View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Accounting for Central Neighborhood
Change, 1980-2010
Nathaniel Baum-Snow and Daniel Hartley

REVISED
December 2017
WP 2016-09

Accounting for Central Neighborhood Change,
1980-2010
Nathaniel Baum-Snow, Daniel Hartley
December 22, 2017

Abstract
Central neighborhoods of most U.S. metropolitan areas experienced population
decline 1980-2000 and population growth 2000-2010. 1980-2000 departures of residents without a college degree accounted for most of the decline while the return of
college educated whites and the stabilization of neighborhood choices by less educated
whites drove most of the post-2000 rebound. Increases in amenity valuations after 2000
encouraged college-educated whites to move in and other whites to remain. Continued departures of less than college educated minorities were mainly driven by relative
improvements in suburban employment opportunities for this group whose declining
amenity valuations of downtown neighborhoods never reversed.

Baum-Snow: University of Toronto, 105 St. George St. Toronto, ON M5S 3E6, Nate.BaumSnow@rotman.utoronto.ca; Hartley: Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 230 S. LaSalle St., Chicago, IL 60604,
Daniel.A.Hartley@chi.frb.org. We thank participants in various seminars and conferences for their helpful
comments. The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, or their sta¤.

1

Introduction

In the decades following WWII, the central regions of most U.S. metropolitan areas were
in decline. Between 1960 and 2000, the aggregate central city population share in the 100
largest metropolitan areas fell from 0.49 to 0.24 while the employment share declined from
0.61 to 0.34 (Baum-Snow, 2017). A host of mechanisms responsible for this decline have
been considered in the literature. These include highway construction (Baum-Snow, 2007),
decentralization of low-skilled work (Kain, 1992), white ‡ight from rising minority populations in cities (Boustan, 2010), rising incomes (Margo, 1992), Federal Housing Authority
mortgage insurance provision favoring the suburbs (Jackson, 1985) and vintage housing in
cities …ltering down to lower-income occupants (Brueckner and Rosenthal, 2009). Following sharp population and economic declines during the 1970s, neighborhoods within 2 km
of central business districts (CBDs) in our sample of the largest 120 U.S. metropolitan areas experienced continued 1980-2000 declines in population, averaging 7 percent. However,
population, income and college fraction all grew on average in these central neighborhoods
during the 2000-2010 period. Though 2000-2010 population growth within 2 km of CBDs
averaged 6 percent, almost equal to the aggregate growth rate in the sample, downtown
neighborhoods were among the most rapidly gentrifying regions of metropolitan areas during the 2000-2010 period when measured in terms of fraction white, income and fraction
with a college degree. This paper investigates the factors that drove this 1980-2000 decline
and 2000-2010 gentri…cation of the central neighborhoods of large U.S. metropolitan areas.
Our evaluation of the causes of central neighborhood change proceeds in two stages.
First, using a procedure akin to that proposed by DiNardo, Fortin & Lemieux (1996) for
decomposing wage distributions, we systematically decompose the sources of changes in
demand for central neighborhoods since 1980 into those due to secular demographic shifts,
holding neighborhood choices constant, and those due to changes in neighborhood choices
of particular demographic groups, holding demographic shares constant. We carry out the
analysis using cells de…ned by joint population distributions of race and: education, age,
1

family structure, or household income decile. While our focus is on central neighborhoods,
this method can be applied more broadly to decompose the drivers of change for any type
of neighborhood.
Second, to better understand why groups’neighborhood choices changed, we use a conditional choice probability procedure to recover changes in valuations of various neighborhood attributes in each decade from 1980 through 2010 in the context of a neighborhood
choice model. The model shows how to combine information about observed neighborhood
choices and housing costs to recover neighborhood valuations that re‡ect a combination of
sub-metropolitan area labor market opportunities and local amenities. Using our model estimates, we evaluate the extent to which shifts in housing costs, labor demand conditions
and various components of demand for local amenities by di¤erent groups are associated
with 1980-2000 and 2000-2010 changes in central neighborhood population and demographic
composition.
The central result from the decompositions is that most central neighborhood change
has been driven by the fact that whites have chosen to live in near-CBD neighborhoods at
much higher rates since 2000 relative to the prior decades. This phenomenon is particularly strong for more educated and higher income whites. Indeed, the area within 2 km of
the CBD is the only CBD-distance interval within 20 km of the CBD in which the white
population grew over the 2000-2010 period, on average, across CBSAs. In contrast, the 19802000 departures of low socioeconomic status (SES) minorities continued after 2000. Shifts
in neighborhood choices drove 1980-2000 central neighborhood population decline, despite
the fact that growth in minority share bolstered demand for these neighborhoods, holding
neighborhood choices constant. Low SES nonwhites’declines in central neighborhood choice
probabilities in each decade over the full 1980-2010 study period represents the largest force
for population declines. High SES whites’slight declines in 1980-2000 central neighborhood
choice probabilities reversed after 2000 to generate the majority of central area population
growth. However, the main driver of the turnaround of central neighborhoods comes from

2

the fact that low-SES whites stopped departing after 2000. Changing neighborhood choices
of high-SES minorities had only small impacts. More rapid 1980-2000 departures of low-SES
households from central neighborhoods contributed to growth of average incomes in these
neighborhoods, even in the face of declining populations.
Since central area residents are disproportionately minority, the growing share of minorities in the U.S. population over time has contributed to downtown population growth.
Indeed, without this force central neighborhoods would have experienced continued population declines after 2000. Shifts in the distribution of family structure (the growing share
of households without children), conditional on race, have pushed in favor of population
growth, as well, since 1980, making it unlikely that these changes have driven the reversal
of downtown population declines. Shifts in the income distribution and the age structure of
the population, conditional on race, have also had small e¤ects.
To recover mechanisms driving shifts in neighborhood choices, we develop a model that
incorporates insights from Berry (1994) and Bayer et al. (2016), and facilitates recovery
of the relative importance of changing labor market opportunities, housing costs and local
amenities in driving each group’s shifts in neighborhood choices. Our estimates indicate
that while each group responded to improved central area labor market opportunities about
equally, di¤erent income elasticities of demand for downtown amenities across groups and
over time have had important in‡uences on downtown demographic change. In the 1980s,
income growth drove suburbanization of all demographic groups, consistent with Margo’s
(1992) evidence. However the 2000-2010 income growth of college educated whites led them
to be more likely to locate near a downtown. In addition, we …nd increases in amenity
valuations of downtown neighborhoods (holding incomes constant) for all groups except low
SES minorities after 2000, relative to the 1980-2000 period. While all groups value improved
2000-2010 downtown labor market opportunities, the average CBSA experienced declining
downtown employment in the 1990s and essentially no change in downtown employment in
the 2000-2010 period. As a result, shifts in central area labor market opportunities had

3

miminal impacts on central area population changes since 2000, though the stabilization of
downtown employment declines represents a force that promoted stabilization after 19802000 downtown population declines, particularly for low SES whites.
Our conclusion that shifts in amenity valuations rather than in nearby labor market opportunities or housing cost changes have primarily driven changes in central neighborhood
choices echoes evidence in Couture & Handbury (2017), which performs a detailed investigation of which amenities are driving these shifts for the young and college educated. However,
our evidence that all groups’central neighborhood valuations are increasing in nearby labor
market opportunities are also in line with those in Edlund, Machado, & Sviatchi (2015),
though that paper focuses on larger cities with more robust 2000-2010 employment growth
than is seen in our broader sample. Our …nding of important racial di¤erences in trends
in the valuation of downtown amenities, especially amongst low SES individuals and households, is an important part of the broader narrative about central neighborhood change that
has not been considered elsewhere in the literature.

2

Characterizing Neighborhood Change

In this section, we establish facts about central neighborhood change between 1970 and 2010
that represent a baseline for the analysis in subsequent sections.

2.1

Data

We primarily use 1970-2010 decennial Census data and the 2008-2012 American Community
Survey (ACS) data tabulated to the 2000 de…nition of census tract boundaries for the analysis. Central to our investigation is the need for joint distributions of population by race,
education, household income, age and family structure across census tracts in each CBSA.
To recover as many of these joint distributions in the most disaggregated form possible, we
make use of both summary tape …le (STF) 3 and 4 census tabulations. We also use informa-

4

tion about family structure and age by race from STF1 data from the 2010 Census. Because
the 2010 Census did not collect information about income or education, we must rely on the
5-year ACS data for these tract distributions. We also make use of some census micro data
to estimate parameters governing shapes of household income distributions above topcodes,
to generate weights used to assign some of the population counts in the tract aggregate data
to di¤erent types of families, and to estimate housing expenditure shares by household demographic type. All census tracts are normalized to year 2000 geographies using allocation
factors from the U.S. Census Bureau.
We construct three di¤erent joint distributions for people and one for households in 1980,
1990, 2000 and 2010. For each one, the race categories are white, black and other. In the
other dimension of each joint distribution, we have either 4 education groups (less than high
school, high school only, some college, college +), 18 age groups (0-4, 5-9, ..., 80-84, 85+) or
6 family type groups (in married couple families with no children, in married couple families
with children, in single female headed families with children, in single male headed families
with children, not in a family, in group quarters). For income, we construct the number
of households in each decile of the household income distribution of those residing in our
sample area in each year. We do this in order to facilitate comparisons across CBSAs and
years in a sensible way while taking into account the secular increase in nationwide income
inequality during our sample period.
The Census Transportation Planning Package (CTPP) reports aggregated census or ACS
micro data to microgeographic units for place of work in 1990, 2000 and 2005-2009. We use
these data broken out by industry to construct localized labor demand shocks. Where
available, we take CBD de…nitions from the 1982 Economic Census. Otherwise, we use the
CBD location as assigned by ESRI. Each CBSA is assigned only one CBD.
Our sample includes the regions of all 120 year 2008 de…nition metropolitan areas (CBSAs) that were tracted in 1970 and had a population of at least 250,000 except Honolulu.1
1

100% of the 2000 de…nition tract must have been tracted in 1970 to be in our sample.

5

In order for our analysis to apply for the average metropolitan area rather than the average
resident, much of the analysis applies tract-level weights such that each CBSA is weighted
equally. So that parameters that govern demand conditions for regions within 4km of CBDs
represent the average CBSA in our sample, we also weight this region equally across CBSAs. The Data Appendix provides more details about our data construction and weighting
procedure.
To achieve a succinct descriptive analysis, we construct a summary measure of neighborhood demographics that incorporates the share of residents that are white, the share that
are college educated and the median household income of the tract. This summary measure
for tract i is the average number of standard deviations tract i is away from its CBSA mean
in each year for each of these components. We call this equally weighted tract z-score the
socioeconomic status (SES) index.2
Figure 1 shows a map of the 120 CBSAs in our sample shaded by the fraction of census
tracts within 4 km of the central business district that are in the top half of the tract
distribution of our SES index in 1980 (top left) and 2010 (top right) in each CBSA. Those
CBSAs above 0.5 have central areas that are less distressed than would be expected given
a random assignment of SES status to census tracts. Particularly striking is the number of
CBSAs whose central areas experience gentri…cation between 1980 and 2010 (moving up the
distribution of blue-red shades). Santa Barbara and New York are the only CBSAs with
downtown areas that were more a- uent than average in 1980. By 2010, 9 additional CBSAs
had relatively a- uent downtown areas. While central areas of other CBSAs remained less
a- uent than average, most became more a- uent between 1980 and 2010. Of the 120 CBSAs
in our sample, the fraction of the population within 4 km of a CBD living in a tract in the
top half of the SES index distribution increased by more than 0.25 in 15 CBSAs, by 0.10
to 0.25 in 35 CBSAs and by 0.00 to 0.10 in 23 CBSAs between 1980 and 2010. Central
2

While race is not a measure of socioeconomic status, there is evidence that conditional on income and
education, black households have lower wealth than white households (Altonji, Doraszelski, and Segal, 2000).
We include the share of residents that are white in our SES index as a proxy for unobserved elements of
socioeconomic status such as wealth.

6

areas of the remaining 47 CBSA experienced only small declines in their SES indexes on
average. These patterns of changes are seen at the bottom of Figure 1, with red shaded
CBSAs experiencing a rise in SES in central areas and the blue shaded CBSAs a decline in
SES in central areas.

2.2

Facts About Neighborhood Change

Figure 2 reports statistics describing various aspects of neighborhood change as functions
of the distance from the CBD since 1970. All plots show medians across the CBSAs in our
sample. We choose medians in order to emphasize that changes are not driven by just a few
large notable cities. Analogous results using means across CBSAs or aggregates are similar.
The broad message from Figure 2 is that downtown gentri…cation since 2000 is evident in
many dimensions and is very localized. Neighborhoods within 2 km of CBDs experienced
the fastest 2000-2010 growth in terms of population, the share of residents that are white,
and the share of residents that are college-educated of all CBD distance bands. The seeds
of this gentri…cation started to form after 1980, as evidenced by more localized upticks in
these indicators right at CBDs.
The evidence in Figure 2 shows that while central area population growth relative to that
in the suburbs is a useful indicator of downtown gentri…cation, two additional features in
the data also indicate a turnaround in overall demand for downtown neighborhoods. First,
the growth in population growth (the second derivative) is positive well beyond 2 km from
the CBD. At each distance out to 10 km, the population growth rate increased in the city
relative to at 20 km from the CBD in each decade after the 1970s, with this relative increase
roughly monotonically declining as a function of CBD distance in the 1980s and the 20002010 periods. Second, even areas within about 5 km of the CBD that experienced declining
2000-2010 populations experienced faster than average growth in fraction white and fraction
college educated. As we show below, in the context of our neighborhood choice model, these
types of residental composition shifts represent increasing aggregate demand for living in
7

these central neighborhoods.3
Table 1 reports transitions of individual census tracts through the distributions of three
indicators. We present this evidence about the nature of demographic change in central
neighborhoods to provide a sense of the heterogeneity around the summary statistics presented in Figure 2 and to show that a few neighborhoods moving quickly up the distribution
are not driving central area gentri…cation. Table 1 shows the fraction of the population
within 4 km of a typical CBSA’s CBD living in tracts moving more than 20 percentile points
or 0.5 standard deviations up or down the CBSA tract distribution. When calculating these
numbers we weight by the tract’s share of CBSA population in the base year, meaning all
CBSAs are weighted equally. Commensurate with the evidence in Figure 2, two of the three
measures indicate that central area tracts were, on balance, in decline during the 1970s, with
these declines slowly reversing sometime in the 1980s or 1990s. As in Figure 2, the evidence
in Table 1 shows that the resurgence of the central areas really took o¤ between 2000 and
2010.4
To help visualize typical trends in neighborhood inequality at the CBSA level, Figure
3 depicts the same three measures of neighborhood change in the Chicago CBSA between
1980 and 2010. We calculate demeaned share white (Panel A), demeaned college-graduate
share (Panel B) and demeaned percentile ranking of the tract’s median household income
within our sample of tracts (Panel C). We calculate these measures for each tract in 1980
and 2010, weighting by tract population. These indicators are graphed against each other in
a scatterplot, with 45-degree and regression lines indicated. By construction, both of these
lines pass through (0,0) in each panel. Dark black dots represent tracts within 4 km of the
CBD. The 45 degree line represents the locus of points where the variable relative to its mean
did not change from 1980 to 2010. Regression slopes of less than 1, for tract income percentile
3

We also looked at analogous …gures which index space instead by the cumulative distribution function
1970 CBSA population moving outward from the CBDs. These results are similar.
4
Downtown neighborhoods were the poorest and had among the lowest education levels and shares of
white residents of any CBD distance ring in 1980. One potential explanation for downtown gentri…cation is,
thus, simple mean reversion. In Section 5.1 we provide evidence that while mean reversion in neighborhood
income and racial composition does exist, it is not the main force behind downtown revitalization.

