View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Did Adhering to the Gold Standard
Reduce the Cost of Capital?
Ron Alquist and Benjamin Chabot

November 22, 2010
WP 2010-13

Did Adhering to the Gold Standard Reduce the Cost of Capital?
Ron Alquist
Bank of Canada

Benjamin Chabot
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago and NBER

Abstract: A commonly cited benefit of the pre‐World War One gold standard is that it reduced
the cost of international borrowing by signaling a country’s commitment to financial probity.
Using a newly constructed data set that consists of more than 55,000 monthly sovereign bond
returns, we test if gold‐standard adherence was negatively correlated with the cost of capital.
Conditional on UK risk factors, we find no evidence that the bonds issued by countries off gold
earned systematically higher excess returns than the bonds issued by countries on gold. Our
results are robust to allowing betas to differ across bonds issued by countries off‐ and on‐gold;
to including proxies that capture the effect of fiscal, monetary, and trade shocks on the
commitment to gold; and to controlling for the effect of membership in the British Empire.

Key words: Gold standard; sovereign borrowing costs; country risk premium.
JEL classifications: F33; G15; N23.
Acknowledgements: We thank Jeremy Atack, Christiane Baumeister, Charles Calomiris, Wei Dong,
Robert Lafrance, Kim Oosterlinck, Gregor Smith, Linda Tesar, and Marc Weidenmier for comments and
suggestions. We also thank seminar participants at the 2006 NBER Summer Institute, the Center for
Financial Studies Summer School, and the 2008 Canadian Economic Association meetings for helpful
comments. Maggie Jim and Rob Precht provided first‐rate research assistance.
The views expressed in the paper represent the authors’ own and should not be attributed to Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago, The Federal Reserve System or the Bank of Canada.
Corresponding Author: Ron Alquist, Bank of Canada, 234 Wellington Street, Ottawa, ON K1A 0G9.
Email: ralquist@bankofcanada.ca.

1. Introduction
The gold standard before 1914 is generally considered to be a prime example of an exchange
rate regime’s ability to confer credibility on a country’s macroeconomic policy. The “good‐
housekeeping seal of approval” interpretation of the gold standard postulates that gold
convertibility ensured that the government acted consistently over time, so that adherence to
gold served as a signal of financial probity. According to this view, countries that always
maintained convertibility or suspended it only during widely agreed‐upon circumstances (such
as war) should have been rewarded with lower borrowing costs.
Despite its sharp prediction, economists have reached conflicting conclusions about the
effect of gold‐standard adherence on sovereign borrowing costs. In their seminal study, Bordo
and Rockoff (1996) compare the coupon yields (coupon‐price ratios) of sovereign bonds issued
by nine countries and find substantial cross‐country variation in pre‐World War One yields.
They attribute the yield differences to differing commitment to gold. These findings are
consistent with the country studies of Martin‐Acena (1993) and Sussman and Yafeh (2000), and
were confirmed in a larger cross‐section of countries by Obstfeld and Taylor (2003). The
reduction in borrowing costs associated with adhering to gold is estimated to be about 30‐40
basis points per year (Bordo and Rockoff 1996; and Obstfeld and Taylor 2003)
On the other hand, Ferguson and Schularick (2006) find no evidence that the capital
market rewarded gold‐standard adherence and conclude that membership in the British Empire
was key to reducing borrowing costs. Clemens and Williamson (2004) examine capital flows
rather than bond yields and present evidence that gold‐standard adherence was only
marginally important compared to fundamental determinants of capital productivity. Flandreau
and Zumer (2004) conclude that adhering to the gold standard had a negligible influence on
coupon yields, conditional on other covariates intended to capture the effect of fiscal and
monetary policy on sovereign borrowing costs. They argue that international lenders focused
on variables that forecast a country's ability to repay its external debt and that these forecasts
assigned little weight to the exchange‐rate regime. Mitchener and Weidenmier (2009) compare
within‐country coupon yields of bonds with and without gold clauses and conclude that the
international capital market placed little weight on gold‐standard adherence.

2

The crux of the empirical disagreement can be traced to differences in the available
data. In contrast to today, sovereign borrowers during the gold‐standard era issued debt with
different maturities and at infrequent intervals. As a result, a typical 19th century sovereign
borrower had only a handful of maturities trading at any given time, making it impossible to
compare a cross‐section of bonds with matched maturities. To complicate matters further,
most countries issued bonds with stochastic maturity schedules that make it impossible to
compute yield‐to‐maturity and prevent direct comparisons of yields across countries.
Data limitations have forced past researchers to infer borrowing costs by comparing the
coupon yield of bonds at different points of the yield curve. Typically, a single representative
bond is chosen for each country based on availability, liquidity, or the amount outstanding. The
coupon yield is observed for as long as possible, after which another representative bond is
chosen. Because bonds with the same (unobserved) discount rate can have very different
coupon yields attributable to differences in time to maturity or coupon amounts, there is no
guarantee that the observed differences in the coupon yield of bonds with different maturities
actually are due to differences in the exchange‐rate regime rather than the term structure of
the borrower’s external debt. In light of these challenges, it is not surprising that authors using
different representative bonds have arrived at conflicting conclusions.
Because it is unlikely that a consensus can be reached with the existing data, we
propose a test of the good‐housekeeping hypothesis based on a new and much larger sample
of realized holding‐period returns. With over 55,000 bond returns, the size of our new data set
represents an almost 40‐fold increase in the cross‐section of available bond prices.1 Our data
set consists of every regularly quoted sovereign bond from the official quotation list of the
London Stock Exchange between 1870 and 1907. We avoid the difficulty of inferring discount
rates from the coupon yield of bonds with different times to maturity by collecting monthly
price data and calculating realized holding‐period returns. Using holding‐period returns is a new
way to measure the cost of capital in tests of the good‐housekeeping hypothesis, but it is very

1

To our knowledge, the two largest previous samples of 19th century sovereign bond prices are the data sets
available from Global Financial Data (GFD) used by Obstfeld and Taylor (2003) and the one constructed by
Ferguson and Schularick (2006). GFD contains 892 annual observations while Ferguson and Schularick’s data set
contains 1461 annual observations.

3

common in asset‐pricing tests that try to account for cross‐sectional differences in expected
bond returns to ex‐ante observable characteristics.
We find that adherence to the gold standard did not reduce the cost of capital. Across a
variety of specifications and samples, there is no systematic link between a country adhering to
gold and the risk‐adjusted return of its sovereign debt. Conditional on British risk factors, the
returns of bonds issued by countries on and off gold are statistically indistinguishable from one
another. We also examine almost 20,000 bond returns from countries that switch their
exchange rate regime and do not find systematic differences in the sensitivity of the returns to
pervasive risk factors across regimes. Our findings cast doubt upon the good‐housekeeping
hypothesis and support the conclusion reached by Flandreau and Zumer (2004) that gold‐
standard adherence did not have an economically important effect on the cost of capital.
Section 2 discusses the logic of the gold standard as a repeated game. Section 3
examines the close parallels between tests of the good‐housekeeping hypothesis and asset‐
pricing tests designed to detect differences in mean returns across securities. Section 4
describes the empirical specification, methods, and data we use to test the good‐housekeeping
hypothesis. Section 5 reports the results and a set of robustness tests.

2. The Gold Standard as a Repeated Game
Bordo and Kydland (1995) model the gold standard as a credible commitment mechanism that
evolved to overcome the time‐inconsistency problem associated with international borrowing.
Borrowers and lenders in the international capital market play a repeated game in which the
government chooses a mix of borrowing, taxation, and inflation to minimize the deadweight
loss for a given level of revenue. The government’s ability to print money and inflate away the
nominal value of external debt creates an incentive problem when it only cares about the
welfare of its residents (Bohn 1991). Foreign lenders recognize the distorted incentives of the
borrowing country and are unwilling to lend funds without a credible commitment that the
government will repay the real value of its debt.
In the repeated game, a government can overcome the time‐inconsistency problem by
adopting an easy‐to‐monitor policy that prevents it from devaluing its currency. The good‐

4

housekeeping hypothesis postulates that adherence to gold served as such a mechanism. The
gold‐standard equilibrium strategy consists of the government committing to currency stability
by standing ready to convert local currency into gold on demand. In response, the international
bond market rewards the government that ties its currency to gold with a low cost of capital.
The empirical implication of the good‐housekeeping hypothesis is that the international capital
market assigned a lower price, and demanded commensurately higher expected returns, to
bonds issued by countries that did not adhere to the gold standard.
The “good‐housekeeping” repeated game equilibrium relies on the capital market
collectively forgoing current expected profits to punish governments that left gold. For
example, if two different countries issue bonds with identical expected cash flows, the
equilibrium punishment strategy requires investors to assign different prices if the countries
have differing commitments to gold. Assigning different prices to the same expected cash flow
creates a statistical arbitrage opportunity. Therefore, the repeated game equilibrium requires a
collective action mechanism to prevent arbitrage‐seeking investors from pushing the prices of
otherwise identical off‐ and on‐gold bonds together. Large institutional investors who were
both sufficiently patient to play the punishment strategy and large enough to influence
equilibrium prices, such as the Council of Foreign Bondholders and investment banks who
underwrote bond issues, were good candidates to punish countries that abandoned the gold
standard. The available archival evidence suggests that the Council was effective at both
organizing lenders when borrowers defaulted and renegotiating with large borrowers like
Argentina, Brazil, and Turkey (Mauro and Yafeh 2003). The test of the hypothesis that off‐gold
bonds earned higher risk‐adjusted returns than on‐gold bonds is a direct empirical test of
whether these organizations were sufficiently powerful to punish cheaters.

