View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

A Series of Occasional Papers in Draft Form Prepared by Members

of the Research Department for Review and Comment

SM-87-5

ALTERNATIVE INSTRUMENTS FOR HEDGING INFLATION
RISK IN THE BANKING INDUSTRY




Gary D. Koppenhaver and Cheng F. Lee

Alternative Instruments for Hedging Inflation Risk
in the Banking Industry
by

G.
D. Koppenhaver
Senior Economist
Research Department
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
and
Cheng F . Lee
IBE Professor of Finance
The Unversity of Illinois at Urbana Champaign

January

1 9 87

The authors thank Morgan Lynge, University of Illinois at Urbana Champaign,
for helpful comments and suggestions. Any errors remain the sole
responsibility of the authors. All views expressed here are those of the
authors and are not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
or the Federal Reserve System.




Alternative Instruments for Hedging Inflation
Risk in the Banking Industry

I. Introduction
The unprecedented volatility in inflation and interest rates experienced
in this country over the past ten years and the subsequent failure and near
failure of financial institutions has forced most bank and thrift executives
to seek effective ways of hedging unexpected changes in inflation and interest
rates.

For example, bank and thrift executives can either use gap management

or derivative market instruments to reduce their inflation risk exposure.

The

main purpose of this paper is to (i) discuss the relationship between
inflation and capital market returns, and (ii) study the possible advantages
of using consumer price index futures relative to other financial futures and
cash market decisions in managing inflation-driven risk exposure for banking
firms.
The idea that economic agents can convert fixed nominal payments into a
constant flow of real purchasing power by linking currency units to a price
index is not new (see Friedman (1984)).

Indexed bonds and escalator wage

clauses are two examples of these adaptions to the uncertainties of
inflation.

Interest in extensive indexation, however, appears only when

inflation rates are high and variable.

Lovell and Vogel (1973) were perhaps

the first to realize the advantages of a distinct futures market based on a
price level index.
Because futures contracts currently exist for a limited menu of
commodities and financial instruments, the recent introduction of a consumer
price index contract is a beneficial innovation; it provides a hedging vehicle
for managing a risk element common in prices throughout the economy: uncertain




2

Inflation.

"Homemade" indexation can now occur outside of bilateral

negotiations.

A consumer price index futures contract also permits a more

efficient allocation of risk-bearing in the economy and could reduce the
overall level of inflation risk exposure, if the market brings long and short
hedgers together.

Finally, a price index futures contract provides a market

consensus on inflationary expectations that could be beneficial to both
private and public decision-makers that are not direct market participants.
For all of these reasons, the utilization and performance of the CPI-W futures
contract merits evaluation, along with alternative methods of managing
inflation risk.
This paper is organized as follows.

Section II examines the relationship

between the Treasury bill rate and inflation and the discusses impact of
inflation on equity returns.

Section III analyzes the impact of inflation on

financial intermediary decisions and discusses the alternatives available to
bank management for hedging inflation risk.
bank hedging of inflation risk.
our theoretical results.

Section IV develops a model for

Empirical results are then used to illustrate

Finally, the conclusions are summarized in section

VI.

II.

The Relationship Between Treasury Bill Rates and Inflation

Since World War II, U.S. inflation has been generally rising, except for
the last several years, and also fluctuating with increasing amplitude, as
pointed out by Cagan (1985).

Cagan's predicted and actual five-year average

inflation rate is listed in Table 1.




Hence, inflation risk management becomes

Predicted and Actual Five-Year Average
Inflation Rates
(percent per year)
Five-Year
Predicted
Actual
_____Error________
Prediction______Average___________ Rate__________ Rate________ Predicted - Actual
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981

1967-71
1968-72
1969-73
1970-74
1971-75
1972-76
1973-77
1974-78
1975-79
1976-80
1978-82
1979-83
1980-84
1981-84a
1982-84b

3.98
4.08
4.88
5.27
5.87
6.08
5.35
5.41
5.79
6.48
7.07
7.52
7.86
7.85
7.90

4.48
4.70
4.96
5.64
6.38
6.42
6.74
7.05
7.01
6.99
7.85
7.18
6.26
5.63
4.44

-0.50
-0.62
-0.08
-0.37
-0.51
-0.34
-1 .39
-1 .64
-1.22
-0.51
-0.78
+0.34
+1 .60
+2.22
+3.46

aFour year average.
bThree year average.
Note: Based on annual average of GNP deflator and Ml. Predictions of
regressions of inflation rate on annual monetary growth for four preceding
years, 1953 to year prediction is made. The prediction from the regression
uses data of actual monetary growth for the four years prior to the predicted
year.
Source:




Phillip Cagan (1985), "The Unpredictability of Inflation" MIMEO.

- 4 -

important for equity and bond investing, mutual fund managers, pension fund
managers and banking executives.

There are commodity futures, financial

futures and options that can be used by inventors and managers to hedge this
inflation risk, albeit imperfectly.

Inflation will generally increase

interest rates and affect the market value of equity.

First, examine the

impact of inflation on interest rates.
Irving Fisher (1930) pointed out that the one-period nominal rate of
interest is the equilibrium real return plus the fully anticipated rate of
inflation.

Roughly speaking, the nominal rate of interest can be thought of

as the sum of the equilibrium expected real return and the market's view of
the expected inflation rate.
Fama (1975) tested the relationship between nominal interest rates on
default-free bonds and price level changes.
the relationship on an ex ante basis.
1)

As such he was the first to test

His conclusions were that:

expected real returns on Treasury Bills were constant during the
testing period, and

2)

the capital markets are efficient in setting the price of the bills
since the nominal rates summarize all the information about future
rates of inflation that is in the time series of past rates.

