View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

o r K i n g r a p e r b e r ie s



A Policymaker's Guide to Indicators
of Economic Activity
Charles Evans, Steven Strongin,
and Francesca Eugeni

3

W o rk in g P a p e rs S e rie s
M a c ro e c o n o m ic Issu e s
R e se a rch D e p a rtm e n t
F e d e ra l R e s e rv e B a n k o f C h ic a g o
N o v e m b e r 1 9 92 (W P -9 2 -1 9)

FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K
OF CHICAGO

A P olicym ak er’s G uide to Indicators o f E conom ic A ctivity

by

Charles Evans
Steven Strongin
and Francesca Eugeni

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
November 1992

The authors would like to thank the participants of the Special Meeting on Operating
Procedures held at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, June 18 and 19, 1992, and the
participants of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago’s Macro Workshop held June 9, 1992,
for their comments. The opinions expressed in this paper are not necessarily those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal Reserve System.




ABSTRACT

This paper implements a set of time series techniques for evaluating indicators of
economic activity that more closely match the actual use of such indicators in the day-to-day
policy process. We view that process as primarily involving the re-assessment of short- to
medium-term economic activity based upon indicator by indicator analysis with the primary
decision matrix being whether it is necessary to ease or tighten policy in order to realize
appropriate levels of economic activity. As policymakers typically use indicators one at a
time, all of our analysis is carried out on a bivariate basis.
We consider four classes of indicators: nominal interest rate levels, interest rate
spreads, monetary aggregates, and composite indicators. Within each class the indicator
evaluation has three primary parts: ranking candidate indicators, characterizing the nature
of the information in those indicators, and assessing their usefulness in practice.

After

selecting the best indicators from each class for each forecast horizon considered, we then
determine what relative weight should be given to each indicator. We find that interest rate
spreads are typically the most informative indicators at short- and medium-term horizons (1-,
2- and 4-quarters ahead). The monetary aggregates are typically not very informative at
these horizons, with the exception of real M2 at the 4-quarter horizon.




INTRODUCTION
The evaluation of economic indicators has often progressed with an odd independence
for the way in which such indicators are actually used in practice in the economic policy
process.

The search is often for one "best" indicator, where "best" typically refers to

winning in some narrowly defined contest of general purpose forecasting ability measured
over some pre-selected time-span.

The actuality of the policy process is far richer.

Indicators are used in a kind of chaotic democracy, each indicator casting a vote based on
its own forecast and the policymakers weighing each vote, based on their assessment of the
current credibility of the indicator.
This is quite different from the standard academic formulation of economic policy
where a "true" model is developed and then policy run in a way that optimizes the
performance of the model. Understanding this difference in approach leads to very different
ways of evaluating indicators. It is not just enough to produce a "best" model; rather, it is
important to understand what type of information is contained in a given indicator so that its
message can be properly evaluated and also how much weight to give that message given
what else is also known.
Indicators, like people, perform better or worse depending on the context in which
they operate. Efficient usage requires matching indicators both with appropriate questions
and with other complementary indicators. For instance, some indicators do far better at
predicting short-run changes in activity, but do not do very well at pinning down the level
of activity over longer time spans, while other indicators forecast short-run phenomena
poorly, but do better at predicting average activity over longer time span. Also while some
indicators have very close substitutes, such as the twenty or so short-term interest rates
sometimes used in econometric studies, and thus provide little additional information beyond
that already contained in other indicators, some indicators can provide substantial additional
information, thus providing important confirming or contradicting information.

The

policymaker needs to know how to match questions with indicators depending on the current




policy context.

A swiss army knife is a fine general purpose tool, but it is hardly a

substitute for a well-equipped workshop.
This paper seeks to develop and implement a set of techniques for evaluating
indicators of economic activity that more closely match the actual use of such indicators in
the day-to-day policy process. We see that process as primarily involving the re-assessment
of short- to medium-term economic activity based on indicator by indicator analysis with the
primary decision matrix being whether it is necessary to ease or tighten policy in order to
realize appropriate levels of economic activity. We do not address the longer run issues of
assessing appropriate levels of economic activity or other issues involving inflation or the
value of the dollar nor do we address the question of how best to implement those decisions.
Evaluating indicators in this context has four primary parts; ranking candidate indicators,
characterizing the nature of the information in those indicators, assessing their usefulness in
practice and determining what relative weight should be given to each indicator. The idea
is to develop the information that a policymaker needs in order to interpret information as
it comes in and to choose which indicators to watch depending on the questions being asked.
As policymakers typically use indicators one at a time, all of our analysis will be
carried out on a bivariate basis. Multivariate regression models allow indicators to play off
against one another so that if two indicators hold both common and independent information
better statistical fits can usually be obtained by fitting one multivariate model rather than
mixing 2 bivariate models. The advantage of using the mixing approach is that when one
of the indicators begins to misbehave, which they do, you can, at least temporarily, just
ignore that indicator. Second, by only using the primary information over-fitting is less of
a worry.

Third and most important, the mixing approach allows a much more precise

assessment of exactly the type of information that is contained in each indicator and thus
allows policymakers to reoptimize their choice of indicator sets based on the type of question
being asked.




-2 -

Beyond the focus on bivariate models, there are a number of other differences
between our work and normal econometric practice that are worth noting. First, as will be
shown in the paper different indicators are useful at different forecast horizons, so that we
will not be suggesting one best model, but rather we will be suggesting ways of combining
indicators depending on the precise policy question being asked. Second, along these same
lines as we are more concerned with the interpretation of each of the individual indicators
rather than the construction of a structural model of the economy, we will pay much more
attention to characterizing the type of information in each individual indicator than is
normally the case.

Also, since the forecasts derived from the indicators typically get

averaged together either informally in the policymaker’s mind or formally in the mixing
models shown in the last section of this paper, we analyze the degree to which one indicator
can be said to have information which is independent from another. Policymakers are often
faced with a variety of indicators pointing one way and another group pointing a different
way, in such cases it is not only useful to know what weight would have produced the best
forecast historically, but the degree to which the indicators are independent bits of
information or the same information being repeated over and over again in a variety of
guises. Policymakers quite rightly give greater weight to information which they see as
independent confirmation. It is useful in this light to more fully analyze the independence
of information in various indicators. It is also helpful to know if the indicator in question
usually contains the type of information being sought.

METHODOLOGY
As noted above, the primary focus of this paper is the examination of various data
series as indicators of changes in real economic activity, which we measure alternately as
annualized log changes in real GDP, employment and industrial production.

In most cases

results are supplied for all three measures of economic activity. The major focus will be on




-3-

forecasting real GDP, except in the sections of the paper which focus on issues of timing in
which case employment will be used, since it is available at the monthly frequency allowing
for more precise estimation of the pattern of impact over time.
Throughout the paper the indicators are used to produce forecasts of economic
activity. The specific functional form of the forecasting equation is always the same. One
year of data for the indicator and one year of lagged economic activity is included in the
regression. Thus, the exercise is strictly equivalent to a bivariate VAR with one year of
lags, 4 lags for the real GDP models and 12 lags for the employment and industrial
production models. The models are estimated in log differences and rates of change are
annualized. Interest rates and interest rate spreads are used in their level form. In many of
the tables an additional forecast is provided with the label "NONE".

In this case, the

forecast is based solely on the past history of economic activity, a pure auto-regressive model
with one year of lagged data. This pure auto-regressive forecast is referred to as the no­
indicator forecast. When the horizon of forecast is varied, we simply change the dependent
variable in the regression rather than dynamically iterate the one period ahead forecast. This
optimizes the parameterization for the forecast horizon in question, rather than
multiplicatively combining estimation errors forward. Symbolically the forecasting equation
can be written:
r^-r,=A(L)Ax,.i+ m

where Yt it the log of economic activity at time t and I, is the indicator at time t, k is the
number of periods in the forecast horizon and A(L) and B(L) are polynomials in the lag
operator L of order one year.
The indicators are split into four groups, which we call families. Each family is
meant to represent a natural division of indicators into groups which are likely to share
similar characteristics. For example, the first family we examine is interest rates, the second




-4-

is money-based measures, the third is interest rate spreads and the fourth is composite
indicators, such as the Department of Commerce Leading Indicators and the S&P 500. The
fourth group also contains those series which do not fit neatly into the overall classification
scheme.
The idea is to first examine the indicators within a family, finding out which
indicators within each family produce the best forecasts and contain the most independent
information and then taking these "best" indicators and examining what is to be gained by
mixing the information from different families. This serves a number of purposes. First,
by breaking the large list of potential indicators into smaller groups it makes each
examination more manageable. Second, by using natural groupings it allows us to look at
questions such as what is the best interest rate or the best money measure in a natural way.
Third, one key issue for indicators is the degree to which they actually contain independent
information. Focusing on groups which are already thought to have similar information
provides a natural focus to learn if these preconceptions are accurate or if some of these
groups contain more than one type of information.

Lastly, by first selecting the best

indicators at the family level and then mixing between families, we can produce a mixed
forecast which, as noted above, closely approximates the way policy forecasting appears to
be done in practice.
Each family of indicators is subjected to the same analysis. First, each family of
indicators is described and a table is presented which lists the indicators examined and their
means, standard deviations and their correlations with the measures of economic activity.
Then each of the indicators is subjected to four evaluations, 1.) Classical goodness of fit
rankings, 2.) Characterization of fit, 3.) Indicators performance in practice and 4.)
Encompassing tests.
The classical goodness of fit rankings are based on simple full sample regressions
estimated on data from the beginning of 1962 through the end of 1991. The results are




-5-

presented in table two of each family analysis section. Table two shows the rankings for
each indicators in the family based on the regression they produce. The idea is that the best
indicators are the ones that produces the best fit where fit is measured by the R2 of the
regression or the standard deviation of the residual from the regression1. This closely
approximates the oldest notions of evaluating the best indicators of economic activity for
policy. It is also closely linked to the notion of Granger causality, which measures whether
or not the indicators actually help forecast economic activity. The p-value for this test is
also included in the table.
The second evaluation seeks to characterize the type of information in the indicator.
Typically the question can be thought of as if the indicator goes up today how does that
change my expectations about economic activity in the future.

This is analyzed by

calculating the dynamic response path of employment for each of the indicator forecasting
equations, which shows how a one standard deviation2 increase in the indicator changes
expectations about future growth rate of employment for each month for the next 36
months3. This allows us to characterize the information in the indicator based on how fast
economic activity responds, how much it responds and how long the change in activity lasts.
Figure 1 in each family section graphs the dynamic response path for each indicator in the
family, as well as the 2 standard deviation bands on the estimates of the dynamic response
paths to show the amount of uncertainty about the response path. Table 3 summarizes this

1. In the appendix tables which include sub-sample results are also presented.
2. The standard deviation measure used is the one from a bivariate VAR for the
indicator and the measure of economic activity. This is used to approximate the average size
of movement in the indicator series.
3. This is basically the same as an impulse response function except that the identifying
assumption is not derived from a specific decomposition of the error matrix, but on the
assumed path of the actual series, i.e. the indicator changes given the level of current
activity. This is arithmetically equivalent to an impulse response function using a Choleski
decomposition with the indicator ordered last.




-6 -

information in terms o f the maximum response for all three o f the measures o f economic
activity, showing the timing, size and uncertainty o f the maximum response o f economic
activity for each indicator in the fam ily.

The third evaluation switches the focus to how well the indicators are likely to work
in practice. To this end, goodness of fit is reinterpreted in a way closer to the way forecasts
are actually used. First, table 4 shows the goodness of fit ranking recalculated for a series
of forecast horizons, so that we can get a better feel for what these indicators are good at.
First, the single period horizon used in the first evaluation and then a one-quarter horizon,
a two-quarter horizon and a one-year horizon4. Table 5 in each section then repeats this
analysis using forecasting equations which do not contain any prior information.
Specifically, the forecasting equations are estimated sequentially using Kalman filtering
techniques using only the sample information available prior to the period being forecast.
This provides a more accurate assessment of how an indicator is likely to perform in
practice. These forecasts are then ranked by the mean squared error (MSE) of the forecasts
from 1972 onward. The R2s are no longer well defined. This analysis is followed up by
Figure 2 in each section which graphs the cumulative residuals for Kalman forecasts from
1972 onward. This allows us to examine if these forecasts tend to perform badly during
recessions or if there was some particular point in the past where they did especially well
or poorly. It also tells us if the forecasts have tended to miss in some systematic fashion
over time. The residuals are measured as the actual growth in economic activity minus the

4.
It should be noted that these are not iterated VAR forecasts, rather the forecast
parameters are chosen to maximize performance at the forecast horizon specified. This can
either be thought of as a state space estimation minimizing the t+ k forecast variance or as
simple OLS with the dependent variable the t+ k growth rate. This avoids any problem that
might result from a indicator that performs poorly at high frequencies having that failure
interfere with longer frequency forecasting.




-7-

forecasted growth. Thus, a downward trend in the cumulative residuals would indicate a
prolonged period of over-predicting growth in activity.
The fourth evaluation switches the focus to independence of information. As noted
above one of the most important factors to understand about indicators is whether of not they
contain independent information relative to some other indicator. This allows a policymaker
to assess whether a new piece of information actually contains any additional information or
whether it is simply the same information with a different label. The way to evaluate this
is through a set of techniques called encompassing tests.