3. Testing the Good‐Housekeeping Hypothesis
The theory proposed by Bordo and Kydland makes a clear prediction: Countries were rewarded
with a low discount rate if they maintain gold convertibility. But bond discount rates vary for
reasons other than a country’s gold‐standard adherence, and any test of the hypothesis needs
to control for other determinants of a country’s risk premium. Traditional tests of the good‐

5

housekeeping hypothesis compare the coupon yield of bonds off‐ and on‐gold controlling for
other risk factors by estimating regressions that are very similar to asset‐pricing tests designed
to detect cross‐sectional differences in returns, conditional on other pervasive risk factors.
Indeed, Bordo and Rockoff write that their empirical specification of the good‐housekeeping
hypothesis is “inspired by the capital asset pricing model” (Bordo and Rockoff 1996). The
empirical specifications of selected tests of the good‐housekeeping hypothesis are reproduced
in Table 1.
All of these tests examine the effect of gold‐standard adherence on risk‐adjusted return
by formally testing for a shift in the intercept δ

0 of a model that controls for other

determinants of the sovereign risk premium. The regression tests are formulated to detect a
common difference in the mean risk‐adjusted coupon yield between on‐ and off‐gold countries.
The specifications listed in Table 1 are very similar to factor model‐based asset pricing
tests that cross‐sectional variation in ex‐ante observable characteristics generates differences
in mean excess returns.2 Both control for risk using factor models and test if an observable
characteristic affects risk‐adjusted return by examining cross‐sectional differences in portfolio
intercepts. Traditional tests of the good‐housekeeping hypothesis and factor model based tests
are thus fully consistent with each another.
Holding‐period returns are a natural way to measuring borrowing costs when the
number of bonds is too small to identify the yield curve or compare coupon yields at matched
maturities. Like coupon‐yield, holding‐period returns are correlated with the unobservable
discount rate and can be used to infer differences in expected returns (Campbell 1995). Unlike
coupon‐yield, holding‐period returns include both the expected coupon yield and the expected
capital gain. Many sovereign bonds during the late 19th century traded well above or below par,
and rational investors surely expected capital losses or gains when purchasing these bonds.
Returns take account of these expected changes.

2

For example, Cornell and Green (1991), Fama and French (1993) and Elton et al. (1995)

6

4. Empirical Methods
We use the holding‐period returns of value‐weighted country portfolios to account for both
maturity mismatch and embedded options. For each country, we compute the holding‐period
return on the value‐weighted portfolio of bonds outstanding. If country i has J bonds
outstanding at time t, the return of country i’s portfolio is

∑

(1)

where
/

is the market‐value weight of bond j in country i at time t;
is the gross holding‐period return of bond j in country I;

bond at time t; and

is the price of the

is the coupon payment (if any) between time t‐1 and time t. The return

and amount outstanding of all of the bonds is directly observable, as is whether a bond is called
and redeemed at par (or any other value).
We focus on holding‐period returns rather than coupon yield because returns account
for maturity mismatch caused by both differences in maturity and embedded options. Many
sovereign bonds contained stochastic maturities due to clauses, such as redemption options
that gave the borrower the right to repay the bond at par between pre‐specified dates; sinking
funds that committed the borrower to redeem annually a fixed portion of the debt outstanding;
or lotteries in which the issuer contracted to redeem a fixed portion of the original issue at par
via annual drawings. If two countries had bonds that matured at different dates, differences in
observed coupon‐yield could be due to observing different points on identical yield curves
(term structures) rather than actual differences in yield curves. If the bond also has a stochastic
maturity date, the measurement error becomes more acute.
The existence of embedded options biases the coupon‐yield measures common in the
good‐housekeeping literature. These options create what Flandreau and Zumer (2004) call
“conversion risk”. Flandreau and Zumer (2004) control for conversion risk by carefully selecting
bonds with coupon rates such that their conversion option that are likely to be far out‐of‐the‐
money. This strategy minimizes the measurement error problem, but, at least with our London

7

sample, comes at the cost of having to exclude many countries that only have bonds where the
option is in or close to in‐the‐money.
Pre‐payment risk is rare in modern‐day sovereign bond markets, but quite common the
markets for mortgage backed securities, real‐estate investment trusts, and corporate bonds.
Studies that examine the returns of these securities face exactly the same problem that we face
in our test of the good‐housekeeping hypothesis: Does an observable trait explain differences in
expected return? The use of holding‐period returns and factor models of the type that inspired
Bordo and Rockoff ‘s specification are commonly used to measure differences in risk adjusted
returns across bond portfolios with different maturities and embedded options.3 Thus, using
holding‐period returns to measure sovereign borrowing costs facilitates the comparison of
bonds with different, possibly stochastic, maturities and takes account of expected capital gains
and losses.

4.1. Leveraged Portfolios
We test the hypothesis that expected returns differ across exchange‐rate regime by forming a
leveraged portfolio that mimics the return associated with purchasing all bonds issued by
countries off gold and selling short all bonds issued by countries on gold.4 At the beginning of
each holding period, all bonds are assigned either to an on‐gold or off‐gold portfolio. If a
country adopts the gold standard, we remove that country’s bonds from the off‐gold portfolio
and add it to the on‐gold portfolio at the beginning of the next holding period, and vice versa. If
the good‐housekeeping hypothesis is true, the leveraged portfolio should earn a positive risk‐
adjusted return.
We use contemporary and modern sources to date each country’s gold‐standard
adherence. A detailed list of the sources is reported in Appendix 2. In cases where it is difficult
to determine de jure versus de facto adherence to the gold standard, we code the country as
3

Bond factor models in the spirit of Fama and French (1993) and Elton et al. (1995) typically include market, term
structure, and default factors similar to our stock market (market), Consol (term structure) and corporate bond
(default) factors. These models are often used to test for differences in the risk‐adjusted return (alpha) of bond
portfolios that have different maturities and embedded options.
4
To be clear, we formulate the test in this way not because we think a 19th century investor formed a leveraged
portfolio of sovereign bonds based on gold‐standard adherence but because doing so allows us to test for a
difference in mean returns across the two exchange‐rate regimes.

8

adhering to gold from the de jure convertibility date. In many cases, we are able to date gold‐
standard adherence quite precisely, identifying the month and sometimes even the day on
which a country adopted or abandoned convertibility. In the cases where we can only identify
the year in which a country adopted the gold standard, we date gold‐standard adherence from
January 1 of that year.
It is important to stress that because of how we date gold‐standard adherence, our
benchmark regressions are biased toward finding evidence in favor of the good‐housekeeping
hypothesis. The London capital market may have anticipated switches in gold‐standard
adherence and repriced bonds in response to the change in expectations. If the good
housekeeping hypothesis is true, the bonds issued by countries off gold that switch to being on
gold experience a capital gain as the market reprices their bonds at a lower discount rate. If the
market anticipates the switch from off to on, the returns of the off gold portfolio are high even
before the date of official convertibility. Similarly, the bonds issued by countries on gold that
switch off experience a capital loss as the market reprices their bonds at a higher discount rate.
Again, if the market anticipates such a switch, the returns of the on‐gold portfolio are low even
before the country official abandons convertibility. Thus, the returns of the off‐gold portfolio
are biased upward because of our dating procedure while the returns of the on‐gold portfolio
are biased downward. The two effects bias the returns of the leveraged portfolio upward. By
sorting bonds into off‐ and on‐gold portfolios and using this dating procedure, we extend the
good‐housekeeping hypothesis every advantage in the empirical test.5

4.2. Empirical Specification
We form a leveraged portfolio by computing the returns of a portfolio that is long in the bonds
issued by countries off gold and short in the bonds issued by countries on gold. If the two
portfolios were equally risky and the market punished bonds issued by countries off gold, this
strategy would have generated positive excess returns.

5

In an early draft, we controlled for anticipation effects by forming perfect‐foresight portfolios. We assigned bonds
to the off‐ and on‐gold portfolios up to two years before the actual change in status occurred. Our conclusion that
gold‐standard adherence did not affect sovereign borrowing costs is robust to this alternative coding scheme.
These results are available upon request.