These conclusions have drawn some criticism.

Carlson (1977) used survey

data on inflation expectations to discount the first conclusion.
that the short-term expected real rate fell during recessions.

He found
Further, he

found that interest rates were not efficient predictors of inflation because
information about inflation was also provided by an additional variable, the
ratio of employment to population.

Using an information set broader than the

past history of the CPI, Joines (1977) concludes that the market is concerned




5

about forecasting a more general index of inflation.

Further, the lack of

monthly sampling of all items in the CPI is a deficiency in the data.
Nelson and Schwert (1977) showed that the autocorrelation function of the
ex post real rate of interest may be quite close to zero at all lags, even if
the ex ante real rate varies substantially and is highly autocorrelated.

They

showed, using a univariate ARIMA model of the rate of inflation, that the
coefficient of the predictor is large and significant in a composite
prediction regression equation which includes the market interest rate.

This

should only occur if the market is inefficient in assimilating information
contained in past inflation rates.

By making more efficient use of the

information about future inflation contained in past rates, Nelson and Schwert
were able to reject Fama's hypotheses.
Hess and Bicksler (1975) also concluded that the behavior of nominal
interest rates on Treasury bills is not consistent with the joint market
efficiency and real rate constancy hypothesis.

Furthermore, the failure to

confirm market efficiency appeared to be the result of naive estimates of the
expected real rate.
Fama (1977) countered that all these challenges do not imply rejection of
the joint hypothesis over the 1953-71 period for the Treasury bill market.

He

found that the interest rate remained the best (if not the sole) single
predictor of the inflation rate.

Although not an exact description of the

actual market, the specific deviations were mostly manifestations of
measurement errors in the estimates of the different rates.
Following Fama (1975, 1977), we have the basic Fisher relationship
(1)

Rt = rt +

At,

where r^ and A^ are random variables with r^ = the real return in month t, A^ =




6

the inflation rate at end of month t-1, and

= the nominal interest rate quoted at

end of month t-1 on a Treasury bill that matures at the end of month t.
The market's expectation about inflation will depend on the difference
between the nominal rate and the market's expectation about the real return,

(2 )

EraUtl*t-l)

Rt -

=
=

Rt

Em(rt l*t-if
-

Rt)

E(rt),

where Em (&tl4»t-l) = the market's expected inflation rate based on a prior
information set used by the market, Em(rtl4‘t-1,Rt) = the market's expected real
return based on prior information and the current nominal rate, and E(rt) = the
expected value of the real return on the bill for the month.

This becomes

a testable hypothesis via the linear equation.1
(3)

&t

=

ao

+

a iRt

+ ct-

If Fama's hypotheses are correct the intercept term should be postive

and significantly diffrent from zero (a0 = E(rt) > 0 ) and the slope
should be insignificantly different from minus one (ax = -1).

Fama found

these estimates in terms of monthly data to be aQ = .00068 (t ratio = 2.27) and

<xx = -.978 (t ratio = -9.59) using 1953-71 data.
In updating Fama's research, data for two subperiods, 1959-1971 and
1972-1986, were used to estimate equation (3).
Table 2.

The results are listed in

Table 2 indicates that the relationship between inflation and the

three-month Treasury bill rate for the period 1972 - 1986 does not follow
Fama's hypotheses, although empirical results from 1959 - 1971 do conform.




OLS results for At = ao + a x Rt
Data
Period

R2

D.W.

ao

ai

1959-1971

0.0037*
(3.021)

-1.009*
(-9.316)

0.6273

1 .621

1972-1986

-0.0125*
(-3.646)

-0.2028
(-1.310)

0.0124

0.475

Note: Values within parentheses are t statistics.
*S1gn1fIcantly different from zero at the 5% level.

Table 3
OLS results for At = aQ + a x Rt + a 2 At_l

Data
Period

ao

1959-1971

0.0026*
(2.018)

1972-1986

-0.0059*
(-2.611)

ai

-0.7316*
(-4.062)
0.1768**
(1.690)

Note: Values within parentheses are t
aDurb1n h test for autocorrelation not
*S1gn1fIcantly different from zero at
**S1gnifIcantly different from zero at




a2

R2

0.2648**
(1.858)

0.6454

0.8610*
(9.431)

0.6158

statistics.
valid.
the 5% level.
the 10% level.

Durbin h

a
0.2384

8
To examine the existence of inefficiency in the Treasury bill market, we add a
lagged inflation variable to equation (3) and obtain
(4)

&t = ao + a i Rt + a a &t-l + ct
If the estimated a 2 is significantly different than zero, then there

exists inefficiency in the Treasury bill market.
equation (4) are listed in Table 3.

Empirical results for

It is shown that the estimated <xa 's are

significant at the 10% and 1% levels for the period 1959-1971 and the period
1972-1986, respectively.

These results imply that equation (3) for 1972-1986

is misspecified.
To investigate the potential impact of the change in Federal Reserve
policy on October 6, 1979, as a source of misspecification for the inflation
and Treasury bill rate relationship, both an intercept dummy and a slope dummy
are added to equations (3) and (4).

On this date, the Federal Reserve System

changed their monetary policy operating procedure from targeting the federal
funds rate to targeting a monetary aggregate (nonborrowed reserves).