In the context of this paper,

indicator A is said to encompass indicator B, if given the forecast implicitly based on A there
is no additional information in indicator B. Indicator A is said to dominate indicator B if A
encompasses B and B does not encompass A. The simplest way to test this is to run a
regression with economic activity as the dependent variable and the forecast of activity based
on indicator A and the forecast of activity based on indicator B as the independent variables.
Symbolically this can be written
A G D P , = < p f o r ( A ) , + (1 - i p ) f o r ( B ) , + e

Where fo r(A \ and for(B)t are the forecasts of GDPt based on indicators A and B respectively
and <f>is relative weight OLS assigns to for(A)t and for(B)t. If <f>is significantly different
from 0 then we can reject that for(A) is encompassed by for(B).

Likewise if 1-<f> is

significantly different from 0 then we can reject that for(B) is encompassed by for(A). If
neither is encompassed then both indicators contain independent information and a better
forecast can be obtained by mixing both sets of information with the relative weight given
by <£. If only one is encompassed, then it is said to be dominated and only the other is
necessary to produce an efficient forecast. If both are encompassed then either indicator
alone can produce an efficient forecast, this occurs when there is a very high degree of




-8-

collinearity and the standard error of the parameter estimate is large.

In this case the

indicator which has the best historical track record would likely be the superior choice. The
generalization to longer horizons is straight forward, though the calculation of the standard
errors is more complicated since the errors are no longer independent.
Table 6 in each family section contains the encompassing test. The table is read as
follows. The indicators are listed both along the top and along the side. The numbers in
the table refer to the test that the indicator listed along the side is encompassed by the
indicator along the top. The test statistics are the significance levels for the test the indicator
along the top does in fact contain all the information in the indicator along the side. For the
sake of readability values below .05 are indicated with a dash.
The way to interpret these tables is that an indicator whose row is blank contains
information that is independent of every other indicator in the family. An indicator whose
column is full of high numbers is said to encompass those indicators. An indicator that did
both would be said to dominate the family. In general, what we will search for is the set
of indicators in each family which contains all the information in the family using as few
indicators as possible. In general this will mean that the best variable from the previous tests
will be included plus additional indicators which contain independent information, i.e. the
indicators that add the most.

Formally this means that all indicators that are not

encompassed by any other indicators in the family plus whatever additional indicators are
necessary to fully encompass or cover all the other indicators in the family.

This is

analogous to finding a set of minimum sufficient statistics.
The indicators that make it through this process will then be tested in the mixing
model section of the paper in between-family encompassing tests, which examine whether
or not there is independent information between families or not.

Then a set of "best"

indicators will be selected in order to develop mixing models of indicators which contain
independent information for each of the forecasting horizons. These models will contain




-9-

estimates of the appropriate relative weights that should be applied to the individual
indicator-based forecasts. Completing the circle of policy forecasts, the mixing model will
be time-varying to see if there is any gain from adjusting the weight applied to these
individual forecasts based on recent performance.

INTEREST RATE LEVELS
Table 1.1 lists the nominal interest rates which were selected for investigation, along
with some descriptive statistics. All of the rates are expressed at annual rates: the Federal
Funds rate (FF), 3- and 6-month Treasury bill rates (TB03 and TB06), 1-, 3-, 5-, and 10year constant maturity Treasury bond rates (CM01, CM03, CM05, and CM10), the 3-month
Eurodollar rate (EUR03), the 6-month Commercial Paper rate (CP6), and the BAA bond rate
(BAA). Each of these interest rates is negatively correlated with the economic activity
variables. The interest rates with the largest absolute correlation with real GDP are the
Federal Funds rate, the 3-month Eurodollar rate, and the 6-month Commercial Paper rate.
Table 1.2 reports statistics for the one-period-ahead forecasting model. Notice that
all of the interest rates provide significant predictive power for all three economic activities.
The R2 fall within fairly narrow bands indicating that the relative rankings are not
particularly important—all of these indicators are useful at the one-month forecast horizon.
Figure 1.1 graphs the response of the employment growth forecast to a one-standard
deviation change in information about last period’s indicator. As with the F-tests in Table
1.2, the response paths are virtually identical across the interest rates considered:
employment growth rises for three or four months and then falls, eventually asymptoting
back to zero from below the axis. The confidence bounds on these responses are sufficiently
wide that the initial response could be zero. For all of the interest rates, however, there is
a point within the first year that employment growth is significantly negative: the largest
such effects are for the 6-month Commercial Paper rate and the BAA bond rate. For all of




-1 0 -

the indicators across all of the activities, the maximum effect is negative and occurs within
one year of the impulse (see Table 1.3).
Tables 1.4 and 1.5 rank the indicator forecasts for in-sample and out-of-sample
forecasting behavior. Focusing on the out-of-sample results first, notice that for industrial
production and employment at the one-month horizon, the no-indicator forecasts perform
better than the interest rate forecasts.

But for GDP all of the interest rate forecasts

outperform the no-indicator forecasts at all horizons. Focusing on GDP, the Federal Funds
rate is ranked first at the four-quarter growth horizon; but the 3-month Eurodollar rate is
best at the one- and two-quarter horizons. The success of the Eurodollar rate is also evident
for industrial production and employment at all horizons beyond one-month. The 6-month
Commercial Paper rate improves in forecasting accuracy as the horizon increases; this is
true for GDP, industrial production, and employment (placing no worse than third at the oneyear horizon). In general, the shorter maturity bills perform better than the longer maturity
bonds (3-, 5-, and 10-year Treasuries).
The in-sample results of Table 1.4 indicate that the Eurodollar rate increases in
ranking due in part to its out-of-sample stability.

In the out-of-sample rankings the

Eurodollar rate is first for industrial production (3-, 6-, 12-months), employment (6- and 12month), and GDP (one- and two-quarters). In 6 of these 7 instances, these represent an
increase in ranking from the in-sample results. In contrast to this stability, the 6-month
Commercial Paper rate does not fare as well. At the shorter forecast horizons, it goes from
being ranked number 1 or 2 in-sample to either 6, 9, or 10 out-of-sample. For the industrial
production and employment, the Federal Funds rate also experiences a substantial out-ofsample forecast deterioration at the shorter forecast horizons relative to the in-sample
rankings.
The cumulated residuals from the Kalman forecasts in Figure 1.2 show that, overall,
the indicators in our interest rate family consistently underforecasted real GDP between 1974




-1 1 -

and 1982. The upward trend in the cumulated residuals during this period can be explained
in part by an unprecedented increase in inflation, which caused interest rates to rise without
the normally anticipated decline in output. On the other hand, between 1983 and 1989, the
Federal Funds rate, the 6-month Commercial Paper rate, the Eurodollar rate, and all of the
Treasury bill rates performed well, as shown by the flattening of their cumulated residuals
slopes during this period. Between 1990 and 1991, however, the indicators performance
deteriorated again, as all of the interest rates missed the 1990-91 recession and consistently
overforecasted real GDP.
Table 1.6 reports the encompassing results for GDP. The simplest case is for the 4quarter horizon:

the Federal Funds rate dominates the other interest rates since it is

unencompassed and it encompasses all other interest rates at this horizon. At the one- and
two-quarter horizons, however, this domination does not hold; none of the interest rates are
unencompassed at these horizons. Since all of the interest rates Granger-cause economic
activity in Table 1.2, it is probably not surprising that each of the interest rates contains
useful forecasting information. For example, at the one-quarter horizon the Federal Funds
rate, the 3-month Eurodollar rate and the 6-month Commercial Paper rate all can be said to
encompass each other, i.e. if you know one interest rate based forecast knowing another is
not much help. Since all of these interest rate forecasts are encompassed by at least one other
interest rate forecast, the next criterion for selection is to determine if any one of the interest
rate forecasts can cover all of the other interest rate forecasts. In fact, at the one-quarter
horizon, the Federal Funds rate, the 3-month Eurodollar rate, and the 6-month Commercial
Paper rate all cover every other interest rate.

The 3-month Eurodollar rate covers the

Federal Funds rate and the 6-month Commercial Paper rate with higher levels of
significance, and since, as noted above, the 3-month Eurodollar rate was the number one
ranked indicator in the out-of-sample forecasts of GDP at the one-quarter horizon, the 3month Eurodollar rate is selected as the best interest rate level indicator at the one-quarter




-1 2 -

horizon. Similar reasoning leads to the selection of the 3-month Eurodollar rate for the twoquarter horizon.




-13-

TABLE 1.1 - DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS

QUARTERLY (Jan 62 - Dec 91)

MONTHLY (Jan 62 - Feb 92)

Mean

Std. Dev.

Correlation with
Real GDP

-0.245

7.370

3.304

-0.353

-0.190

-0.222

6.620

2.686

-0.299

2.647

-0.186

-0.219

6.777

2.622

-0.295

7.265

2.872

-0.173

-0.215

7.282

2.849

-0.282

CM03

7.597

2.746

-0.162

-0.226

7.608

2.737

-0.257

CM05

7.736

2.708

-0.161

-0.231

7.744

2.705

-0.251

CM10

7.866

2.674

-0.154

-0.231

7.869

2.678

-0237

EUR03

8.033

3.282

-0.224

-0254

8.055

3.232

-0.352

CP6

7.341

2.879

-0.223

-0.252

7.359

2.844

-0.342

BAA

9.588

3.108

-0.188

-0286

9.590

3.120

-0.269

Correlation with
Industrial
Employment
Production

Indicator

Mean

Std. Dev.

FF

7.352

3.345

-0.230

TB03

6.605

2.715

TB06

6.761

CM01




TABLE 1.2 - CLASSICAL GOODNESS-OF-FfT STATISTICS

MONTHLY (Jan 62 - Feb 92)

MONTHLY (Jan 62 - Feb 92)

INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION

QUARTERLY (Jan 62 - Dec 91)

EMPLOYMENT

R2

Change
in R2

SEE

P-Value Rank

FF

0.259

0.063

8.965

0.0057

TB03

0.263

0.067

8.940

TB06

0.271

0.076

CM01

0.273

CM03

GDP

R2

Change
in R2

SEE

P-Value

Rank

R2

Change
in R2

SEE

P-Value

10

0.423

0.050

2.303

0.0052

6

0.338

0.220

3.148

0.0000

3

0.0030

8

0.426

0.053

2.297

0.0028

5

0.293

0.176

3.252

0.0001

6

8.887

0.0007

5

0.429

0.055

2.291

0.0015

3

0.304

0.186

3.227

0.0000

5

0.078

8.875

0.0005

4

0.428

0.054

2.294

0.0020

4

0.309

0.191

3.216

0.0000

4

0.265

0.069

8.930

0.0022

7

0.421

0.047

2.307

0.0080

7

0.279

0.161

3.285

0.0002

7

CM05

0.263

0.067

8.941

0.0030

9

0.419

0.046

2.310

0.0109

8

0.268

0.150

3.310

0.0003

8

CM10

0.265

0.070

8.925

0.0020

6

0.417

0.043

2.315

0.0171

10

0.253

0.136

3.343

0.0009

10

EUR03

0.276

0.081

8.859

0.0003

3

0.431

0.057

2.287

0.0010

2

0.354

0.236

3.110

0.0000

1

CP6

0.286

0.091

8.797

0.0001

1

0.438

0.065

2.273

0.0002

1

0.348

0.231

3.123

0.0000

2

BAA

0.283

0.087

8.818

0.0001

2

0.419

0.045

2.312

0.0124

9

0.258

0.140

3.333

0.0007

9

Indicator




Rank

TABLE 1.3 - MAXIMUM IMPACT OF DYNAMIC MULTIPLIERS

MONTHLY (Jan 62 - Feb 92)

QUARTERLY (Jan 62 - Dec 91)

MONTHLY (Jan 62 - Feb 92)

INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION

GDP

EMPLOYMENT

Months to
Max

Max Impact

Std. Dev.
at Max

Months to
Max

Max Impact

Std. Dev.
at Max

Quarters to
Max

Max Impact

Std. Dev.
at Max

FF

7

-1.349

0.454

10

-0.406

0.129

3

-1.442

0.307

TB03

5

-1.577

0.499

9

-0.335

0.135

3

-1.250

0.280

TB06

5

-1.610

0.496

12

-0.365

0.130

3

-1.354

0.303

CM01

5

-1.655

0.468

12

-0.411

0.123

3

-1.443

0.308

CM03

5

-1.550

0.482

12

-0.414

0.146

3

-1.383

0.326

CMOS

5

-1.446

0.480

10

-0.431

0.141

3

-1.367

0.303

CM10

12

-1270

0.488

12

-0.382

0.145

3

-1.332

0.314

EUR03

5

-1.615

0.475

9

-0.494

0.124

3

-1.605

0.290

CP6

5

-1.793

0.484

9

-0.464

0.123

3

-1.502

0.282

BAA

5

-1.973

0.486

7

-0.395

0.138

3

-1280

0.310

Indicator




TABLE 1.4 - MULTIPERIOD FORECASTS (IrvSample)
MONTHLY (Jan 62 - Feb 92)
____________ INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION_________________

INDICATOR

1 MON
R2 RANK

3 MOS
R2 RANK

6 MOS
R2 RANK

QUARTERLY (Jan 62 - Dec 91)

MONTHLY (Jan 62 - Feb 92)