8

and tract share white, indicate that Chicago neighborhoods have experienced convergence
in these dimensions. Points above a regression line that are far to the left of a 1980 mean
represent gentrifying census tracts.
Figure 3 reveals considerable heterogeneity in Chicago neighborhood change over the
period 1980-2010, with our three neighborhood change measures clearly capturing distinct
things. The masses of points at the bottom left and top right of Panel A represent large
concentrations of stable minority and white census tracts, respectively. The relatively large
number of tracts along the right edge of the graph at almost 100 percent white in 1980 and
ending up less than 70 percent white may have experienced tipping (Card, Mas & Rothstein,
2008). But a handful of tracts went in the other direction between 1980 and 2010, seen in
the upper left area of the graph. These largely minority tracts in 1980, that gained white
share much faster than the typical Chicago tract, are almost exclusively within 4 km of the
CBD. Indeed, all but 4 of the tracts within 4 km of the CBD that were less than 80 percent
white in 1980 experienced increases in white share between 1980 and 2010, even though
share white decreased on average. Such downtown area gentri…cation is clear from the other
measures in Figure 3, as well. Central area tracts are clustered in the upper left area of each
panel.

3

Decomposing Central Neighborhood Change

Results in the previous section show that central neighborhoods have been chosen at higher
rates by high-SES demographic groups since 2000. Thus far, our examination of location
choices one demographic group at a time has limited our ability to determine which groups’
shifts in neighborhood choices have driven downtown gentri…cation, since college education,
high incomes and racial composition are all correlated. In addition, we wish to recover the
extent to which demographic change toward more education, a more unequal income distribution and smaller families has contributed to central area gentri…cation. To separate out

9

the relative importance of changing race-speci…c neighborhood choices from other observed
demographic factors that may be correlated with race, we use tract-level joint distributions of
race and education or race and: age, family structure or income over time to construct counterfactual neighborhood compositions absent changes in neighborhood choices for particular
race-education (and race-other factor) combinations. The analysis simultaneously evaluates
the extent to which population growth and SES improvement in central neighborhoods are
driven by shifts in the demographic compositions of CBSA populations.
Our decompositions follow the logic developed by DiNardo, Fortin & Lemieux (1996) for
decomposing wage distributions. To quantify the relative importance of group-speci…c changing neighborhood choices versus demographic shifts for generating neighborhood change, we
calculate magnitudes of central area population and demographic change under various counterfactual scenarios. First, we hold the fraction of the CBSA population made up by various
demographic groups …xed over time but allow neighborhood choices by speci…c groups to
shift as in equilibrium, one at a time. This allows us to evaluate the extent to which changes
in the choices of high-SES individuals and households in each racial group have driven central neighborhood change while holding the demographic composition of CBSA populations
constant. We then additionally calculate how shifts in the CBSA-level compositions of various demographic groups, conditional on race, have mechanically in‡uenced neighborhood
change. Finally, we quantify the impacts of CBSA-level racial change on central area population and demographics. This procedure, laid out in more detail below, has similarities to
that developed in Carillo & Rothbaum (2016).
While the procedure used to construct counterfactual neighborhood demographic compositions is mechanical, the results are informative about magnitudes of relative neighborhood
demand shifts across demographic groups. Given that all groups compete for housing in each
tract and face the same local price of housing services, relative contributions across groups
to tract population changes, because of shifts in choice probabilities, holding demographic
composition constant, are indicative of relative demand shifts for living in a tract. Demand

10

shifts due to changes in relative group sizes are also independently informative about why
some neighborhoods may have grown or declined in population. We emphasize that our decompositions are not intended to trace out counterfactual equilibrium allocations of people
across neighborhoods by type. Instead, they are intended to allow us to discern the extent to
which shifts in equilibrium choices by each demographic groups have contributed to central
neighborhood change. After establishing which groups’ shifts in choices were the largest
drivers of central neighborhood change, we investigate why their choices changed.

3.1

Construction of Counterfactual Neighborhoods

We observe the joint population distribution fjt (i; r; x) of race r and the other demographic
attribute x across census tracts i in CBSA j in year t. The attribute x indexes education
group, age group, family structure or household income decile in the national distribution.
That is, fjt (i; r; x) denotes the fraction of CBSA j population at time t that is in demographic
group (r; x) and lives in tract i. Given the structure of the tabulated census data, we are
forced to evaluate counterfactual joint distributions of race (white, black, or other) and
only one other demographic attribute at a time across census tracts. Denote Njt as the
total population of CBSA j at time t and CBSA density functions of demographics as
P
gjt (r; x) = i fjt (i; r; x). Crucially, we treat CBSA-level allocations gjt (r; x) and populations

Njt as exogenous to the allocation of people across neighborhoods, which can be justi…ed in a
long-run open-city model in which households …rst choose a CBSA and then a neighborhood
within a CBSA.
Central to our recovery of counterfactuals is the following decomposition:

fjt (i; r; x) = fjt (ijr; x)gjt (xjr)hjt (r)

(1)

This expression shows how to separate out neighborhood choices of particular demographic
groups fjt (ijr; x) from the CBSA-level distribution of (r; x) across locations. It additionally

11

shows how to separate out shifts in education, age, income, or family type compositions
independent of racial composition. Components of demographic change driven by changes
in demand by group (r; x) for tract i are captured by shifts in fjt (ijr; x). Components driven
by changes in the demographic makeup of whites, blacks or other minorities holding the racial
distribution constant are captured by shifts in gjt (xjr). Components driven by changes in the
racial composition of the population holding the demographic makeup of each race constant
are captured by shifts in hjt (r).
Tables 2-4 report results of the counterfactual experiments. Tables 2 and 3 separate out
mechanisms driving total central area population change. Table 4 decomposes sources of
changes in central areas’ share white, share college-graduate and median income. In each
table, Panels A and B report results for 1980-2000 and 2000-2010, respectively. Table 2
focuses on joint distributions of race and education for 2 km and 4 km CBD distance rings.
In Table 3, each row uses a di¤erent data set with joint distributions of race with age,
family type and income. The remainder of this subsection details the construction of the
counterfactual distributions that are used to generate the output for each column in the
tables.
Column 1 in Tables 2-4 reports changes in outcomes of interest for central areas calculated
using the raw data as a basis for comparison with counterfactuals. Because of sampling
variability across the education, age and family type data sets and the use of households
rather than people in the income data set, the numbers in Column 1 of Tables 2 and 3 do
not match perfectly across data sets. Column 2 shows the change that would have occurred
had choices and shares not shifted from the base year. In Tables 2 and 3, this is the CBSA
population growth rate. Because objects of interest in Table 4 are invariant to scale, Column
2 is all 0s in this table.
The remaining columns of Tables 2-4 are built using counterfactual distributions. Our notation indicates column number superscripts on these probability density functions. Column
3 of Tables 2-4 reports counterfactual central neighborhood change given CBSA demographic

12

shares that are unchanged from the base year. In particular, they are constructed using the
counterfactual distributions

fjt3 (i; r; x) = fjt (ijr; x)gjb (xjr)hjb (r).

Here, demographic shares gjb (xjr)hjb (r) are for the base year but neighborhood choices for
each group fjt (ijr; x) change as they did in equilibrium. Results in Column 4 of Tables 2-4
show the e¤ects of holding choices constant but allowing demographic shares to shift as in
equilibrium. These statistics are constructed using the counterfactual distribution

fjt4 (i; r; x) = fjb (ijr; x)gjt (xjr)hjt (r).

In most cases, baselines in Column 1 are closer to the results in Column 3 than they are to the
than the results in Column 4. This means that changes in neighborhood choices have been
more important than changes in demographic composition for generating observed patterns
in the data.
Columns 5-10 in Tables 2-4 decompose the di¤erence between the actual changes in
Column 1 and the counterfactuals given no changes in choices or shares (in Column 2)
into components that are related to changes in neighborhood choices (Columns 5-8) and
demographic shares (Columns 9-10). The four e¤ects in Columns 5-8 sum to the total e¤ect
of changing choices holding demographic shares constant reported in Column 3 (relative to
no changes reported in Column 2). Adding the e¤ects of changing demographic shares yields
the full di¤erence between the actual data in Column 1 and the "no changes" baseline in
Column 2. That is, taking a cumulative sum from left to right starting at Column 5 can be
thought of as piling on additional components of population growth from a baseline of no
changes in Column 2 to equal the full changes in Column 3.
Columns 5-8 report components of changes in equilibrium tract composition due to changing neighborhood choices of target whites, non-target whites, target non-whites and non13

target non-whites, respectively, holding demographic shares at their base year levels. “Target" refers to college graduates, 20-34 year olds, single people and married couples without
children, or households in the top three deciles of the income distribution of the full sample
area, depending on the data set used. In particular, the set of results for counterfactual
column c (5 to 8) is constructed using distributions built as

fjtc (i; r; x) = fjtc (ijr; x)gjb (xjr)hjb (r),
where fjtc (ijr; x) = fjt (ijr; x) for the elements of (r; x) listed in the column headers and
fjtc (ijr; x) = fjb (ijr; x) for the remaining elements of (r; x). In Tables 2-4, the results are
expressed as the e¤ect of imposing fjtc (i; r; x) relative to the counterfactual distribution that
sets choices of all groups to the base year b, (fjb (i; r; x)). As such, Column 5 shows the
impacts of target whites’ changes in choices only, Column 6 shows the impacts of target
nonwhites’changes in choices only, etc..
We note that the order of demographic groups for which we impose year t choices does
not a¤ect the results. This is because the change in the fraction of the population in tract i
as a result of imposing any of these counterfactuals is linear. Each counterfactual amounts
to imposing year t rather than year b choices for a few additional elements of (x; r) at a time.
Mathematically, the di¤erence in the fraction of the population living in tract i associated
with counterfactual c relative to c
XX
x

1 is

[fjtc (ijr; x)

fjtc 1 (ijr; x)]gjb (xjr)hjb (r).

(2)

r

Because of linearity within the square brackets, Equation (2) indicates that the full choice
adjustment in counterfactual 3 can be achieved by imposing counterfactuals 5, 6, 7 and 8
cumulatively in any order. Equation (2) also indicates that counterfactual c’s in‡uence on
tract composition depends not only on the magnitudes of di¤erences in choices made by the
group (x; r) in question between t and the base year [fjtc (ijr; x)
14

fjb (ijr; x)], but also on

the fraction of that group in the CBSA population in the base year, gjb (xjr)hjb (r). That is,
neighborhoods change the same amount if a large group makes small changes in neighborhood
choices or a small group makes large changes in neighborhood choices. To provide information
about which is driving the results, Tables 2 and 3 report the average fraction of the near-CBD
populations in each of the four demographic categories in parentheses.
The key comparison that drives our calculations about the importance of changes in
neighborhood choices by a particular group (r0 ; x0 ) is between fjt (ijr0 ; x0 ) and fjb (ijr0 ; x0 ),
holding the neighborhood choice probabilities of other groups constant. We recognize that a
counterfactual in which choice probabilities are simultaneoulsy fjt (ijr0 ; x0 ) for group (r0 ; x0 )
and fjb (ijr00 ; x00 ) for group (r00 ; x00 ), holding overall demographic shares constant, may not be
the equilibrium of a model for two reasons. First, housing costs faced by group (r00 ; x00 ) may
be a¤ected by changes in group (r0 ; x0 ) ’s neighborhood choice probabilities. Second, group
(r00 ; x00 ) may have direct preferences over the fraction of group (r0 ; x0 ) in the neighborhood.
Rather than explore counterfactual equilibria, we emphasize that our main objective in this
section is to perform a systematic accounting of the neighborhood changes that did occur.
The empirical implementation of the model in the following section addresses the possibility
of interdependence in neighborhood choice probabilities.
After determining the roles of changes in neighborhood choices holding demographic composition constant, the remaining changes must be due to shifts in demographic composition.
To look at this, we …rst maintain the base year racial distribution and examine how shifts
in other demographic attributes conditional on race have in‡uenced neighborhood choices.
This allows us to see the in‡uences that rising education levels, changes in income inequality,
more single people and couples without children, and the aging of the population have had
on downtown neighborhood change while holding CBSA white, black and other race population shares constant.5 Doing so avoids including the mechanical e¤ects that rising minority
shares have on the education, age, family type and income distributions. These results are
5

For some outcomes, we further split out this demographic e¤ect for whites and other races respectively.

15

reported in Column 9 of Tables 2-4, and are built using the expression

fjt9 (i; r; x) = fjt (ijr; x)gjt (xjr)hjb (r).

The residual e¤ect (Column 10) is due to changes in racial composition, which typically
works against gentri…cation since the white share of the population has declined over time
and downtown neighborhoods have higher base year minority shares than does the average
neighborhood.
Table A1 mathematically speci…es the construction of each counterfactual distribution
and Table A2 reports the average shares of target groups across CBSAs overall and within
2 km and 4 km CBD distance rings.
We use the counterfactual distributions fjtc (i; r; x) and base year distributions fjb (i; r; x)
to calculate counterfactual central neighborhood change as follows. Population growth for
counterfactual c between years b and t reported in Tables 2 and 3 is constructed using the
following expression:
P P P
X
1
N
x
r
i
jt
c
gbt
=
ln
+ ln P P P
J j
Njb
x
r
i

CBDj

fjtc (i; r; x)

CBDj

fjb (i; r; x)

!

(3)

That is, the central area population growth rate in a CBSA can be expressed as the sum of the
CBSA growth rate and the growth rate of the fraction of the population in the central area.
The objects reported in Table 2 and 3 are averages across the 120 CBSAs in our sample,
as is captured by the outer summation. The reference "no change" results in Column 2
X
are simply average CBSA population growth rates, calculated as J1
ln(Njt =Njb ). The
j

entries in Columns 5-10 of Tables 2-4 decompose the di¤erence between the actual changes

in Column 1 and the counterfactuals given no changes in choices or shares in Column 2
into components that are related to changes in neighborhood choices (Columns 5-8) and
demographic shares (Columns 9-10). The four e¤ects in Columns 5-8 sum to the total e¤ect
of changing choices holding demographic shares constant reported in Column 3 (relative to
16

no changes reported in Column 2). Adding the e¤ects of changing demographic shares yields
the full di¤erence between the actual data in Column 1 and the "no changes" baseline in
Column 2. That is, taking a cumulative sum from left to right starting at Column 5 can be
thought of as piling on additional components of demographic change from a baseline of no
changes in Column 2 to equal the full changes in Column 3.
We construct the counterfactual white share, college graduate share and median income
of neighborhoods within 2 or 4 km of CBDs, appearing in Table 4, in an analogous manner.
The exact expressions used to construct these counterfactuals are presented in Appendix B.
Since choices and shares matter multiplicatively for the overall population distribution
across tracts, the ordering matters for quantifying the in‡uence of each channel. Table
A3 shows results analogous to those in Tables 2 and 3 but imposes the counterfactuals
in the reverse order: shares adjustments …rst and sub-group-speci…c choice adjustments
second. In practice, it shows that the ordering does not materially a¤ect conclusions from
this decomposition exercise.