Under

the new regime, short-term interest rates were allowed to seek an equilibrium
level consistent with the availability of funds in our financial system.

This

change in operating procedure could be one reason for the breakdown in the
inflation-Treasury bill rate relationship for 1972 - 1986 noted above.
then obtain
(5)

&t = a0 + a iRt

+

a a Dt + a 3 °t Rt + ct

(6)

&t = aO + a lRt

+

a 2 Dt + a 3 Dt Rt + a4 &t-l

where

= 0 for 1972 to the third quarter 1979, and

* et

= 1 for the 4th quarter 1979 to the third quarter




1986.

We

- 9 -

Estimation results for equations 5 and 6 over the 1972-1986 period are
presented in Table 4.

Table 4 indicates that there is an impact of the 1979

Federal Reserve policy change on the relationship between the inflation rate
and the Treasury bill rate.

These results also imply that Fama's hypotheses

as indicated in equation (3) cannot adequately describe the current
relationship between the inflation rate and the Treasury bill rate.
The results above have important implications for using three-month
Treasury bill futures to hedge inflation-driven interest rate risk in the
banking industry.

Inflation will generally have an impact on the market

values of assets, liabilities, equity and profits of commercial banks.

If the

relationship between the inflation and Treasury bill rate follows Fama's
hypothesis, then Treasury bill futures can be effectively used by
decision-makers to hedge short-run inflation risk.

If the relationship does

not follow Fama's hypothesis, then Treasury bill futures will not necessarily
be useful for hedging inflation risk.

Other financial futures contracts or

the recently introduced CPI-W futures contract may be better candidates for an
effective hedging instrument.2
Next examine the impact of inflation on the market value of equity.

This

topic has been extensively examined by Roll (1973), Merton (1973), Chen and
Bones (1975), Friend, Landskroner and Losq (1976), Jaffe and Mandelker (1976),
Chu et al. (1985), Elton et al. (1983), Gultekin (1983), Lee et al. (1985) and
others.

Lee et al. (1985) found individual equity returns can be either

postively or negatively related to the inflation rate.

However, Taffe and

Mandeker (1976) and Lee et al. (1985) have also found that rates of return on
stock indexes are generally negatively related to the inflation rate.
theoretical value of a stock index can be written as
(7)




It

= l
t=l

dp (1 + g)t
(1 + k)t

The

- 10 -

Table 4
OLS results for equations (5) and (6), 1972 - 1986
Coefficient

Equation (51

Equation (6)

ao

0.0045
(0.905)

0.0002
(0.047)

ai

-1.4842*
(-4.894)

-0.3407
(-1.097)

a2

-0.0023
(-0.303)

-0.0071
(-1 .194)

<*3

0.8864*
(2.427)
-

0.7546*
(5.792)

R2

0.3991

D.W.

1 .294

-

_

1 .125

Durbin h

Note: Values in parentheses are t statistics.
*S1gn1fIcantly different from zero at the 5% level.
**S1gn1fIcantly different from zero at the 10% level.




0.5085**
(1.719)

0.6251

n

where d0 = the initial dividend payment of the stock index, g = the growth
rate associated with dividend payments, and k = the required rate of return.
Inflation will affect the market value of a stock index in terms of
earnings, dividends and the discount rate.

If the impact of inflation on 1^-

is essentially determined by k, then the correlation coefficient between 1^
and the inflation rate

should be negative.

Most of the above-mentioned

research finds that the ex post relationship between the inflation rate and
rate of return on equity is negative.

However, Gultekin (1983) found that

expected real equity returns from the S&P 500 are postively correlated to
expected inflation.
Cornell and French (1983) show that forward price of index futures can be
defined as
r(T - t)
(8)

F(t , T)

=

I(t) (e

[1 - d/r] + d/r)

where F(t, T) represents the forward price in period t with maturity T, I-f. is
the stock index, and r and d represent the interest rate and the dividend
yield, respectively.

If stock indexes are negatively related to inflation

then index futures will be positively correlated with inflation.

Therefore,

stock index futures, along with debt instrument futures, and foreign exchange
futures are potential instruments that can be used to hedge inflation risk in
the banking industry.
III. The Impact of Inflation on Banking Firms
In a recent article, Landskroner and Ruthenburg (1985) investigate the
optimal behavior of a commercial bank under uncertain inflation.

This model

of a risk averse, multiproduct, and price-discriminating intermediary reveals
that an increase in uncertainty about the end of period inflation rate reduces




- 12
total bank lending, lowers the deposit rate set by the bank, and Induces the
bank to shift the composition of assets and liabilities toward those linked
directly to the inflation rate and away from those that are not linked to
Inflation.

Inflation risk enters the model as a determinant of the profits

from the nominal (non-1Inked) segment of the multiproduct bank.

Other Impacts

of inflation on bank decision-making, such as the effect of disinflation on
loan defaults and the effect of Inflation on mismatched bank balance sheets,
are not considered.
First consider the Impact of disinflation on bank credit risks.

If the

bank's loan portfolio 1s not well diversified over all segments and Industries
1n the economy, disinflation may affect the cash flows of bank borrowers and
reduce their ability to service financial obligations.

To the extent that the

greater credit risk of the bank's loans are realized 1n actual loan defaults,
the bank's return on earning assets 1s reduced, squeezing bank profits and the
return on equity.

On the other hand, 1f the bank's loan portfolio is well

diversified, then losses due to default in one loan sector are offset by the
Increased credit worthiness of borrowers in another loan sector.
total loan returns are stabilized.