12MOS
R2 RANK

_________
1 MON
R2 RANK

GDP

EMPLOYMENT
3 MOS
6 MOS
R2 RANK_______R2 RANK

12 MOS
R2 RANK

1 QTR
R2 RANK

2QTRS
R2 RANK

4QTRS
R2 RANK

FF

0258

10

0251

3

0.400

3

0530

2

0.423

6

0576

3

0571

3

0561

2

0.338

3

0.463

3

0.530

1

TB03

0263

8

0233

7

0237

6

0.477

5

0.426

5

0564

7

0543

6

0529

4

0293

6

0.402

5

0.496

3

TB06

0271

5

0246

5

0253

4

0.483

4

0.429

3

0570

5

0.550

4

0528

5

0204

5

0.406

4

0.487

5

CM01

0273

4

0241

6

0250

5

0.455

6

0.428

4

0567

6

0.547

5

0509

6

0209

4

0297

6

0.443

6

CM03

0264

7

0225

8

0229

8

0.410

7

0.421

7

0561

8

0.540

8

0.486

7

0279

7

0250

7

0.377

7

CM05

0263

9

0218

9

0214

9

0288

8

0.419

8

0560

9

0.536

9

0.474

8

0268

8

0232

8

0.346

8

CM10

0265

6

0207

10

0280

10

0246

10

0.417 10

0550

10

0.514

10

0.442

10

0253

10

0296

10

0207

10

EUR03

0276

3

0271

2

0.420

2

0.509

3

0.431

2

0581

2

0.575

2

0546

3

0254

1

0.471

2

0.490

4

CP6

0286

1

0282

1

0.438

1

0541

1

0.438

1

0592

1

0592

1

0564

1

0248

2

0.475

1

0.516

2

BAA

0283

2

0248

4

0232

7

0261

9

0.419

9

0570

4

0543

7

0.468

9

0258

9

0229

9

0.315

9

NONE

0.196

11

0201

11

0.115

11

0.097

11

0273

11

0.489

11

0.414

11

0269

11

0.118

11

0.123

11

0.076

11




TABLE 1.5 - KALMAN MULTIPERIOD FORECASTS (Out-of-Sample)
MONTHLY(Jti73-Feb92)
________INDUSTRIALPRODUCTION
INDICATOR

1MON
RMSE RANK

FF

11232

11

8.845

1MON
RMSE RANK

8
11

4.778 3

2761

TB03

11.168 9

8.601

TB06

10.735

8

CM01
CMCO

6MOS
RMSERANK

8.301 7

10.664 7

3MOS
RMSE RANK

11

2.162

6

2707 9

2.129

7076 7

4.847 4

2644 7

2.074

8.196 5

6898 4

4.882 5

2630 5

10.577 4

8.154 3

6.897 3

5.029 7

2604 3

CMOS

10.609 5

8.229

6.973 5

8

2

CM10

10.629

8349

EUR03

10.483

CP6

11.196

6
2
10

6
8
1

BAA

10.518 3

NONE

9.901




1

11
10

7.141
7.353

4.993

5.131

8.426 9

6001

10
1
2

4.724

8.184 4

7.158 9

6

7.899

7.902

2

7.172
6.415

7.068

GDP

EMPLOYMENT
12MOS
RMSE RANK

3MOS
RMSERANK

QUARTERLY(Jul73-Dec91)

MONTHLY(Jii73-Feb92)

5.354 9

2599

2625 4

5.495

1
2
11

2657

6
10
8

5.485

10

2463

1

4.531

2630
2752

11
10
8

6MOS
RMSE RANK
10
11

12MOS
RMSE RANK

1QTR
2QTRS
4QTRS
RMSE RANK___ RMSE RANK___ RMSE RANK
2

2
6

3.969 9

3.075

6

2260 5

1974 9

1.702 4

3862 4

3.000 5

2251 4

2.042 7

1932 5

1.706 5

3826 3

2996 4

2356

2.011 5
2.010 4
2036 6
1993 2

1.913

2

1.732 7

3876 5

3094 7

2483 7

1920 4

3936 7

2.124 9

1.951

1.998 3

1915 3

1.784 9

4006

8
1
6
10

3.249

1.847

8
1
6

1757 8
1.626 10
1.610 1
1.686 3

3.144

1

1.953 7

1.913

11

4015

11

1.948

1.988
2031

1.969

1.664
1.728

3.793

3.949
3.622
3880

2859 3

2160

8
10
1
2

2552

3197 9

11

2754
2827

3358

1

6
8

2683 9

2222

3

2216
2725

2
10

2.819

11

TABLE 1.6 - MULTIPERIOD ENCOMPASSING TESTS (Sample Period: Jan 62 - Dec 91)
Probability Value for Null Hypothesis: X is Encompassed by Y
GDP: 1 qtr

FF
TB03
TB06
CM01
CM03
CM05
CM10
EUR03
CP6

BAA

n.a.
0.482
0.945
0.677
0.682
0.637
0.464
0.119
0.272
0.326

TB03

TB06

CM01

CM03

CM05

CM10

EUR03

CP6

BAA

Maximum
P Value

—
n.a
0.204
0.103
0.343
0.375
0.371
—

—
0.796
n.a.
0.342
0.949
0.910
0.798
—

—
0.830
0.947
n.a.
0.264
0.412
0.684

—

—
0.061
—
__
n.a
0.251
0.508
—

—
0.221

—
0.431

—
0.638

—
0.485

—
-—
__
0.065
n.a.
0.563
—
—
0.407

—
—
—
__
—
0.066
n.a
—
—

0.932
0.391
0.403
0.723
0.803
0.906
0.818
n.a.
0.659
0.666

0.856
0.262
0.241
0.524
0.601
0.702
0.976
0.240
n.a.
0.783

—
—
—
__
0.053
0.154
0.380
—
—
n.a.

0.932
0.830
0.947
0.723
0.949
0.910
0.976
0.240
0.659
0.783

0.605
0.340
0.250
0.293
0.360
0.450
0.491
n.a.
0.340
0.989

0.867

—

0.867
0.925
0.448
0.864
0.959
0.975
0.794
0.598
0.340
0.989

—
0.139
0.255
0.980
0.623
0.506
0.555
n.a
0.052
0.767

—
0.661
0.662
0.157
0.166
0.140
0.211
0.785
n.a.
0.456

'

FF

i
UD
I

TB03
TB06
CM01
CM03
CM05
CM10
EUR03
CP6

BAA

n.a.
0.090
0.337
0.582
0.617
0.694
0.665
0.231
0.214
0.574

—
n.a
0.448
0.515
0.959
0.975
0.763
—

—
0.302

0.253

GDP: 2 qtrs
—
0.925
n.a.
0.864
0.443
0.520
0.418
__

—
0.635

—

—

0.310
0.220
n.a.
0.109
0.191
0.210
__
—
0.837

__
—
__
n.a.
0.132
0.096
__
—
.0.429

—

__

__
—
__
—
n.a.
—
__
—
0.228

__
—
__
—

—
n.a.
__
—

—

__
—
__
0.107
0.197
0.263
0.598
n.a.
0.742

—
_
—
0.137
0.794

_
—
n.a.

GDP: 4 qtrs
FF
TB03
TB06
CM01
CM03
CM05
CM10
EUR03
CP6
BAA

n.a.
0.963
0.920
0.596
0.593
. 0.541
0.588
0.539
0.746
0.845

—
n.a
0.910
0.373
0.363
0.302
0.362
0.263
—
0.776

~T
0.152
n.a.
—
—
—
0.130
0.173
—
0.507

NOTE: Values less than or equal to 0.05 are marked with a dash.




—
—
—
n.a.
—
—
0.074
—
—
0.534

—
—
—
—
n.a
—
—
—
0.692

—
—
__
—
—
n.a.
0.072
—
—
0.895

—
—
__
—
—
—
n.a
—
—
0.101

—
—
—

—
—
—
0.419
—

—
n.a.

0.044
0.963
0.920
0.980
0.623
0.541
0.588
0.785
0.746
0.895

1.1. Dynamic Response of Employment to Interest Rate Levels
Fed Funds (FF)

5 year Treasury bond (CM05)

a n n u a l i z e d p e r c e n t g r o w t h rates

a n n u a l i z e d p e r c e n t g r o w t h rates

3 month Treasury bill (TB03)

10 year Treasury bond (CM 10)

6 month Treasury bill (TB06)

1 year Treasury bond (CM01)

6 month commercial paper (CP6)

3 year Treasury bond (CM03)

BAA corporate bond (BAA)




-2 0 -

1.2. Interest Rate Levels: Cumulated Kalman Residuals in Forecasting Real GDP
Fed funds (FF)

5 year Treasury bond (CM05)

c u m u l a t e d K a l m a n residuals

c u m u l a t e d K a l m a n residuals

3 month Treasury bill (TB03)

10 year Treasury bond (CM 10)

3 month eurodollar (EUR03)

6 month Treasury bill (TB06)




BAA corporate bond (BAA)

-21

THE MONETARY AGGREGATES
Table 2.1 lists the monetary indicators which were selected for investigation, along
with some descriptive statistics. For this family of indicators all but one of the variables are
expressed as (log) growth rates: the monetary base [Board of Governors (MB) and St. Louis
(MBSTL) versions], M l, M2, M3, L, and long-term debt of nonfinancial institutions, as well
as real M l and real M2 (deflated by the consumer price index).

The other monetary

indicator is the ratio of nonborrowed reserves (this period) to total reserves (last period)
(NBRX). Strongin (1991) has found that this normalized reserve aggregate contains much
of the information about monetary policy actions which Sims (1991) attributes to innovations
in the Federal Funds rate (orthogonalized relative to output and prices).
Two observations about the descriptive statistics seem to be in order. First, these
aggregates are plausible choices as monetary indicators of economic activity. Focusing on
GDP, the aggregates tend to be correlated with GDP, and the highest correlations are with
the real aggregates Ml and M2.

In fact, it appears to be roughly the case that as the

endogenous component of the monetary aggregate increases, the contemporaneous correlation
with economic activity increases. This is loosely the causation/reverse causation debate—do
the larger monetary aggregates influence activity more than the narrower aggregates, or are
they influenced more? Second, for most of the aggregates the standard deviations are about
one-half or less than the average growth rates; however, for real Ml and M2, the standard
deviations are 2 and 6 times greater than the average growth rate. It turns out below, that
these two aggregates, nominal M2, and the NBR/TR ratio are the most useful indicators.
Table 2.2 reports statistics for the one-period-ahead forecasting model, an
autoregression of the economic activity variable with lagged values of the indicator included.
Focusing on GDP, notice that nominal M2, real M l, real M2, and the NBR/TR ratio provide
significant predictive power for GDP beyond the information contained in past values of
GDP. These three indicators consistently provide predictive power for industrial production




-2 2 -

and employment as well. For GDP the lowest ranking indicators tend to be nonfinancial
debt, the monetary base, and the broad aggregate L.
Figure 2.1 graphs the response of the employment growth forecast to a one-standard
deviation change in information about last period’s indicator.

For all of the monetary

indicators, a positive impulse eventually leads to a positive growth of employment. For most
of these indicators, however, the imprecision of these forecasts is large enough so that the
response is either not statistically significant for most of the response path (nominal M l, M3,
L and nonfinancial debt) or entirely insignificant (both monetary bases). Real Ml and M2
all have similar response patterns: persistent and quick, with the Ml response being a bit
earlier. The responses of nominal M2 and the NBR/TR ratio are also persistent with a bit
more raggedness than the responses to the real aggregates. The NBR/TR ratio also has the
longest significant response. For all of the indicators and economic activity variables, the
maximum one-period impact occurs within one year (reported in Table 2.3).
Tables 2.4 and 2.5 rank the indicator forecasts for in-sample and out-of-sample
forecasts at various horizons. Turning to Table 2.5 first, notice that for the one-month
forecast horizon for both industrial production and employment, the best forecast is one
without any monetary indicators.

For GDP there are four indicators which consistently

provide additional information for forecasts: real M2 (which is always first), the NBR/TR
ratio (always second), nominal M2 and real M l.

These indicators are also useful for

industrial production and employment for six-month horizon and beyond. They are also the
highest ranked indicators in Table 2.4 for the in-sample forecasts.
The monetary aggregates which consistently provide no additional predictive power
beyond the no-indicator model in the out-of-sample rankings are the two monetary base
measures, nominal M l, and L. They also do poorly in the in-sample rankings. This lack
of information is stable across forecast horizons.




-23-

The cumulated residuals from the Kalman forecasts shown in Figure 2.2 provide
another perspective of the out-of-sample performance of our family of money based
measures. In our case, the best indicator is again real M2 as its cumulated residuals path
clearly stays near zero values, except for isolated periods of large forecast errors in 1978 and
1981, when real M2 underforecasted economic activity. Real M2’s performance was again
noticeably good between 1990 and 1991, when most of the other money based indicators
clearly failed to predict the recession. The NBR/TR ratio was relatively stable from 1973
to 1981, but has shown a consistent pattern of overforecasting output growth since 1982.
This deterioration may be due to increasing reluctance on the part of banks to borrow from
the discount window. The performance of other monetary aggregates is less reliable and
clearly more volatile than the behavior of real M2 and the NBR/TR ratio. For example, the
two measures of the monetary base and Ml consistently underforecasted real GDP between
1974 and 1977, as shown by their upward sloping paths.

Overall, the path of nominal

aggregates plunged during the credit control program of 1980, overpredicting output growth
during the mild recession. From 1983 to 1988, these nominal aggregates performed fairly
well, exhibiting uncharacteristic stability, except for Ml which did substantially worse
between 1983 and 1984.

Finally, between 1990 and 1991, there was a considerable

deterioration in the performance of M l, L, and the two measures of the monetary base, as
they consistently overpredicted economic growth.
Table 2.6 reports the encompassing results for GDP.

For each of the forecast

horizons, we find that real M2 is not dominated by any of the other forecasts (reading across
the real M2 row, the hypothesis is always rejected at low marginal significance levels).
None of the other indicator forecasts can cover the information contained in real M2.
Furthermore, the real M2 forecasts cover the information contained in all of the other
indicator forecasts (reading down the real M2 column, the hypothesis that real M2 covers




-24-

each forecast is not rejected). Therefore, real M2 is a dominant indicator within the class
of monetary indicators selected here for GDP.




