 1960:2-1988:12.

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
October 1990, WP-1990-17




7




Table 4

F-Statistics for Expanded Stock-Watson Equation

1960:2-1985:12

1960:2-1988:12

/^-Statistic for Money

1.425
(0.205)

0.539
(0.779)

F-Statistic for Paper Rate

0.786
(0.665)

0.913
(0.535)

F-Statistic for Paper-Bill Spread

3.419
(0.0001)

3.249
(0.0002)

F-Statistic for Constraint

3.787
(0.00002)

3.973
(0.00001)

Note: Numbers in parentheses are marginal significance levels.
Constraint forces coefficients on the paper rate and the paper-bill spread to
be equal in magnitude and opposite in sign.
as in Stock and Watson’s work) warrants rejecting this constraint at even stronger
significance levels in both sample periods.
These additional results do not contradict the conclusion that, between the Trea­
sury bill rate and the commercial paper rate, the latter is superior for purposes of
assessing financial influences on nonfinancial activity, nor do they affect the paral­
lel conclusion that Stock and Watson’s finding of a strongly statistically significant
effect of money on real output depends on their use of the Treasury bill rate instead
of the commercial paper rate. As Friedman and Kuttner (1990) emphasized in a
different context, however, they do suggest that the sources of imperfect covari­
ation between these two interest rates — presumably including an important role
for a default premium that varies over time as perceptions of business creditwor­
thiness change — capture more of the relevant information about what aspects of
financial markets matter for the determination of real income than do movements
in either interest rate by itself, or fluctuations in money.

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
October 1990, WP-1990-17

8

Footnotes
1 Instead using long-tenn interest rates or equity prices would make interpreting
positive results more problematic because of die inherently anticipatory nature
of long-lived asset markets. See Friedman (1984) for a comparative treatment
of long- versus short-term interest rates, and Eichenbaum and Singleton (1986)
for a discussion of equity prices, in this context.
2 The F-statistics reported by Stock and Watson, in the order shown in the table,
were 2.39, 3.04 and 2.50. The differences tire attributable to subsequent data
revisions.
3 The F-statistics reported by Stock and Watson were, in order, 2.68, 1.75 and
1.49.
4 Eichenbaum and Singleton were incorrect in stating (p. 125) that Sims had
used the Treasury bill rate; see Sims (p. 252).

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
October 1990, WP-1990-J7




9

References
Eichenbaum, Marlin, and Singleton, Kenneth J. “Do Equilibrium Real Busi­
ness Cycle Theories Explain Postwar U.S. Business Cycles?” Fischer (ed.),
Cambridge: MIT Press, 1986.

N E Mcocnmc Ana 18.
B R areoois nul 96

Friedman, Benjamin M. “The Roles of Money and Credit in Macroeconomic Anal­
ysis.” Tobin (ed.),
Washington: The Brookings Institution, 1983.

Mcocnmc,PieadQatte: sasiM m
areoois rcs n uniisEsy n e ­
oyoAtu M Ou.
r frhr . kn

Friedman, Benjamin M. “The Value oflntermediate Targets in Implementing Mon­
etary Policy.” Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City,
Kansas City: 1984.

PietbltadP b
rcSaiiyn u ­

l Plc.
i oiy
c

Friedman, Benjamin M., and Kuttner, Kenneth N. “Money, Income, Prices and
Interest Rates after the 1980s.” Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Working
Paper #1990-11, 1990.
Litterman, Robert B., and Weiss, Lawrence. “Money, Real Interest Rates and Out­
put: A Re-interpretation of Postwar U.S. Data.”
, 53 (January,
1985), 128-156.

Eooerc
cnmtia

Sims, Christopher A. “Comparison of lnterwar and Postwar Business Cycles:
Monetarism Reconsidered.”
, 70 (May, 1980),
250-257.

Aeia Eooi Rve
mrcn cnmc eiw

Stock, James H., and Watson, Mark W. “Interpreting the Evidence on MoneyIncome Causality.”
40 (January, 1989), 161-182.

JunloEooerc,
ora fcnmtis

FRB CHICAGO Working Paper
October 1990, WP-1990-17




10

Working Papers and Staff Memoranda
The following lists papers developed in recent years by the Bank's research
staff. Copies of those materials that are currently available can be obtained by
contacting the Public Information Center (312) 322-5111.

Working Paper Series
A series of research studies on regional economic issues relating to the
Seventh Federal Reserve District, and on financial and economic topics.