Ex ante, the

Ex post with loan default, however, the

Increased credit worthiness of some of the bank's borrowers can not be
Internalized unless the loans are sold.

If the lower credit risk loans are

not sold, the defaulting borrowers again reduce the return on earning assets.
If the lower credit risk loans are sold, asymmetric information about loan
quality may prevent the bank from realizing the full value of the loans 1n the
secondary market.
There are several cash market decisions that the bank can take to manage
inflation-driven credit risk, 1f bank management expects disinflation.

The

bank could make fewer loans or increase Its credit standards that determine




- 13 qualified borrowers.

To cushion the impact of loan write-offs, the bank could

add to its equity capital.

Futures market decisions could also prove useful,

given a contract that accurately tracks the inflation rate.

To protect

against unanticipated disinflation and the loss of loan revenues, the bank
could sell futures contracts.

Should unexpected disinflation occur, futures

profits could be used to augment bank cash market returns.

It is also

conceivable that the joint interaction of cash and futures market decisions
could induce the bank to increase its inflation-driven credit risk by
increasing nondiversified lending or lowering credit standards.

As long as

this risk can be transferred to the futures market, these decisions could help
the bank maximize the expected utility of profits.3
There are other impacts of inflation on banking firms.

Since banks are in

the business of lending money, bank management may be interested in locking in
high real rates of return on lending activities and preventing them from
falling with unexpected inflation.

The risk to the bank is that an

unanticipated increase in inflation will erode the purchasing power of the
funds lent out.

The bank can counter this specific risk either by buying

futures contracts whose prices move sympathetically with the inflation rate or
by setting nominal loan rates higher than would be the case in the absence of
inflation risk.

However, except for a small amount of equity (usually in the

neighborhood of 6% of total assets), nominal bank assets are funded by nominal
debt liabilities.

Therefore, the erosion of loan revenues due to inflation

are offset almost completely by the erosion of funding (liability) costs.
Since the financial intermediary is both a borrower and a lender, the bank's
nominal profits are insulated from the realization of unexpected changes in
inflation.
Of course, the offsetting impact of inflation is greatest when the
maturity structure and repricing characteristics of each asset is exactly




- 14

matched to each liability (called a zero maturity gap).

If this is not the

case and bank liabilities reprice or mature faster than bank assets (called a
negative maturity gap), then inflation does have an impact on bank profits.
The realization of unanticipated inflation raises market interest rates,
increases the cost of funding bank assets, and squeezes the bank's profit
margin.

If bank assets reprice or mature faster than bank liabilities (called

a positive maturity gap), then inflation has a favorable impact on bank
profits and the risk in decision-making is that disinflation occurs.

With a

non-zero maturity gap, the bank can manage inflation risk either by asset and
liability decisions that move the maturity gap toward zero or by futures
market decisions that transfer the inflation risk to futures market
participants.
What types of maturity gaps characterize U.S. commercial banks?

The

Federal Reserve collects quarterly maturity gap data on banks nationwide
(Schedule J in the quarterly Report of Condition) and Table 5 is a summary of
the data reported for June 1985.

Table 5 reveals that negative maturity gaps

for less than three months forward are the rule for all sized banks responding
to the June 1985 Report of Condition.

This data also tends to support the

hypothesis that the larger the bank the smaller the maturity gap.4
With the above possible impacts of inflation on banking firms in mind, the
next section of this paper presents a model of bank behavior with financial
futures to investigate the management of inflation risk through joint cash and
futures market decisions.

Inflation risk enters the model by assuming

different repricing characteristics of bank assets and liabilities, i.e., one
of the bank's balance sheet items reprices faster than the rest of the balance
sheet.

A model of inflation-driven credit risk management by commercial banks

is not explicitly treated.




15

Table 5
Summary of U.S. Commercial Bank Maturity Gaps
June 1985
(means with standard error of the mean 1n parentheses)
Bank Category

N

Gap 3

Gap 6

Gap 12

Gap 60

1.

All banks

14,382

-0.0360*
(0.0012)

-0.0126*
(0.0006)

0.0413*
(0.0006)

0.1835*
(0.0009)

2.

Banks with
assets less
than $100
million

11,848

-0.0366*
(0.0014)

-0.0109*
(0.0007)

0.0437*
(0.0007)

0.1834*
(0.0011)

2,044

-0.0362*
(0.0029)

-0.0210*
(0.0012)

0.0333*
(0.0011)

0.1902*
(0.0023)

Banks with
assets $500$1000 million

198

-0.0274*
(0.0089)

-0.0255*
(0.0038)

0.0227*
(0.0032)

0.1854*
(0.0093)

Banks with
assets $1$10 billion

268

-0.0199*
(0.0065)

-0.0112*
(0.0022)

0.0154*
(0.0024)

0.1460*
(0.0060)

24

-0.0230*
(0.0094)

0.0020
(0.0039)

0.0040
(0.0031)

0.0720*
(0.0075)

3.

4.

5.

6.

Banks with
assets $100$500 million

Banks with
assets greater
than $10
billion

Source: Report of Condition, June 1985.
Variable definitions:
Assets: total bank assets plus allowance for loan losses and minus
goodwill.
Gap 3: Schedule J allocated assets maturing 1n three months or less minus
liabilities maturing 1n three months or less (Including Super NOW deposits and
money market deposits) all divided by assets.
Gap 6: Schedule 0 assets maturing In three to six months minus liabilities
maturing 1n three to six months all divided by assets.
Gap 12: Schedule J assets maturing 1n six months to one year minus
liabilities maturing 1n six months to one year all divided by assets.
Gap 60: Schedule J assets maturing 1n one to five years minus liabilities
maturing 1n one to five years all divided by assets.
N: Number of banks 1n category.
*S1gn1fIcantly different from zero at the 5% level.