9

The key words are “equally risky”. Investors during the late 19th century almost surely
demanded compensation for risks beyond those embodied in gold‐standard adherence. If
exposure to other risk factors differed across portfolios, differences in realized return may be
due to exposure to the other risks and not exclusively due to differences in gold‐standard
adherence.
We control for risk with a factor pricing model that compares the return of a test
portfolio to that of a similarly risky portfolio of British financial assets. We estimate the
regression

(2)

,

where
consol;
,

,

is the time t return of portfolio i;

,

,

is the time t return on the UK government

is the return on the value‐weighted portfolio of all British equities at time t; and

,

is the value‐weighted portfolio of UK corporate bonds. We use the London banker’s bill

rate as a proxy for the risk‐free rate

.

is called Jensen’s alpha after Jensen (1967), who proposed using it to measure a
portfolio’s return controlling for risk. Alpha measures the difference between portfolio i’s
return and the return of the portfolio of British securities with percentage weights
in the UK government consol,

invested

invested in the value‐weighted UK stock market portfolio,

invested in the value‐weighted British bond market portfolio and 1

invested in

the London banker’s bill.
We estimate the excess return of the leveraged portfolio with the regression equation:

(3)

where

,

,

,

,

,

,

,

by construction. The betas of the leveraged portfolio in equation (3)

are equal to the difference in the sensitivities of the off‐gold and on‐gold portfolios to
fluctuations in the UK risk factors. A test of the good‐housekeeping hypothesis amounts to the
test that alpha is greater than zero.

10

An advantage of this test is that it addresses the problem that countries did not leave
gold randomly. If a country wanted to remain on gold but was forced off due to a negative
business‐cycle shock, we need to distinguish between excess returns due to exposure to
business‐cycle risk and the repeated game punishment. If business‐cycle shocks are correlated
across countries, UK investors could have legitimately demand higher expected returns as
compensation for bearing greater business‐cycle risk. In this case, the good‐housekeeping
hypothesis could be false but the returns of the bonds issued by countries on gold would be
lower because they were less exposed to British business‐cycle risk. By comparing foreign
returns to this control group of similarly risky UK securities, we disentangle the two effects and
can test if investors demanded a premium due to gold‐standard adherence or business‐cycle
risk.

4.3. Data
These methods necessarily require monthly return data from a large cross‐section of sovereign
bonds. We collect a sample of sovereign and colonial bonds trading on the London Stock
Exchange between 1870 and 1907. Our data set consists of the bid and ask prices and coupon
payments for every foreign government bond regularly quoted on the Exchange. The data
represent a broad cross‐section of bonds issued by countries both on and off gold (Figure 1).
The prices are sampled every 28‐days from the official Friday quotation list published in the
Money Market Review and the Economist.6 We use the price and coupon data to compute a
time series of 28‐day holding‐period returns corrected for sovereign defaults.7 Appendix 1
contains more information about the underlying data.

4.4. Sample of Countries
In addition to the challenges associated with consistently measuring the sovereign cost of
capital during the late 19th century, a possible explanation for the lack of consensus among

6

The holding period is 28‐days because our sources published the London Stock Exchange published official bid
and ask prices every Friday. We sampled them every 4 weeks.
7
We use the Council of Foreign Bondholders, Winkler (1933), Suter (1990), and default data provided by Obstfeld
and Taylor (2003) to date periods of default.

11

previous tests of the good‐housekeeping hypothesis is that each study uses a different sample.
Since our sample of countries spans those considered in previous studies, we can examine the
effect of varying sample countries. We conduct our tests on our full sample of countries as well
as on subsamples corresponding to those used in Bordo and Rockoff (1996), Bordo and
Schwartz (1999), Obstfeld and Taylor (2003), and Flandreau and Zumer (2004). The countries in
these subsamples are listed in Appendix 2.

4.5. Country Weights
It is also important to guard against the possibility that our conclusions are driven by outliers.
Some countries have much larger bond issues than others and any conclusions should be robust
to our weighting scheme. To address this problem, we form both value‐weighted and equally
weighted portfolios. The value‐weighted portfolio weights each bond by its market value. For
example, if the market value of all Argentine bonds is ten times that of Danish bonds, the
returns of Argentine bonds receive ten times the weight of returns of Danish bonds in the
value‐weighted portfolio. Thus, weighting returns by the market value of the debt outstanding
weights large bonds issues more heavily. The equally weighted portfolio examines if large
borrowers drive our conclusions; it consists of individual country portfolios.8 If there are
countries in the sample, the return of each country portfolio receives a weight of 1⁄ . This
weighting scheme minimizes the effect of the returns of bonds issued by large borrowers.

5. Empirical Results
Table 2 reports the individual regression results for the off‐ and on‐gold value‐ and equally
weighted portfolios. It also reports the regression results for the leveraged portfolio in equation
(3) that is long the off‐gold portfolio and short the on‐gold portfolio. The table shows that the
British factor model does well in accounting for the variation in off‐ and on‐gold portfolio
returns. The adjusted R‐squared statistics are respectable for monthly data – between 10‐20%.
When one forms the leveraged portfolio by taking the difference between the off‐ and on‐gold
portfolios, the R‐squared statistics are low, which suggests that the returns from the leveraged
8

Each country portfolio is itself value‐weighted.

12

portfolio are approximately white noise. This finding is what one expects under the null
hypothesis that the gold standard was not a determinant of sovereign borrowing costs. Sorting
bonds into off‐ and on‐gold portfolios should not generate systematically higher returns, after
controlling for the UK market factors.
Unconditionally, the difference between the mean return of off‐gold and on‐gold bonds
was 1.4‐1.6% per year, depending on the weighting scheme. This evidence seems to suggest the
presence of a gold premium: Off‐gold bonds paid higher returns to induce investors to hold
them because they were perceived to be riskier. But projecting the returns on the market
factors shows that the difference in risk‐adjusted returns, measured by the alphas, are
economically small, statistically insignificant, and has the sign opposite to that predicted by the
good‐housekeeping hypothesis.
The betas obtained from the leveraged portfolio indicate that the off‐gold bond
portfolio is more sensitive to fluctuations in the UK government consol index and the British
corporate bond index. This evidence indicates that the higher unconditional mean return of the
off‐gold portfolio compared to the on‐gold portfolio is attributable to the portfolio’s greater
exposure to the risk associated with fluctuations in the UK risk factors. Thus, going long on
bonds issued by countries off gold and shorting bonds issued by countries on gold would have
generated positive returns, but the excess returns represented compensation for bearing more
risk associated with fluctuations in the UK market factors rather failing to adhere to the gold
standard.
To examine the sensitivity of this conclusion to changing the sample, Table 3 reports the
regression results for leveraged off‐gold minus on‐gold portfolios using different subsamples of
countries. Depending on the sample, sovereign off‐gold bonds generated an average return
between 1.6‐2.5% higher per year than the return generated by bonds on gold. Again, the
excess return is primarily attributable to differences in exposure to business‐cycle risk rather
than market punishment for not adhering to gold. Once we control for market risk by
comparing the leveraged portfolios to similarly risky British securities, the excess returns
vanish. The alphas of the leveraged portfolios decrease in size and, in all cases, are not
statistically different from zero. In two out of the five country samples, the sign of the alphas

13

contradict the empirical implication of the good‐housekeeping hypothesis in that the alphas are
negative. In both the full sample and the Obstfeld‐Taylor sample, off‐gold bonds earned smaller
risk‐adjusted returns than on‐gold bonds.
The betas in Panel A are positive, with only one exception. In general, the off‐gold
portfolio is more sensitive to movements in the returns of UK government consol, stock, and
corporate bond indices than the on‐gold portfolios, suggesting that the higher unconditional
returns associated with holding the off‐gold bonds were compensation for bearing risk. UK
investors demanded a premium to bear this additional risk, but it did not reflect punishment for
abandoning gold. That the alphas are close to zero implies that a portfolio of British shares and
bonds with the same exposure to the UK indices would generate statistically identical returns.
Because the UK securities were not being punished for violating the rules of the gold standard,
the average excess return is compensation for bearing business‐cycle risk.
The alphas reported in Table 3 indicate that portfolios selected based on gold‐standard
adherence do not outperform portfolios of UK securities with the same exposure to business‐
cycle risk. However, a test that alpha equals zero is a joint test of the good‐housekeeping
hypothesis and the risk and return model implied by the excess return regression. To be certain
that the small alphas are not due to model misspecification, we compare the alphas of the
leveraged portfolios to the alpha based on selecting bonds randomly.
Expected alpha will equal zero if the British portfolios do a good job of capturing
consumption risk. But if the model is misspecified, the expected alpha of a random portfolio will
be different from zero. Our concern is a misspecified model in which a random portfolio would
have negative alpha. In that case, the portfolio selected using gold‐standard adherence could
have an alpha statistically indistinguishable from zero and yet still significantly outperform
randomly selected portfolios. This finding would cast doubt on the null hypothesis that gold‐
standard adherence does not matter for sovereign borrowing costs.
To address this possibility, we compare the returns generated by the leveraged gold
portfolio to portfolios selected at random. For each subsample in Table 3, we compute excess
return portfolios by randomly assigning the same sample of securities to one of two portfolios.
Bonds are assigned in the same proportion as the proportion of gold‐standard adherence. We