3.2

Counterfactual Results

Before discussing the results of each counterfactual exercise, we summarize the broad picture
provided by these decompositions. The results of the exercise primarily point to a shifting
balance between departures of low SES minorities and in‡ows of high SES whites driving
1980-2010 neighborhood change. In the 1980-2000 period, central neighborhoods experienced
the ‡ight of the poor and less educated. This was true for both white and minority households. Their ‡ight was sizable enough to counterbalance a growing minority population,
which mechanically pushed to increase central area populations. By 2000, there was a clear
shift in the racial and SES makeup of near CBD neighborhoods. The 2000-2010 movement
of high-SES whites into central neighborhoods strengthened while the out‡ow of low-SES
whites ceased or reversed. The net e¤ect was 2000-2010 central neigborhoods population
growth at about the same rate as CBSAs as a whole. Increases in the fraction of singles and
17

unmarried couples in the population drove central area population growth during the entire study period, mostly due to whites. Increasing income inequality and college-graduates
in the population, especially among whites, have been important for driving composition
shifts of downtown neighborhoods toward being more highly educated and of higher incomes
during the entire study period.
Table 2 shows what population growth in 1980-2010 would have been within 2 and 4 km
of CBDs under the various counterfactual scenarios laid out in the prior sub-section using
the race-education joint distributions only. The evidence in Column 1 reiterates the Figure
2 result that populations near CBDs declined until 2000, after which the population within
2 km of CBDs grew at about the same rate as the overall urban population growth reported
in Column 2, while that within 4 km was almost unchanged, on average.
The results holding the shares constant in Column 3 show slightly lower population
growth than the actual changes in Column 1, meaning that shifting demographics pushed
toward central area population growth since growing demographic groups were disproportionately located in downtown neighborhoods. Had the race-education distribution not changed
from 1980 through 2000, the central area population would have declined by 12 percentage
points (Column 3) rather than the actual decline of 7 percentage points (Column 1) in the
average CBSA. In the 2000-2010 period, the central area populations within 2 km of CBDs
would have grown by 4 percentage points (Column 3) rather than the 6 percentage points
(Column 1) they actually grew, on average. That is, even in the 2000-2010 period, central
neighborhood choice probabilities declined in the overall population, with growth in minority shares large enough to counteract these declines and generate small rates of central area
population growth. The e¤ects of secular demographic change are roughly the same within
4 km of CBDs as within 2 km of CBDs.
Column 4 of Table 2 shows what would have happened to central area populations had
neighborhood choices not changed from base years but demographic shares had. For 19802000, it shows 31 percent growth and for 2000-2010, it shows 9 percent growth within 2

18

km of CBDs. These results re‡ect the positive e¤ects associated with a rising minority
population reinforced by the imposed lack of shifts in neighborhood choices away from central
neighborhoods. Comparing the magnitudes of the results in Columns 3 and 4 of Table 2
indicates that changing neighborhood choices have been the key generator of central area
population decline in 1980-2000, even as shifting demographics have pushed for central area
population growth. In the 2000-2010 period, shifts in neighborhood choices continued to
hold central neighborhoods slightly below CBSA growth rates, with demographic change
almost making up for this de…cit.
The results in Columns 5-8 of Table 2 show the amount of central area population change
driven by changes in neighborhood choices by each of the indicated demographic groups. The
entries in Columns 5-8 sum to the di¤erence between the entries in Columns 3 and 2 (-0.34
for 1980-2000 and -0.03 for 2000-2010 within 2 km of CBDs), or the total impact of changing
neighborhood choices holding CBSA demographic composition …xed. These results show that
1980-2000 central area population losses are mostly explained by the ‡ight of less than college
educated whites and nonwhites alike, whose e¤ects are similar at -0.14 and -0.18, respectively
within 2 km of CBDs. The fraction of the population within 2km or 4km of the CBD made
up by each demographic is shown in parentheses. With less than college whites representing
the largest shares of CBSA and central area populations, the logic discussed in the context
of Equation (2) indicates that the changing choices of less than college nonwhites must be
of greater magnitudes. While college educated whites and nonwhites were also choosing
to move away from central neighborhoods during 1980-2000, these out‡ows were much less
pronounced and thus contributed little to 1980-2000 central area population declines.
In the 2000-2010 period, minority ‡ight continued and white ‡ight reversed. While less
than college educated nonwhites departed central neighborhoods at similar rates as in 19802000, whites of all education levels started to return to central neighborhoods. In particular,
changing choices of college-educated whites accounted for population growth within 2 km of
CBDs of 4 percentage points. Less educated whites were also returning to central areas, but

19

at lower rates than their college-educated counterparts, accounting for 2 percentage points
of growth holding shares constant. However, less educated minorities continued to depart
central neighborhoods at about the same rate as they had in the prior period, contributing
negative 8 percentage points to central area population growth. This evidence of the return
of college educated whites to downtown areas is in line with Couture and Handbury (2017),
who show similar evidence using di¤erent census tabulations. We emphasize, however, that
the return choices of college educated whites were outweighed by the continued departure
choices of less than college educated minorities.
The results in Column 9 of Table 2 show how shifts in the composition of the education
distribution in‡uenced the central area population share holding racial composition constant.
Estimates of -0.04 before 2000 and -0.01 after 2000 indicate declining shares of less educated
groups in the population, groups who disproportionately lived in central area neighborhoods
in each base year. The results in Column 10 show that the declining white share of the
population promoted increases in downtown populations by 10 percentage points in 19802000 and 3 percentage points in 2000-2010.
Table 3 reports numbers analogous to those in Table 2, except using joint distributions
of age, family type and income with race instead of education. “Target" groups are ages
20-34, singles and couples without children and households in the top 30 percent of the
income distribution of our study area. Results in Table 3 are broadly consistent with those
in Table 2, with the exception of those using the family type-race joint distribution. Childless
households were always prevalent in downtown areas, generating contributions to central area
population growth of of 0.10 in 1980-2000 and 0.03 in 2000-2010 holding neigborhood choices
…xed, as reported in Column 9. Over 70 percent of this phenomenon is driven by whites in
both time periods. However, childless whites also departed central neighborhoods at much
higher rates than young and high income whites during the 1980-2000 period (Column 5 of
Panel A). After 2000, however, like young, educated and high income whites, childless whites
returned to central neighborhoods, with their changes in neighborhood choices contributing

20

2 percentage points toward central area population growth (Column 5 of Panel B). The fact
that the mechanical e¤ect of white childless household relative population growth on central
area growth was positive before 2000 and decelerated after 2000 indicates that this is not
the main driver of central area post-2000 gentri…cation.
Table 4 reports decompositions of changes in fraction white, fraction college educated and
median income of residents within 2 km of CBDs into choice- and share-based components. It
shows why education and income growth before 2000 were leading indicators of racial change
in downtown neighborhoods after 2000. While the central mechanisms driving changes in
these demographic indicators can mostly be inferred from the population results in Tables
2 and 3, a few observations are of note for the 1980-2000 period. First, secular growth
in college fraction accounted for an increase in 0.06 in the fraction of downtown residents
with a college education (Panel A, Row 3, Column 9). Second, departures of lower income
households from central areas of cities promoted a sizable average increase of 1.8 percentiles
in median income of these neighborhoods during this period (Panel A, Row 4, Columns 7
and 8). For the 2000-2010 period, central area median income growth accelarated to 3.8
percentiles, with changes in central neighborhood choices by white high income households
contributing 1.9 percentiles to this increase - in addition to persistence in mechanisms that
existed before 2000.

4

Understanding Changes in Neighborhood Choices

The prior section presents uni…ed decompositions of the extent to which demographic change
in central neighborhoods can be understood through shifts in neighborhood choices by various
demographic subgroups. In this section, we interpret this descriptive evidence in the context
of a model that ultimately facilitates decompositions of changes in neighborhood aggregate
demand into various mechanisms. In particular, this framework allows us to assess the extent
to which rising home prices, local labor demand shocks and various types of amenities and

21

demand for amenities have driven central neighborhood change.

4.1

Neighborhood Choice Model

Here we lay out a standard neighborhood choice model that facilitates the use of neighborhood choice shares by demographic group along with housing prices to recover information
about changes in demand for neighborhoods over time. The procedure makes use of conditional choice probabilities - …rst formalized in Hotz & Miller (1993) - in a way similar to
Bayer et al.’s (2016) dynamic analysis of demand for neighborhood attributes. For clarity of
exposition, we begin by thinking about the choice of neighborhood within one CBSA only.6
The indirect utility of household r of type h residing in census tract i at time t is

t
t
verhi
= vh (pti ; whi
; qit ) + "trhi

t
vhi
+ "trhi .

t
In this expression, pti is the price of one unit of housing services in tract i, whi
is wage net

of commuting cost, qit summarizes local amenities and "trhi is an independent and identically
distributed (i.i.d.) random utility shock, with a Type I extreme value distribution. qit may be
a function of exogenous and endogenous neighborhood attributes including the population
t
composition. whi
can depend on human capital characteristics and access to employment

locations from tract i. We think of a long-run equilibrium in which moving costs are negligible. This setup delivers the following population shares of household type h in each census
tract i, which are observed in the data.

t
hi
6

t
exp(vhi
)
;
=P
t
i0 exp(vhi0 )

Couture & Handbury (2017) shows that this is equivalent to considering a nested choice of …rst CBSA
and then neighborhood within the chosen CBSA.

22

implying the relationship

ln

t
hi

t
= vhi

X

ln

!

t
:
exp(vhi
0)

i0

(4)

This equation shows that we can use conditional choice probabilities to recover the
mean, median or modal utility associated with each tract by each demographic group up to
a scale parameter.7
We now consider the derivation of estimates of components of indirect utility that capture
neighborhood attributes for a reference household type h and use it as a basis for recovering
such components for other types. The broad goal here is to show how to control for di¤erences
in living costs across locations. We impose, as a normalization, that average modal utility
P t
across neighborhoods I1 i0 vhi
0 = 1. This allows for inversion of (4) to an expression relating

neighborhood choice probabilities to indirect utility, as in Berry (1994):

ln

t
hi

1X
(ln
I i0

t
)
hi0

t
+ 1 = vh (pti ; whi
; qit )

Fully di¤erentiating yields an expression that tells us that ln vhi equals a weighted average
of wages net of commuting costs, home prices and neighborhood attributes relative to those
in the average location. This expression assumes utility over goods x, housing H and a
local amenity index q, where, U (x; H; q) takes the form qu(x; H), and u is homothetic. The
expression is,
ln

t
hi

1X
ln(
I i0

t
)
hi0

= d ln wht

t
h d ln pi

+

t
h dqi

Here we express utility relative to the composite reference location with utility normalized
to 1. As in Rosen (1979) and Roback (1982), we see that di¤erences in neighborhood choice
probabilities re‡ect di¤erences in incomes, housing costs and amenity values of locations.
The parameter

h

rerpesents the housing expenditure share of type h and

7

h

is a parameter

t
Given the extreme value assumption for the errors, the mean tract utility is vhi
+ 0:58 (Euler’s constant)
t
t
with normalization of the scale parameter to 1, the median is vhi ln(ln(2)) and the mode is vhi
.

23

governing the preference of type h for local amenities, where we suspect that

h

is increasing

in income. We can recover the combination of di¤erences in wages net of commuting costs
and local amenities across tracts for the average household type h by imposing that d ln pi =
P
ln pi I1 i0 ln pi0 .

To recover analogous expressions for household types other than h, we di¤erentiate in-

direct utility over type, holding location constant, to reveal

ln v =

ln w. Therefore, the

ln wh ; where wh is the wage net

reference utility level for households of type h is 1 + ln wh

of commuting cost for type h in the reference (average) location. Thus, for a generic type h
we have

ln

t
hi

+

t
h d ln pi =

1X
ln(
I i0

t
hi0 )

+ (ln wht

t
+
ln wht ) + d ln whi

This formulation incorporates type-speci…c intercepts

1
I

P

i0

ln(

t
h dqi

t
t
hi0 ) + (ln wh

t
hi :

(5)

ln wht ) that we

account for empirically using type-CBSA speci…c …xed e¤ects.
Equation (5) summarizes how to recover the component of di¤erences in neighborhood
demand that are driven by di¤erences in wages net of commuting costs and neighborhood
amenities. We directly observe

t
hi

in the data as fjt (ijx; r) in the context of the counterfac-

tual calculations of the prior section. Zero shares do not match the model well, so we assign
tracts with zero shares to the smallest observed positive share for that demographic group
for the purpose of calculating shares only. We set valuations of tracts with zero shares to a
missing value. To recover estimates of d ln pti , we use a hedonic price index. That is, we take
residuals from tract-level regressions of log reported median home price on average home
characteristics and CBSA …xed e¤ects in each year.
We aim to construct estimates of

hj

(type and CBSA-speci…c housing expenditure

shares), that both re‡ect potential di¤erences in preferences across groups and that accommodate preferences over housing that may not be homothetic (Albouy, Ehrlich & Liu,
2016). We estimate

hj

using data from the 5% public use micro data sample of the 1980

24

decennial Census so as to avoid introducing endogenous adjustments to

hj

in response to

market conditions.8 To do this, we calculate median type and CBSA-speci…c household level
expenditure shares from census micro data and use type-speci…c simple regressions of CBSA
median housing expenditure share on a CBSA home value index to predict

hj .

We choose

to calibrate these parameters rather than estimate them because we are dubious about the
potential to …nd clean identifying variation in house prices required for their estimation, in
our context. More details about our process for constructing

hj

can be found in Sction A.6

of the Data Appendix.
Reintroducing the index j for CBSAs, we can decompose changes in CBD area neighborhood choice probabilities from Equation (5) as follows, where

indicates di¤erentials over

time and d continues to denote di¤erentials across locations at a point in time. To carry
out this decomposition, we allow tract amenities dqij to depend on tract relative income
d ln whij and the group-CBSA-speci…c marginal utility of amenities

hj

to depend on mean

CBSA log income ln whj . We also incorporate the fact that some amenities are observed and
others (most) are unobserved.

(ln

hij )

=[

hj

+[(1 +
+[dqij

hj

dqij
) (d ln whij )]
(d ln w)

hj

ln w

+[dqijobserved (
+[dqijunobserved (
+[

(6)

(d ln pij )]

(ln whj )]
hj j w=0 )]
hj j w=0 )

+

hj

( dqij j

dw=0 )]

hj ]

Equation (6) characterizes a number of channels through which neighborhood choice probabilities may change. Changes in neighborhood choice shares re‡ect shifts in the relative cost
8

Alternative approaches are to instrument for price with attributes of houses and neighborhoods that are
located far away, as in Bayer, Ferreira & MicMillan (2007), or natural amenities, as in Couture & Handbury
(2017).

25

of living, shifts in relative labor market opportunities and the impact of local income on the
quality of local amenities, an income e¤ect for existing local amenities, shifts in the valuation
of existing observed amenities, shifts in valuations of or levels of unobserved amenities and
a CBSA-speci…c trend.
We note that shifts in labor market opportunities
indirect e¤ects on neighborhood demand. Decomposing

(d ln whij ) can have both direct and
(d ln whij ) =

ln whij

ln whi0 j ,

0

where i applies to a composite of other tracts, we have that if i is in the central region, suburban wage growth

ln whi0 j should have the opposite e¤ect as downtown wage growth on

central area labor market opportunities and relative amenity values, as represented in the second term of (6). However, with reverse-commuting possible, income e¤ects from both shocks
should shift the demand for downtown amenities in the same direction. That is, increases
in both downtown and suburban employment opportunities increase mean CBSA incomes,
making the third term in (6) positive if dqij

hj

ln w

> 0. Therefore, our …nding described

below of no impact of CBD-oriented labor demand shocks on downtown choice probabilities
for some groups in some years is evidence that dqij

hj

ln w

is negative, and downtown neighbor-

hood amenities are thus inferior goods in these cases. Equation (6) also takes into account
the possibility that demand shifts by high-SES groups may push up home prices in certain
neighborhoods, thereby dissuading low-SES groups from choosing these neighborhoods even
if their valuations have been rising for other reasons.
In Section 4.4, we empirically implement decompositions motivated by Equation (6).
These exercises take changes in house prices as given, just as households do when they
choose a neighborhood, and decompose the sources of group-speci…c neighborhood demand
shifts into components. Recovering the impacts of deeper shocks that operate through prices
would require us to specify a full general equilibrium model and pin down housing supply
elasticities at the tract level, useful exercises that come with a number of challenges that
have heretofore not been addressed successfully in the literature. Instead, we primarily use
these decompositions to evaluate how important shifts in labor market opportunities could

26

have been relative to shifts in amenity valuations for generating increases in central area
residential demand.9

4.2

Evidence of Relative Demand Shifts for Central Area Neighborhoods

Equation (5) clari…es the existence of equilibrium relationships between decadal changes in
log neighborhood choice probabilities, adjusted for housing cost changes, and factors that
in‡uence labor market opportunities and amenities in each tract. We now look to isolate
the magnitudes of secular relative demand shifts for central neighborhoods and the extent
to which these shifts are driven by observed changes in nearby labor market opportunities
and consumer amenities. To benchmark the size of these group-speci…c demand shifts, we
…rst report summary measures of shifts in neighborhood SES that incorporate information
from all demographic groups simultaneously. We use our index of equally weighted z-scores
built using fraction college educated, fraction white and household income as a summary
measure.
We generalize the logic discussed previously for the Chicago example presented in Figure
3 to each tract in our full sample. In particular, we investigate patterns of changes in
central area tracts’ demographic composition while accounting for CBSA speci…c trends
in neighborhood inequality and observable natural amenities whose valuations may have
changed over time. The following regression equation measures such average di¤erences in
central area neighborhood change relative to other neighborhoods.