-

IV.

16

Hedging Inflation Risk

This section presents a model of Interest rate risk management where the
underlying source of the Interest rate risk Is an unanticipated change 1n the
Inflation rate.

A position 1n the futures market 1s used jointly with earning

asset rate-setting to hedge, ex ante, the uncertain cost of funds.

That 1s,

the futures hedge 1s an anticipatory hedge of a liability price risk faced by
the financial Intermediary.

Hedging permits the separation of Inflation risk

considerations from gap management considerations 1n setting earning asset
rates.

Asset and liability management through financial futures hedging and

rate-setting become tools for controlling risk exposure created by ex post
liability management.

This application of financial futures hedging Is

different than the literature on the anticipatory hedging of bank liability
Interest rates (see Franckle and Senchack (1982), Koppenhaver (1985), Parker
and Dalgler (1981), and Speakes (1983)) because 1t explicitly considers the
management of the Inflation risk faced by rate setting Intermediaries.
Furthermore, cash and futures market decisions are determined simultaneously.
It 1s assumed the bank uses two tools to manage the uncertainty of
unanticipated Inflation: trading futures contracts and setting earning asset
Interest rates.

To manage an Increase 1n the cost of funds, the bank can sell

futures contracts and raise loan Interest rates.

The sale of futures

contracts represents an anticipatory hedge of funding costs (a funding hedge)
because 1t acts as an alternative source of funds.

If Inflation 1s closely

associated with a rise 1n market Intrest rates, the profits from a short
(sell) futures position augment the Increased cash market cost of funds.
profits can be sustained In the face of higher rates.

Conversely, both lower

Inflation and lower market Interest rates create less need for a funding
hedge; the short position should be reduced or possibly changed to a long




Bank

17

(buy) position to Increase bank profitability.

In conjunction with the

funding hedge, the bank can raise (lower) loan interest rates to counter
expected increases (decreases) in inflation, assuming a negative interest
elasticity of loan demand.
Assume the bank has a one-period planning horizon.

At the beginning of

the period, the bank must decide on the futures position, X, and the earning
asset interest rate, R l .

At this time, the bank knows the current futures

price, Px, the rate on retail deposits, Rg, and the loan demand
schedule, L(Rl ), but does not know the interest rate on purchased funds,
Rg, or the futures price, Px, at the end of the period.
random variables realized in the future.)

(Tildes indicate

When the purchased funds rate is

realized and the futures position is offset, bank borrowing, B, takes place to
fill out the balance sheet.
be perfectly competitive.
v '

Rjj

=

The market for these funds is assumed to
Let Rg be

r

+

e,

with aRg/ac and aRg/ao

> 0

where r is the end of period real rate of interest and e is the end of period
expected inflation rate, both unknown ex ante but with a known subjective
probability distribution.

Bank profits (nominal) at the end of the period are

given by:

(1 0 )

n

= RLL(RL)

*

(Px - px)x - Rb B

where D is the known level of retail deposits.

-

Rd D

For simplicity, initial

margins and variation margin calls are ignored.
The bank's problem is to make two ex ante decisions, X and R l , and one ex
post decision, B, that will maximize the expected utility of profit subject to
the balance sheet contraint at the end of the period.5




These decisions are

18

based on the bank's subjective expectation about future events, described by
the joint cumulative density F(Px,RB).

It is assumed that this joint

distribution does not change over the planning period.

The decision problem

can be written:
(11)

Maximize E[max U(n)| F(Px,RB)]
X,Rl S O B S 0
subject to: L = B +■ D

where E is the expectations operator, and U is a risk averse utility function
such that U'(n) > 0 and U"(n) < 0 ( a prime indicates derivation).
Assuming bank management is constant absolute risk averse and the joint
distribution of random variables is normal, the objective function in
expression (11) can be rewritten in a mean-variance expected utility
framework, after substituting for B from the balance sheet contraint.
Assuming no correlation between real rates and futures market prices and that
loan demand is given by L(Rl ) = aG - s x Rl with a0 , ax > 0, the optimal
solution can be shown to be:
(12)

X*= E(PX - PX)

*

[L(RQ - D]

T Var(Px)
(13)

RL

=

Cov(8, PX), and

Var(Px)

ERb ‘ (ao/ai)
2 + ^ax Var(Rs)

+

(aQ - D) Var(RB) - X*Cov(9, Px)
(2/y)

+

ax Var(RB)

where f is the index of risk aversion, Var represents variance, and Cov
represents covariance.6
In the right hand side of equation (12), the optimal futures position is
written as the sum of two terms:
term.




an expectations term and a risk exposure

Initially, let the expectations term be zero.

If the futures market

19

moves in the same direction as inflation rates, Cov[e,Px] > 0.

If the

*

bank must purchase funds to support its lending, (D - L(Rl )) < 0, the optimal
futures position represents a long hedge of the anticipated risk exposure.

If

inflation and higher interest rates occur, the profits from a long hedge
substitute for the higher funding costs.

A nonzero expectations term

reinforces the incentive to take a long position if prices are expected to
rise.
In the absence of futures trading, the solution to the model would be
given by equation (13) with X* = 0 in the second term on the right hand side.
In the nonhedging solution, higher expected inflation and funding costs are
managed by raising the loan rate; lower expected inflation and funding costs
by lowering the loan rate.