14

compute 1000 random portfolios and report the proportion of times the portfolio selected
using the gold standard criterion earns a higher excess return than a portfolio selected at
random.
For example, in the value‐weighted Bordo‐Rockoff sample of sovereign bonds, 56% of
the observed returns were returns of bonds on the gold‐standard. We compute an excess
return portfolio from the same sample of countries by randomly buying 44% of the bonds each
period and shorting the other 56%. We then calculate the random portfolio’s alpha and
compare it to the alpha of the gold‐sorted portfolio. We repeat the random selection 1000
times. The result is 1000 sample alphas corresponding to the risk‐adjusted return of 1000
randomly selected portfolios. By comparing the number of times that the leveraged portfolio
generated positive excess returns with the number of times that a randomly selected portfolio
generated positive excess return, we are able to see whether sorting bonds by gold‐standard
adherence results in higher returns than one would expect from sorting bonds into portfolios
randomly.
Table 3 reports the proportion of times the leveraged gold‐sorted portfolios beat
portfolios formed at random, or what we call the “success rate”. The results are consistent with
the conclusion that gold‐standard adherence did not matter for the excess returns of sovereign
bonds. In the full sample, sorting sovereign bonds into value‐weighted portfolios based on gold
would have earned greater excess returns than sorting bonds randomly only 24.1% of the time.
Although the success rate exceeds 50% for the Bordo‐Rockoff and Flandreau‐Zumer samples, it
is less than 50% for the Obtsfeld‐Taylor sample. The Obstfeld‐Taylor sample contains more
countries than the Bordo‐Rockoff and Flandreau‐Zumer samples but fewer than are contained
in the full sample, indicating that some of the disagreement about the effect of gold on
borrowing costs may be attributable to the set of countries being studied. Overall, portfolios
selected by gold‐standard adherence do no better than portfolios selected at random.
Taken together, these pieces of evidence all point in the same direction. Differences in
bond returns represented compensation for exposure to British risk factors and did not reflect a
gold premium.

15

5.1. Robustness Check: Gold‐Standard Adherence and Betas
Differences between the returns of bonds issued by countries on gold and those issued by
countries off gold appear to be explained by differences in their betas. The finding that the
betas differ with gold‐standard adherence is not new. For example, Bordo and Rockoff (1996)
and Obstfeld and Taylor (2003) both observe that the countries’ market betas appear to vary
with gold‐standard adherence. Neither set of authors formally tests for differences in the betas
by allowing them to vary with gold‐standard adherence, but both point out that countries on
gold tend to have smaller betas than those off gold over their respective samples.9 Thus, it is
possible that gold‐standard adherence and the betas are correlated with one another. In that
case, adhering to gold could reduce the cost of capital by reducing the beta of a country’s
bonds. The international capital market may have viewed bonds issued by countries on gold as
less sensitive to business‐cycle risk than those issued by countries off gold, so that a country
could lower its cost of capital by adhering to gold.
To examine this possibility, we estimate the equation for the subset of our individual
bonds that change their gold status:

(4)
,

,

,

,

,

,

where all of the variables are defined as before; and

is an interaction dummy variable

equal to 1 if the issuing country is on gold at time t. The regression produces three interaction
coefficients equal to the difference between the beta on gold and the beta off gold.
To ensure that differences in the three betas are identified, we need a set of countries
whose bonds trade while the issuing country is both on and off gold. Our data set contains 86
such bonds. We estimate 86 separate time series regressions which result in 258 (

3

86)

interaction coefficients. Figure 2 shows the histogram of the t‐statistics from the interaction
9

In addition, Ferguson and Schularick (2006) find that differences in mean coupon yields between Empire and non‐
Empire bonds disappear when they control for market risk and that the betas of Empire bonds are smaller than the
betas of non‐Empire bonds.

16

coefficients. The distribution of interaction coefficients is symmetric and centered on zero. 15
of the 258 (5.8%) are statistically different from zero at the 5% significance level and 22 (8.5%)
at the 10% significance level. Using the Simes (1986) modified Bonferroni test, we cannot reject
the joint null hypothesis that all interaction coefficient are jointly equal to zero. While the
difference in returns between the off‐ and on‐gold portfolios can be explained by differences in
the betas, the differences in betas do not appear to be attributable to gold‐standard
adherence. The result is what one would expect if gold‐standard adherence had no effect on
the cost of capital.

5.2. Sensitivity Analysis
5.2.1. Fiscal, Monetary, and Trade Controls
Gold‐standard adherence may act as a proxy for following prudent fiscal and monetary policies,
as proposed by Flandreau and Zumer (2004). It is therefore important to test if gold reduces
sovereign borrowing costs, conditional on covariates that capture the risks associated with
weak fiscal and monetary policies. In addition, other studies of the good‐housekeeping
hypothesis have included macroeconomic controls like the lagged inflation rate and the deficit‐
GDP ratio to detect deviations from the commitment to gold (Bordo and Rockoff 1996; and
Obstfeld and Taylor 2003). Including covariates to capture these risks in the factor model also
facilitates comparison with these other studies.
We control for fiscal, monetary, and trade shocks by forming factor‐mimicking portfolios
using data on the deficit‐GDP ratio, annual inflation, and the export‐GDP ratio that are available
for 22 countries.10 Columns 1‐3 in Table 4 show that including the factor‐mimicking portfolios
has no effect on the conclusions. The off‐gold minus on‐gold portfolio alpha remains
indistinguishable from zero.
10

Fama and French (1995) and Daniel and Titman (1997) use an identical procedure to evaluate the effect of size
and value characteristics on equity returns. We form the factor‐mimicking portfolios in the following way. First, at
the beginning of each year we sort countries into three mutually exclusive categories (high, medium, and low)
based on the value of each characteristic. The high category contains the top one‐third of countries while the low
category contains the bottom one‐third of countries. Second, we use the bonds issued by countries in the high and
low categories to form value‐weighted portfolios. Third, we compute a factor‐mimicking portfolio by forming a
leveraged high minus low (HML) portfolios for each of the three macroeconomic variables. For example, the deficit
HML portfolio is the portfolio formed by buying sovereign bonds in the top one‐third of the deficit‐GDP category
and selling short the sovereign bonds in the bottom one‐third of the deficit‐GDP category.

17

5.2.2. Controlling for the Empire Effect
Accominotti et al. (2010) demonstrate that dummy variables regression tests of the effect of
membership in the British Empire on borrowing costs are potentially misspecified. They show
that pooling bonds issued by British colonies with bonds issued by independent countries can
lead to biased parameter estimates and misleading inferences in yield‐spread regressions. To
ensure that our conclusions about the effect of gold standard adherence on sovereign
borrowing costs are robust, we exclude the British colonies from the portfolio sorts and re‐run
our test on the subset of bonds that were issued by independent countries.
Columns 4‐6 in Table 4 report the alphas and betas obtained from forming off‐ and on‐
gold portfolios for the set of independent countries in our sample (i.e., bonds not issued by
British colonies). The unconditional difference between on‐gold and off‐gold bond returns
shrinks when we exclude colonial bonds and the risk‐adjusted returns of the off‐gold minus on‐
gold portfolio decreases. Importantly, the main result that gold‐standard adherence is
uncorrelated with risk‐adjusted return is unaffected when the colonial bonds are omitted.

6. Conclusion
Using a comprehensive new data set, we find no evidence in favor of the good‐housekeeping
hypothesis. Although the bonds issued by countries off of gold did earn higher unconditional
returns than the bonds of countries on gold, this difference vanishes once we control for
exposure to common risk factors. This evidence rejects the good housekeeping hypothesis and
is consistent with Flandreau and Zumer’s (2004) finding that the effect of gold standard
adherence on borrowing costs vanishes with the inclusion of other explanatory variables that
capture default risk.
This conclusion is robust. We find no evidence of a gold‐standard effect in any of the sub
samples of countries included in previous studies. The results are not sensitive to adding fiscal,
monetary, and trade controls to account for macroeconomic shocks that can affect the
commitment to gold. Finally, omitting the British colonies from the benchmark specification
does alter our conclusions.

18

These results shed light on the perceived benefits of the classical gold standard in
particular and fixed exchange‐rate regimes more generally. A widely cited benefit of the gold
standard – arguably the most credible fixed exchange‐rate regime in modern history – is that it
reduced borrowing costs. Whatever other benefits a credibly fixed exchange‐rate regime
confers on its adherents, the international capital market did not reward gold‐standard
adherence with a lower cost of capital.