Sijt =

9

X
4
d
b
1
+
ln Empdjt + s1t cbddis1ij
jt
d=1 dt cbddisij + 1t cbddisij
X
X
4
d
m
+
m mt ln(amendisij ) + "ijt
d=1 dt topdisij +

ln CBDEmpdjt
(7)

Ouazad & Ranciere (2017) demonstrate how the considerable variation in tract level housing supply
elasticities can in‡uence equilibrium responses to shocks in a model …t to San Francisco Bay Area data.

27

We express

Sijt , the change in tract i’s SES index (in CBSA j at time t) as a function of

CBSA …xed e¤ects (

jt ),

4 km CBD distance ring indicators (cbddisdij ) with the innermost

ring interacted with CBD-oriented ( ln CBDEmpdjt ) and CBSA ( ln Empdjt ) labor demand
shocks (described below), distance bands to top quartile SES tracts in 1970 (topdisdij ) and
log distances to various natural amenities (ln(amendism
ij )), including coastlines, lakes and
rivers. We include controls for natural amenities given evidence in Lee & Lin (2017) that
they "anchor" a- uent neighborhoods, meaning nearby neighborhoods may be less likely to
experience demographic change. The control for distance to top quartile tracts accounts
for the possibility that tracts near CBDs gentri…ed simply because of expansions of nearby
high-income neighborhoods (Guerrieri, Hartley, & Hurst, 2013). We estimate coe¢ cients in
Equation (7) over each decade 1970-2010 and for the full 1980-2010 period. We give equal
weight to each CBSA region within 4 km of a CBD and a separate equal weight to each
residual CBD region (more than 4 km from the CBD). To achieve this, we weight each
tract by

1
# of tracts in CBSA-region

, as explained in the Data Appendix. As a result, each CBSA

contributes equally to identi…cation of key parameters of interest
Panel A of Table 5 reports estimates of

1,

b
1

and

s
1.

1

1,

b
1

and

s 10
1.

describes how much more or

less gentri…cation occurred in tracts within 4 km of CBDs relative to what was typical among
tracts beyond 16 km from the CBD, which is the excluded distance category, quantifying the
patterns seen in Figure 2.

b
1

describes how this gap di¤ered by CBSA employment growth,

ln Empdjt , driven by CBSA labor demand shocks. In most periods, we instrument for
ln Empdjt using a Bartik (1991) type industry shift-share variable, isolating demand shocks
for living in a CBSA that are driven by national trends in industry growth rather than
factors that could be correlated with unobservables driving central neighborhood change.

s
1

describes how SES growth within 4 km of CBDs di¤ered for CBSAs with larger CBD-oriented
labor demand shocks. Here,

ln CBDEmpdjt is the change in employment within 4 km of

10

Giving equal weight to all tracts within each CBSA instead yields quantitatively similar results that are
slightly muted by the fact that smaller CBSAs receive greater weight in the identi…cation of 1t since the
share of tracts within 4 km of the CBD is higher in smaller CBSAs.

28

a CBD.

ln CBDEmpdjt is instrumented with a CBD-oriented industry shift share variable

analogous to the instrument for total CBSA employment growth. We detail the construction
of the Bartik instruments in Section A.5 of the Appendix. So that

1

can be interpreted

as the average demographic change in central area tracts, we standardize

ln Empdjt and

ln CBDEmpdjt and their instruments to have means of 0 and standard deviations of 1.
Since we do not observe the change in employment within 4 km of CBDs before 1990, we
cannot use it as a regressor directly. For this reason (and to maintain consistency across
the two Bartik demand shifters) we estimate reduced forms for the 1970-1980, 1980-1990
and 1980-2010 periods instead of instrumental variable (IV) regressions. Therefore, for these
periods magnitudes of

b
1

and

s
1

do not accurately capture e¤ects of 1 standard deviation

changes in CBSA- and CBD-oriented employment growth, respectively. However, the sign
and signi…cance of these coe¢ cients remain informative. Table A4 reports summary statistics
about these two types of shocks in each decade, allowing for translation into direct e¤ects of
employment changes.
We use employment growth rather than wage or income growth to build predictor variables for both identi…cation and practical reasons. On identi…cation, we have stronger …rst
stages of Bartik employment shocks on CBSA employment growth than we could get for
wages during the 1990s. More critically, our data do not allow for construction of any
measure of CBD-area wage growth for the 1990-2000 period and we can build only a noisy
measure for the 2000-2010 period. To maintain consistency across our two shocks, we thus
found it preferable to consistently use quantities rather than prices, though, of course, the
model is more naturally speci…ed in terms of prices. The regression-based decompositions
we carry out below are not a¤ected by this choice.
The results in Panel A of Table 5 parsimoniously quantify the rebounds experienced by
central neighborhoods as visualized in Figure 2, previewing our estimates from the structural
model. Our estimate of

1

in the …rst row is signi…cantly negative for the 1970s, becomes near

zero for the 1980s and 1990s, and strengthens further in the 2000-2010 period, showing that,

29

on average, central areas experienced 0.15 standard deviations more positive demographic
change than the typical suburban neighborhood. Over the longer 1980-2010 period, central
areas experienced 0.21 standard deviations more positive demographic change relative to
suburban neighborhoods. Due to the interaction terms being normalized to be mean zero
and our tract weighting scheme, the interpretation of this …rst row of coe¢ cients is as an
average across CBSAs.
The second and third rows present estimates of

b
1

and

s
1,

respectively. One consistent

…nding is that central neighborhoods of CBSAs with more robust central area employment
growth experienced relatively more gentri…cation (seen in the positive

s
1

coe¢ cients), even

in the 1970s. However, this phenomenon was strongest in the 2000-2010 period, when 1 standard deviation greater downtown employment growth generated a 0.13 standard deviation
relative increase in central area SES index. (These coe¢ cients only have clean interpretations for the 1990s and 2000s when we can estimate them by IV.) The e¤ects of CBSA
employment growth on downtown neighborhood change depend a lot more on the time period and better track average trends. In the 1970s, central areas of CBSAs with more robust
exogenous employment growth deteriorated more than was typical, whereas by 2000-2010
the reverse was true, though our estimate is not statistically signi…cant. That is, broader
forces bu¤eting central area neighborhoods appear to be reinforced by trends in aggregate
CBSA labor demand shocks. Similar patterns are found separately within each tercile of the
1970 SES index distribution. That is, these results are not only being driven by low-SES
central neighborhoods.
The evidence from Chicago, shown in Figure 3, revealed that neighborhoods experienced
mean reversion in their SES index. This mean reversion is pervasive across CBSAs, and it
may be relevant to our setting because central area tracts disproportionately appear in the
bottom half of the SES index distribution. We account for such potential mean reversion by
including an additional control for Sijt

10

in Equation (7) and consolidate Sijt

10

onto the

right-hand side of the regression equation. This yields an AR(1) speci…cation with CBSA

30

…xed e¤ects fully interacted with the lagged SES index. This speci…cation generates regression lines for each CBSA*decade combination analogous to those in Figure 3 for Chicago.

0
jt

Sijt =

+
+

+

0
jt Sijt 10

b0
1
1t cbddisij

X

4
d=1

+

X

4
d=1

0
d
dt cbddisij
0

ln Empdjt + s1t cbddis1ij ln CBDEmpdjt
X
0
0
0
m
d
+
topdis
m mt ln(amendisij ) + "ijt
ij
dt

(8)

These regressions feature the same remaining set of regressors as in (7). Table 5, Panel B
reports estimates of coe¢ cients in Equation (8).
The results in Panel B of Table 5 are quite similar to those in Panel A. Whichever assumption we impose about the underlying data-generating process, three main facts persist.
First, there is a clear statistically meaningful demographic rebound of central neighborhoods
in the 2000-2010 period. Second, central area employment growth bolstered central neighborhood demographic change, especially in the 1970-1980 and 2000-2010 periods. Third,
CBSA employment growth bolstered central neighborhoods only in the 2000-2010 period,
when the neighborhoods were changing for other reasons.
While the empirical approach used in Panel B addresses mean reversion, it is well known
that in short panels OLS estimates of
in‡uence coe¢ cients of interest

1,

b
1

jt

may be biased downward. Such "Hurwicz bias" will

and

s
1

if the lagged SES index is correlated with CBD

distance, which is likely as near-CBD areas are more likely to be poor - the whole justi…cation
for exploring this speci…cation from the start. To deal with this bias, we experimented with
implementing a standard Arellano-Bond (1991) type correction. Beginning with Equation
(8), impose that

jt

=

jt 1

and, without loss of generality, add a Census tract …xed e¤ect.

31

First-di¤erencing yields the following equation:

Sijt =

00
jt

+
+

+

00
jt

Sijt

b00
1
1t cbddisij

X

4
d=1

1

+

X

4
d=1

d
00
dt cbddisij

1
ln Empdjt + s00
ln CBDEmpdjt
1t cbddisij
X
00
00
m
00
d
topdis
+
m mt ln(amendisij ) + "ijt
dt
ij

As in the standard Arellano-Bond (1991) procedure, we instrument for

Sijt

(9)

1

with Sijt 2 .

Unfortunately, this procedure did not generate su¢ ciently precise estimates to merit reporting them. However, the coe¢ cients are similar to those reported in Panel B of Table
5.11
Overall, the evidence in Table 5, as well as facts about central area employment growth,
indicates that the bulk of 2000-2010 downtown gentri…cation could not have been driven
by shifts in the spatial structure of labor demand. With 2000-2010 CBD area employment
growth averaging -1 percent across CBSAs, downtown neighborhood growth must have come
about for other reasons in most CBSAs, with improvements in the relative amenity values
of downtown neighborhoods appearing to be the most logical mechanism.12

4.3

13

Using the Model

Figure 4 gives a sense of how tract valuations,

t
hi

from Equation (5) have changed since 1980

as functions of CBD distance for four demographic groups (one in each panel). It shows the
average change across CBSAs in calibrated versions of
The calculated valuation changes,
11

t
hi

for 0.5 km CBD distance rings.

bt , are constructed using tract choice shares, housing
hij

As an alternative for examining the impact of mean reversion, we generated results as in Panel A of
Table 5 for tracts in terciles of the 1970 SES distribution. We get similar results for the top and bottom
terciles, further evidence that mean reversion is not driving the results.
12
Regression results analogous to those in Table 5 using an index of tract housing value growth rates as
the dependent variable give similar results. These results appear in Table A5.
13
Edlund, Machado, & Sviatchi (2015) …nd that 26 large CBSAs with stronger skilled labor Bartik shocks
experienced more rapid decadal central home price growth and demographic change in central areas than
other areas of the city. These patterns are replicated in our data as well if census tracts are equally weighted,
giving greater weight to larger CBSAs.

32

expenditure shares and home price indexes. Figure 4 shows that college whites and blacks
and high school dropout whites and blacks all experienced rising valuations of neighborhoods
within 2 km of CBDs after 2000, though the estimates for the blacks are much noisier given
their small population shares. However, comparing results in Panel A to those in other panels
reveals that college whites have valuations that increase the most over the broadest distance
range, out to about 3 km from CBDs. Next, we evaluate the drivers of these changes and
their implications for central area population and demographic changes.
We investigate the extent to which CBSA-level and localized labor demand shocks have
driven changes in neighborhood valuations using regression equations similar to Equation
(8) for each demographic group, separately. We think of CBD-oriented and CBSA-oriented
t
, as is laid out in Equation (6). We report IV
labor demand shocks as in‡uencing d ln whi

regression results from estimating the following equation for the 1990-2000 and 2000-2010
periods, since we only observe the change in employment near CBDs starting in 1990. For
other time periods, we report the reduced form. The speci…cation is as follows:
bt

hij

=

X
4
d
b
1
+
ln Empjt + ash1t cbddis1ij
hjt
d=1 ahdt cbddisij + ah1t cbddisij
X
X
m
4
d
b
topdis
+
+
m chmt ln(amendisij ) + ehijt :
hdt
d=1
ij

ln CBDEmpjt
(10)

This estimation equation is the empirical analog to a time-di¤erenced version of Equation
P
(5). hjt accounts for the intercept I1 i0 ln( thi0 ) + (ln wht ln wht ), and the remaining terms
allow us to measure variation in tract-level labor market opportunities and local amenities
relative to those in the average location. Here, we no longer impose that

ln Empjt and

ln CBDEmpjt have means of 0, though we maintain standard deviations of 1. As a result,
ahdt represents average demand shifts for central neighborhoods that occur for unobserved
reasons only. Because we use these coe¢ cient estimates to perform a uni…ed accounting of
mechanisms driving central neighborhood change, we need a consistent sample over time for
each demographic group. To achieve this, we only use tracts with nonzero choice shares in

33

all years 1980-2010 by type h for the estimation of Equation (10) for type h. Observations
are weighted analogously to those in Table 5 except for the sample di¤erence. See Section
A.4 of the Appendix for details.
There are two potential concerns with using Equation (10) to infer reasons for changes
in neighborhood valuations. First is the issue of whether we have accurately measured
housing costs. To get around this, instead of Equation (10) one could estimate a uni…ed
equation for all household types simultaneously with type by tract …xed e¤ects, similar to
Ellickson’s (1981) procedure. Because the housing cost is common across types, the tract
…xed e¤ect would control for these costs if the housing expenditure share were the same for
all types. The costs of this approach are that the absolute change in tract valuation is lost
to a normalization, meaning that one can only recover relative changes in tract valuations
across demographic groups, and that housing expenditure shares empirically di¤er across
groups. Our experimentation with such uni…ed regression speci…cations yield very similar
conclusions about relative changes in central area tract valuations across demographic groups
to the results reported in Table 6 without the need to impose these two additional constraints.
In addition to providing evidence about the mechanisms driving shifts in central area
valuations, we use the estimates of the coe¢ cients in Equation (10) to carry out uni…ed
decompositions of the mechanisms driving the numbers reported in Columns 5-8 of Table 2.
These decompositions require us to be able to calculate neighborhood choice probabilities
for each demographic group for each tract in each sample year under various counterfactual
scenarios. Since the analysis is carried out in logs, there is an issue of what to do about
neighborhoods with zero choice shares. Our solution is to exclude any tract from the estimation sample if it had a zero neighborhood choice share in any year 1980-2010, applying
this rule separately by demographic group. While this restriction means we do not use potentially useful information about increasing group demand for tracts going from zero to
positive choice shares and vice versa, it is needed to use these results to carry out decompositions that apply to a consistent geography over time. As a robustness check, we estimate

34

versions using a data set in which all tracts within 2 km CBD bands are combined into a
single observation per group per CBSA. The results using this aggregate data set are very
similar to the results presented in Table 6.
The results in Table 6 show that each group’s demand for central area residency is typically estimated to respond positively to central area employment shocks, particularly in the
2000-2010 period (3rd row of each panel).14 Commensurate with our discussion of Equation
(6), the associated coe¢ cients re‡ect some combination of improved job opportunities, improved local amenities and income e¤ects on existing local amenities. Given stability of the
standard deviation of the central area employment shock decade to decade, it is more likely
that shifts in dqij

hj

ln w

rather than

hj

dqij
(d ln w)

cause these coe¢ ciencts to grow, since dqij

can change sign over time. Increases in this coe¢ cient from the 1990s to the 2000s, which
occurred for all groups, thus likely indicates an increase in income e¤ects on downtown
neighborhood amenities, with a particularly strong increase for college educated whites.
Conditional on nearby labor market opportunities, rising 2000-2010 CBSA employment
drove suburbanization for all but college educated whites (2nd row of each panel). While
the responses to CBSA employment shocks are mixed across groups in the 1990s (and not
statistically signi…cant in any case), in the 1980s, each group’s central neighborhood demand
is estimated to respond negatively to CBSA employment shocks. Once again, Taken together,
this evidence is also consistent with a narrative in which central neighborhood amenities
were mostly inferior goods for all groups prior to 1990, but became normal goods for college
educated whites after 2000, meaning that dqij for central area tracts likely increased from a
negative base in 1980.
The coe¢ cients in the top row of each panel of Table 6 corroborate this narrative. They
indicate the additional changes in central area demands that are due to unobserved amenities
holding incomes constant, or dqijunobserved (

hj j w=0 )

14

+

hj

( dqij j

dw=0 ).