These qualitative effects are preserved when

futures trading is introduced, but loan rates with an inflation hedge (X* > 0)
are lower than loan rates without hedging.

Low loan rates may exacerbate the

inflation risk in the bank's balance sheet; hedging the risk in the futures
market makes low loan rates less risky.

Alternatively, a large expected fall

in inflation could result in a short futures position (X* < 0 from equation
(12)).

Loan interest rates would then be set higher with futures trading than

without

futures trading.

A short futures position offers no protection

against higher purchased funding costs and is speculative; to compensate, loan
rates must be raised to reduce the bank's exposure.

Futures market risk is a

substitute for funding market risk in maximizing expected utility.
*

Of course, if the bank should not need purchased funding, (D - L(Rl )) > 0,
and invests this difference at Rg at the end of the period, the optimal
futures




position is a short hedge of the anticipated risk when the

- 20 -

expectations term 1s small.

This type of hedge offers protection against a

fall 1n Inflation and Interest rates.

If X* < 0, then from equation (13), the

optimal loan rate will be higher with rather than without futures hedging.
With futures hedging, the higher loan rate rations loan demand and Increases
the amount to be Invested at the end of the period, Increasing the bank's
exposure.

In this case, the opportunity to shed risk via the futures market

Induces the bank to expand Its cash market risk exposure 1n maximizing
expected utility.
Before proceeding, note that 1f bank management 1s extremely risk averse
(t *»), then the optimal solution 1n equations (12) and (13) becomes
(12')

X* =

(13')

Rl

=

[L(Rl ) - D] Cov(e, Px)/Var(Px), and
t(a0 - D)/aJ

-

[X* Cov(e,Px)/a1Var(RB) ].
★

From equation (12'), the optimal hedge ratio, X*/[L(Rl ) - D], 1s given
by Bi 1n the regression
(14)

e = B0

+

Bx PX + c,

where e and Px are usually expressed as the changes 1n each respective variable.
This result 1s well known (see Ederlngton (1979)) under these assumptions and
will prove useful 1n the estimations below.

In sum, bank decision-makers with

an extreme aversion to risk will not employ expectations 1n simultaneous cash
and futures market decisions.
V.

Estimation of Hedging Strategies

This section estimates hedge ratios and hedging effectiveness for the
CPI-W futures contract.

To Investigate the quantitative values of the optimal

hedge ratio Implied by equation (12'), equation (14) 1s our focus.7




Of

21

primary interest here is the optimal hedge ratio associated with the recently
introduced CPI-W futures contract since this contract most closely fits the
dependent variable in equation (14).

The problem in estimating equation (14)

is that observations on the actual CPI-W index are not reported daily, but
only monthly, and with a lag, and at this writing only 15 values of the CPI
index have been observed.

Nevertheless, it would still seem worthwhile to

estimate equation (14) using actual CPI index numbers and CPI-W futures data.
Unfortunately, for hedging periods of less than one month, the estimated hedge
ratio and hedging effectiveness using actual CPI index numbers might be
misleading and inappropriate.
is needed.

A proxy for changes in inflation within a month

Two different proxies are investigated here.

One proxy for e in equation (14) can be constructed from section II of
this paper.

Recall from that earlier discussion that Fama's (1975) joint

hypothesis does not hold using data from 1972-86.

But from the estimated

results for equation (5) in Table 4, a x + a 3 is an estimate of the marginal
effect of a change in nominal Treasury bill rates on the ex post purchasing
power of money. Assuming this relationship holds on a daily or weekly basis,
a proxy for 0 in equation (14) is (ax + a 3) times the change in daily Treasury
bill returns.8

By substituting daily Treasury bill returns for e in equation

(14), the resulting

could then be multiplied by

+ a 3 = - 0.6 to

approximate the optimal CPI-W futures contract hedge ratio.
The other inflation proxy used here is the change in the cash price of
gold.

As an actively-traded precious metal, gold price changes are sensitive

to aggregate demand and supply conditions and have implications for the
purchasing power of money.




Indeed, recent articles in the popular press have

22

called for using either the price of gold or an index of sensitive commodity
prices as an intermediate target for monetary policy.
Using daily data from June 21, 1985, to September 29, 1986, for one- and
three-month T-bill returns, gold prices, and the CPI-W futures market,
equation (14) was estimated using ordinary least squares.

The CPI-W futures

series was constructed by using the near-term contract until the first day of
the maturity month and then rolling over to the next most near term contract.
Both the dependent and independent variables were expressed as percentage
changes to adjust for different units of measurement.9

The percentage changes

in CPI-W futures prices, gold prices, and the cash CPI index were also recast
in terms of the purchasing power of money, rather than the inflation rate, to
facilitate computation of the CPI-W futures hedge ratio using the results in
Section II.
Table 6 presents estimates of the coefficients in equation (14).

Three

different sets of regression results are reported for each of the inflation
proxies based on three different hedge periods: daily, 14-day, and 28-day
intervals.

The results indicate that there is no statistically significant

relationship between the interest rate proxies for inflation and CPI-W futures
prices at any of the three different intervals.

If one- and three-month

T-bill returns reflect information about inflation, the CPI-W futures market
does not reflect it, although the signs of

are as expected.

Cash gold

price changes as an inflation proxy are reflected in CPI-W futures prices but
only on the 28-day hedging period.