19

References
Accominotti, Olivier, Marc Flandreau, and Riad Rezzik. “The Spread of Empire: Clio and the
Measurement of Colonial Borrowing Costs.” Economic History Review forthcoming.
Bohn, Henning. “Time Consistency of Monetary Policy in the Open Economy.” Journal of
International Economics 30, no. 3‐4 (1991): 249‐266.
Bordo, Michael D., and Anna J. Schwartz. “The Operation of the Specie Standard: Evidence for
Core and Peripheral Countries: 1880‐1990.” In The Gold Standard and Related Regimes:
Collected Essays, edited by Michael D. Bordo, 238‐317. New York: Cambridge University Press,
1999.
Bordo, Michael D., and Finn Kydland. “The Gold Standard as a Rule.” Explorations in Economic
History 32, no. 4 (1995): 423‐464.
Bordo, Michael D., and Hugh Rockoff. “The Gold Standard as a Good‐housekeeping Seal of
Approval.” Journal of Economic History 56, no. 2 (1996): 389‐428.
Clemens, Michael A. and Jeffrey G. Williamson. “Wealth Bias in the First Global Capital Market
Boom, 1870‐1913.” Economic Journal 114, no. 495 (2004): 304‐337.
Campbell, John. “Some Lessons from the Yield Curve.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 9, no. 3
(1995): 129‐152.
Cornell, Bradford and Kevin Green. “The Investment Performance of Low‐Grade Bond Funds”
Journal of Finance, (1991) 46, 29–48
Daniel, Kent and Sheridan Titman. “Evidence on the Characteristics of Cross‐Sectional Variation
in Common Stock Returns”, Journal of Finance (1997) 52, 1—33
Elton, Edwin J., Martin J. Gruber, Christopher R. Blake. “Fundamental Economic Variables,
Expected Returns, and Bond Fund Performance.” Journal of Finance 50 (1995): 1229‐1256.
Fama, Eugene F. and Kenneth R. French. “Common Risk Factors in the Returns on Stocks and
Bonds.” Journal of Financial Economics 33 (1993): 3‐56.
Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French. “Size and Book‐to‐Market Factors in Earnings and
Returns.” Journal of Financial Economics 50, no. 1 (1995): 131‐155.
20

Ferguson, Niall, and Moritz Schularick. “The Empire Effect: The Determinants of Country Risk in
the First Age of Globalization, 1880‐1913.” Journal of Economic History 66, no. 2 (2006): 283‐
312.
Flandreau, Marc, and Frederic Zumer. The Making of Global Finance, 1880‐1913.
Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, 2004.
Jensen, Michael C. “The Performance of Mutual Funds in the Period 1945‐1964.” Journal of
Finance 23, no. 2 (1967), 389‐416.
Martin‐Acena, Pablo. “Spain During the Classical Gold Standard Years, 1880‐1914.” In Monetary
Regimes in Transition, edited by Michael D. Bordo and Forrest Capie, 135‐172. New York:
Cambridge University Press, 1993.
Mauro, Paolo, and Yishay Yafeh. “The Corporation of Foreign Bondholders.” IMF Working Paper
No. 03/107, Washington, D.C., May 2003.
Mitchener, Kris, and Marc D. Weidenmier. "Are Hard Pegs Ever Credible in Emerging Markets?
Evidence from the Classical Gold Standard," NBER Working Papers 15401, National Bureau of
Economic Research.
Obstfeld, Maurice, and Alan M. Taylor. “Sovereign Risk, Credibility, and the Gold Standard:
1870‐1913 versus 1925‐31.” Economic Journal 113, no. 487 (2003): 241‐275.
Simes, S. John. “An Improved Bonferroni Procedure for Multiple Tests of Significance.”
Biometrika 73, no. 3 (1986): 751‐754.
Sussman, Nathan, and Yishay Yafeh. “Institutions, Reforms, and Country Risk:
Lessons from Japanese Government Debt in the Meiji Period.” Journal of Economic History 60,
no. 2 (2000): 442‐467.
Suter, Christian. Schuldenzyklen in der dritten Welt: Kreditaufnahme, Zahlungskrisen und
Schuldenregelungen peripherer Länder im Weltsystem von 1820 bis 1986. Frankfurt, a. M.:
Anton Hain, 1990.
Winkler, Max. Foreign Bonds: An Autopsy. New York: Roland Swain Company, 1933.

21

Not es: Countries a re coded by year, even if we know t he mont h t he count ry a dopted t he gold st a nda rd. For e xa mple, Austria -Hungary ad opte d gold on August 2, 1892, but we code it
as a dhering from Ja nua ry 1, 1892 for t his t a ble. In cases where a count ry a dhe red t o t he gold st a nda rd for less t ha n a year, we cod e it as ad hering to gold for t he e nt ire year in t he
ta ble. For exa mple, Greece a dhered t o gold from Ja nua ry 1885-Sept ember 1885. We code it as a dhering t o gold for a ll of 1885.

22

Figure 2. Interaction Coefficient t‐statistics
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
< ‐2

‐2

‐1.5

‐1

‐0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

>2

Notes: The histogram reports the robust t‐statistics associated with the 258 interaction terms that result from
estimating equation (4) in the text for each of the 86 bonds that were traded when the issuing country was both
on and off the gold standard.

23

Table 1. Selected Tests of the Good‐Housekeeping Hypothesis

Authors

Baseline Regression Specification

Lagged money growth
Lagged deficit‐GNP ratio

=

Bordo ‐Rockoff

Obstfeld ‐Taylor

Controls in

Lagged inflation
Lagged debt‐output level
Export‐GDP ratio
Real income per capita
Terms of trade
British Empire dummy
War dummies

=

=

Flandreau‐Zumer

Notes:
, . In Bordo and Rockoff,
yields in their sample. In Obstfeld and Taylor,
,
in their sample.

24

Interest service‐revenue ratio
Reserves‐bank notes ratio
Exports per capita
Deficit‐revenue ratio
Exchange‐rate volatility
Default
Memory of default
Enfranchised population
Political crisis dummies

+

,
,

,
,

, where

,

, , where
, is the average of all coupon
is the GDP‐weighted average of all coupon yields

Table 2. Excess Return Regressions: Off and On‐Gold Portfolios
Value‐Weighted

Mean Excess Return

Equally Weighted

Off Gold

On Gold

Off On

Off Gold

On Gold

Off On

4.24

2.71

1.53

4.33

2.90

1.43

‐0.11

0.49

‐0.59

‐0.90

0.91*

‐1.80

(‐0.08)

(0.72)

(‐0.44)

(‐0.51)

(1.92)

(‐1.09)

0.359***

0.132***

0.227**

0.321***

0.153***

0.168

(3.97)

(2.78)

(2.40)

(2.60)

(4.63)

(1.45)

0.407***

0.305***

0.101

0.730***

0.245***

0.485***

(5.00)

(7.18)

(1.19)

(6.57)

(8.26)

(4.66)

0.365***

0.100*

0.265***

0.212

0.101***

0.111

(3.73)

(1.96)

(2.58)

(1.58)

(2.83)

(0.88)

0.208

0.126

0.062

0.179

0.180

0.087

Notes: The regressions are equations (2) and (3). The mean excess return and estimated alpha are expressed in annualized
percentage points. Robust t‐statistics are in parentheses. *** (**) (*) indicates significance at the 1% (5%) (10%) level.

25

Table 3. Excess 28‐day Return Regressions: Off‐Gold Portfolio – On Gold Portfolio
Panel A: Value‐Weighted
Full
Mean Excess Return


Success Rate

Bordo‐Rockoff Bordo‐Schwartz Obstfeld‐Taylor Flandreau‐Zumer

1.53

2.33

1.58

2.26

2.52

‐0.59

0.48

0.08

‐0.37

0.70

(‐0.44)

(0.34)

(0.07)

(‐0.23)

(0.49)

0.227**

0.141

0.052

0.217**

0.314***

(2.40)

(1.45)

(0.60)

(1.99)

(3.18)

0.101

‐0.000

0.167**

0.134

‐0.013

(1.19)

(‐0.01)

(2.17)

(1.37)

(0.15)

0.265***

0.387***

0.145

0.365***

0.272**

(2.58)

(3.69)

(1.56)

(3.09)

(2.54)

0.062

0.045

0.027

0.069

0.047

24.1%

68.9%

48.4%

39.1%

78.7%

Panel B: Equally Weighted
Full
Mean Excess Return


Success Rate

Bordo‐Rockoff Bordo‐Schwartz Obstfeld‐Taylor Flandreau‐Zumer

1.43

2.39

2.29

2.22

2.36

‐1.80

0.91

0.95

‐0.39

0.39

(‐1.09)

(0.75)

(0.82)

(‐0.28)

(0.32)

0.168

0.082

0.011

0.094

0.187**

(1.45)

(0.97)

(0.14)

(0.97)

(2.19)

0.485***

0.076

0.167**

0.304***

0.154**

(4.66)

(1.01)

(2.29)

(3.50)

(2.01)

0.111

0.232**

0.130

0.231**

0.188**

(0.88)

(2.54)

(1.48)

(2.21)

(2.04)

0.087

0.030

0.028

0.078

0.053

8.0%

78.1%

84.2%

36.2%

64.3%

Notes: The regressions are equations (2) and (3). The mean excess return and estimated alpha are expressed in
annualized percentage points. Robust t‐statistics are in parentheses. *** (**) (*) indicates significance at the 1%
(5%) (10%) level.