REGIONAL ECONOMIC ISSUES
Taxation of Public Utilities Sales: State Practices
and the Illinois Experience

WP-86-1

Measuring Regional High Tech Activity with Occupational Data

WP-87-1

Alternative Approaches to Analysis of Total Factor Productivity
at the Plant Level

WP-87-2

Industrial R&D An Analysis of the Chicago Area

WP-87-3

Metro Area Growth from 1976 to 1985: Theory and Evidence

WP-89-1

Unemployment Insurance: A State Economic Development Perspective

WP-89-2

DaeF SeeadWlim.Tsa
in . igl n ila A et

Aek SGeeadWlim.Tsa
lna . is n ila A et

Rbr H ShobsadPiiR Irieih
oet . cnru n hlp. salvc
Aek SGeeadWlim .Tsa
lna . is n ila A et
Wlim.Tsa
ila A et

Wlim.TsaadNtle.Dvl
ila A et n aaiA aia
AWindow of Opportunity Opens for Regional Economic Analysis:
BEA Release Gross State Product Data
Aek SGee
lna . is

WP-89-3

Determining Manufacturing Output for States and Regions

WP-89-4

The Opening of Midwest Manufacturing to Foreign Companies:
The Influx of Foreign Direct Investment

WP-89-5

PiiR Irieih n Wlim .Tsa
hlp. salvcad ila A et
Aek SGee
lna .is




l

Working paper series continued

A New Approach to Regional Capital Stock Estimation:
Measurement and Performance

WP-89-6

Why has Illinois Manufacturing Fallen Behind the Region?

W P-89-7

Regional Specialization and Technology in Manufacturing

W P-89-8

Theory and Evidence of Two Competitive Price Mechanisms for Steel

WP-89-9

Aek SGeead oetI Shobs
lna . is n Rbr I cnru
.
Wlim.Tsa
ila A et

Aek SGeeadWlim.Tsa
lna . is n ila A et

Crsohr re,PiiR Irieih n Rbr H Shobs
hitpe Ecg hlp. salvcad oet . cnru

Regional Energy Costs and Business Siting Decisions:
An Illinois Perspective

WP-89-10

Manufacturing's Changeover to Services in the Great Lakes Economy

WP-89^12

DvdR AlrieadWlim .Tsa
ai . ladc n ila A et
Wlim .Tsa
ila A et

Construction of Input-Output Coefficients
with Flexible Functional Forms

WP-90-1

Regional Regulatory Effects on Bank Efficiency

W P-90-4

Regional Growth and Development Theory: Summary and Evaluation

W P-90-5

Institutional Rigidities as Barriers to Regional Growth:
A Midwest Perspective

W P-90-6

PiiR Irieih
hlp. salvc

DulsD Eaof n PiiR Irieih
oga . vnfad hlp. salvc
Gofe J .Hwns
efry D eig

McalKni
ihe edx

ISSUES IN FINANCIAL REGULATION
Technical Change, Regulation, and Economies of Scale for Large Commercial
Banks: An Application of a Modified Version of Shepard's Lemma

DulsD Eaof PiiR.salvcadRnalC Mri
oga . vnf, hlp Irieih n adl . ers




WP-89-11

2

Working paper series continued

Reserve Account Management Behavior: Impact of the Reserve Accounting
Scheme and Carry Forward Provision

W P-89-12

Are Some Banks too Large to Fail? Myth and Reality

WP-89-14

Variability and Stationary of Term Premia

W P-89-16

A Model of Borrowing and Lending with Fixed and Variable Interest Rates

WP-89-17

Do "Vulnerable" Economies Need Deposit Insurance?: Lessons from the
U.S. Agricultural Boom and Bust of the 1920s

W P-89-18

The Savings and Loan Rescue of 1989: Causes and Perspective

WP-89-23

The Impact of Deposit Insurance on S&L Shareholders' Risk/Retum Trade-offs

W P-89-24

Payments System Risk Issues on a Global Economy

W P-90-12

DulsD Eaof
oga . vnj
Gog G Kumn
ere . afa

R m nP D GnaoadJmsTMsr
a o . e enr n ae . oe
Toa Mnsha
hms odcen

CalsW Clmrs
hre . aoii
Gog G Kumn
ere . afa

EiaBee I
ljh rwrI
I

Hret . aradDuls .Eaof
ebr LBe n oga D vnj
MACRO ECONOMIC ISSUES

Back of the G-7 Pack: Public Investment and Productivity
Growth in the Group of Seven

WP-89-13

Monetary and Non-Monetary Sources of Inflation: An Error
Correction Analysis

WP-89-15

Trade Policy and Union Wage Dynamics

WP-89-19

DvdA Acae
ai . shur

KnehN Ktnr
ent . ute
Eln .Rsmn
leR isa




3

Working paper series continued

Investment Cyclicality in Manufacturing Industries

W P-89-20

Labor Mobility, Unemployment and Sectoral Shifts:
Evidence from Micro Data

WP-89-22

BueC Ptre adWlim .Srus
rc . eesn n ila A tas

PaahLugn,Rcad oesnadYn-onSn
rks onai ihr Rgro n agHo on
Unit Roots in Real GNP: Do We Know, and Do We Care?