These estimates

To connect these estimates directly to the model, one could rescale these estimates by the (unknown)
elasticity of labor supply to a CBSA region. Expressing labor demand shocks in terms of quantities rather
than prices does not a¤ect our calculations below of the relative quantitative importance of mechanisms
driving changes in neighborhood choice probabilities.

35

are consistently negative across groups in the 1980s, increasing to zero or positive by the
2000-2010 period with a particularly large increase for white college graduates. Therefore, a
greater taste for amenities

hj

by white college graduates coupled with increases in central

neighborhood amenity values for reasons other than income changes would generate the
observed patterns in the data.
The results for whites and blacks who completed high school but not college (not reported
in Table 6) are in between the college graduate and high school dropout results for each race.
Conditional on educational attainment, the results for the "other" demographic group are
between those for whites and blacks, though somewhat more similar to those for whites. We
also performed the same exercise as in Table 6 using income deciles instead of education
groups, and found results similar to those in Table 6. The background changes in central
neighborhood valuations improved more for the high income deciles than for the low income
deciles, but only turned signi…cantly positive after 2000 for high-income whites, not blacks.

4.4

Decompositions of Shifts in Neighborhood Choices

With education-race speci…c estimates from Equation (10) in hand, we combine insights from
the model with estimates similar to those in Table 6 for each education-race group to generate
uni…ed decompositions of the relative importance of various mechanisms driving shifts in
downtown neighborhood choices. This exercise decomposes the contributions of shifts in
neighborhood choices by the four education-race groups to central neighborhood population
change, reported in Columns 5-8 of Table 2, into 6 components: home price changes, CBDoriented labor demand shocks, CBSA labor demand shocks, central area …xed e¤ects, and a
residual. Combining Equations (5) and (10), we have the following decomposition of shifts

36

in the log share of group h choosing to live in census tract i

ln

t
hij

=

s
1
h1t cbddisij

+
+
+

The parameters

s
h1t ,

d ln ptij

hj

hX

hX

b
h1t ,

4
d=1
4
d=1

hdt ,

ln CBDEmpjt + bh1t cbddis1ij ln Empjt
i
X
d
m
topdis
+
ln(amendis
)
m
hmt
hdt
ij
ij
i
t
d
hdt cbddisij + ["hijt ] + ehj

hmt ,

t
hj

and

hdt

(11)

are estimated in the context of Equation

(10), as reported for four of the 12 race-education groups in Table 6, while

hj

is calibrated

as described in Section 4.1. We use observed values for all variables on the right hand
side of Equation (11). The normalization ethj ensures that the sum of neighborhood choice
probabilities for group h in CBSA j sum to 1 in each year.

Each bracketed term in (11) has a substantive interpretation in the context of Equation
(6) from the model, where each parameter should be interpreted as an average for central
areas across CBSAs. We recognize that some of these objects may move in tandem because
of external shocks. For example, a positive productivity shock in the …nance industry may
increase both CBSA and near CBD employment in New York relative to other cities and also
result in a rise in housing prices near the CBD. Callibrating the coe¢ cients

hj

on

d ln ptij

means that the impacts of changes in house prices on neighborhood demand are imposed
as if

d ln ptij were independent of employment shocks. Our estimation of coe¢ cients on

employment growth incorporates endogenous relationships between employment growth and
changes in housing costs but imposes independence of the two employment shocks for identi…cation. In the decomposition, we use the actual values of

ln CBDEmpjt and

ln Empjt ,

rather than their exogenous (instrumented) components used for estimation. As a result,
the residual term ["hijt ] is not mean 0 for central areas; instead, its mean is an indicator of
the decomposition bias due to general equilibrium e¤ects.
To carry out the decompositions, we construct a series of counterfactual census tract

37

choice shares for each education-race group in 2000 and 2010, taking 1980 and 2000 neighborhood choice shares as given. To build counterfactual group-speci…c year 2000 neighborhood choice shares (denoted

2000;1
,
hij

2000;2
,
hij

etc.), we apply the regression results from the

1980s and the 1990s sequentially. Since we do not observe central area employment growth
between 1980 and 1990, yet reduced form coe¢ cients on the CBD-oriented Bartik variable
are close to zero and statistically insigni…cant for all groups, we set

s
h1t

in Equation (10) to

zero and estimate the resulting equation by IV for the 1980s (instrumenting for

ln Empjt ).

For the following decades, we estimate Equation (10) by IV, as speci…ed, for each group.
Counterfactual neighborhood choice shares incorporate each component described in
Equation (11), one by one. For example, counterfactual 2010 neighborhood choice shares
that only incorporate 2000-2010 housing price changes are calculated as
2010;1
hij

= s2010;1
hj

2000
hij e

h

d ln ptij

.

(12)

In this expression, s2010;1
is a group-CBSA speci…c scale factor that is set to ensure that
hj
group-speci…c neighborhood choice shares sum to 1 within each CBSA. Counterfactual 2010
neighborhood choice shares that incorporate additional mechanisms include additional components of Equation (11) in the exponential component of Equation (12). For each set of
counterfactual choices

y;c
hij ,

we form a data set and recalculate Columns 5-8 of Table 2 using

each of these counterfactual data sets.
Table 7 presents the components of population growth within 2 km (left side) or 4 km
(right side) of CBDs driven by changes in neighborhood choices of each indicated demographic group, holding demographic shares constant. Each entry can be interpreted as the
impact of the indicated force listed at left on the shift in central neighborhood choices for
the group listed in the column heading on the average change in central area population,
expressed in growth rates. The entries in the "Total" row do not exactly match the numbers
in Columns 5-8 of Table 2 because the sample used to estimate the components in Table 7 is

38

slightly more restrictive than the full set of tracts used to construct the numbers in Table 2.
For Table 7, we exclude 3 CBSAs for which we have no information on observed amenities.
When generating inputs to Table 7 for demographic group, h, we also exclude any tract
with zero population of that group in any year from 1980 through 2010. Each component
listed in the table corresponds to a term in brackets in Equation (11) in the same order.
The entries are calculated in the following manner. First, we estimate separate regressions
using Equation (10), like those used to create Table 6, for each decade and narrowly de…ned
education-race group. Then, the components are cumulatively added to log neighborhood
choices shares from the base year following Equation (11), exponentiated and normalized to
sum to 1 across Census tracts for each demographic group in each CBSA. The results are
expressed as marginal contributions of each listed mechanism to the component of central
area population growth that is due to shifts in the indicated demographic group’s change in
neighborhood choices.
The results in Panel A of Table 7 indicate that improving CBSA employment opportunities was the largest force driving 1980-2000 central area population declines. This force was
the most important driver of central area departures for all groups except educated minorities, accounting for 15 and 10 percentage point declines in central area population through
impacts on less educated minorities’ and less educated whites’ neighborhood choices, respectively. While rising suburban employment opportunities may have drawn these groups
to the suburbs, their responses may also indicate that attributes of downtown neighborhoods were inferior goods for these groups relative to suburban neighborhoods, or that
dqCBDj

hj

(d ln w)

< 0. The impacts of declining central area employment were slightly negative

for less educated whites and slightly positive for less educated minorities, which is consistent
with o¤setting e¤ects of reduced job opportunities and downtown neighborhoods being an
inferior good. Reductions in the valuation or quality of unoberved amenities represented
the second most important driver of 1980-2000 central area population decline. They accounted for central area population declines of 3 percentage points because of impacts on

39

less educated whites’ and 4 percentage points due to impacts on less educated minorities’
neighborhood choices. We …nd a minimal role for shifting housing costs. General equilibrium e¤ects (captured in the "unexplained" component) are not large enough to a¤ect our
conclusions about the main drivers of 1980-2000 shifts in neighborhood choices for any group.
The results in Panel B indicate important shifts in the relative importance of mechanisms
driving 2000-2010 central area population growth as compared to the prior period. Changes
in the valuation of- and/or levels of- unobserved amenities becomes the most important
force, quantitatively, for college and less than college whites, and this e¤ect turns positive,
accounting for 1.6 and 2.4 points of 2000-2010 central area population growth through the
changing neighborhood choices of these two groups, respectively. Only less than college
educated minorities continued to value these unobserved amenity changes negatively, and less
so than in the prior period. Also notable is the almost zero e¤ect of central area employment
growth and that CBSA employment growth only continues to impact departures of less than
college minorities after 2000, at 5 percentage points out of their 8 percentage point impact on
2000-2010 central area population declines. Commensurate with our discussion of the results
in Table 6, this is evidence that the income elasticity of demand for downtown amenities
had grown, and likely turned positive for whites. It is only logical that downtown living
was a normal good for those groups that experienced 2000-2010 growth in the valuation of
unobserved amenities.
The evidence for areas within 4 km of CBDs, reported in the right block of Table 7,
is very much in line with that for areas within 2 km of CBDs. Put together, the evidence
shows a turnaround in the valuation of central neighborhood amenities by whites, and college
educated whites in particular, with continued declines in valuation of central neighborhoods
among less educated minorities.15
15

The results in Tables 6 and 7 use regressions that weight the central area of each CBSA equally. If
we instead weight each tract equally, thereby giving more weight to smaller CBSAs, we …nd similar results
except that CBSA employment growth drives increases in college whites’ 2000-2010 central neighborhood
choices rather than unobserved amenities. This is an additional indication that central area neighborhood
amenities are normal or even luxury goods for this group in this time period.

40

5

Conclusions

Neighborhoods near central business districts of U.S. metropolitan areas have experienced
remarkable rebounds in population and their residents’socioeconomic status since 2000. Our
decompositions reveal that this turnaround in population has primarily been driven by the
return of college-graduate and high-income whites to these neighborhoods, coupled with a
halt in the out‡ows of other white demographic groups. At the same time, the departures
of minorities without college degrees continued unabated.
Estimates from our neighborhood choice model indicate that better nearby labor market
opportunities draw in residents, but conditional on such opportunities higher incomes only
draw in more college graduates to central neighborhoods in the 2000-2010 period. However,
we …nd that most groups except less than college educated minorities experienced growth in
their valuations of central area unobserved amenities in the 2000-2010 period after declines
in the 1980-2000 period. Decompositions of the mechanisms driving central area population
change reveal that 1980-2000 suburban employment growth and reductions in the quality of
central neighborhood amenities were the most important drivers of these areas’population
declines. For the 2000-2010 period, low SES minorities continued departures from central
neighborhoods were driven by suburban opportunities, while the newly positive impacts of
unobserved amenities was most important for other groups. While all groups value improved
downtown labor market opportunities, the average CBSA experienced declining downtown
employment in the 1990s and essentially no change in downtown employment in the 20002010 period. As a result, shifts in central area labor market opportunities had a miminal
impact on central area population changes since 2000, though the stabilization of downtown
employment declines represents a force that promoted post-2000 stabilization, after 19802000 downtown population declines, among less educated whites.
The gentri…cation of cities’ central neighborhoods inverts the decentralization of highincome whites that had been occurring for decades prior to 1980. This represents a fundamental change in the demographic structure of cities, for which this paper provides only a
41

starting point from which to build a deeper understanding. This phenomenon may be the
beginning of an urban rebirth with many broader consequences for the economy. It may
also exacerbate the rise in real income inequality that has occurred over recent decades, as
it is a mechanism through which the cost of living may be rising for the poor. A general
equilibrium framework which incorporates housing supply is required to recover information
about associated welfare consequences. Developing such a framework which could be used
to evaluate the welfare consequences of gentri…cation for poor incumbents is a particularly
fruitful area for future research.

A

Data Appendix

A large portion of the data used in our analysis come from tract-level tabulations from the
Decennial Census of Population and Housing for the years 1970, 1980, 1990, and 2000, and
from the American Community Survey (ACS) for the years 2008-2012. We use census tract
boundaries from the 2000 census. We begin with the normalized data provided in Geolytics’
1970-2000 Neighborhood Change Database (NCDB) which provides a subset of the tractlevel tabulation variables available from the 1970, 1980, 1990, and 2000 censuses normalized
to year 2000 tract boundaries. We augment this data with other tract-level tabulations
from these censuses that are not available in the NCDB and tract-level estimates from the
2008-2012 ACS. In these cases, we perform normalizations to 2000 tract boundaries using
the appropriate census tract relationship …les provided by the U.S. Census Bureau.

A.1

Tract-level Sample

Our sample includes all of the 2008 de…nition Core Based Statistical Areas (CBSAs) that
had a population of at least 250,000 in the area that was tracted in 1970 except Honolulu.16
16
Since we are using year 2000 tract boundaries, we limit our sample slightly further by using only tracts
for which 100% of the 2000 de…nition tract was tracted in 1970.

42

Our sample consists of 120 CBSAs and 39,087 year 2000 census tracts.17 The CBSAs in the
sample can be seen in Figure 1.
A.1.1

1970, 1990, and 2000 Tract Data

We take these directly from the Neighborhood Change Database (NCDB) STF3A tabulations.
A.1.2

1980 Tract Data

We read in these data from the summary tape …le 4 …les. This allows us to incorporate
household income distributions by race and age by race into the data set. It also facilitates
imposing various appropriate adjustments for suppression that are not handled well in the
NCDB.
Suppression results in undercounting of whites and blacks in various tables. To handle
this, we use tract-level full population or household counts of whites, blacks and others
to form in‡ation factors. We calculate in‡ation factors that scale up the total number of
people in each age, education, family type or income bin in the STF4A data to equal the
total reported in the NCDB data.
In particular, in the case of age, when the 1980 STF4A tract tabulations by race and age
do not sum to the total population, we implement the following algorithm:
1. In‡ate the total in each age bin so that the total of the age bins sums to the total
population in the NCDB data.
2. Calculate other race in each age bin by taking the total population in each age bin
and subtract the white and black population of that age bin from the STF4A.
17

For CBSAs that are split into Metropolitan Divisions, we treat each Division as a separate entity except in the following 4 cases in which we combine Metropolitan Divisions. The 4 cases are as follows: 1)
Bethesda-Rockville-Frederick, MD, is combined with Washington-Arlington-Alexandria, DC-VA-MD-WV;
2) Cambridge-Newton-Framingham, MA, and Peabody, MA Metropolitan Divisions are combined with
Boston-Quincy, MA; 3) Nassau-Su¤olk, NY, is combine with New York-White Plains-Wayne, NY-NJ; and
4) Warren-Troy-Farmington Hills, MI, is combined with Detroit-Livonia-Dearborn, MI.

43

3. Calculate the number of whites and blacks that are missing in the STF4A data by
summing across the age bins for white and for black and subtracting the totals from the
NCDB totals.
4. Calculate the number of people missing from each age bin by subtracting the STF4A
total (that uses the recalculated other category) from the NCDB total.
5. In‡ate the number of others in each age bin by the ratio of the NCDB other total to
the STF4A other total.
6. Calculate the residual number of blacks and whites missing from each age bin by
subtracting the in‡ated other from the in‡ated total for the age bin.
7. Reassign the residual number of blacks and whites missing from each age bin to either
the white or black count in proportion to the share of the total missing that white and black
make up as calculated in 3.
We perform the same process for education and family type in 1980.
A.1.3

2010 Census and ACS

We use the 2010 census summary tape …le 1 for information about age and household structure by race. Because of the lack of a census long form in 2010, we are forced to use the
ACS to measure joint distributions of race by education and race by income.