26

Table 4. Excess Return Regressions: Macroeconomic Risk Factors and Independent Countries

Full Sample

Mean Excess Return


Ind. Countries

Off Gold

On Gold

Off On

Off Gold

On Gold

Off On

4.27

2.59

1.68

4.24

3.21

1.02

0.03

0.24

‐0.21

‐0.11

0.81

‐0.92

(0.02)

(0.36)

(‐0.16)

(‐0.08)

(1.01)

(‐0.65)

0.345***

0.157***

0.188**

0.359***

0.117**

0.242**

(3.86)

(3.40)

(2.00)

(3.97)

(2.07)

(2.46)

0.366***

0.185***

0.181**

0.407***

0.353***

0.054

(4.48)

(4.39)

(2.10)

(5.01)

(6.98)

(0.611)

0.381***

0.143***

0.238**

0.365***

0.097

0.268**

(3.97)

(2.89)

(‐2.35)

(3.73)

(1.59)

(2.52)

‐0.061

0.089***

‐0.150**

(‐1.03)

(2.94)

(‐2.41)

‐0.124***

‐0.053**

‐0.071

(‐2.88)

(‐2.38)

(‐1.57)

‐0.172***

‐0.189***

0.017

(‐3.75)

(‐8.01)

(0.36)

0.237

0.252

0.091

0.208

0.112

0.052

Notes: The regressions are equations (2) and (3). The portfolios are value‐weighted. The mean excess return and
estimated alpha are expressed in annualized percentage points. The “Ind. Countries” sample includes all
independent countries in our sample and excludes the British colonies. “Def‐GDP”, “Inf”, and “Exp‐GDP” refer to
the coefficients associated with the factor‐mimicking portfolios described in the text. Robust t‐statistics are in
parentheses. *** (**) (*) indicates significance at the 1% (5%) (10%) level.

27

Appendix 1: Sample of Countries
The data set includes 213 sovereign bonds issued by 37 non‐colonial countries and 110 colonial
bonds issued by 12 British colonies and possessions. The prices are sampled every 28 days from
the official quotation list published in the Money Market Review and the Economist from 1866
until 1907, when the publisher ceased providing such detailed price quotations. We use the
price, dividend, and coupon data to compute a time series of realized holding‐period returns
corrected for dividends, stock splits, and sovereign defaults. To date sovereign defaults, we rely
on the annual reports issued by the Council of Foreign Bondholders, Winkler (1933), and Suter
(1990). In the regressions, the time series span the period from January 1870 until December
1907 due to data constraints.

Sovereign Bond Data
The countries included in our dataset are: Argentina; Australia; Austria‐Hungary; Belgium;
Brazil; British Guiana; Bulgaria; Canada; Ceylon; Chile; China; Colombia; Costa Rica; Denmark;
Ecuador; Egypt; France; Germany; Greece; Guatemala; Hawaii; Honduras; Hong Kong; Italy;
Jamaica; Japan; Liberia; Mauritius; Mexico; Netherlands; New Zealand; Nicaragua; Norway;
Orange Free State; Paraguay; Peru; Portugal; Russia; Saint Lucia; Santo Domingo; South Africa;
Spain; Straits Settlements; Sweden; Trinidad; Turkey; United States; Uruguay; and Venezuela.

The British colonies and possessions are a subset of the countries in the full sample. They are:
Australia; British Guiana; Canada; Ceylon; Hong Kong; Jamaica; Mauritius; New Zealand; Saint
Lucia; South Africa; Straits Settlements; and Trinidad.

Subsamples
We formed subsamples of countries based upon previous work on the gold standard. We are
able to mimic closely each of the samples of countries listed below.

Bordo and Rockoff (1996) : Argentina; Australia; Brazil; Canada; Chile; Italy; Portugal; Spain; and
United States.

28

Bordo and Schwartz (1999) : Argentina; Australia; Belgium; Brazil; Canada; Chile; Denmark;
Finland; Greece; Italy; Japan; Netherlands; Norway; Portugal; Sweden; and Switzerland. The
four core countries are France, Germany, the UK, and the United States. We exclude Finland
and Switzerland due to lack of data.

Obstfeld and Taylor (2003) : Argentina; Australia; Austria‐Hungary; Brazil; Canada; Chile; Egypt;
Greece; India; Italy; Japan; Mexico; New Zealand; Norway; Portugal; South Africa; Spain;
Sweden; Turkey; the United States; and Uruguay.

Flandreau and Zumer (2004): Argentina; Austria‐Hungary; Belgium; Brazil; Denmark; France;
Germany; Greece; Italy; Netherlands; Norway; Portugal; Spain; Sweden; Switzerland; and
Russia. We exclude Switzerland due to lack of data.

We adopt the definition of cheater from Bordo and Schwartz’s Table 1 (Bordo and Schwartz
1999). We code a country as a cheater if it suspended gold convertibility because of war, lax
fiscal policy, a financial crisis, failed convertibility, or some combination of the four. The
countries that fall into this category are Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Greece, Italy, and Portugal.

29

Appendix 2: Gold‐standard adherence
Argentina: January 3, 1867‐May 1876: Leaving gold in May 1876 did not result in a change in
parity. July 1883‐December 1884: Leaving gold in December 1884 did not result in a change of
parity. October 31, 1899: Law establishing external convertibility. Source: della Paolera and
Taylor (2001), pp. 25, 41, 47.
Australia: Adopted the free convertibility of currency into gold before 1870. Source: Meissner
(2005).
Austria‐Hungary: August 2, 1892. Source: Helfferich (1927), pp. 200.
Belgium: November 5, 1878. Source: Helfferich (1927), pp. 180.
Brazil: October 1888‐October 1890. Leaving gold in October 1890 did not result in a change of
parity. December 31, 1906: Conversion Office opened. Sources: Martin‐Acena (2000), pp 155;
and Subercaseaux (1931).
British Guiana: Adopted the free convertibility of currency into gold before 1870. Source:
Officer (2001).
Bulgaria: Did not adopt the free convertibility of currency into gold before 1914. Source:
Meissner (2005).
Canada: Adopted the free convertibility of currency into gold before 1870. Newfoundland did
not adopt the free convertibility of currency into gold until 1895, according to Officer (2001).
We date the bonds from Newfoundland from January 1, 1895. Sources: Meissner (2005).
Ceylon: 1898. We date Ceylon as adhering to the gold standard from January 1, 1898. Source:
Officer (2001).
Chile: Law passed February 11, 1895 providing for conversion from June 1, 1895. Suspended
convertibility July 31, 1898. This event resulted in a change of parity. Source: Kemmerer (1926).
China: Did not adopt the free convertibility of currency into gold before 1914. Source:
Bloomfield (1959).
Colombia: From 1903, Colombia has fixed gold parities, but it did not adopt a complete gold
standard until 1923, when the first Kemmerer Mission intervened. We code Colombia as not
30

adopting the free convertibility of currency into gold before 1914. Source: Martin‐Acena (2000),
pp. 237.
Costa Rica: Law passed in October 1896, but currency was not convertible into gold until July
15, 1900. We date it from November 1896. Source: Young (1925), pp. 193‐96.
Denmark: Agreement reached December 18, 1872. Formed monetary union with Sweden in
May 1873. We date it from June 1873. Sources: Helfferich (1927), pp. 175; and Jonung (1984),
pp. 367.
Ecuador: 1900. We date Ecuador as adhering to the gold standard from January 1, 1900.
Source: Meissner (2005).
Egypt: 1885. We date Egypt as adhering to the gold standard from January 1, 1885. Source:
Officer (2001).
France: November 5, 1878. Source: Helfferich (1927), pp. 180.
Germany: December 4, 1871. Source: Helfferich (1927), pp. 156‐7.
Greece: January 1885‐September 1885. This event did not result in a change of parity. Greece
did not join the gold standard again until March 1910. Sources: Bordo and Schwartz (1999), pp.
251; and Lazaretou (2005).
Guatemala: Did not adopt the free convertibility of currency into gold before 1914. Source:
Bulmer‐Thomas (2003), pp 112.
Hawaii: Adopted the Gold Law of 1884, which made the gold coins of the United States legal
tender. We date Hawaii as adhering to the gold standard from January 1, 1884. Source: Tate
(1965), pp. 69.
Honduras: Did not adopt the free convertibility of currency into gold before 1914. Source:
Bulmer‐Thomas (2003), pp 112.
Hong Kong: Did not adopt the free convertibility of currency into gold before 1914. Source: Tom
(1989).