In this case (line 3c, Table 6), gold

prices and CPI-W futures prices move in the same direction and one cannot
reject the hypothesis that the percentage changes are one-for-one.

The

release of actual CPI index numbers subsequent to contract maturity is




23 -

Table 6
Estimation of Equation (14) for Different
Dependent Variables, June 1985 - September 1986
(t ratios in parentheses)

Deoendent Variable
1.

b. Three-month T bills
c. Goldd

R2

0.00017*
(24.783)
0.00019*
(27.224)
-0.00049
(-0.919)

-0.00024
(-0.603)
-0.00015
(-0.373)
-0.01758
(-0.610)

0.0012

2.161

-

316

0.0004

1 .848

-

316

0.0013

2.351

0.00018*
(45.461)
0.00020*
(34.190)
-0.00712
(-1.020)

0.00008
(0.186)
-0.00011
(-0.161)
0.89219
(1.234)

0.0013

0.704

-

28

0.0010

1 .809

-

28

0.0676

2.638

DWa

Nc

Pb

281

Two-week Returns on:
a. One-month T-bills
b. Three-month T-bills
c. Gold

3.

Pi

Daily Returns on:
a. One-month T-bills

2.

Po

21
■

Four-week Returns on:
a. One-month T-bills
b. Three-month T-bills
c. Gold
d. CPIe
e. Lag CPI

0.00017*
-0.00014
(-0.556)
(21.752)
0.00020*
-0.00031
(-1.072)
(29.676)
-0.00947
1.43848**
(1.934)
(-1.050)
-0.01720
-0.00178
(-1.589)
(-0.336)
-0.00126**
0.10425**
(-1.951)
(1.884)

0.0251

-

0.0874

“

0.2377

1 .961

0.0093

-

0.2144

1 .341

*Significantly different from zero at the 5% level.
**Significantly different from zero at the 10% level.
aDurbin-Watson test statistic for autocorrelation.
bEstimate of first-order autocorrelation coefficient.
cNumber of observations.
Engelhard industrial billion.
eConsumer price index for all urban workers, not seasonally adjusted.
calendar months.




0.58057
(-2.762)
-0.45570
(-1.983)
—
-0.41942
(1.789)

Estimates based on

13
13
14
13
15

24 -

not significantly related to CPI-W futures prices (line 3d, Table 6), but the
release of the prior month's actual CPI index is reflected in the current
futures price change (line 3e, Table 6).

That is, CPI-W futures prices for

the current month are positively related to the contemporaneous release of the
new CPI index number that applies to the previous month.

Given the lag in the

release of actual CPI data, the CPI-W futures market utilities this
information in revising expectations about the CPI index number to be realized
at contract maturity.
In sum, CPI-W futures prices are not significantly related to short-term
returns on Treasury bills or the subsequently released CPI index.

To the

extent that these instruments reflect changes in inflation, the CPI-W futures
contract is a poor vehicle for hedging this risk.

With gold prices as a

indicator of inflation and over a four-week hedging period, the results here
indicate that the optimal ratio of CPI-W futures contracts to exposure should
be at least equal to 1.

Little solace can be taken from the result that

current CPI-W futures prices reflect the release of inflation data for prior
months except that the market does react to new information, however
irrelevant it might be for risk management today.

The short-term inefficiency

of the CPI-W futures market is probably a manifestation of the lack of open
interest (rarely greater than 100 contracts for all maturity months) and
thinness in the volume of trading since contract introduction.

Whether the

root problem is a overall lack of inflation over the data period or a flaw in
contract design remains to be seen.
VI. Conclusions
This paper has empirially investigated the quality of information about
inflation imbedded in cash market Treasury bill rates and found that Fama's
(1975) joint hypothesis about the constancy of the real rate and the




- 25

efficiency of the Treasury bill market do not hold for 1972-1985 data.

This

result may be due to the structural change that occured with the October 1979
shift in Federal Reserve policy.

Once the Federal Reserve switched from

pegging interest rates to pegging banking system reserves as a monetary
control device, market determined interest rates lost much of their predictive
power with respect to inflation.
This paper also discussed the impact of inflation on banking firm
profitability, with particular emphasis on inflation driven credit and
interest rate risks.

A model of inflation-driven interest rate risk

management was developed and the principal result from the model is that a
risk averse bank would set nominal interest rates on loans lower with futures
market hedging of inflation risk than without hedging.

Using price data for

the recently introduced CPI-W futures contract, estimates of the optimal hedge
ratio that a bank might employ are not significantly different from zero for
intervals of less than one month.

Although the CPI-W futures has not attained

sufficient open interest and trading volume to insure its long-run viability
as of this writing, banks do have need for an Instrument to hedge inflation
risk and could be a market participant when the CPI-W futures market attains
viability.