A.2

Procedure for Allocating Income To Percentile Bins

The counterfactual analysis uses 10 household income deciles, with dollar cuto¤s calculated
using census micro data for the CBSAs in our sample. In each year, the census tract data
reports the number of households by race in each of up to 20 income bins bounded by …xed
dollar cuto¤s. To re-allocate into percentile bins, we assume a uniform distribution within
each dollar value bin except the top one. For the top one, we use a Pareto distribution with
parameters estimated separately for each year using census micro data.

44

A.3

Central Business District De…nitions

For each of our 120 CBSAs, we de…ne the Central Business District (CBD) of the CBSA as
that of the most populous Census place within the CBSA based on the year 2000 population.
We make two exceptions to this rule based on our knowledge of the cities. For the Santa
Barbara-Santa Maria-Goleta, CA Metropolitan Statistical Area we use the Santa Barbara
CBD rather than the Santa Maria CBD even though Santa Maria was more populous in 2000
than Santa Barbara. For the Virginia Beach-Norfolk-Newport News, VA-NC Metropolitan
Statistical Area we use the Norfolk CBD rather than the Virginia Beach CBD. For 113 of
the our 120 CBSAs we were able to determine the CBD of the most populous city from the
1982 Census of Retail Trade. We use the latitude and longitude of the centroid of the tract
or tracts speci…ed as CBD tracts. For the remaining 7 CBSAs, we used the latitude and
longitude as designated by the mapping software maker ESRI.18

A.4

Construction of Weights

The regressions in Tables 5 and 6 give equal weight to each CBSA region within 4 km of a
CBD and each region beyond 4 km, provided that valid data exists in the region in question.
For Table 5, the tract-level weight is:

weight5ijr =

X Njr

1
J

j

Nj

!

1
Njr

where i indexes tract in ring r (< 4 km from CBD or > 4 km from CBD) and CBSA j.
Njr is the number of tracts in ring r of CBSA j and Nj is the total number of tracts in
CBSA j.
For Table 6, the tract level weight is analogous except only tracts with at least some
people from the demographic group in each year 1980-2010 are included in the sample. All
18

These 7 cities are Duluth, MN, Edison, NJ, Indianapolis, IN, Jacksonville, FL, Nashville, TN, and York,
PA. Manual inspection of these 7 cities revealed CBD placement where we would expect it. Also, for the
113 cities where we have both Census of Retail Trade and Esri CBD de…nitions, the points line up closely.

45

other tracts get zero weight. Denote Njr as the number of tracts in ring r of CBSA j with
at least 1 resident of type h in each year 1980-2010.

weight6ijhr

1
=
J

h
X Njr
j

Njh

!

1
h
Njr

h
For some smaller groups in a few smaller CBSAs, Njr
= 0. In this case, all tracts in area jr

are assigned 0 weight.

A.5

Bartik Instrument Construction

We construct two Bartik instruments from several data sources. We label these instruments
“Employment Bartik" and “Spatial Employment Bartik."
The “Employment Bartik" attempts to predict CBSA-level employment growth for each
of the 4 decades using initial year employment shares and decadal employment growth (implemented as changes in log employment levels) with 10 broad industry categories that can
be consistently constructed from 1970 through 2010 using the county-level U.S. Census and
ACS tabulations. The 10 industry categories are: 1) Agriculture, forestry, …sheries, and
mining; 2) Construction; 3) Manufacturing; 4) Wholesale trade; 5) Retail trade; 6) Transportation, communication, other public utilities, and information; 7) Finance, insurance,
and real estate; 8) Services; 9) Public administration; and 10) Military. We refer to these as
1-digit industry categories. This measure uses the exact geographical boundaries included in
each of our CBSA de…nitions over the entire time period. The Bartik instrument for CBSA
j that applies to the period t

10 to t is constructed as

Bartikjt =

X

Sjk1970 ln(empktj =empktj

10 );

k

where Sjk1970 is the fraction of employment in CBSA j that is in industry k in 1970 and
empktj is national employment in industry k at time t excluding CBSA j.

46

The aim of the “Spatial Employment Bartik" is to predict which CBSAs might be particularly a¤ected near the CBD by national industry growth. To construct this index, we
calculate the share of employment located within 4 km of the CBD made up by each industry
for each CBSA using the year 1990 Census Transportation Planning Package. We take these
shares and interact them with the national growth rate of that industry to form a spatial
or CBD-focused Bartik instrument. Ideally, we would calculate the shares in each initial
year, 1970, 1980, 1990, and 2000. However, the data are only available starting in 1990.
Therefore, we use the 1990 1-digit industry distribution as the base. For CBSA j, denote
emp
emp
the fraction of employment near the CBD in industry k in 1990 as fjk
. We think of fjk

as being driven by the interaction of fundamental attributes of the production process like
the importance of agglomeration spillovers to total factor productivity (TFP). Therefore, we
predict the change in the fraction of employment near the CBD to be

Spatbartikjt =

X

emp
fjk
ln(empktj =empktj

10 ):

k

A.6

Construction of Housing Expenditure Shares

To construct estimates of

hj

hj

(type and CBSA-speci…c housing expenditure shares) we use

the 1980 Census 5% public use microdata sample. We begin with a sample of renters and
owner-occupier households with a mortgage that moved in the 5 years leading up to 1980
and are not living in group quarters. This group experiences housing costs that are closest
to 1980 market conditions. We include all mortgage payments, rent, utilities and insurance
in housing costs. We trim the 1st and 99th percentiles of housing cost and the 1st and 99th
percentiles of household income and take their ratio to calculate the housing expenditure
share for each household. Next, we calculate the median expenditure share for each race educational attainment - CBSA cell. Since some of the cell sizes are quite small we use the
predicted values from a linear regressions of housing expenditure shares on a CBSA home
value index within each race - educational attainment combination. The resulting housing
47

expenditure shares range from 0.20 to 0.37.

B

Construction of Counterfactuals in Table 4

We calculate changes in central areas’white and college-graduate shares using the following
expressions, respectively. The associated results appear in rows 1-3 of each panel of Table 4.
1X
J j
1X
J j

P P
x

i CBDj

P P P
x

P P

r

P P

fjtc (i; r = w; x)

i CBDj

x

i CBDj

P P P

fjtc (i; r; x)

x

r

P P

c
r
i CBD fjt (i; r; x = col)
P P P j
c
x
r
i CBDj fjt (i; r; x)

fjb (i; r = w; x)

i CBDj

fjb (i; r; x)

!

r
i CBD fjb (i; r; x = col)
P P P j
x
r
i CBDj fjb (i; r; x)

!

(13)

:

(14)

In these expressions, x indexes education group or income decile as indicated in the row label
of Table 4. i

CBDj indicates a summation only over tracts within 2 or 4 km of CBSA j’s

CBD. The reference change for both outcomes is zero (Column 2 of Table 4), since there is
no scale component.
The remaining rows in Table 4 report counterfactual changes in central area median
household income. We use median rather than mean income in order to be more robust in
avoiding misallocating households into incorrect income deciles.19 To see how these medians
are constructed, begin with the following expression for the cumulative distribution function
of CBSA j’s central area households across income deciles x
X hP P
r

Gcjt (X)

x X

= P P P
x

r

i

f1; 2; :::; 10g.

i
c
f
(i;
r;
x)
CBDj jt

i CBDj

fjtc (i; r; x)

.

The income deciles are de…ned for the full national study area, but here we only focus on
the cumulative distribution function (cdf) for central neighborhoods under counterfactual
c
c. Using these distributions over deciles x, we identify the deciles Djt
that contain 0:5. We
19

Since the cuto¤s associated with each decile do not match the dollar cuto¤s in the tract data, we assume
uniform distributions within census data dollar bands for allocation purposes. Section A.2 of the Appendix
details our procedure for allocating households to income deciles.

48

assign the median percentile assuming a uniform distribution of household income within
c
c
Djt
. For example, if Gcjt (2) = 0:45 and Gcjt (3) = 0:55, Djt
= 3. In this case, we would

assign the median household income Mjtc in CBSA j at time t under counterfactual c to be
25, representing the 25th percentile of the full study area’s household income distribution.
Then, the statistics reported in Table 4 are
1X
Mjtc
J j

Mjb :

(15)

As a result, positive numbers in Table 4 mean that the counterfactual in question pushed
central area median incomes up by the indicated number of percentile points out of the
national urban household income distribution.
References
Ahlfeldt, Gabriel, Stephen Redding, Daniel Sturm, Nikolaus Wolf (2015) "The Economics
of Density: Evidence from the Berlin Wall," Econometrica 83(6): 2127-2189.
Altonji, Joseph, Ulrich Doraszelski, and Lewis Segal (2000) “Black/White Di¤erences in
Wealth,”Economic Perspectives, Vol. 24(1): 38–50.
Arellano, Manuel, and Stephen Bond (1991) "Some tests of speci…cation for panel data:
Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations." The Review of Economic Studies 58.2, 277-297.
Bartik, Timothy (1991) Who Bene…ts from State and Local Economic Development Policies? Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research.
Baum-Snow, Nathaniel (2007) “Did Highways Cause Suburbanization?”Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(2), 775-805.
Baum-Snow (2017) “Urban Transport Expansions, Employment Decentralization, and
the Spatial Scope of Agglomeration Economies,”manuscript.
Bayer, Patrick, Fernando Ferreira & Robert McMillan (2007) “A Uni…ed Framework for
Measuring Preferences for Schools and Neighborhoods”Journal of Political Economy 115(4):
49

588-638.
Bayer, Patrick, Robert McMillan, Alvin Murphy, & Christopher Timmins (2016) “A
Dynamic Model of Demand for Houses and Neighborhoods.”Econometrica, 84(3): 893-942.
Berry, Steven (1994) “Estimating Discrete-Choice Models of Product Di¤erentiation,”
The RAND Journal of Economics, 25 (2), 242–262
Boustan, L.P. (2010) "Was Postwar Suburbanization "White Flight"? Evidence from the
Black Migration." Quarterly Journal of Economics 125.1: 417–43.
Brueckner, J. K., & Rosenthal, S. S. (2009) "Gentri…cation and neighborhood housing
cycles: will America’s future downtowns be rich?" The Review of Economics and Statistics,
91(4), 725-743.
Card, David, Alex Mas & Jesse Rothstein (2008) "Tipping and the Dynamics of Segregation," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123 (1): 177-218.
Carrillo, Paul & Jonathan Rothbaum (2016) "Counterfactual Spatial Distributions,"
Journal of Regional Science, 56(5): 868-894.
Couture, Victor and Jessie Handbury (2017) "Urban Revival in America, 2000 to 2010,"
manuscript.
DiNardo, John, Nicole Fortin and Thomas Lemieux (1996) "Labor Market Institutions,
and the Distribution of Wages 1973-1992: A Semiparametric Approach," Econometrica, 64,
1001-1044.
Edlund, Lena, Cecilia Machado & Michaela Sviatchi (2015) "Bright Minds, Big Rent:
Gentri…cation and the Rising Returns to Skill," NBER Working Paper #21729.
Guerrieri, Veronica, Daniel Hartley and Erik Hurst (2013) “Endogenous Gentri…cation
and Housing Price Dynamics,”Journal of Public Economics, 100, 45-60.
Hotz, V. Joseph and Robert A. Miller (1993) "Conditional Choice Probabilities and the
Estimation of Dynamic Models," Review of Economic Studies, 60(3), 497-529.
Jackson, Kenneth (1985) Crabgrass Frontier: The Suburbanization of the United States,
Oxford University Press, New York.

50

Kain, John F. (1992) “The Spatial Mismatch Hypothesis: Three Decades Later,”Housing
Policy Debate, 3:2, 371-462.
Lee, Sanghoon & Je¤rey Lin (2017) “Natural Amenities, Neighborhood Income Dynamics, and Persistence in the Spatial Income Distribution,”Review of Economic Studies, forthcoming.
Margo, Robert (1992) "Explaining the postwar suburbanization of population in the
United States: The role of income," Journal of Urban Economics 31(3): 301-310.
McKinnish, Terra, Randall Walsh & T. Kirk White (2010) "Who Gentri…es Low-Income
Neighborhoods?" Journal of Urban Economics 67: 180-193.
Ouazad, Amine & Romain Ranciere (2017) "City Equilibrium with Borrowing Constraints: Structural Estimation and General Equilibrium E¤ects," manuscript.
Roback, Jennifer. 1982. “Wages, Rents, and the Quality of Life.” Journal of Political
Economy, 90: 1257-1278.
Rosen, Sherwin. 1979. “Wages-based Indexes of Urban Quality of Life.” In Current
Issues in Urban Economics, edited by P. Mieszkowski and M. Straszheim. Baltimore: Johns
Hopkins Univ. Press.
Saiz, Albert (2010) “The Geographic Determinants of Housing Supply”Quarterly Journal
of Economics, 125(3):1253-1296.

51

Figure 1: Share Within 4 km of the CBD in a Top Half SES Distribution Census Tract
1980

2010

1980-2010 Change

Figure 2: Measures of Gentrification as a Function of CBD Distance (km)
Medians Across 120 CBSAs, 0.5 km CBD Distance Bands
Panel A: Percent Change in Population
0.4

1970-1980
1980-1990

0.2

2000-2010

1990-2000

0

-0.2

0

4

8

12

16

20

Panel B: Change in Fraction White
0.025

2000-2010

0
-0.025

1980-1990

-0.05
-0.075

1990-2000

1970-1980

-0.1

0

4

8

12

16

20

16

20

Panel C: Change in Fraction 25+ with College Education
0.1

0.08

2000-2010

1970-1980

0.06

1980-1990
0.04

0.02

1990-2000
0

4

8

12

Figure 3: 1980-2010 Neighborhood Change in Chicago

Figure 4: Changes in Neighborhood Valuations as a function of CBD Distance by Race and Education
0.3

0.3

0.2

0.2

2000-2010

2000-2010
0.1

0.1

0

0

1990-2000

-0.1

1990-2000

-0.2

-0.2
-0.3

1980-1990

-0.1

1980-1990
0

4

8

12

16

20

-0.3

0

4

Panel A: Whites with College or More

12

16

20

16

20

Panel B: Blacks with College or More

0.3

0.3

0.2

0.2

2000-2010

0.1

8

2000-2010

0.1

0

0

-0.1

-0.1

1990-2000

1980-1990

-0.2

1990-2000

-0.2

1980-1990
-0.3

0

4

8

12

16

20

-0.3

0

4

8

12

Panel C: White High School Dropouts
Panel D: Black High School Dropouts
Notes: Each plot indicates the average change across CBSAs in λ for the indicated demographic group over the indicated decade. λ is calculated for each 0.5 km CBD distance band
using the expression in Equation (5) in the text.

Table 1: Share of Population within 4 km of CBD
in Tract Changing by at Least
20 Percentile Points
up
down

1/2 Standard Deviation
up
down

Panel A: Fraction White
1970-1980
1980-1990
1990-2000
2000-2010
1980-2010

6.5%
4.4%
4.0%
5.2%
5.3%

13.3%
6.0%
3.1%
1.3%
1.3%

14.5%
8.1%
12.1%
14.2%
34.8%

20.8%
13.9%
11.0%
5.5%
23.2%

Panel B: Fraction College Educated
1970-1980
1980-1990
1990-2000
2000-2010
1980-2010

10.3%
5.2%
3.8%
10.3%
10.8%

10.0%
5.8%
6.1%
4.0%
4.0%

14.7%
6.0%
5.5%
14.4%
18.8%

7.6%
7.5%
7.6%
5.3%
16.6%

3.3%
7.8%
7.6%
14.6%
30.6%

21.3%
3.3%
2.9%
4.7%
9.1%

Panel C: Median Income
1970-1980
1980-1990
1990-2000
2000-2010
1980-2010

0.8%
3.5%
3.3%
8.1%
8.0%

12.2%
1.1%
1.4%
1.5%
1.4%

Notes: We compare changes in tracts within 4 km of the CBD to the
distribution of tract changes within each of the 120 CBSAs in our sample. Each
tract is weighted by its share of CBSA population in the base year.