-25-

TABLE 2.1 - DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS

MONTHLY (Jan 62- Feb 92)

QUARTERLY (Jan 6 2 - Dec 91)

Correlation with
Industrial
Employment
Production

Mean

Std. Dev.

Correlation with
Real GDP

-0.058

6.784

2.195

0.034

-0.021

-0.027

6.662

2.282

0.013

5.864

0.005

-0.033

6.055

3.730

0.157

7.750

4.082

0.119

0.013

7.769

3.292

0.236

M3

8.323

4.072

0.113

0.092

8.363

3.520

0.246

L

8.138

3.662

0.167

0.175

8.183

3.057

0.239

DBTNF

8.977

2.752

0.175

0.290

9.017

2.446

0.180

M1R

1.085

7.245

0.063

0!009

0.971

5.143

0.297

M2R

2.675

5.837

0.156

0.053

2.685

4.868

0.353

NBRX

0.976

0.027

0.059

-0.026

0.983

0.029

0.154

Indicator

Mean

Std. Dev.

MBSTL

6.785

3.617

-0.014

MB

6.710

3.321

M1

6.160

M2




TABLE 2.2 - CLASSICAL GOODNESS-OF-FIT STATISTICS

MONTHLY (Jan 62 - Feb 92)

MONTHLY (Jan 62 - Feb 92)

INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION

QUARTERLY (Jan 62 - Dec 91)

EMPLOYMENT

GDP

R2

Change
in R2

SEE

P-Value

Rank

R2

Change
in R2

SEE

P-Value

Rank

R2

Change
in R2

SEE

P-Value

MBSTL

0.225

0.029

9.169

0.3997

8

0.393

0.019

2.363

0.5618

9

0.166

0.049

3.532

0.1744

7

MB

0.222

0.027

9.182

0.4760

9

0.389

0.015

2.370

0.7445

10

0.145

0.027

3.577

0.4734

9

M1

0.221

0.026

9.188

0.5172

10

0.401

0.028T

2.346

0.2192

8

0.172

0.055

3.519

0.1284

5

M2

0.252

0.057

9.003

0.0144

3

0.442

0.069

2.264

0.0001

2

0.219

0.101

3.419

0.0084

4

M3

0.229

0.033

9.144

0.2755

7

0.412

0.039

2.324

0.0383

5

0.169

0.052

3.525

0.1483

6

L

0.236

0.041

9.100

0.1246

5

0.404

0.030

2.341

0.1486

6

0.164

0.046

3.538

0.1993

8

DBTNF

0.231

0.036

9.128

0.2092

6

0,401

0.028

2.346

0.2156

7

0.124

0.006

3.620

0.9352

10

M1R

0.244

0.048

9.054

0.0477

4

0.418

0.044

2.314

0.0148

4

0.250

0.132

3.351

0.0012

2

M2R

0.284

0.089

8.808

0.0001

1

0.444

0.071

2.260

0.0001

1

0.346

0.228

3.128

0.0000

1

NBRX

0.277

0.081

8.854

0.0003

2

0.426

0.053

2.297

0.0028

3

0.249

0.131

3.352

0.0012

3

Indicator

-27-




Rank

TABLE 2.3 - MAXIMUM IMPACT OF DYNAMIC MULTIPLIERS

MONTHLY (Jan 62 - Feb 92)

MONTHLY (Jan 62 - Feb 92)

EMPLOYMENT

INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION

Months to
Indicator__________Max

-28


QUARTERLY (Jan 62 - Dec 91)
GDP

Max Impact

Std. Dev.
at Max

Months to
Max

Max Impact

Std. Dev.
at Max

Quarters to
Max

Max Impact

Std. Dev.
at Max

MBSTL

4

1.054

0.489

8

0.221

0.148

2

0.787

0.323

MB

10

0.894

0.508

5

0.192

0.138

2

0.410

0.300

M1

7

1.145

0.515

3

0.370

0.126

2

0.671

0.328

M2

7

1.755

0.476

9

0.705

0.137

2

0.904

0.309

M3

7

1.393

0.538

9

0.500

0.149

3

0.787

0.344

L

7

1.655

0.507

9

0.458

0.143

3

0.739

0.333

DBTNF

2

1.214

0.447

5

0.332

0.126

4

0.113

0.301

M1R

7

1.371

0.513

5

0.485

0.124

2

1.011

0.321

M2R

7

1.567

0.464

5

0.568

0.128

2

1.069

0.289

NBRX

12

1.467

0.496

8

0.449

0.148

3

1.047

0.308

TABLE Z4 - MULTIPERIOD FORECASTS (In-Sample)

Indicator

1 MON
R2 RANK

MONTHLY (Jan 62 - Feb 92)

MONTHLY (Jan 62 - Feb 92)

INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION

EMPLOYMENT

3MOS
R2 RANK

6 MOS
R2 RANK

12MOS
R2 RANK

1 MON
R2 RANK

3 MOS
R2 RANK

QUARTERLY (Jan 62 - Dec 91)
GDP

6 MOS
R2 RANK

12 MOS
R2 RANK

1 CTTR
R2 RANK

2QTRS
R2 RANK

4 0TRS
R2 RANK

MBSTL

0225

8

0230

8

0.144

10

0.113

10

0393

9

0506

8

0.434

8

0274

10

0.166

7

0.154

8

0.102

8

MB

0222

9

0226

9

0.145

8

0.135

8

0389 10

0.499

9

0.424

9

0276

9

0.145

9

0.144

9

0.121

5

M1

0221

10

0259

7

0.199

6

0.127

9

0.401

8

0523

7

0.454

7

0288

7

0.172

5

0.183

7

0.096

10

M2

0252

3

0335

3

0333

3

0268

4

0.442

2

0581

2

0540

2

0394

4

0219

4

0249

4

0.186

4

M3

0229

7

0274

5

0211

5

0.165

5

0.412

5

0546

5

0.487

5

0324

5

0.169

6

0.189

5

0.107

7

L

0236

5

0269

6

0.195

7

0.146

7

0.404

6

0527

6

0.461

6

0291

6

0.164

8

0.184

6

0.097

9

DBTNF

0231

6

0225 10

0.144

9

0.151

6

0.401

7

0.496

10

0.420

10

0285

8

0.124

10

0.133

10

0.121

6

M1R

0244

4

0320

4

0304

4

0282

3

0.418

4

0557

4

0517

4

0.415

3

0250

2

0288

3

0244

3

M2R

0284

1

0.413

1

0.478

1

0567

1

0.444

1

0.609

1

0.604

1

0573

1

0346

1

0.447

1

0514

1

NBRX

0277

2

0365

2

0386

2

0.417

2

0.426

3

0562

3

0525

3

0.446

2

0249

3

0.327

2.

0292

2

NONE

0.196 11

0201

11

0.115

11

0.097

11

0373 11

0.489

11

0.414

11

0269

11

0.118

11

0.123

11

0.076

11




TABLE 2-5 - KALMAN MULTIPERIOD FORECASTS (Out-of-Sample)
MONTHLY(Jii73-Feb92)

MONTHLY(Jul73-Feb92)

________INDUSTRIALPRODUCTION __________

____

QUARTERLY (Jul73-Doc91)

GDP

EMPLOYMENT

Indicator

1MON
RMSE RANK

3MOS
RMSERANK

SMOS
RMSERANK

12MOS
RMSE RANK

1MON
RMSE RANK

3MOS
RMSE RANK

6MOS
RMSE RANK

12MOS
RMSE RANK

1QTR
RMSE RANK

2QTRS
RMSE RANK

4QTRS
RMSE RANK

MBSTL

10406 8

8.317 11

7.468 11

5.736 8

2583 6

2.040 10

2058 11

2012 9

4.108 7

3.474 10

2904 8

MB

10.275 5

8.142 5

7244 6

5.594 7

2553 5

2.011 6

2023 7

1.986 7

4.114 8

3426 7

2840 7

M1

10.452 10

8.218 10

7.273 8

5.760 9

2587 8

2.022 7

2030 8

2023 10

4149 10

3455 9

2992 11

M2

10.368 6

7.780 3

6.648 3

5.425 4

2585 7

1.931 3

1.896 3

1.894 3

3944 3

3.252 3

2809 4

M3

10.447 9

8.161 8

7.308 9

5.843 10

2610 9

1.998 5

2006 6

1.997 8

4.073 5

3.394 6

2948 10

L

10.405 7

8.174 9

7.382 10

5.843 11

2630 10

2.028 8

2050 10

2043 11

4136 9

3.432 8

2926 9

DBTNF

10.112 4

8.157 6

7.270 7

5.498 6

2535 4

2034 9

2041 9

1.955 6

4.242 11

3.495 11

2820 6

M1R

10.630 11

8.159 7

6.952 4

5.309 3

2671 11

2.064 11

2004 5

1.905 4

4.097 6

3.285 4

2775 3

M2R

10111 3

7.368 2

5.902 1

4.229 1

2483 3

1.838 1

1.731 1

1.558 1

3674 1

2.844 1

2.219 1

NBRX

9947 2

7.362 1

6.096 2

4.594 2

2477 2

1.903 2

1.828 2

1.711 2

3799 2

3.003 2

2550 2

NONE

9.890 1

7894 4

7.064 5

5.485 5

2463 1

1.948 4

1.953 4

1913 5

4.015 4

3358 5

2.819 5







TABLE 2.6 - MULTIPERIOD ENCOMPASSING TESTS (Sample Period: Jan 62 Dec 91)
Probability Value for Null Hypothesis: X is Encompassed by Y
GDP: 1 qtr_____________
Y

MBSTL

MB

M1

M2

M3

L

DBTNF

M1R

M2R_________ NBRX

n.a.
0.726
0.055
—
0.138
0.119
0.694
—
—

0.064
n.a
—
—
__
—
0.755
—

0.150
0.307
n.a.
—

0.462
0.569
0.506
n.a.
0.733
0.407
0.771
—
—

0.178
0.296
0.105
__
n.a
0.324
0.716
—
—

0.094
0.224
0.054
__
0.174
n.a.
0.825
—
—

__
0.075
.—

—

0.759
0.936
0.855
0.954
0.653
0.449
0.970
0.924
n.a
0.286

0.411
0.500
0.671
—
0.149
0.286
0.755
—

—

__
—
n.a.
—
—
—

0.763
0.682
0.658
0.098
0.327
0.322
0.829
n.a
—

0.359
0.445

0.167

0.959
0.722
0.845
0.119
0.193
0.333
0.745

n.a

0.954
0.994
0.970
0.833
0.560
0.284
0.973
0.752

—

n.a

Maximum
P Value

X
MBSTL
MB
M1
M2
M3
L
DBTNF
M1R
M2R
NBRX

—

—
—

0.135
0.136
0.669
—
—
—

—

—

—
n.a.

0.763
0.936
0.855
0.954
0.733
0.449
0.970
0.924
0.000
0.286

GDP: 2 qtrs
MBSTL
MB
M1
M2
M3
L
DBTNF
M1R
M2R
NBRX

n.a.
0.595
—
—

—
—
0.490
—
—
—

0.266
n.a
—
—
—
—
0.715
—
—
—

0.760
0.516
n.a.

—

0.064
—
0.604
—
—
—

0.817
0.654
0.667
n.a.
0.603
0.258
0.691
—
—
—

0.484
0.477

0.112

—

—

—
0.197

n.a.

0.294
0.533
—
—

n.a.

0.697
—
—

__
—
—
—

—
n.a.

—

—

1.000
0.686
0.803
0.173
0.323
0.274
0.774

0.101

1.000
0.994
0.970
0.833
0.603
0.333
0.973
0.752

—

0.000

0.133

n.a.

0.133

n.a

0.782
0.817
0.841
0.430
0.918
0.824
0.836
0.257

0.930
0.817
0.987
0.430
0.918
0.975
0.836
0.305

—
—

n.a

0.896
0.464
0.958
0.400
0.746
0.975
0.334
0.305
—

0.473

n.a.

0.473

GDP: 4 qtrs
MBSTL
MB
M1
M2
M3
L
DBTNF
M1R
M2R
NBRX

n.a.
0.336
0.658
—
0.452
0.521
0.196

—

—
—

0.930
n.a
0.693
—
0.392
0.523
0.331
—
—
—

0.341
0.126
n.a.
—
0.424
0.396
0.072

—

—

—

NOTE: Values less than or equal to 0.05 are marked with a dash.

0.604
0.248
0.914
n.a.
0.612
0.523
0.230
—

—

—

0.525
0.228
0.669
—

0.344
—

n.a

0.439
—
0.442

0.626
0.209
—
—
—

0.089
—
—
—

n.a.

0.659
0.330
0.517
—
0.375
0.652
n.a.