31

Italy: Law establishing convertibility April 12, 1884 passed March 1, 1883. Affidavit introduced
on second semester coupon payments in July 1893. Required Italians to swear rendita coupon
payments received abroad did not belong to Italian citizens. Introduced incentives for lenders
to redeem in Milan. This event resulted in a change in parity. Sources: Helfferich (1927), pp.
175; and Fratianni and Spinelli (1984), pp. 415.
Jamaica: Adopted the free convertibility of currency into gold before 1870. Source: Officer
(2001).
Japan: Law passed March 29, 1897 providing for conversion between October 1, 1897‐July 31,
1898. Sources: Helfferich (1927), pp. 201; and Laughlin (1900).
Liberia: Pegged to US dollar at the exchange rate L$1 = US$1. We code it the same as the US.
Source: http://users.erols.com/kurrency/africa.htm
Mauritius: 1898. We date Mauritius as adhering to the gold standard from January 1, 1898.
Source: Officer (2001).
Mexico: Law passed December 9, 1904. Decree enforced March 25, 1905. Source: Helfferich
(1927), pp. 204.
Netherlands: June 6, 1875. Source: Helfferich (1927), pp. 176.
New Zealand: Adopted the free convertibility of currency into gold before 1870. Source: Officer
(2001).
Nicaragua: Did not adopt the free convertibility of currency into gold before 1914. Sources:
Bulmer‐Thomas (2003), pp 115; and Young (1925), pp. 119‐30; Appendix E.
Norway: Agreement reached December 18, 1872. Norway formed a monetary union with
Denmark and Sweden in October 1875. Sources: Helfferich (1927), pp. 175; and Jonung (1984),
pp. 367.
Orange Free State: 1870‐December 14, 1899. December 15, 1899‐March 14, 1900: Gold
standard suspended. March 15, 1900‐1910: Gold standard re‐established. Source:
http://users.erols.com/kurrency/africa.htm

32

Paraguay: Did not adopt the free convertibility of currency into gold before 1914. Source:
Bulmer‐Thomas (2003), pp 114.
Peru: Did not adopt the free convertibility of currency into gold before 1914. Source: Meissner
(2005).
Portugal: 1854‐May 1891. This event resulted in a change in parity. Source: Reis (2000), pp 94.
Russia: February 1897. Source: Anonymous (1897).
St. Lucia: Adopted the free convertibility of currency into gold before 1870. Source: Officer
(2001).
Santo Domingo: Did not adopt the free convertibility of currency into gold before 1914.
Sources: Laughlin (1894); and Meissner (2005).
South Africa: Adopted the free convertibility of currency into gold before 1870. Source: Officer
(2001).
Spain: Suspended summer 1883 because of decline in foreign investment after January 1882
stock market crash. The precise date is vague, and we date it from the end of June 1883.
Source: Martin‐Acena (2000), pp 128.
Straits Settlements: 1903. We date the Straits Settlements as adhering to the gold standard
from January 1, 1903. Source: Meissner (2005).
Sweden: Agreement reached December 18, 1872. Formed monetary union with Denmark in
May 1873. Sources: Helfferich (1927), pp. 175; and Jonung (1984), pp. 367.
Trinidad: Adopted the free convertibility of currency into gold before 1870. Source: Officer
(2001).
Turkey: 1881. We date Turkey as adhering to the gold standard from January 1, 1881 Sources:
Pamuk (2000), pp. 218.
United States: January 1, 1879. Source: Officer (2001).

33

Uruguay: 1885. We date Uruguay as adhering to the gold standard from January 1, 1885.
Source: Meissner (2005).
Venezuela: Did not adopt the free convertibility of currency into gold before 1914. Source:
Meissner (2005).

34

Appendix References
Anonymous. “Specie Resumption in Russia.” Journal of Political Economy 5, no. 2 (1897): 241‐
244.
Bloomfield, Arthur. Monetary Policy Under the Gold Standard. New York: Federal Reserve Bank
of New York, 1959.
Bordo, Michael D., and Anna J. Schwartz. “The Operation of the Specie Standard: Evidence for
Core and Peripheral Countries: 1880‐1990.” In The Gold Standard and Related Regimes:
Collected Essays, edited by Michael D. Bordo, 238‐317. New York: Cambridge University Press,
1999.
Bulmer‐Thomas, Victor. The Economic History of Latin America since Independence. New York:
Cambridge University Press, 2003.
Della Paolera, Gerardo, and Alan Taylor. Straining at the Anchor: The Argentine Currency Board
and the Search for Macroeconomic Stability: 1880‐1935. Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
2001.
Fratianni, Michele, and Franco Spinelli. “Italy in the Gold Standard Period, 1861‐1914.” In A
Retrospective on the Classical Gold Standard: 1821‐1931, edited by Michael D. Bordo and Anna
J. Schwartz, 405‐454. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1984.
Helfferich, Karl. Money, 2 vols. Translated by Louis Infield. New York: Adelphi Company
Publishers, 1927.
Jonung, Lars. “Swedish Experience under the Classical Gold Standard: 1873‐1914.” In A
Retrospective on the Classical Gold Standard: 1821‐1931, edited by Michael D. Bordo and Anna
J. Schwartz, 361‐399. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1984.
Kemmerer, Edwin Walter. “Chile Returns to Gold Standard.” Journal of Political Economy 34, no.
3 (1926): 265‐273.
Laughlin, J. Laurence. “Gold and Silver in Santo Domingo.” Journal of Political Economy 2, no. 4
(1894): 536‐560.
__________ “Report on the Adoption of the Gold Standard in Japan.” Journal of Political
Economy 8, no. 3 (1900): 424‐427.
35

Lazaretou, Sophia. “The Drachma, Foreign Creditors, and the International Monetary System:
Tales of a Currency during the 19th and 20th Centuries.” Explorations in Economic History 42, no.
2 (2005): 202‐236.
Martin‐Acena, Pablo. “The Spanish Monetary Experience: 1848‐1914.” In Monetary Standards
in the Periphery, edited by Pablo Martin Acena and Jaime Reis, 112‐151. New York: St. Martin’s
Press, 2000.
Meissner, Chris. “A New World Order: Explaining the International Diffusion of the Gold
Standard, 1870‐1913.” Journal of International Economics 66, no. 2 (2005): 385‐406.
Officer, Lawrence. “Gold Standard.” EH.Net Encyclopedia, edited by Robert Whaples. October 1,
2001. URL http://eh.net/encyclopedia/article/officer.gold.standard
Pamuk, Sevket. A Monetary History of the Ottoman Empire. New York: Cambridge University
Press, 2000.
Reis, Jamie. “The Gold Standard in Portugal: 1854‐1891.” In Monetary Standards in the
Periphery, edited by Pablo Martin‐Acena and Jaime Reis, 69‐111. New York: St. Martin’s Press,
2000.
Subercaseaux, Guillermo. “The Modern Gold Standard with Illustrations from South America.”
American Economic Review 21, no. 2 (1931): 249‐259.
Suter, Christian. Schuldenzyklen in der dritten Welt: Kreditaufnahme, Zahlungskrisen und
Schuldenregelungen peripherer Länder im Weltsystem von 1820 bis 1986. Frankfurt, a. M.:
Anton Hain, 1990.
Tate, Merze. The United States and the Hawaiian Kingdom. New Haven and London: Yale
University Press, 1965.
Tom, C. F. Joseph. Monetary Problems of an Entrepot: The Hong Kong Experience. New York:
Peter Lang Publishing, 1989.
Winkler, Max. Foreign Bonds: An Autopsy. New York: Roland Swain Company, 1933.

36

Young, John Parke. Central American Currency and Finance. Princeton: Princeton University
Press, 1925.

37

Working Paper Series
A series of research studies on regional economic issues relating to the Seventh Federal
Reserve District, and on financial and economic topics.
Risk Taking and the Quality of Informal Insurance: Gambling and Remittances in Thailand
Douglas L. Miller and Anna L. Paulson

WP-07-01

Fast Micro and Slow Macro: Can Aggregation Explain the Persistence of Inflation?
Filippo Altissimo, Benoît Mojon, and Paolo Zaffaroni

WP-07-02

Assessing a Decade of Interstate Bank Branching
Christian Johnson and Tara Rice

WP-07-03

Debit Card and Cash Usage: A Cross-Country Analysis
Gene Amromin and Sujit Chakravorti

WP-07-04

The Age of Reason: Financial Decisions Over the Lifecycle
Sumit Agarwal, John C. Driscoll, Xavier Gabaix, and David Laibson

WP-07-05

Information Acquisition in Financial Markets: a Correction
Gadi Barlevy and Pietro Veronesi

WP-07-06

Monetary Policy, Output Composition and the Great Moderation
Benoît Mojon

WP-07-07

Estate Taxation, Entrepreneurship, and Wealth
Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-07-08

Conflict of Interest and Certification in the U.S. IPO Market
Luca Benzoni and Carola Schenone

WP-07-09

The Reaction of Consumer Spending and Debt to Tax Rebates –
Evidence from Consumer Credit Data
Sumit Agarwal, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles

WP-07-10

Portfolio Choice over the Life-Cycle when the Stock and Labor Markets are Cointegrated
Luca Benzoni, Pierre Collin-Dufresne, and Robert S. Goldstein

WP-07-11

Nonparametric Analysis of Intergenerational Income Mobility
with Application to the United States
Debopam Bhattacharya and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-07-12

How the Credit Channel Works: Differentiating the Bank Lending Channel
and the Balance Sheet Channel
Lamont K. Black and Richard J. Rosen