Table 2: Decomposition of Percent Changes in Population within 2 and 4 km of CBDs
Based on Joint Population Distributions of Education and Race

Choices in year t
Shares in year t
CBD Radius

All
All
(1)

None
None
(2)

All
None
(3)

None
All
(4)

College+
White
(5)

Contribution to Difference Between (1) and (2) from
∆choices of
∆shares of
College+
< College
< College Educ|Race
Race
NonWhite
White
NonWhite
(6)
(7)
(8)
(9)
(10)

Panel A: 1980-2000

2 km

-0.07

0.21

-0.12

0.31

4 km

-0.07

0.21

-0.12

0.28

-0.01
(0.07)
-0.02
(0.07)

0.00
(0.01)
-0.01
(0.01)

-0.14
(0.52)
-0.16
(0.56)

-0.18
(0.40)
-0.15
(0.36)

-0.04

0.10

-0.04

0.09

0.00
(0.03)
0.00
(0.03)

0.02
(0.40)
-0.02
(0.42)

-0.08
(0.46)
-0.09
(0.44)

-0.01

0.03

-0.01

0.03

Panel B: 2000-2010
2 km

0.06

0.07

0.04

0.09

4 km

-0.01

0.07

-0.03

0.08

0.04
(0.11)
0.01
(0.11)

Notes: All results are averages over the 120 CBSAs in our sample weighting each CBSA equally. Results in (1) and (2) report actual percent changes in
population in the indicated CBD distance ring and average CBSA population growth rates respectively. Results in remaining columns use counterfactual data.
See the text for a full explanation of the construction of each counterfactual. Table A1 presents the mathematical expression for each one. Results in (5)(10) sum to actuals in (1) minus CBSA growth in (2). Entries in parentheses show the average fraction of the near-CBD population in the indicated
demographic group.

Table 3: Decomposition of Percent Changes in Population within 2 km of CBDs
for Additional Demographic Categories

Choices in year t
Shares in year t
Data Set

All
All
(1)

None
None
(2)

All
None
(3)

None
All
(4)

Target
White
(5)

Contribution to Difference Between (1) and (2) from
∆choices of
∆shares of
Target
NonTarget NonTarget
X|Race
Race
NonWhite
White
NonWhite
(6)
(7)
(8)
(9)
(10)

Panel A: 1980-2000

Age

-0.07

0.21

-0.14

0.34

Family Type

-0.07

0.21

-0.27

0.43

Income

-0.11

0.27

-0.19

0.37

0.01
(0.19)
-0.11
(0.28)
0.00
(0.08)

-0.04
(0.11)
-0.06
(0.12)
-0.01
(0.02)

-0.15
(0.40)
-0.12
(0.31)
-0.24
(0.56)

-0.17
(0.30)
-0.19
(0.29)
-0.21
(0.33)

-0.03

0.10

0.10

0.10

0.00

0.09

-0.01
(0.13)
-0.03
(0.15)
0.00
(0.03)

0.01
(0.34)
-0.01
(0.24)
0.00
(0.47)

-0.08
(0.36)
-0.08
(0.34)
-0.08
(0.40)

0.00

0.03

0.03

0.03

0.00

0.03

Panel B: 2000-2010
Age

0.06

0.07

0.03

0.12

Family Type

0.05

0.08

-0.01

0.15

Income

0.08

0.09

0.05

0.13

0.04
(0.17)
0.02
(0.27)
0.04
(0.09)

Notes: Entries are analogous to those in Table 2 except that they are calculated using joint distributions of age, family type or income and race rather than
education and race. The income joint distribution uses households rather than people. Target groups are ages 20-34, single or married without children and
in the top 3 deciles of the sample area household income distribution.

Table 4: Decompositions of Changes in Demographic Composition within 2 km of CBDs

Choices in year t
Shares in year t
Outcome
Data Set

All
All
(1)

None
None
(2)

All
None
(3)

None
All
(4)

Fraction White
1 Education
-0.08
0.00
0.02
-0.11
2 Income
-0.08
0.00
0.02
-0.10
Fraction College
3 Education
0.06
0.00
0.01
0.05
Median Income (Percentile Points of Sample Area Distribution)
4 Income
1.18
0.00
1.65
-0.23

Target
White
(5)

Contribution to All in (1) from
∆choices of
∆shares of
Target
NonTarget NonTarget
X|Race
Race
NonWhite
White
NonWhite
(6)
(7)
(8)
(9)
(10)

Panel A: 1980-2000
-0.00
0.00

0.00
0.00

-0.05
-0.09

0.08
0.10

0.01
0.00

-0.11
-0.10

-0.01

0.00

0.01

0.01

0.06

-0.01

0.08

-0.22

0.77

1.01

0.47

-0.93

0.02
0.01

-0.00
0.00

0.01
0.00

0.04
0.04

0.00
0.00

-0.04
-0.04

0.03

0.00

-0.01

0.01

0.03

-0.00

1.90

0.10

1.13

0.98

0.14

-0.48

Panel B: 2000-2010
Fraction White
1 Education
0.03
0.00
0.06
-0.04
2 Income
0.01
0.00
0.05
-0.04
Fraction College
3 Education
0.06
0.00
0.03
0.02
Median Income (Percentile Points of Sample Area Distribution)
4 Income
3.78
0.00
4.11
-0.17

Notes: Entries are analogous to those in Tables 2 and 3 except that the CBSA-level statistic of interest differs. For the education data set, the target group is
college graduates. See the notes to Table 3 for a description of other target groups and Table A1 for mathematical expressions used to calculate these
counterfactuals.

Estimator

Table 5: SES Index Regressions
Equally weighted Rings
1970-1980 1980-1990
RF
RF

1990-2000
IV

2000-2010
IV

1980-2010
RF

0.024
(0.008)
0.120
(0.091)
0.052
(0.043)
38,275
(19.0)

0.153
(0.008)
0.025
(0.020)
0.129
(0.035)
38,249
(71.6)

0.205
(0.043)
0.108
(0.044)
0.064
(0.038)
38,279
0.114

-0.001
(0.008)
0.143
(0.091)
0.059
(0.040)
38,306
(22.0)

0.153
(0.009)
0.018
(0.023)
0.136
(0.037)
38,281
(87.3)

0.082
(0.044)
0.100
(0.046)
0.071
(0.037)
38,279
0.666

Panel A: Difference Specification
1(< 4 km to CBD)
Standardized CBSA Emp Growth
X 1(< 4 km to CBD)
Standardized CBD Area Emp Growth
X 1(< 4 km to CBD)
Observations
R-Squared (First Stage F)

-0.203
(0.022)
-0.043
(0.020)
0.047
(0.015)
37,924
0.123

0.013
(0.013)
0.011
(0.015)
0.017
(0.013)
38,329
0.028

Panel B: AR(1) Specification
1(< 4 km to CBD)
Standardized CBSA Emp Growth
X 1(< 4 km to CBD)
Standardized CBD Area Emp Growth
X 1(< 4 km to CBD)
Observations
R-Squared (First Stage F)

-0.308
(0.025)
-0.040
(0.022)
0.043
(0.021)
37,924
0.780

-0.033
(0.016)
0.000
(0.018)
0.020
(0.016)
38,329
0.882

Notes: Each column in each panel reports results from a separate regression of the change in (Panel A) or level of (Panel B)
the tract SES index on variables listed at left and indicators for 4-8, and 8-12 km from a CBD and 0-4, 4-8 and 8-12 km from
the nearest top 1970 quartile SES index tract. Log of distance to the nearest coastline, lake, and river are also included as
controls. See Equations (10) and (11) in the text for specifications used in Panels A and B respectively. Employment growth
variables and their Bartik instruments are standardized to be mean 0 and standard deviation 1. "RF" refers to "reduced
form" and "IV" stands for "instrumental variables" in column headers. Tracts with valid data 1980-2010 are equally
weighted within 0-4 km and beyond 4 km in each CBSA, such that each distance ring gets equal weight across CBSAs.
Coefficients that are significant at the 10% level are shaded red if positive and blue if negative. RF standard errors are
clustered by CBSA.

Table 6: Changes in Tract Valuations by Race and Education
1980-1990
RF

Estimator

1990-2000
IV

2000-2010
IV

-0.162
(0.297)
0.034
(0.211)
0.094
(0.104)
32,712
(14.1)

0.133
(0.060)
-0.002
(0.057)
0.315
(0.148)
32,712
(28.3)

-0.981
(0.683)
0.400
(0.491)
-0.187
(0.237)
14,413
(7.1)

0.082
(0.120)
-0.198
(0.097)
0.144
(0.180)
14,413
(43.4)

-0.177
(0.280)
0.013
(0.199)
0.024
(0.093)
33,301
(14.9)

-0.002
(0.059)
-0.108
(0.055)
0.210
(0.149)
33,301
(37.5)

0.267
(0.553)
-0.494
(0.401)
0.113
(0.204)
13,625
(10.9)

0.080
(0.114)
-0.324
(0.099)
0.346
(0.184)
13,625
(50.6)

Panel A: White College+
1(< 4 km to CBD)
CBSA Employment Growth* 1(< 4 km to CBD)
CBD Area Employment Growth* 1(< 4 km to CBD)
Observations
R-Squared (First Stage F)

0.029
(0.067)
-0.220
(0.045)
0.042
(0.027)
32,712
0.059

Panel B: Black College+
1(< 4 km to CBD)
CBSA Employment Growth* 1(< 4 km to CBD)
CBD Area Employment Growth* 1(< 4 km to CBD)
Observations
R-Squared (First Stage F)

-0.595
(0.305)
-0.036
(0.186)
-0.019
(0.060)
14,413
0.084

Panel C: White <HS
1(< 4 km to CBD)
CBSA Employment Growth* 1(< 4 km to CBD)
CBD Area Employment Growth* 1(< 4 km to CBD)
Observations
R-Squared (First Stage F)

-0.200
(0.049)
-0.093
(0.034)
0.001
(0.018)
33,301
0.086

Panel D: Black <HS
1(< 4 km to CBD)
CBSA Employment Growth* 1(< 4 km to CBD)
CBD Area Employment Growth* 1(< 4 km to CBD)
Observations
R-Squared (First Stage F)

-0.125
(0.232)
-0.191
(0.132)
-0.019
(0.038)
13,625
0.116

Notes: Reported coefficients are from regressions analogous to those in Table 5 Panel A, except using
changes in λ utility components for each group indicated in panel headers rather than the unified SES
index, with group specific samples defined so as to be consistent over the full 1980-2010 period.
Equation (13) in the text shows the full regression specification used. CBSA and CBD area employment
shocks are normalized to have a standard deviation of 1 but are not demeaned. All regressions have
CBSA fixed effects. Tracts with valid data 1980-2010 are equally weighted within 0-4 km and beyond 4
km in each CBSA, such that each distance ring gets equal weight across CBSAs. Because of sample
differences, weights differ across groups. Coefficients that are significant at the 10% level are shaded
red if positive and blue if negative.

Table 7: Contributions to Changes in Central Area Population Growth
by Various Demographic Groups Using the Model

Due to …

College
White

Within 2 km of CBDs
College
< College
White
NonWhite

< College
NonWhite

College
White

Within 4 km of CBDs
< College
College
NonWhite
White

< College
NonWhite

Panel A: 1980-2000

Chg. In Home Prices
Central Area Employment
CBSA Employment
Val. Of Observed Amenities
Unobserved Amenities
Unexplained

0.000
-0.001
-0.011
-0.001
-0.004
0.005

0.000
0.001
0.002
0.000
-0.008
0.001

0.002
-0.015
-0.096
-0.029
-0.030
0.024

-0.006
0.008
-0.153
-0.007
-0.040
-0.002

0.000
-0.002
-0.011
-0.002
-0.004
0.002

0.000
0.001
0.002
0.000
-0.009
0.001

0.002
-0.017
-0.107
-0.029
-0.030
0.022

-0.002
0.006
-0.135
-0.005
-0.035
0.022

Total

-0.01

0.00

-0.14

-0.20

-0.02

0.00

-0.16

-0.15

Panel B: 2000-2010
Chg. In Home Prices
Central Area Employment
CBSA Employment
Val. Of Observed Amenities
Unobserved Amenities
Unexplained
Total

0.001
0.004
0.000
-0.002
0.016
0.007

0.001
0.000
-0.005
-0.001
0.004
-0.001

0.001
0.003
-0.008
-0.012
0.024
-0.004

-0.005
0.009
-0.050
-0.007
-0.014
-0.018

0.000
0.005
0.000
-0.003
0.016
-0.014

0.000
0.000
-0.004
-0.001
0.004
-0.002

0.000
0.001
-0.008
-0.012
0.026
-0.028

-0.004
0.010
-0.049
-0.006
-0.016
-0.017

0.03

0.00

0.00

-0.08

0.00

0.00

-0.02

-0.08

Notes: Each entry is the marginal contribution of the component listed at left on central area population within the CBD distance ring indicated at top because
of shifts in neighborhood choices of the demographic group indicated at top. Columns do not always sum exactly to entries in Table 2 because of minor sample
differences, as is explained in the text.

Table A1: Explanation of Counterfactual Experiments
Population Distributions Used to Construct Counterfactuals
Column in
Tables 2-4
1

Choices
All t

Shares
All t

Race
All

2

All Base Yr

All Base Yr

All

All

fjb(i|r,x)gjb(r,x)

3

All t

All Base Yr

All

All

fjt(i|r,x)gjb(r,x)

4

All Base Yr

All t

All

All

fjb(i|r,x)gjt(r,x)

5

Target Whites t

All Base Yr

Whites

Target

fjt(i|r,x)gjb(r,x)

Blacks, Others

Target

fjb(i|r,x)gjb(r,x)

Whites

Non-Target

fjb(i|r,x)gjb(r,x)

Blacks, Others

Non-Target

fjb(i|r,x)gjb(r,x)

Whites

Target

fjt(i|r,x)gjb(r,x)

Blacks, Others

Target

fjt(i|r,x)gjb(r,x)

Whites

Non-Target

fjb(i|r,x)gjb(r,x)

Blacks, Others

Non-Target

fjb(i|r,x)gjb(r,x)

Whites

Target

fjt(i|r,x)gjb(r,x)

Blacks, Others

Target

fjt(i|r,x)gjb(r,x)

Whites

Non-Target

fjt(i|r,x)gjb(r,x)

Blacks, Others

Non-Target

fjb(i|r,x)gjb(r,x)

6

7

Target t

Target+Whites t

All Base Yr

All Base Yr

Group

X-Dimension
All

Math Notation
fjt(i|r,x)gjt(r,x)

8

All t

All Base Yr

All

All

fjt(i|r,x)gjb(r,x)

9

All t

X|r in t, r in Base Yr

All

All

fjt(i|r,x)gjt(x|r)hjb(r)

10

All t

All t

All

All

fjt(i|r,x)gjt(x|r)hjt(r)

Notes: Entries show the basis for the construction of each counterfactual in Tables 2-4. See Section 3.1 of the text for an
explanation of notation. Target groups are college graduates, households in the top three deciles of the income
distribution, people aged 20-34 and singles or married couples with no kids. Entries in Columns 1-4 of Tables 2-4 only are
built using the indicated counterfactual distributions. Entries in Column 5 are built using the indicated distribution to
calculate statistics relative to those calculated using the distribution in Column 2. Entries in remaining columns c>5 use the
indicated distribution relative to statistics built using the distributions associated with columns c-1.