—
—
—

0.840
0.362
0.987
0.263
0.776
0.802
0.300

0.000

2.1. Dynamic Response of Employment to Money Based Measures
St. Louis monetary base (MBSTL)

Nominal L (L)

FRB monetary base (MB)

Nominal nonfinancial debt (DBTNF)

Nominal M1 (M1)

Real M1 (M1R)

Nominal M2 (M2)

Real M2 (M2R)

Nominal M3 (M3)

NBR/TR ratio (NBRX)




-3 2 -

2.2. Money Based Measures: Cumulated Kalman Residuals in Forecasting Real GDP
St. Louis monetary base (MBSTL)

Nominal L (L)

c u m u l a t e d K a l m a n residuals

c u m u l a t e d K a l m a n residuals

FRB monetary base (MB)

Real M1 (M1R)

y ^ v x T ^ T -v
.50 i l I 1 l l I 1 l.-1 1 I i l 111 1.I
Nominal M2 (M2)

Real M2 (M2R)

NBR/TR ratio (NBRX)

Nominal M3 (M3)




33

INTEREST RATE SPREADS
Recent research on financial market indicators of economic activity has brought
renewed attention to interest rates spreads. Laurent (1988), Bernanke (1990), Estrella and
Hardouvelis (1991), Friedman-Kuttner (1992), Kashyup-Stein-Wilcox (1991), and StockWatson (1989) have suggested and tested various interest rate spreads as predictors of
economic activity with significant success. The idea behind most of these spreads is that the
difference in yields between two different debt instruments provides information beyond that
in the level of interest rates. The two primary types of interest rates spreads that have been
used are risk-spreads which measure the difference in yield between a private debt instrument
and the yield on a government bond of equivalent maturity and term-spreads which measure
the difference in yield of government debt instruments of different maturities.
Typically, the motivation for the risk spreads is that the risk in the private debt
instrument is a measure of the market’s assessment of the near term risk in the relevant
business environment and that high risk implies a tough time for business ahead. FriedmanKuttner have argued that this interpretation is probably flawed since the spreads are typically
too large to be explained by any reasonable estimate of the risk inherent in the private debt
instruments and suggest that liquidity considerations play a significant role in the pricing of
public-private spreads. Following their lead, we also will refer to these spreads as publicprivate spreads.
The term-spreads seek to measure the relative availability of credit through time. The
convention is that the shorter maturity yield is subtracted from the longer. Thus, a positive
spread would indicate that short term funding is available at a lower rate than longer term
funding. The normal interpretation is that if short-term funds are especially cheap relative
to long-term funds this will encourage borrowing and economic activity. An alternative
explanation is that the higher long-term yields are signaling expectations of higher future
credit demand resulting from increased economic activity. A third interpretation is that by




-34-

taking the difference between a short- and long-term interest rate you are correcting the
shorter term rate for changes in inflationary expectations and taxes, leaving a better measure
of short-run credit conditions. In any case, all of these term-spread measures have the
counter-intuitive implication that a rise in long-term interest rates is good for the near-term
outlook of the economy. Estrella and Hardouvelis (1991) and Strongin (1990) attempt to
reconcile the term-spread results with current theory with limited success.
We test 3 public-private spreads and 5 term-spreads5. The specific measures we use
are the TED or Eurodollar spread which is the 3-month Eurodollar rate minus the 3-month
Treasury bill rate. The Commercial Paper spread which is the 6-month Commercial Paper
spread minus the 6-month Treasury bill rate, and the Baa spread which is the Baa yield
minus the 10-year Treasury bond rate6. The five term-spreads contain three spreads based
on the Federal Funds Rate, a short, a medium, and a long spread -- the short spread is the
3-month bill rate minus the Federal Funds rate -- the medium spread is the 12-month bill rate
minus the Federal Funds rate —the long spread is the 10-year bond rate minus the Federal
Funds rate. There are two intermediate spreads as well, the 12-month/3-month spread and
the 10-year/1-year spread.
Table 3.1 shows that as expected the public-private spreads all show a strong negative
correlation with economic activity and the term-spreads all show a positive correlation with
activity: the shorter the term-spread, the higher the correlation.
Table 3.2 indicates that based on classical measures of fit all of the spreads do fairly
well in explaining all three measures of economic activity. The R2s for industrial production

5. These are the only commonly used spreads available for the entire data sample. We
also examined other spreads for shorter sample periods, but the results did not change and
the public-private spreads here presented continued to dominate.
6. The 10-year rate is used because the 7-year which might be preferred is not available
for a sufficient time span.




-35-

range from .236 to .339; the range for employment growth is .416 to .459; and the range
for GDP is from .234 to .339. With the exception of the 12-month/3-month term-spread,
every spread Granger causes activity at a high level of significance. The only exception is
the 12-month/3-month spread which fails to Granger cause industrial production.

The

public-private spreads do a better job of predicting employment and industrial production
with the Commercial Paper spread and the Baa spread ranking 1 and 2. For GDP the results
are more mixed with the Commercial Paper spread and 12-month/Federal fund spread
coming in 2nd.
The dynamic response path graphs in Figure 3.1 show substantial difference in the
dynamic response of employment growth by type of spread. The response of employment
to an increase in the Baa spread shows a quickly rise, peaking at only 3 months. The
response then dies just as quickly. The response paths for the two shorter-term publicprivate spreads, the Commercial Paper spread, and the Eurodollar spread build rapidly then
plateau for a number of months and then die quickly. The term-spread response paths, with
exception of the 12-month/3-month spread, all build slowly, peak and then slowly die out.
Only in the case of the Baa spread is there a well-defined peak in the response path, all of
the other spreads show extended periods of impact. This would suggest that the strength of
the Baa spread will be in very short horizon forecasts, the strength of the Commercial Paper
and Eurodollar spreads will be at short and middle horizons, while the strength of the termspreads will be in longer term forecasts. Table 3.3 suggests similar conclusions with the Baa
spread showing the quickest, largest and most tightly estimated peak for employment and
industrial production. The longer horizon GDP results show the impact of the Baa spread
falling off considerably, though still very quickly.
Tables 3.4 and 3.5 strongly re-enforce these conclusions and provide some startling
evidence on the effect of forecast horizons on indicator performance. First, in Table 3.4 it
is clear that the performance of the Baa spread falls off dramatically as the forecast horizon




-36-

is increased.

Ranking 2nd for industrial production and employment at the one-month

horizon, the rank drops to 6th and 7* for industrial production and employment respectively
for the three-month horizon and is dead last by six months for all measures of activity. The
Commercial Paper spread, on the other hand, does very well ranking 1st until the one-year
horizon in both employment and industrial production, when it is superseded by a number
of term-spreads. In forecasting GDP, the Commercial Paper spread still does very well at
the one-quarter horizon, but fades quickly falling to 4th at the six-month horizon and 6th at
the one-year horizon. The Federal Funds rate based spreads do very well as the forecasting
horizon lengthens. Starting out in the middle to back of the pack at the shortest horizons
they rise to dominate the top of the ranking at the one-year horizon with the 12month/Federal Funds spread rising to 1st for all three measures of activity. The intermediate
spreads rarely do well.
Table 3.5, showing the out-of-sample results, shows a very similar story in terms of
rankings. The interesting additional fact is how well the spread models stand up to the no­
indicator model. At every horizon except one-month the spread models strongly outperform
the no-indicator model, though at the one-month horizon the no-indicator model does
outperform all of the spread models except the Baa spread, which is only good at short
horizons. Clearly the forecast horizon is extremely important to the evaluation of interest
rate spread models.
The cumulated residuals from the Kalman forecasts in Figure 3.2 show some striking
similarities in the overall forecasting performance of our family of interest rate spreads.
Except for the 3-, 6-, and 12-month/Federal Funds rate spreads, all of our spreads tend to
overforecast real GDP, as shown by their consistently negative residuals. While the 3-, 6-,
and 12-month/Federal Funds rate spreads performed fairly well from 1973 to 1980, they
clearly failed during the last three recessions. In fact, they all underforecasted economic
activity between 1980 and 1982, and then overpredicted real GDP between 1990 and 1991.




-3 7 -

Between 1982 and 1989, their path was conspicuously flat. This suggests that these spreads
do well in forecasting normal periods of economic activity, but periodically fail in predicting
recessions. Although the 5-year/ and 10-year/Federal Funds rate spreads follow a similar
pattern between 1973 and 1981, after 1982 their cumulated residuals path never stabilized
but plunged to persistently negative values. Our intermediate term spreads (12-month/3month and 10-year/l-year spreads) failed during all of the recessions in our sample period
(including the 1973-1975 recession), and developed a consistently negative bias after 1982,
as they clearly overpredicted real GDP. All of the private/public spreads followed the same
general pattern of mediocre performance from 1973 to 1981, and persistent overprediction
of economic activity thereafter. In general, we conclude that, although a persistent bias in
forecasting exists in all of the interest rate spreads we investigated, some of them did fairly
well during most of our sample period, but failed during periods of large scale financial
restructuring.
The encompassing tests in Table 3.6 are exactly what would be expected given the
previous results. To fully encompass all of the information in the interest rate spreads it is
usually necessary to include both a public-private spread and a term-spread.

Also not

surprisingly, the Commercial Paper spread and the 12-month/Federal Funds rate spreads
dominate their respective groupings at the one- and two-quarter horizons. It is interesting
to note that the Stock-Watson leading indicator index, which was designed to fit data at the
six-month horizon, chose the Commercial Paper spread and the 10-year/l-year spread. For
our sample period, the 12-month/Federal Funds spread narrowly dominates the 10-year/lyear spread. At the 4-quarter horizon the public-private spread no longer contains additional
information beyond that contained in the 12-month/Federal Funds spread.

The 12-

month/Federal Funds spread, however, does not dominate since it fails to cover (only) the
10-year/l-year spread. We selected the 10-year/Federal Funds spread since it covers more
spreads than the 10-year/l-year spread, covers the 10-year/l-year spread, and performs




-38-

better out-of-sample. The selection of two term spreads is consistent with the previously
noted results that the public-private spreads do not contain as much long run information as
the term-spreads. It is interesting to note that examination of the entire encompassing results
indicate that the separation between the public-private spreads and the term-spreads is not
very clear. At some horizons some term-spreads encompass some public-private spreads
while at other horizons the results reverse.

This would seem to indicate that there are

common multiple driving forces in the determination of these spreads, and that those driver
factors associated with longer horizon economic activity predominate in the term-spreads
with the common factors that drive short-run performance and dominate the public-private
spreads.




-39-




TABLE 3.1 - DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS

QUARTERLY (Jan 62- Dec 91)

MONTHLY (Jan 62- Feb 92)
Correlation with
Industrial
Employment
Production

Mean

Std. Dev.

Correlation with
Real GDP

0.252

-0.750

0.807

0.449

0.292

0.255

-0593

0.886

0.442

1.149

0.291

0.254

-0580

1.082

0.425

0.384

1586

0.210

0.123

0.373

1511

0.321

CM10FF

0514

1.791

0.200

0.114

0.499

1.713

0.309

TB12TB3

0.170

0.468

0.177

0.158

0.170

0.434

0.225

CM10CM1

0.601

1.036

0.083

0.001

0588

0.997

0.170

EUR0TB3

1.428

0331

-0.235

-0.248

1.434

0.885

-0.378

CP6TB6

0579

0.489

-0.305

-0297

0582

0.461

-0.431

BAACM10

1.722

0.698

-0.248

-0.390

1.720

0.690

-0.297

Indicator

Mean

Std. Dev.

TB3FF

-0.747

0.864

0.291

TB6FF

-0.591

0348

TB12FF

-0.577

CM05FF

.

TABLE 3.2 - CLASSICAL GOODNESS-OF-FIT STATISTICS

GDP

EMPLOYMENT

INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION

R2

Change
In R2

3

0.327

0209

3.174 0.0000

3

0.0012

5

0.321

0204

3.187 0.0000

4

2291

0.0016

6

0.330

0212

3.166 0.0000

2

0.042

2.318

0.0224

10

0.302

0.185

3.231

0.0000

6

0.416

0.043

2.316

0.0186

9

0.309

0.191

3.216 0.0000

5

10

0.424

0.050

2.302

0.0047

7

0238

0.120

3.377 0.0026

9

0.0207

9

0.417

0.044

2.315

0.0163

8

0284

0.166

3.273

0.0001

8

8.870

0.0004

6

0:431

0.058

2.286

0.0009

4

0294

0.177

3.250

0.0001

7

0.144

8.462

0.0000

1

0.459

0.086

2.229

0.0000

1

0.339

0221

3.145 0.0000

1

0.108

8.691

0.0000

2

0.437

0.064

2.274

0.0002

2

0234

0.116

3.386 0.0033

10

R2

Change
in R2

SEE

P-Value

Rank

R2

Change
In R2

SEE

TB3FF

0.291

0.095

8.769

0.0000

3

0.435

0.062

2.278

0.0004

TB6FF

0.280

0.085

8.834

0.0002

4

0.430

0.057

2.289

TB12FF

0275

0.079

8.866

0.0004

5

0.429

0.055

CMQ5FF

0.256

0.061

8.981

0.0084

7

0.415

CM10FF

0254

0.059

8.992

0.0111

8

TB12TB3

0.236

0.041

9.099

0.1224

CM10CM1

0250'

0.054

9.018

EUROTB3

0.274

0.079

CP6TB6

0.340

BAACM10

0.303

Indicator




QUARTERLY (Jan 62 - Dec 91)

MONTHLY (Jan 62 - Feb 92)

MONTHLY (Jan 62 - Feb 92)

P-Value Rank

SEE

P-Value Rank

TABLE 3.3 - MAXIMUM IMPACT OF DYNAMIC MULTIPLIERS

MONTHLY (Jan 62 - Feb 92)

MONTHLY (Jan 62 - Feb 92)
INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION

Months to
Indicator_________ Max

QUARTERLY (Jan 62 - Dec 91)