- 26 -

Footnotes
1 Following Fama (1975),
redefined here as the rate of change of the
purchasing power of a unit of money (the reciprocal of the price level)
instead of the inflation rate, as in equation (1).
3CPI-W futures were introduced by the Coffee, Sugar, and Cocoa Exchange and
started to trade on June 21, 1985. This is a cash settlement contract that
trades until the release of the actual index number for the CPI, approximately
three weeks after the month for which the actual index applies.
3Bank management risk aversion is assumed to motivate the transfer of risk to
those more willing to bear it. See footnote 5 below.
4This hypothesis is based on the observation that large banks are less reliant
on retail deposits and better able to manage the term structure of their
liabilities through purchased funds.
5For justification of expected utility maximization by banks, see the
empirical studies by Edwards (1977) and Ratti (1980). This analysis also
treats a bank's futures position as an off balance sheet item.
sufficient condition for the solution equations (12) and (13) is that the
utility function demonstrate risk aversion. If real rates and futures market
prices are correlated, the covariance terms in equations (12) and (13) are
replaced by Cov(r,Px) + Cov(e,Px). The solutions (12) and (13) could also be
derived by assuming the real rate of interest is constant over the hedging
period.
^Contrary to the theoretical model, this assumes that either: i) the loan
rate is predetermined, or ii) that the loan rate is set in such a way that
X*/[L(R*l ) varies only with Cov(e,Px)/Var(Px). In either case, the
loan rate may not be set optimally.
®This follows by direct substitution into equation (5) for the proxy of
inflation used here, assuming the intercept term is not significantly
different from zero.
9The regressions that used the actual CPI index numbers as dependent variables
were also estimated for level changes instead of percentage changes. Although
not reported below, the results were not significantly different than those
that are reported.




References
Cagan, P. (1985), "The Unpredictability of Inflation", Columbia University,
Mimeo.
Carlson, 3. A. (1977), "Short-Term Interest Rates as Predictors of Inflation:
Comment," American Economic Review, 67, pp. 469-75.
Chu, C. C., C. F. Lee and Oohn K. C. Wei (1985), "Market Risk Premium Under
Uncertain Inflation," The University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign,
Mimeo.
Cornell 8. and K. R. French (1983), "Taxes and the Pricing of Stock Index
Futures," Journal of Finance. 38, 675-694.
Ederington, L. (1979), "The Hedging Performance of the New Futures Markets."
Journal of Finance, 34, pp. 154-170.
Edwards, F. R. (1977), "Managerial Objectives in Regulated Industries: Expense
Preference Behavior in Banking," Journal of Political Economy. 85, pp.
147-162.
Elton, E., M. Gruber, and J. Rentzler (1983), "The Arbitrage Pricing Model and
Return on Assets Under Uncertain Inflation," Journal of Finance. 38, pp.
525-537.
Fama, E. F. (1978), "Short-Term Interest Rates as Predictors of Inflation,"
American Economic Review. 65, pp. 269-82.
Fama, E. F. (1977), "Interest Rates and Inflation: The Message in the
Entrails," American Economic Review. 67, pp. 487-96.
Fisher, I. (1930), Theory of Interest. New York, MacMillan.
Franckle, C. and Senchack, A. (1981), "Economic Considerations in the Use of
Interest Rate Futures," Journal of Futures Markets. 2, pp. 107-116.
Friedman, M. (1984), "Financial Futures Markets and Tabular Standards,"
Journal of Political Economy. 92, pp. 165-167.
Friend, I., Y. Landskroner and E. Losq (1976), "The Demand for Risky Assets
Under Uncertain Inflation," Journal of Finance. 31, pp. 1287 - 129.
Gultekin, N. B. (1983), "Stock Market Returns and Inflation Forecasts,"
Journal of Finance. 38, pp. 663-674.
Hess, P. and J. Bicksler (1975), "Capital Asset Prices Versus Time Series
Models as Predictors of Inflation: The Expected Real Rate of Interest and
Market Efficiency," Journal of Financial Economics. 2, pp. 341-60.
Jaffe, J. F. and G. Mandelker (1976), "The 'Fisher Effect1 for Risky Assets:
An Empirical Investigation," Journal of Finance. 31, pp. 447-458.




28

References (cont'd)
Jolnes, D. (1977), "Short-Term Interest Rates as Predictors of Inflation:
Comment," American Economic Review. 67, pp. 476-77.
Koppenhaver, G. D. (1985), "Bank Funding Risks, Risk Aversion, and the Choice
of Futures Hedging Instrument," Journal of Finance. 40, pp. 241-255.
Landskroner, Y., and D. Ruthenberg (1985), "Optimal Bank Behavior under
Uncertain Inflation," Journal of Finance. 40, pp. 1159-1171.
Lee, C.F., F. C. Jen, and John K. C. We1 (1985) "Responsive Coefficient
Approach to Investigate Capital Asset Pricing Process Under Uncertain
Inflation," paper presented at 1985 FMA annual meeting, Denver.
Lovell, M., and R. Vogel (1973), "A CPI-Futures Market," Journal of Political
Economy. 81, pp. 1009-1012.
Merton, R. C. (1973), "An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model,"
Econometrlca. 41, pp. 867-887.
Nelson, C.R. and G. W. Schwert (1977), "Short-Term Intrest Rates as Predictors
of Inflation: On Testing the Hypothesis that the Real Rate of Interest 1s
Constant," American Economic Review. 67, pp. 478-86.
Parker, J. and R. Dalgler (1981), "Hedging Money Market CDs with Treasury Bill
Futures," Journal Futures Markets. 1, pp. 597-606.
Ratti, R. A. (1980), "Bank Attitude Toward Risk, Implicit Rates of Interest
and the Behavior of an Index of Risk Aversion for Commercial Banks,"
Quarterly Journal of Economics. 95, pp. 309-331.
Roll, R. (1973), "Assets, Money, and Commodity Price Inflation Under
Uncertainty; Demand Theory," Journal of Money. Credit and Banking. 5, pp.
903-923.
Speakes, J. K. (1983), "The Phased-1n Money Market Certificate Hedge," Journal
of Futures Markets. 3, pp. 185-190.