Table A2: Aggregate Quantities

Fraction White

Fraction
College

Median HH
Income

Share in
Families
without Kids

Share 20-34

0.328
0.357
0.384
0.401

0.266
0.255
0.211
0.209

0.404
0.376
0.420
0.454

0.300
0.317
0.298
0.324

0.366
0.358
0.396
0.423

0.288
0.289
0.267
0.286

Panel A: Entire Sample
1970
1980
1990
2000
2010

0.883
0.836
0.809
0.753
0.717

0.116
0.102
0.138
0.167
0.196

47881
44266
52310
58308
55532

Panel B: Within 2 km of CBDs
1970
1980
1990
2000
2010

0.683
0.590
0.548
0.507
0.533

0.082
0.085
0.115
0.144
0.204

32626
26281
30991
36770
38423

Panel C: Within 4 km of CBDs
1970
0.722
0.089
36523
1980
0.629
0.087
31055
1990
0.584
0.115
35777
2000
0.531
0.139
40934
2010
0.537
0.183
39882
Notes: Each entry is an average across CBSAs in the sample.

Table A3: Decomposition of Percent Changes in Population - Reverse Order
Contribution to Difference Between (1) and (2) in Tables 2 and 3
from ∆shares of
from ∆choices of
Choices in year t
X|Race
Race
Target
Target
NonTarget
Shares in year t
White
NonWhite
White
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
Data Set & CBD Distance Ring
Panel A: 1980-2000
Education, 2km
Education, 4km
Age, 2km
Family Type, 2km
Income, 2km

-0.04
-0.03
0.00
0.10
0.00

0.13
0.10
0.13
0.12
0.10

-0.02
-0.03
0.01
-0.11
0.00

NonTarget
NonWhite
(6)

-0.01
-0.01
-0.04
-0.09
-0.01

-0.11
-0.12
-0.14
-0.09
-0.20

-0.24
-0.19
-0.23
-0.21
-0.27

0.00
0.00
-0.01
-0.03
0.00

0.02
-0.01
0.01
-0.01
0.00

-0.09
-0.09
-0.09
-0.09
-0.08

Panel B: 2000-2010
Education, 2km
Education, 4km
Age, 2km
Family Type, 2km
Income, 2km

-0.02
-0.02
0.01
0.03
0.00

0.05
0.04
0.05
0.04
0.04

0.04
0.01
0.04
0.02
0.03

Notes: Results are analogous to those in Tables 2 and 3. The only difference is the order in which the counterfactuals are imposed.

Table A4: Descriptive Statistics for Employment Shocks
Panel A: Employment Shocks

1980-1990
1990-2000
2000-2010

Mean
0.17
0.10
0.08

∆ ln(CBSA Employment)
SD
Coeff of Var
0.12
1.42
0.09
1.11
0.09
0.89

∆ ln(Employment Within 4 km of CBD)
Mean
SD
Coeff of Var
Not Available
-0.07
0.12
-0.58
-0.01
0.13
-0.08

Panel B: Instruments

1970-1980
1980-1990
1990-2000
2000-2010
1980-2010

Mean
0.11
0.17
0.05
0.07
0.29

Bartik
SD
0.02
0.03
0.03
0.03
0.08

Coeff of Var
5.15
5.99
1.49
2.44
3.64

Mean
0.14
0.20
0.10
0.08
0.39

Spatial Bartik
SD
0.02
0.02
0.03
0.02
0.07

Coeff of Var
6.29
8.27
3.00
3.54
5.23

Notes: We only use actual employment shocks for the 1990-2000 and 2000-2010 periods in Tables 5, 6 and 7,
instrumented with variables whose summary statistics are reported in Panel B. For other periods, those tables
report reduced form results. Statistics above are for the 120 CBSAs in the sample.

Table A5: Patterns of Housing Costs in Tracts within 4 km of CBDs

Estimator

1970-1980
RF

1980-1990
RF

1990-2000
IV

2000-2010
IV

1980-2010
RF

-0.026
(0.007)
0.072
(0.084)
0.062
(0.044)
37,096
(21.5)

0.017
(0.008)
0.015
(0.019)
0.074
(0.040)
36,715
(61.8)

0.005
(0.022)
0.037
(0.028)
0.085
(0.028)
35,078
0.365

0.007
(0.008)
-0.126
(0.074)
0.146
(0.040)
35,572
(25.1)

0.039
(0.008)
0.019
(0.020)
0.030
(0.040)
36,330
(73.4)

0.047
(0.022)
0.010
(0.026)
0.072
(0.026)
35,078
0.024

Panel A: Difference Specification
1(< 4 km to CBD)
Standardized CBSA Emp Growth
X 1(< 4 km to CBD)
Standardized CBD Area Emp Growth
X 1(< 4 km to CBD)
Observations
R-Squared (First Stage F)

-0.065
(0.016)
-0.046
(0.013)
0.032
(0.015)
31,011
0.400

-0.029
(0.012)
0.013
(0.013)
0.048
(0.016)
35,704
0.568

Panel B: AR(1) Specification
1(< 4 km to CBD)
Standardized CBSA Emp Growth
X 1(< 4 km to CBD)
Standardized CBD Area Emp Growth
X 1(< 4 km to CBD)
Observations
R-Squared (First Stage F)

-0.061
(0.015)
-0.042
(0.011)
0.037
(0.014)
31,011
0.033

-0.003
(0.012)
0.000
(0.013)
0.024
(0.013)
35,704
0.009

Notes: Each column in each panel reports results from a separate regression of the change in tract owner occupied
housing price index using the same specification as in Table 5. The housing cost index is formed from the residuals of a
regression of log mean owner occupied home value on housing unit structure characteristics (number of units in
building, number of bedrooms in unit, age of building) of the tract and CBSA fixed effects. See the notes to Table 5 for
a description of variables and weights.

Working Paper Series
A series of research studies on regional economic issues relating to the Seventh Federal
Reserve District, and on financial and economic topics.
The Urban Density Premium across Establishments
R. Jason Faberman and Matthew Freedman

WP-13-01

Why Do Borrowers Make Mortgage Refinancing Mistakes?
Sumit Agarwal, Richard J. Rosen, and Vincent Yao

WP-13-02

Bank Panics, Government Guarantees, and the Long-Run Size of the Financial Sector:
Evidence from Free-Banking America
Benjamin Chabot and Charles C. Moul

WP-13-03

Fiscal Consequences of Paying Interest on Reserves
Marco Bassetto and Todd Messer

WP-13-04

Properties of the Vacancy Statistic in the Discrete Circle Covering Problem
Gadi Barlevy and H. N. Nagaraja

WP-13-05

Credit Crunches and Credit Allocation in a Model of Entrepreneurship
Marco Bassetto, Marco Cagetti, and Mariacristina De Nardi

WP-13-06

Financial Incentives and Educational Investment:
The Impact of Performance-Based Scholarships on Student Time Use
Lisa Barrow and Cecilia Elena Rouse

WP-13-07

The Global Welfare Impact of China: Trade Integration and Technological Change
Julian di Giovanni, Andrei A. Levchenko, and Jing Zhang

WP-13-08

Structural Change in an Open Economy
Timothy Uy, Kei-Mu Yi, and Jing Zhang

WP-13-09

The Global Labor Market Impact of Emerging Giants: a Quantitative Assessment
Andrei A. Levchenko and Jing Zhang

WP-13-10

Size-Dependent Regulations, Firm Size Distribution, and Reallocation
François Gourio and Nicolas Roys

WP-13-11

Modeling the Evolution of Expectations and Uncertainty in General Equilibrium
Francesco Bianchi and Leonardo Melosi

WP-13-12

Rushing into the American Dream? House Prices, the Timing of Homeownership,
and the Adjustment of Consumer Credit
Sumit Agarwal, Luojia Hu, and Xing Huang

WP-13-13

1

Working Paper Series (continued)
The Earned Income Tax Credit and Food Consumption Patterns
Leslie McGranahan and Diane W. Schanzenbach

WP-13-14

Agglomeration in the European automobile supplier industry
Thomas Klier and Dan McMillen

WP-13-15

Human Capital and Long-Run Labor Income Risk
Luca Benzoni and Olena Chyruk

WP-13-16

The Effects of the Saving and Banking Glut on the U.S. Economy
Alejandro Justiniano, Giorgio E. Primiceri, and Andrea Tambalotti

WP-13-17

A Portfolio-Balance Approach to the Nominal Term Structure
Thomas B. King

WP-13-18

Gross Migration, Housing and Urban Population Dynamics
Morris A. Davis, Jonas D.M. Fisher, and Marcelo Veracierto

WP-13-19

Very Simple Markov-Perfect Industry Dynamics
Jaap H. Abbring, Jeffrey R. Campbell, Jan Tilly, and Nan Yang

WP-13-20

Bubbles and Leverage: A Simple and Unified Approach
Robert Barsky and Theodore Bogusz

WP-13-21

The scarcity value of Treasury collateral:
Repo market effects of security-specific supply and demand factors
Stefania D'Amico, Roger Fan, and Yuriy Kitsul
Gambling for Dollars: Strategic Hedge Fund Manager Investment
Dan Bernhardt and Ed Nosal
Cash-in-the-Market Pricing in a Model with Money and
Over-the-Counter Financial Markets
Fabrizio Mattesini and Ed Nosal

WP-13-22

WP-13-23

WP-13-24

An Interview with Neil Wallace
David Altig and Ed Nosal

WP-13-25

Firm Dynamics and the Minimum Wage: A Putty-Clay Approach
Daniel Aaronson, Eric French, and Isaac Sorkin

WP-13-26

Policy Intervention in Debt Renegotiation:
Evidence from the Home Affordable Modification Program
Sumit Agarwal, Gene Amromin, Itzhak Ben-David, Souphala Chomsisengphet,
Tomasz Piskorski, and Amit Seru

WP-13-27

2

Working Paper Series (continued)
The Effects of the Massachusetts Health Reform on Financial Distress
Bhashkar Mazumder and Sarah Miller

WP-14-01

Can Intangible Capital Explain Cyclical Movements in the Labor Wedge?
François Gourio and Leena Rudanko

WP-14-02

Early Public Banks
William Roberds and François R. Velde

WP-14-03

Mandatory Disclosure and Financial Contagion
Fernando Alvarez and Gadi Barlevy

WP-14-04

The Stock of External Sovereign Debt: Can We Take the Data at ‘Face Value’?
Daniel A. Dias, Christine Richmond, and Mark L. J. Wright

WP-14-05

Interpreting the Pari Passu Clause in Sovereign Bond Contracts:
It’s All Hebrew (and Aramaic) to Me
Mark L. J. Wright

WP-14-06

AIG in Hindsight
Robert McDonald and Anna Paulson

WP-14-07

On the Structural Interpretation of the Smets-Wouters “Risk Premium” Shock
Jonas D.M. Fisher

WP-14-08

Human Capital Risk, Contract Enforcement, and the Macroeconomy
Tom Krebs, Moritz Kuhn, and Mark L. J. Wright

WP-14-09

Adverse Selection, Risk Sharing and Business Cycles
Marcelo Veracierto

WP-14-10

Core and ‘Crust’: Consumer Prices and the Term Structure of Interest Rates
Andrea Ajello, Luca Benzoni, and Olena Chyruk

WP-14-11

The Evolution of Comparative Advantage: Measurement and Implications
Andrei A. Levchenko and Jing Zhang

WP-14-12

Saving Europe?: The Unpleasant Arithmetic of Fiscal Austerity in Integrated Economies
Enrique G. Mendoza, Linda L. Tesar, and Jing Zhang

WP-14-13

Liquidity Traps and Monetary Policy: Managing a Credit Crunch
Francisco Buera and Juan Pablo Nicolini

WP-14-14

Quantitative Easing in Joseph’s Egypt with Keynesian Producers
Jeffrey R. Campbell

WP-14-15

3

Working Paper Series (continued)
Constrained Discretion and Central Bank Transparency
Francesco Bianchi and Leonardo Melosi

WP-14-16

Escaping the Great Recession
Francesco Bianchi and Leonardo Melosi

WP-14-17

More on Middlemen: Equilibrium Entry and Efficiency in Intermediated Markets
Ed Nosal, Yuet-Yee Wong, and Randall Wright

WP-14-18

Preventing Bank Runs
David Andolfatto, Ed Nosal, and Bruno Sultanum

WP-14-19

The Impact of Chicago’s Small High School Initiative
Lisa Barrow, Diane Whitmore Schanzenbach, and Amy Claessens

WP-14-20

Credit Supply and the Housing Boom
Alejandro Justiniano, Giorgio E. Primiceri, and Andrea Tambalotti

WP-14-21

The Effect of Vehicle Fuel Economy Standards on Technology Adoption
Thomas Klier and Joshua Linn

WP-14-22

What Drives Bank Funding Spreads?
Thomas B. King and Kurt F. Lewis

WP-14-23

Inflation Uncertainty and Disagreement in Bond Risk Premia
Stefania D’Amico and Athanasios Orphanides

WP-14-24

Access to Refinancing and Mortgage Interest Rates:
HARPing on the Importance of Competition
Gene Amromin and Caitlin Kearns

WP-14-25

Private Takings
Alessandro Marchesiani and Ed Nosal

WP-14-26

Momentum Trading, Return Chasing, and Predictable Crashes
Benjamin Chabot, Eric Ghysels, and Ravi Jagannathan

WP-14-27

Early Life Environment and Racial Inequality in Education and Earnings
in the United States
Kenneth Y. Chay, Jonathan Guryan, and Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-14-28

Poor (Wo)man’s Bootstrap
Bo E. Honoré and Luojia Hu

WP-15-01

Revisiting the Role of Home Production in Life-Cycle Labor Supply
R. Jason Faberman

WP-15-02

4

Working Paper Series (continued)
Risk Management for Monetary Policy Near the Zero Lower Bound
Charles Evans, Jonas Fisher, François Gourio, and Spencer Krane
Estimating the Intergenerational Elasticity and Rank Association in the US:
Overcoming the Current Limitations of Tax Data
Bhashkar Mazumder

WP-15-03

WP-15-04

External and Public Debt Crises
Cristina Arellano, Andrew Atkeson, and Mark Wright

WP-15-05

The Value and Risk of Human Capital
Luca Benzoni and Olena Chyruk

WP-15-06

Simpler Bootstrap Estimation of the Asymptotic Variance of U-statistic Based Estimators
Bo E. Honoré and Luojia Hu

WP-15-07

Bad Investments and Missed Opportunities?
Postwar Capital Flows to Asia and Latin America
Lee E. Ohanian, Paulina Restrepo-Echavarria, and Mark L. J. Wright

WP-15-08

Backtesting Systemic Risk Measures During Historical Bank Runs
Christian Brownlees, Ben Chabot, Eric Ghysels, and Christopher Kurz

WP-15-09

What Does Anticipated Monetary Policy Do?
Stefania D’Amico and Thomas B. King

WP-15-10

Firm Entry and Macroeconomic Dynamics: A State-level Analysis
François Gourio, Todd Messer, and Michael Siemer

WP-16-01

Measuring Interest Rate Risk in the Life Insurance Sector: the U.S. and the U.K.
Daniel Hartley, Anna Paulson, and Richard J. Rosen

WP-16-02

Allocating Effort and Talent in Professional Labor Markets
Gadi Barlevy and Derek Neal

WP-16-03

The Life Insurance Industry and Systemic Risk: A Bond Market Perspective
Anna Paulson and Richard Rosen

WP-16-04

Forecasting Economic Activity with Mixed Frequency Bayesian VARs
Scott A. Brave, R. Andrew Butters, and Alejandro Justiniano

WP-16-05

Optimal Monetary Policy in an Open Emerging Market Economy
Tara Iyer

WP-16-06

Forward Guidance and Macroeconomic Outcomes Since the Financial Crisis
Jeffrey R. Campbell, Jonas D. M. Fisher, Alejandro Justiniano, and Leonardo Melosi

WP-16-07

5

Working Paper Series (continued)
Insurance in Human Capital Models with Limited Enforcement
Tom Krebs, Moritz Kuhn, and Mark Wright

WP-16-08

Accounting for Central Neighborhood Change, 1980-2010
Nathaniel Baum-Snow and Daniel Hartley

WP-16-09

6