EMPLOYMENT

GDP

Max Impact

Std. Dev.
at Max

Months to
Max

Max Impact

Std. Dev.
at Max

Quarters to
Max

Max Impact

Std. Dev.
at Max

TB3FF

7

1.991

0.483

6

0.500

0.127

3

1.408

0.310

TB6FF

7

1.731

0.468

6

0.466

0.128

3

1.283

0.277

TB12FF

7

1.446

0.466

6

0.412

0.125

3

1.259

0.285

CM05FF

7

1.091

0.478

15

0.355

0.087

3

1.195

0.294

CM10FF

7

1.022

0.497

9

0.370

0.134

3

1.243

0.293

TB12TB3

14

1.375

0.382

14

0.534

0.111

5

0.879

0.282

CM10CM1

5

1.471

0.486

9-

0.342

0.134

3

1.243

0.296

EUROTB3

7

-2.083

0.515

12

-0.553

0.146

3

-1.493

0.338

CP6TB6

9

-2.476

0.480

8

-0.711

0.136

3

-1.449

0.312

BAACM10

3

-2.645

0.473

3

-0.519

0.121

2

-0.833

0.312




'

TABLE3.4- MULTIPERIODFORECASTS(IrvSample)
MONTHLY (Jan 62 - Feb 92)

MONTHLY (Jan 62 - Feb 92)

___________ INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION________________

Indicator

1 MON
R2 RANK

3 MOS
R2 RANK

6MOS
R2 RANK

12MOS
R2 RANK

________
1 MON
R2 RANK

QUARTERLY (Jan 62-•Dec 91)

EMPLOYMENT
3 MOS
R2 RANK

GDP

6 MOS
R2 RANK

12 MOS
R2 RANK

1 OTR
R2 RANK

2QTRS
R2 RANK

4GTRS
R2 RANK

TB3FF

0.291

3

0.402

2

0.477

2

0224

3

0.435

3

0291

3

0285

4

0249

6

0.327

3

0.446

3

0.437

5

TB6FF

0280

4

0282

3

0.456

3

0247

2

0.430

5

0290

4

0295

3

0295

2

0.321

4

0.459

2

0.490

4

TB12FF

0275

5

0269

5

0.438

4

0255

1

0.429

6

0293

2

0.604

2

0.626

1

0330

2

0.470

1

0218

1

CM05FF

0256

7

0234

7

0281

7

0.488

4

0.415 10

0269

7

0269

6

0285

4

0302

6

0.428

6

0.498

2

CM10FF

0254

8

0237

6

0285

6

0.484

5

0.416

9

0272

5

0274

5

0287

3

0309

5

0.435

4

0.491

3

TB12TB3

0236

10

0286

10

0269

9

0258

8

0.424

7

0267

8

0263

7

0272

5

0238

9

0333

9

0383

7

CM10CM1

0250

9

0205

9

0296

8

0261

7

0.417

8

0252

10

0226

9

0.489

8

0284

8

0374

7

0396

6

EUROTB3

0274

6

0280

4

0.413

5

0223

9

0.431

4

0271

6

0242

8

0.431

9

0294

7

0364

8

0230

9

CP6TB6

0240

1

0200

1

0259

1

0.426

6

0.459

1

0234

1

0.623

1

0206

7

0339

1

0.429

5

0289

8

BAACM10

0203

2

0224

8

0218

10

0.168

10

0.437

2

0253

9

0.461

10

0293

10

0234

10

0.175

10

0.138

10

NONE

0.196

11

0201

11

0.115 11

0.097

11

0273 11

0.489

11

0.414

11

0269

11

0.118

11

0.123

11

0.076

11




TABLE33•KALMANMULTIPERIODFORECASTS(Out-of-Sampte)
MONTHLY(Jul73•Feb92)

MONTHLY(Jul73-Feb92)
INDUSTRIALPRODUCTION

QUARTERLY(Jut73-Dec91)
GDP

EMPLOYMENT

Indicator

1MON
RMSE RANK

3MOS
RMSERANK

6MOS
RMSERANK

12MOS
RMSERANK

1MON
RMSE RANK

3MOS
RMSE RANK

6MOS
RMSE RANK

12MOS
RMSE RANK

1QTR
RMSE RANK

2QTRS
RMSE RANK

4QTRS
RMSE RANK

TB3FF

10.161 5

7.421 3

5.763 2

4.209 3

2.581 5

1.937 4

1.785 3

1.599 6

3.609 1

2.674 1

2253 5

TB6FF

10.371 6

7.768 4

6.075 4

4.081 1

2.624 7

1.960 6

1.775 2

1.492 3

3.691 3

2.691 2

2081 2

TB12FF

10.582 8

8.164 8

6.539 5

4.207 2

2.658 9

1.986 7

1.791 4

1.435 1

3.753 6

2.754 3

2015 1

CM05FF

10.931 9

8.386 9

6.742 7

4.517 4

2.708 10

2.055 9

1.866 8

1.504 5

3.745 5

2811 6

2111 3

CM10FF

10.970 10

8.390 10

6.656 6

4.542 5

2.740 11

2.063 11

1.853 6

1.495 4

3.763 7

2785 5

2161 4

TB12TB3

11.054 11

8.539 11

7.169 11

4.906 7

2.653 8

2.030 8

1.866 7

1.479 2

4.197 11

3.187 9

2370 6

CM10CM1

10.572 7

8.149 7

6.891 8

5.053 9

2.622 6

2.055 10

1.937 9

1.674 7

3.857 8

2970 8

2389 7

EUROTB3

9.898 3

7.289 2

5.937 3

5.048 8

2.512 3

1.926 3

1.834 5

1.779 9

3.698 4

2886 7

2721 8

CP6TB6

9.930 4

6.703 1

4.922 1

4.806 6

2.543 4

1.790 1

1.632 1

1.710 8

3656 2

2760 4

2744 9

BAACM10

9.858 1

7.785 5

7.025 9

5.575 11

2.446 1

1.913 2

1.972 11

1.998 11

3.983 9

3.485 11

2846 11

NONE

9.890 2

7.894 6

7.064 10

5.485 10

2.463 2

1.948 5

1.953 10

1.913 10

4.015 10

3.358 10

2.819 10




siaSsKlSil
oooooooooo

oooooooooo

III
III

II III
II III

! I III
I j$ cd
I I I
1^ c

I I I

II III




1 l to*
1 1 -Sdo

h- <
y> 0> r- N. CO
52 S
gj 2 88 aS3 ££ 2S
£

d o'

dodo

II I M2
1 ' 18
o

CO O | |
1 !8
o' o'
o

r- O rCD
r-s
cm co co i i o>
o
o o o'

l l
l I

I I
I l

|| |

co r-.co to to
3 R 2 8 815Si
oooo

in ,s Q) cm n
$2 ria £ 8 8 I III
o' c o o o' d 1 III

cd o
d o 1 1 o'

COtOr-O^v-JlCCtp^
CQCQQQS2QQ23Q.<
hhhOOhSiuom

I I I

I I

I I I

1 1 1 1 1 2- • «
1 ill
1 1 1 o co i
1i
1§
o>
11
o'
o' c

1 1 1 o .CO o> 1 1 1 CL
0.54
n.a
0.41
0.69

t
0
1
o

r*§
o

II

II

I I cd t 8

I I I I H I ft

IIIIM

a5R
c o o' o'

I l I I I I 5 § - o>

i l

l

I

I cd l © l

l I l l I c I S I £

4qtrs

&

i i 1 i i i i8 (d K
I I I I I I I o c ^o

8 ^ 8 8 8

o

i

o' d o' d I

i i

o
8
o'

o>
I 3
I o

T
to
CO
^ i i i l iC
▼—
M 6>
§ i ' i 1 'do'

COtOr-O^^^OCtp^;
2 D Q . <

C Q C Q C D 2 5

c q

hhhOOhOlUUCD

-45-

Q_
S
^

8

o'

! i § ^ 8 § 8 £ §

o

C
O8
•*“
o
o' o'

o' o' o' o' o'

n
jn
S c
So i
8n 8
Jj
oo S
n 8
co

o' d o' d o' d

CD N ,(D Tf (D CM O) O CM
8 Si5 £ 2 fc 8 & 3 3
o o' o' o' o' o' d o'o'

C\l
C
M
CO

I I ’- I

CM

I I I I I
I I I I I

c q c d c q

2

2

c q

O) O (M
o' o' o'
S?£o8

I £
I d

2

d

c

l

<

hhhOUhOUJOEQ

NOTE: Values less than or equal to 0.05 are marked with a dash.

c
o r-m
1CsM
0
*—- (
j 1
|
O) n
O■
r
Jt!
1 1I
oo
odd

I I I

n.a.

CO
e
C
M
T“
C
HO

II

I I I I I I I I I ffl
I I I I I I I lie

0.436

I I
I I

l l _j

n.a.

I
I

II

II II™

SSSSgBSSSg
oooooooooo

I I I I cd
I I lie

tooo> j
ig
co i
m |
t0
o <do
w
jg
I0

II I

TABLE 3.6 - MULTIPERIOD ENCOMPASSING TESTS (Sample Period: Jan 62 - Dec 91)
Probability Value for Null Hypothesis: X is Encompassed by Y

II II I I eg*
II II lid

GDI 2qtrs

|l

.£ «
S>
■5 a-

3.1. Dynamic Response of Employment to Interest Rate Spreads
3 month T bill less fed funds (TB3FF)
annualized percent growth rates

1 year T bill less 3 month T bill (TB12TB3)
annualized percent growth rates

10 year T bond less 1 year T bond (CM10CM1)

12 month T bill less fed funds (TB12FF)




3 month eurodollar less 3 month T bill (EUROTB3)

6 month commercial paper less 6 month T bill (CP6TB6)

BAA corporate bond less 10 year T bond (BAACM10)

-46-

3.2. Interest Rate Spreads: Cumulated Kalman Residuals in Forecasting Real GDP
3 month T bill less fed funds (TB3FF)

12 month T bill less 3 month T bill (TB12TB3)

c u m u la t e d K a lm a n r e s id u a ls

c u m u la t e d K a lm a n r e s id u a ls

12 month T bill less fed funds (TB12FF)

3 month eurodollar less 3 month T bill (EUROTB3)




6 mo. commercial paper less 6 mo. T bill (CP6TB6)

BAA corporate bond less 10 year T bond (BAACM10)

-47-

C O M P O S IT E IN D ICA TO RS

The composite indicator family consists of the NBER experimental leading indicator
series (XLI) and the NBER experimental non-financial recession index (XRI2) (which
measures the probability of a recession), the Department of Commerce leading indicators
(LEAD), the National Association of Purchasing Managers Index (PMI), the change in the
S&P 500 (S&P), changes in sensitive materials prices (SMPS), and the Kashyap-SteinWilcox "mix" (KSWMIX), which is the ratio of bank lending to the sum of bank lending and
commercial paper lending [see Kashyap et al. (1991)]. It should be noted that the NBER
experimental index includes the 10-year/1-year interest rate spread and the Commercial
Paper spread and that the Department of Commerce leading indicator index includes real
M2, which have been used in previous sections. All three leading indicator composites are
designed to predict economic activity at a six-month horizon, though the optimization for the
Department of Commerce index is not as specific as either of the NBER indices.
Table 4.1 shows that most of these series have the expected correlation with
contemporaneous economic activity, except for the change in the S&P 500 which has small
negative correlations with growth in industrial production and employment and only a small
positive correlation with growth in real GNP.

The KSWMIX variable is positively

correlated with real GDP: one interpretation of this correlation is that increased (decreased)
bank lending is associated with expansions (contractions).
Table 4.2 shows that all of these series perform very well in classical regression
analysis. They all produce high R2s. The R2s for industrial production range from .289 to
.391; the range for employment growth is .434 to .527; and the range for GDP is from .205
to .455.

Further, each of these indicators Granger causes activity at a high level of

significance. In terms of ranking, the Department of Commerce leading indicators and
NBER experimental index are 1st and 2nd for all of the measures of economic activity, with
the Department of Commerce leading indicators coming in 1st for industrial production and




-48-

employment and the NBER experimental index coming in 1st for real GNP. The change in
S&P 500 comes in last in every category and the change in sensitive materials prices comes
in next to last in every category.
The dynamic response path graphs in Figure 4.1 show somewhat similar patterns.7
For all three leading indicators series -- the NBER leading indicator, the NBER nonfmancial
recession index and the Department of Commerce’s leading indicators —employment growth
shows a rapid rise peaking at 5 months. From that peak all three graphs exhibit significantly
different behaviors. The NBER leading indicator graph plateaus for 4-5 months and then
drops off before the end of the year. Employment’s response to changes in the NBER
nonfmancial recession index drops off steadily from the peak while the response to changes
in the Department of Commerce’s response path is in-between with a high initial peak
followed by a stable period then a steady decline.
The response of employment to the changes in the Purchasing Managers Index and
the change in sensitive material prices both show dramatic jumps in forecasted employment
growth peaking at 3 and 2 months, respectively. Employment increases then falls steadily
in the Purchasing Managers Index graph while it plateaus in the sensitive material prices
graph. The S&P 500 graph is similar, showing a leap up followed by a steady decline,
except it has a small initial drop in the first month. It is interesting to note that all of these
dynamic response paths are barely significant at the one year mark, despite showing fairly
precisely estimated effects earlier. As a group these series seem to hold a lot of information
about short-run changes in economic activity, with most of that information centered at the
3-9 month horizon.
Tables 4.4 and 4.5, which examine the forecasting ability of these indicators at
different forecast horizons, in-sample and out-of-sample, show very stable rankings as the

7.
The dynamic response of employment to the KSWMIX variable is not reported since
it is only available on a quarterly basis.




-49-

forecast horizon changes.