WP-07-13

Labor Market Transitions and Self-Employment
Ellen R. Rissman

WP-07-14

First-Time Home Buyers and Residential Investment Volatility
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Martin Gervais

WP-07-15

1

Working Paper Series (continued)
Establishments Dynamics and Matching Frictions in Classical Competitive Equilibrium
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-07-16

Technology’s Edge: The Educational Benefits of Computer-Aided Instruction
Lisa Barrow, Lisa Markman, and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP-07-17

The Widow’s Offering: Inheritance, Family Structure, and the Charitable Gifts of Women
Leslie McGranahan

WP-07-18

Incomplete Information and the Timing to Adjust Labor: Evidence from the
Lead-Lag Relationship between Temporary Help Employment and Permanent Employment
Sainan Jin, Yukako Ono, and Qinghua Zhang

WP-07-19

A Conversation with 590 Nascent Entrepreneurs
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-07-20

Cyclical Dumping and US Antidumping Protection: 1980-2001
Meredith A. Crowley

WP-07-21

Health Capital and the Prenatal Environment:
The Effect of Maternal Fasting During Pregnancy
Douglas Almond and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-07-22

The Spending and Debt Response to Minimum Wage Hikes
Daniel Aaronson, Sumit Agarwal, and Eric French

WP-07-23

The Impact of Mexican Immigrants on U.S. Wage Structure
Maude Toussaint-Comeau

WP-07-24

A Leverage-based Model of Speculative Bubbles
Gadi Barlevy

WP-08-01

Displacement, Asymmetric Information and Heterogeneous Human Capital
Luojia Hu and Christopher Taber

WP-08-02

BankCaR (Bank Capital-at-Risk): A credit risk model for US commercial bank charge-offs
Jon Frye and Eduard Pelz

WP-08-03

Bank Lending, Financing Constraints and SME Investment
Santiago Carbó-Valverde, Francisco Rodríguez-Fernández, and Gregory F. Udell

WP-08-04

Global Inflation
Matteo Ciccarelli and Benoît Mojon

WP-08-05

Scale and the Origins of Structural Change
Francisco J. Buera and Joseph P. Kaboski

WP-08-06

Inventories, Lumpy Trade, and Large Devaluations
George Alessandria, Joseph P. Kaboski, and Virgiliu Midrigan

WP-08-07

2

Working Paper Series (continued)
School Vouchers and Student Achievement: Recent Evidence, Remaining Questions
Cecilia Elena Rouse and Lisa Barrow
Does It Pay to Read Your Junk Mail? Evidence of the Effect of Advertising on
Home Equity Credit Choices
Sumit Agarwal and Brent W. Ambrose

WP-08-08

WP-08-09

The Choice between Arm’s-Length and Relationship Debt: Evidence from eLoans
Sumit Agarwal and Robert Hauswald

WP-08-10

Consumer Choice and Merchant Acceptance of Payment Media
Wilko Bolt and Sujit Chakravorti

WP-08-11

Investment Shocks and Business Cycles
Alejandro Justiniano, Giorgio E. Primiceri, and Andrea Tambalotti

WP-08-12

New Vehicle Characteristics and the Cost of the
Corporate Average Fuel Economy Standard
Thomas Klier and Joshua Linn

WP-08-13

Realized Volatility
Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

WP-08-14

Revenue Bubbles and Structural Deficits: What’s a state to do?
Richard Mattoon and Leslie McGranahan

WP-08-15

The role of lenders in the home price boom
Richard J. Rosen

WP-08-16

Bank Crises and Investor Confidence
Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

WP-08-17

Life Expectancy and Old Age Savings
Mariacristina De Nardi, Eric French, and John Bailey Jones

WP-08-18

Remittance Behavior among New U.S. Immigrants
Katherine Meckel

WP-08-19

Birth Cohort and the Black-White Achievement Gap:
The Roles of Access and Health Soon After Birth
Kenneth Y. Chay, Jonathan Guryan, and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-08-20

Public Investment and Budget Rules for State vs. Local Governments
Marco Bassetto

WP-08-21

Why Has Home Ownership Fallen Among the Young?
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Martin Gervais

WP-09-01

Why do the Elderly Save? The Role of Medical Expenses
Mariacristina De Nardi, Eric French, and John Bailey Jones

WP-09-02

3

Working Paper Series (continued)
Using Stock Returns to Identify Government Spending Shocks
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Ryan Peters

WP-09-03

Stochastic Volatility
Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

WP-09-04

The Effect of Disability Insurance Receipt on Labor Supply
Eric French and Jae Song

WP-09-05

CEO Overconfidence and Dividend Policy
Sanjay Deshmukh, Anand M. Goel, and Keith M. Howe

WP-09-06

Do Financial Counseling Mandates Improve Mortgage Choice and Performance?
Evidence from a Legislative Experiment
Sumit Agarwal,Gene Amromin, Itzhak Ben-David, Souphala Chomsisengphet,
and Douglas D. Evanoff

WP-09-07

Perverse Incentives at the Banks? Evidence from a Natural Experiment
Sumit Agarwal and Faye H. Wang

WP-09-08

Pay for Percentile
Gadi Barlevy and Derek Neal

WP-09-09

The Life and Times of Nicolas Dutot
François R. Velde

WP-09-10

Regulating Two-Sided Markets: An Empirical Investigation
Santiago Carbó Valverde, Sujit Chakravorti, and Francisco Rodriguez Fernandez

WP-09-11

The Case of the Undying Debt
François R. Velde

WP-09-12

Paying for Performance: The Education Impacts of a Community College Scholarship
Program for Low-income Adults
Lisa Barrow, Lashawn Richburg-Hayes, Cecilia Elena Rouse, and Thomas Brock
Establishments Dynamics, Vacancies and Unemployment: A Neoclassical Synthesis
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-09-13

WP-09-14

The Price of Gasoline and the Demand for Fuel Economy:
Evidence from Monthly New Vehicles Sales Data
Thomas Klier and Joshua Linn

WP-09-15

Estimation of a Transformation Model with Truncation,
Interval Observation and Time-Varying Covariates
Bo E. Honoré and Luojia Hu

WP-09-16

Self-Enforcing Trade Agreements: Evidence from Antidumping Policy
Chad P. Bown and Meredith A. Crowley

WP-09-17

Too much right can make a wrong: Setting the stage for the financial crisis
Richard J. Rosen

WP-09-18

4

Working Paper Series (continued)
Can Structural Small Open Economy Models Account
for the Influence of Foreign Disturbances?
Alejandro Justiniano and Bruce Preston

WP-09-19

Liquidity Constraints of the Middle Class
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

WP-09-20

Monetary Policy and Uncertainty in an Empirical Small Open Economy Model
Alejandro Justiniano and Bruce Preston

WP-09-21

Firm boundaries and buyer-supplier match in market transaction:
IT system procurement of U.S. credit unions
Yukako Ono and Junichi Suzuki
Health and the Savings of Insured Versus Uninsured, Working-Age Households in the U.S.
Maude Toussaint-Comeau and Jonathan Hartley

WP-09-22

WP-09-23

The Economics of “Radiator Springs:” Industry Dynamics, Sunk Costs, and
Spatial Demand Shifts
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Thomas N. Hubbard

WP-09-24

On the Relationship between Mobility, Population Growth, and
Capital Spending in the United States
Marco Bassetto and Leslie McGranahan

WP-09-25

The Impact of Rosenwald Schools on Black Achievement
Daniel Aaronson and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-09-26

Comment on “Letting Different Views about Business Cycles Compete”
Jonas D.M. Fisher

WP-10-01

Macroeconomic Implications of Agglomeration
Morris A. Davis, Jonas D.M. Fisher and Toni M. Whited

WP-10-02

Accounting for non-annuitization
Svetlana Pashchenko

WP-10-03

Robustness and Macroeconomic Policy
Gadi Barlevy

WP-10-04

Benefits of Relationship Banking: Evidence from Consumer Credit Markets
Sumit Agarwal, Souphala Chomsisengphet, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles

WP-10-05

The Effect of Sales Tax Holidays on Household Consumption Patterns
Nathan Marwell and Leslie McGranahan

WP-10-06

Gathering Insights on the Forest from the Trees: A New Metric for Financial Conditions
Scott Brave and R. Andrew Butters

WP-10-07

Identification of Models of the Labor Market
Eric French and Christopher Taber

WP-10-08

5

Working Paper Series (continued)
Public Pensions and Labor Supply Over the Life Cycle
Eric French and John Jones

WP-10-09

Explaining Asset Pricing Puzzles Associated with the 1987 Market Crash
Luca Benzoni, Pierre Collin-Dufresne, and Robert S. Goldstein

WP-10-10

Does Prenatal Sex Selection Improve Girls’ Well‐Being? Evidence from India
Luojia Hu and Analía Schlosser

WP-10-11

Mortgage Choices and Housing Speculation
Gadi Barlevy and Jonas D.M. Fisher

WP-10-12

Did Adhering to the Gold Standard Reduce the Cost of Capital?
Ron Alquist and Benjamin Chabot

WP-10-13

6