W P-90-2

Money Supply Announcements and the Market's Perception
of Federal Reserve Policy

WP-90-3

Sectoral Shifts in Interwar Britain

W P-90-7

Money, Output, and Inflation: Testing the P-Star Restrictions

WP-90-8

Current Real Business Cycle Theories and Aggregate Labor
Market Fluctuations

WP-90-9

Lwec JCrsin adMri Ecebu
arne. hitao n atn ihnam
See Srni adVf Tra
tvn togn n ea ahn

PaahLugn adM r Rs
rks onai n a k uh
KnehN Ktnr
ent . ute

Lwec JCrsin adMri Ecebu
arne. hitao n atn ihnam

The Output, Employment, and Interest Rate Effects of
Government Consumption

WP-90-10

Money, Income, Prices and Interest Rates after the 1980s

WP-90-11

Real Business Cycle Theory: Wisdom or Whimsy?

WP-90-13

Macroeconomic Models and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

WP-90-14

SR oAygr, arneJCrsin adMri Ecebu
. a iaai Lwec . hitao n atn ihnam

Bnai M Fida adKnehN Ktnr
ejmn . remn n ent . ute
Mri Ecebu
atn ihnam
See Srni
tvn togn




4

Working paper series continued

Stock Market Dispersion and Real Economic Activity:
Evidence from Quarterly Data

WP-90-15

Term-Structure Spreads, The Money Supply Mechanism,
and Indicators of Monetary Policy

WP-90-16

Another Look at the Evidence on Money-Income Causality

WP-90-17

PaahLugn,M r Rs adWlimTv
rks onai a k uh n ila ae
Rbr D Luet
oet . arn

Bnai M Fida adKnehN Ktnr
ejmn . remn n ent . ute




5

Staff Memoranda
A series of research papers in draft form prepared by members of the
Research Department and distributed to the academic community for review
and comment. (Series discontinued in December, 1988. Later works appear in
working paper series).
Risks and Failures in Banking: Overview, History, and Evaluation

SM-86-1

The Equilibrium Approach to Fiscal Policy

SM-86-2

Banking Risk in Historical Perspective

SM-86-3

The Impact of Market, Industry, and Interest Rate Risks
on Bank Stock Returns

SM-86-4

Wage Growth and Sectoral Shifts: New Evidence on the
Stability of the Phillips Curve

SM-87-1

Testing Stock-Adjustment Specifications and
Other Restrictions on Money Demand Equations

SM-87-2

The Truth About Bank Runs

SM-87-3

On The Relationship Between Standby Letters of Credit and Bank Capital

SM-87-4

Alternative Instruments for Hedging Inflation Risk in the
Banking Industry

SM-87-5

The Effects of Regulation on Bank Participation in the Market

SM-87-6

Bank Stock Valuation: Does Maturity Gap Matter?

SM-87-7

Gog JBntnadGog G Kumn
ere. eso n ere . afa

DvdAa Acae
ai ln shur
Gog G Kumn
ere . afa

EiaBee,IadCegF wLe
ljh rwrII n hn e e

Eln.Rsmn
leR isa

RnalC Mri
adl . ers

Gog G Kumn
ere . afa

Gr D KpehvradRgrSoe
ay . opnae n oe tvr

Gr D KpehvradCegF Le
ay . opnae n hn . e
Gr D Kpehvr
ay . opnae
Vf Tra
ea ahn




6

Staff Memoranda continued

Finite Horizons, Intertemporal Substitution and Fiscal Policy

SM-87-8

Reevaluation of the Structure-Conduct-Performance
Paradigm in Banking

SM-87-9

Net Private Investment and Public Expenditure in the
United States 1953-1984

SM-87-10

DvdAa Acae
ai ln shur

DulsD Eaof n DaaL Frir
oga . vnfad in . ote
DvdAa Acae
ai ln shur

Risk and Solvency Regulation of Depository Institutions:
Past Policies and Current Options

SM-88-1

Public Spending and the Return to Capital

SM-88-2

Is Government Spending Stimulative?

SM-88-3

Securities Activities of Commercial Banks: The Current
Economic and Legal Environment

SM-88-4

A Note on the Relationship Between Bank Holding Company
Risks and Nonbank Activity

SM-88-5

Duration Models: A Taxonomy

SM-88-6

Gog JBntnadGog G Kumn
ere.eso n ere . afa

DvdAcae
ai shur
DvdAcae
ai shur

Gog G Kumnad ar R Mt
ere . afa n Lry . oe

Eia Bee,II
ljh rwr I

G 0 Bewg Gog G KumnadCnhaM Lta
. . ira, ere . afa n yti . at

Durations of Nondefault-Free Securities

G O BewgadGog G Kumn
. . ira n ere . afa
Is Public Expenditure Productive?

DvdAcae
ai shur




SM-88-7

1




Staff Memoranda continued

Commercial Bank Capacity to Pay Interest on Demand Deposits:
Evidence from Large Weekly Reporting Banks

SM-88-8

Imperfect Information and the Permanent Income Hypothesis

SM-88-9

EiaBee,I adToa H Mnsha
ljh rwr I n hms . odcen
I
AhjtVBnre adKnehN Ktnr
bii . aeje n ent . ute

Does Public Capital Crowd out Private Capital?

SM-88-10

Imports, Trade Policy, and Union Wage Dynamics

SM-88-11

Dvd shur
ai Acae
Eln isa
leRsmn

8