The leading indicator series do best, posting very similar

performances. The other series do not do as well, though the Purchasing Manager’s Index
does well at the one-month horizon for industrial production. Placing 3rd in-sample and 2nd
out-of-sample for the one-month horizon then falling off at longer horizons. Among the
leading indicator series, the Department of Commerce series does best at horizons of less
than six months, while the NBER index ranks first for horizons of 6 months and longer. For
GDP, the NBER index always does better with the differential in performance increasing
with horizon. The KSWMIX variable does reasonably well in-sample, but out-of-sample it
performs worse than "NONE," the no-indicator forecast. The one anomaly in the tables is
that the change in sensitive material prices does very well out-of-sample for GDP at the 4
quarter horizon, actually outperforming all of the other indicators except the NBER leading
indicator series.
The cumulated Kalman residuals in Figure 4.2 show some striking similarities and
some differences in actual performance across these indicators. Except for KSWMIX, all
of our composite indicators have overforecasted real GDP over time, as their cumulated
residuals are consistently negative.

This bias is clearly evident during recessions and

becomes more dramatic after 1980. After 1982, while the negative bias is exacerbated in
the NBER leading indicator and S&P 500, the path becomes somewhat more stable for most
of our indicators. The NBER nonfinancial recession index is our best performer during this
period, which is not surprising since the index was originally developed in response to the
failure of the NBER leading indicator index to forecast the 1990-1991 recession.
The encompassing results in Table 4.6 show that for horizons of two- and fourquarters the NBER index dominates this entire family of indicators, with the possible
exception of the KSWMIX. At the one-quarter horizon both the Department of Commerce
and the NBER nonfinancial recession indices are not encompassed by any of the other
forecasts. These results are not surprising in light of the ranking discussed earlier and the




-50-

fact that the NBER leading indicator index was designed to provide a "best" forecast of
economic activity at a six-month horizon, using virtually all of the macroeconomic data
available. At the one- and two-quarter horizons, the KSWMIX is encompassed by the NBER
index at the 5% significance level, but not the 10% level. We chose not to include the
KSWMIX in the survivor list of indicators due to its poor out-of-sample performance in
Table 4.5.




-51-

TABLE 4.1 ■DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS

QUARTERLY (Jan 63 - Dec 91)

MONTHLY (Jan 63 -Feb 92)
Correlation with
Industrial
Employment
Production

Mean

Std. Dev.

Correlation with
Real GDP

0.429

3.039

4.067

0.547

-0.556

-0.523

0.156

0.131

-0.649

11.148

0.454

0.249

2.993

8.832

0.600

53.380

7.668

0.524

0.681

53.400

7.473

0.632

S&P

6.463

42.410

-0.028

-0.050

6.451

24.588

0.185

SMPS

0.319

0.930

0.325

0.444

0.322

0.912

0.278

0.925

0.040

0.316

Indicator

Mean

Std. Dev.

XLI

3.070

4.162

0.439

XRI2

0.157

0.139

LEAD

2.990

PMI

KSWMIX




TABLE 4.2 - CLASSICAL GOODNESS-OF-FfT STATISTICS

MONTHLY (Jan 63 -Feb 92)

MONTHLY (Jan 63 -Feb 92)

INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION

i

EMPLOYMENT

R2

Change
in R2

SEE

P-Value Rank

XLI

0.369

0.165

8.353

0.0000

XRI2

0.338

0.134

8.555

LEAD

0.391

0.187

PMI

0.355

S&P
SMPS

Indicator

KSWMIX




QUARTERLY (Jan 63 - Dec 91)

GDP

R2

Change
in R2

SEE

2

0.484

0.104

2.198

0.0000

0.0000

4

0.483

0.102

2.200

8.204

0.0000

1

0.527

0.146

0.152

8.439

0.0000

3

0.463

0.289

0.085

8.864

0.0002

6

0.300

0.096

8.795

0.0000

5

R2

Change
in R2

2

0.455

0.338

2.893 0.0000

1

0.0000

3

0.385

0.268

3.073 0.0000

3

2.104

0.0000

1

0.405

0.288

3.022 0.0000

2

0.083

2.241

0.0000

4

0.265

0.148

3.359 0.0005

4

0.434

0.054

2.301

0.0029

6

0.205

0.089

3.493 0.0222

7

0.436

0.056

2.297

0.0019

5

0.232

0.115

3.433 0.0045

6

0.243

0.126

3.410 0.0023

5

P-Value Rank

SEE

P-Value Rank

TABLE 4.3 - MAXIMUM IMPACT OF DYNAMIC MULTIPLIERS

MONTHLY (Jan 63 - Feb 92)

MONTHLY (Jan 63 - Feb 92)

INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION

QUARTERLY (Jan 63 - Dec 91)

GDP

EMPLOYMENT

Months to
Max

Max Impact

Std. Dev.
at Max

Months to
Max

Max Impact

Std. Dev.
at Max

Quarters to
Max

Max Impact

Std. Dev.
at Max

XLI

6

2.441

0.455

5

0.650

0.124

3

1.731

0.310

XRI2

3

-2.668

0.446

5

-0.811

0.137

2

-1.829

0.309

LEAD

5

2.475

0.453

5

0.766

0.132

2

1.851

0.274

PMI

2

2.655

0.454

3

0.617

0.124

2

1.223

0.314

S&P

5

2.310

0.487

7

0.596

0.145

2

0.935

0.322

SMPS

2

1.801

0.468

2

0.401

0.120

7

-0.679

0.246

2

1.021

0.302

Indicator

KSWMIX




TABLE4.4 - MULTIPERIODFORECASTS(In-Sample)

Indicator

1 MON
R2 RANK

MONTHLY (Jan 6 3-Feb 92)

MONTHLY (Jan 63 - Feb 92)

INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION

EMPLOYMENT

3MOS
R2 RANK

6 MOS
R2 RANK

12 MOS
R2 RANK

1 MON
R2 RANK

3 MOS
R2 RANK

QUARTERLY (Jan 63 - Dec 91)
GDP

6 MOS
R2 RANK

12 MOS
R2 RANK

1 QTR
R2 RANK

2QTRS
R2 RANK

4QTRS
R2 RANK

XU

0.369

2

0.555

2

0.638

1

0.510

1

0.484

2

0.675

2

0.694

1

0.608

1

0.455

1

0.568

1

0.401

1

XRI2

0.337

4

0.419

3

0.364

3

0.255

6

0.484

3

0.646

3

0.584

3

0.417

3

0.382

3

0.316

3

0.168

6

LEAD

0.391

1

0.569

1

0.606

2

0.460

2

0.527

1

0.705

1

0.656

2

0.500

2

0.405

2

0.341

2

0.247

2

PMI

0.355

3

0.389

4

0.356

4

0.255

5

0.463

4

0.580

4

0.483

5

0.325

6

0.265

4

0.203

7

0.173

5

S&P

0.289

6

0.364

5

0.349

5

0.269

4

0.434

6

0.572

5

0.530

4

0.381

4

0.205

7

0.216

5

0.152

7

SMPS

0.300

5

0.346

6

0.327

6

0.334

3

0.436

5

0.547

6

0.479

6

0.345

5

0.232

6

0.206

6

0.229

3

-

-

0.243

5

0.249

4

0.193

4

0.088

7

0.117

8

0.117

8

0.072

8

KSWMIX

NONE

l
cn
cn
i




-

0.204

-

7

0.204

7

0.116

7

0.381

7

0.493

7

0.417

7

0.282

7

TABLE4.5- KALMANMULTIPERIODFORECASTS(Out-of-Sample)
MONTHLY (Jul 73 - Feb 92)

MONTHLY (Jul 73 - Feb 92)

_________________ INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION__________________

EMPLOYMENT

___________

3 MOS
RMSE RANK

6 MOS
RMSE RANK

12 MOS
RMSE RANK

1 MON
RMSE RANK

3MOS
RMSE RANK

6 MOS
RMSE RANK

XU

9.441

3

6.293

2

4.586

1

4.226

1

2.405

3

1.662

2

1.481

1

1.473

1

3.246

1

2.376

1

2.392

1

XRI2

9.589

4

7.353

4

6.604

6

5.444

6

2.439

4

1.801

3

1.839

3

1.897

4

3.427

3

3.026

3

2.758

5

LEAD

9.057

1

6.081

1

4.899

2

4.449

2

2.290

1

1.614

1

1.632

2

1.717

2

3.307

2

3.024

2

2.669

3

PMI

9.172

2

7.163

3

6.156

3

5.101

4

2.402

2

1.864

4

1.935

6

1.978

7

3.838

4

3.319

6

2.736

4

S&P

9.921

7

7.442

6

6.287

4

5.124

5

2.522

7

1.921

5

1.884

4

1.882

3

3.964

6

3.253

4

2.758

6

SMPS

9.685

5

7.391

5

6.291

5

4.779

3

2.495

6

1.944

6

1.926

5

1.915

5

3.914

5

3.306

5

2.612

2

-

-

4.078

8

3.377

8

2.846

8

1.966

7

4.052

7

3.369

7

2.799

7

NONE

1 MON
RMSE RANK

GDP

Indicator

KSWMIX

12MOS
RMSE RANK

QUARTERLY (Jul 73 - Dec 91)

-

9.894

I
cn
cr>
i




6

7.945

7

7.125

7

5.575

7

2.467

5

1.953

7

-

1.943

6

1 QTR
RMSE RANK

2QTRS
RMSE RANK

4QTRS
RMSE RANK

TABLE 4.6 - MULTIPERIOD ENCOMPASSING TESTS (Sample Period: Jan 63 - Dec 91)
Probability Value for Null Hypothesis: X is Encompassed by Y
GDP: 1 qtr_____________

XU
XRI2
LEAD
PMI
S&P
SMPS
KSWMIX

n.a.
—
—
0.300
0.754
0.598
0.061

XRI2

LEAD

PMI

—

—
—
n.a.
0.889
0.619
0.923
0.088

—
—
__
n.a
0.100
0.127
—

n.a.
—
0.195
0.334
0.114
—

S&P

—

SMPS

—

—
—

__
—

__
—

n.a.
—
—

0.090
n.a.
—

KSWMIX

—
- __
—
—
—
n.a

Maximum
P Value

0.001
0.012
0.030
0.889
0.754
0.923
0.088

GDP: 2qtrs

i
cn
i




XU
XRI2
LEAD
PMI
S&P
SMPS
KSWMIX

n.a
0.370
0.761
0.609
0.897
0.644
0.087

—

n.a.
—
0.603
0.211
0.305

—
—

—
—

n.a.

—

0.314
0.861
0.728
0.060

n.a
—
0.162

—
—
—
0.065

n.a.

r—
—
—
0.197
0.097

0.160

n.a.

T-----0.143
0.064
0.179
n.a

0.000
0.370
0.761
0.609
0.897
0.728
0.087

GDP: 4 qtrs
XU
XRI2
LEAD
PMI
S&P
SMPS
KSWMIX

n.a
0.939
0.420
0.903
0.616
0.377
0.166

—
n.a.
—
0.244
0.104
0.055
0.056

—

—

0.690

n.a.

'

0.829
0.748
0.153
0.056

NOTE: Values less than or equal to 0.05 are marked with a dash.

__
—
—
0.121

__

___

0.310
0.087
0.636
0.329

0.113
__
0.181
0.142
0.090
n.a

0.282
0.076 n.a
0.303
—

—

n.a.

0.113

—

0.196

n.a.

0.000
0.939
0.420
0.903
0.748
0.377
0.196

4.1. Dynamic Response of Employment to Composite Indicators
NBER Experimental Leading Index (XU)

National Purchasing Managers’ Index (PMI)

a n n u a liz e d p e r c e n t g ro w th r a te s

a n n u a liz e d p e r c e n t g ro w th r a te s

NBER Nonfinancial Recession index (XRI2)

S&P 500 Stock Index (S&P)

DOA Composite Index of Leading Indicators (LEAD)

Change in sensitive materials prices (SMPS)




-58-

4.2. Composite Indicators: Cumulated Kalman Residuals in Forecasting Real GDP
NBER Experimental Leading Index (XLI)

S&P 500 Stock Index (S&P)

c u m u la t e d K a lm a n r e s id u a ls

c u m u la t e d K a lm a n r e s id u a ls

NBER Nonfinancial Recession Index (XRI2)

Change in sensitive materials prices (SMPS)

DOC Composite Index of Leading Indicators (LEAD)

Bank lending/(bank lending + CP) ratio (KSWMIX)

National Purchasing Managers’ Index (PMI)




-59-

MIXING MODELS FOR REAL GDP
This section analyzes those indicators drawn from the previous sections that contain
independent information and did well in the out-of-sample Kalman rankings. The indicators
are subjected to another round of encompassing tests and rankings. Finally the usefulness
of these final indicators is assessed in the context of a time-varying forecast-mixing model.
Table 5.1 presents the Kalman forecast RMSE for the one-, two-, and four-quarter
horizon forecasts of real GDP. For the one-quarter horizon the best indicators are the NBER
composite indicators (XLI and XRI2), and the Department of Commerce Leading Indicators
Index (LEAD). The spreads and real M2 do the worst at this short horizon, but all of the
remaining indicators do contribute information beyond the own past history of GDP
(NONE). At the two-quarter horizon, the best indicator is the NBER leading indicator index
with the 12-month/Federal Funds rate spread coming in a distant second: the NBER leading
indicator index is 14% more accurate than the 12-month/Federal Funds rate spread. This
is not surprising since the NBER leading indicator index was constructed by Stock and
Watson to produce the "best" forecast of the growth in economic activity over the six-month
horizon considered here. Turning to the four-quarter horizon, it seems surprising that the
NBER leading indicator index comes in last after the 12-month/Federal Funds rate spread,
the Federal Funds rate, the 10-year/Federal Funds spread, and real M2. This demonstrates
again that the choice of economic indicators depends critically upon the horizon being
forecast— at the four-quarter growth horizon, a different collection of interest rate spreads
than the ones selected by Stock and Watson are useful.
New encompassing results are displayed in Table 5.2. At this point, the purpose of
these tests is to narrow the list of indicators in a structured manner. However, a rigid
adherence to a statistical significance level is not maintained if an indicator is relatively
useful and of independent interest. At the one-quarter horizon, the composite indicators (the
NBER leading indicator index, the NBER nonfinancial recession index, and the Department




-60-

of Commerce leading indicators) are each undominated and together sufficient. The twoquarter horizon is more interesting. Three indicators are clearly necessary. The NBER
leading indicator index is undominated, and the 12-month/Federal Funds rate spread is
undominated at the 10% level. The 3-month Eurodollar rate is not covered by these two
indicators, and it is not dominated at the 11% significance level. Real M2 is also included
in this final cut for two reasons: it is only covered by the NBER leading indicator index at
the 14% significance level and it is of inherent interest as the best monetary aggregate
considered here. Finally, notice that the 6-month Commercial paper spread (CP6TB6) did
not make the final list at the two-quarter forecast horizon, but it is a component of the NBER
leading indicator index.
At the four-quarter horizon, three indicators are undominated: the Federal Funds
rate, real M2, and the 12-month/Federal Funds rate spread. The NBER leading indicator
index does not contain independent information beyond these indicators.

The 10-

year/Federal Funds rate spread is included in the final list for three reasons:

it is

undominated at the 15% significance level, it covers the NBER leading indicators index
better than the shorter end of the term structure (12-month/Federal Funds rate spread), and
it is interesting to include a long spread at this horizon since Stock and Watson found a long
spread useful at the two-quarter horizon.
The next step is to combine these forecasts into a forecasting model (for each
horizon) which allows the weights on the indicators to vary over time depending upon their
recent performance. Essentially we would like the model to take the following form:
F , = 0 i , f o r ( A ) + c p 2l f o r ( B ) ' + <p3l f o r ( C ) ,

where/or(A) represents a forecast based upon indicator A and Fx is the combined forecast.
The weights </>it should be non-negative and sum to one: in this case, the indicator’s weight
is a direct measure of its importance for the forecast. When the weights vary over time




-61-

according to their forecast accuracy, the time path of the weights provide a direct measure
of the indicators’ reliability over time. We implement this model in the following way. Let
eit2 be the sum of (recent) squared forecast errors based upon indicator i’s model. In this
paper, we take "recent" to be one year of known forecast errors (4 quarters). Let «vgt(eit2)
be the average of the eit2s at time t and /q is the average of eit2 - av^fe,2) over time. Then
<j>jt is defined to be:
<Pu

= ai - Pi

( £l -

av3 | ( " P,) #

<*i , Pi > 0

where the parameters a and j8 can be estimated by a linear regression model if the non­
negativity constraints are ignored, or nonlinear methods if the constraints are imposed.8
Since eit2 - flvgt(eit2) - /q is mean zero by construction, the time-variation due to the /3’s nets
out to zero over time. Consequently, the a estimates represent the average weight associated
with each indicator forecast.

However, over short periods of time when an indicator’s

forecast misbehaves, its errors eit2 will be larger than the average errors; this will lead to
the indicator’s forecast receiving a temporarily smaller weight.
Table 5.3 displays the estimated a weights for these models. The one-quarter results
indicate that the NBER leading indicator index is the most reliable, having an average weight
of .533 in the combined forecast. The other indices (NBER Experimental Recession Index
and the BEA Leading Indicators Index) received about equal shares of the remaining weight.
The /3’s in this case are estimated to be zero; that is, there is no significant contribution to
the forecast accuracy by allowing the weights to vary over time.
The two-quarter results are more interesting.

As was expected from the

encompassing results, the NBER leading indicator index receives the bulk of the weight in

8.
The results in Table 5.3 were obtained by imposing the nonnegativity constraints.
Initially, each of the /3’s was constrained to be positive. If the initial estimate was on the
boundary (zero), its corresponding time-varying component was deleted from the estimation.
The a ’s were constrained to be positive and sum to one.




-62-

the final forecast (61 %). This agrees with the analysis of Stock and Watson who constructed
the NBER leading indicator index explicitly for its ability to forecast at this two-quarter
ahead horizon. We do find that real M2 receives a substantial weight (19%), while the 12month/Federal Funds rate spread is at 10% and the 3-month Eurodollar rate is 9%. Figure
5.1 graphs the time path of the <t>weights for these four indicators, as well as the two-quarter
GDP forecast and actual. Notice first that the NBER leading indicator index forecasts have
been quite reliable, only once dropping below a 50% weight in the combined forecast. Real
M2, however, has varied dramatically in its usefulness, going negative on two occasions:
in 1976 and immediately following the 1981-82 recession. During that recession, real M2
did not forecast negative growth at any time (although it did in the 1980 recession), whereas
the 3-month Eurodollar rate, the 12-month/Federal Funds rate spread, and the NBER leading
indicators index did forecast negative growth during some portion of this recession.9 This
poor performance is captured in the time-varying model by decreasing the weight on the real
M2 forecast temporarily until it begins to improve.

On the other hand, during the most

recent recession real M2 has gone above a 50% weight (keep in mind that the average weight
for real M2 is . 19). During this time, real M2 has grown only slowly and this lead to a
forecast of slow growth during 1991 (see Figure 5.1).

At this same time, the 3-month

Eurodollar rate, the 12-month/Federal Funds rate spread, and the NBER leading indicators
index signalled substantially higher growth than was realized. Each of these indicators is
currently receiving less than its average weight. Consequently, the time-varying mixing
model finds that real M2 has been an unusually useful indicator during the recent recession,

9.
It is useful to remember that the primary components of the NBER leading indicators
index are the 6-month Commercial paper spread and the 10-year/1-year spread. So it should
not be surprising that the NBER leading indicator index misbehaved during this period when
the 3-month Eurodollar rate and the 12-month/Federal Funds rate spreads also misbehaved.




-63-

despite its generally erratic performance at this horizon versus its relative failure at the
twelve month horizon.
By contrast the four-quarter horizon results appear to be a picture of stability. Real
M2 and the 12-month/Federal Funds rate spread receive the largest unconditional weights,
41% and 37% respectively. The Federal Funds rate and the 10-year/Federal Funds rate
spread receive considerably less (around 10% each). The graphs of the time-varying weights
indicate that, at this horizon, real M2 and the 12-month/Federal Funds rate spread have been
reasonably reliable indicators, always staying near their unconditional weight. On the other
hand, the 10-year/Federal Funds spread has been extremely unreliable, going to zero or
negative in 1987-88 and during the recent recession.
The contrast between the dominance of the NBER leading indicator index at the sixmonth forecast horizon versus its lack of independent information at the twelve-month
horizon demonstrates strongly the need for a different set of indicators for each forecast
horizon.

The usefulness of the 12-month/Federal Funds rate spread and real M2 for

forecasting real GDP at the twelve-month horizon indicates that a different index would be
constructed if this forecast horizon was the relevant objective. A note on standard errors is
in order. Examination of Table 5.3 indicates that the standard errors associated with the
parameters of these mixing models are fairly large. This is not surprising in light of the high
degree of collinearity that would be expected of a set of reasonably successful forecasts. In
fact, it is typically the case that only the strongest indicator at a given horizon is statistically
significant. All this is saying is that the relative weights among successful indicators is
subject to substantial uncertainty and that the marginal information after the first one or two
indicators is quickly dropping toward 0. Nevertheless the point estimates and time paths of
these relative weights provide a useful bench-mark, even though the precision they are
estimated with would not change strongly held prior beliefs.




-64-

TABLE 5.1 - KALMAN RESIDUALS FOR SURVIVING INDICATORS

Quarterly (Jul 73 - Dec 91)
Real GDP

Indicator

1 Qtr
RMSE Rank

2 Qtrs
RMSE Rank

EUR03

3.622

4

2.754

3

n.a.

n.a.

n.a.

n.a.

n.a.

n.a.

2.160

2

M2R

3.674

6

2.844

5

2.219

4

CP6TB6

3.656

5

2.760

4

n.a.

n.a.

TB12FF

3.753

7

2.751

2

2.002

1

CM10FF

n.a.

n.a.

n.a.

n.a.

2.161

3

XLI

3.246

1

2.376

1

2.392

5

XRI2

3.427

3

n.a.

n.a.

n.a.

n.a.

LEAD

3.307

2

n.a.

n.a.

n.a.

n.a.

NONE

4.052

8

3.369

6

2.799

6

FF

n.a.: The indicator isnot an initialsurvivor atthisforecast horizon.




-65-

4 Qtrs
RMSE Rank

TABLE 5.2 -MIXED MULTIPERIOD ENCOMPASSING TESTS (Sample Period: Jan 63 -Dec 91)
Probability Value for Null Hypothesis: X is Encompassed by Y
GDP: 1 qtr

Y

EUR03

FF

n.a.
0.958

0.100
n.a
__

M2R

CP6TB6

TB12FF

CM10FF

—
n.a.
—
—

—

0.067
—
—
n.a
0.260
—

—
—
—
—

XU

XRI2

LEAD

Maximum
P Value

—
0.055
—
—
—
—
—
n.a

0.107
0.958
0.168
0.288
0.453.
0.809
0.001
0.012
0.030

—
—
—
—
—
—
__
__
n.a

0.110
0.868
0.139
0.304
0.082
0.514
0.000
0.370
0.761

«._
—
—
—
—
__
__

0.609
0.023
0.007
0.850
0.011
0.147
0.298
0.959
0.960

X
EUR03
FF
M2R
CP6TB6
TB12FF
CM10FF
XU
XRI2
LEAD

—
—
0.186
0.168

—
—

—
0.193
0.098

—
—

—
—
—

—

—
n.a.
—
—
—

—

—

n.a.

—
—

0.107
0.144
0.168
0.288
0.453
0.809
n.a.
—
—

n.a
—

—
0.139
0.304
0.062
0.514
n.a.
0.370
0.761

—
—
—
—
—
___
n.a
__

__
—
—

__
—

“T
—
__
—
—
—
—

GDP: 2qtrs

EUR03
FF
M2R
CP6TB6
TB12FF
CM10FF
XU
XRI2
LEAD

n.a.
0.868
—
—
0.064
0.076
—
—
—

0.110
n.a
—
—
0.082
—
__
—
—

—
—
n.a.
—
—
—
__
0.066
0.230

__

—

0.161
—
—

—
n.a.
—
—

n.a
0.228
—
—

—
—

n.a.
—
—
0.270
—
—
—
. 0.791
0.102

0.609
n.a

—

0.327

—
—

—
0.817
0.122

GDP: 4qtrs

"

—

__

—
n.a.
0.420
—
—
0.105
0.959
0.960

—
—

—
—

—
—

n.a.
—

0.850
n.a
0.147
0.157
0.839
0.240

0.779
—

NOTE: Values less than or equal to 0.05 are marked with a dash.




—
—
n.a.
—
—

0.088
.

EUR03
FF
M2R
CP6TB6
TB12FF
CM10FF
XU
XRI2
LEAD

__
—
—

—
—
0.364
—

n.a.
0.298
0.711
0.300

0.401

—
—
n.a.
0.939
0.420

—

—
—
—
__
n.a

—

0.690
n.a




TABLE 5.3 - RELATIVE WEIGHTS IN MIXING REGRESSIONS

Real GDP

Indicator

EUR03
FF
M2R
CP6TB6

★

★

CM10FF

n.a.

LEAD

0.187
(0.227)
★

*
*

XRI2

0.093
(0.260)
n.a.

n.a.

TB12FF

XLI

2 Qtrs

1 Qtr

0.103
(0.238)
n.a.
0.617
(0.197)
n.a.

0.533
(0.174)
0.214
(0.155)
0.253
(0.206)

n.a.

4 Qtrs

n.a.
0.105
(0.209)
0.414
(0.178)
n.a.
0.368
(0.259)
0.114
(0.212)
★
n.a.
n.a.

NOTES:
-Numbers inparenthesis are standard errors.
-n.a.: The indicator isnot an initialsurvivor atthisforecast horizon.
-(*): The indicatorisencompassed by other indicators atthis horizon.

-67-

5.1. Mixing Results
3 month eurodollar (EUR03)

2 Quarter Ahead Forecast vs. Actual
Real M2 (M2R)

12 month T bill less fed funds (TB12FF)

w e ig h t

12 month T bill less fed funds (TB12FF)




NBER Experimental Leading Index (XLI)

w e ig h t

NBER Experimental Leading Index (XLI)

-6 8 -

5.2. Mixing Results
4 Quarter Ahead Forecast vs. Actual
Fed funds (FF)

10 year T bond less fed funds (CM 10FF)

a n n u a liz e d g ro w th r a te s

Real M2 (M2R)

Fed funds (FF)

12 month T bill less fed funds (TB12FF)

Forecast Reliability Weight
10 year T bond less fed funds (CM 10FF)

w e ig h t

w e ig h t

Real M2 (M2R)

12 month T bill less fed funds (TB12FF)




69-

CONCLUSION
Four things become clear as the preceding analysis developed. First, the forecast
horizon is an essential aspect of choosing and evaluating indicators. Second, substantial
information resides in the term and public-private spreads and that both of these seemingly
very different types of spreads seem to include significant common as well as distinct
information sets. Third, while composite indicators may be extremely useful they are only
as good as their design allows. The Stock-Watson NBER leading indicator series does very
well at precisely what it was designed for, forecasting economic activity at a six-month
horizon.

Its usefulness beyond this is far more limited than prior analysis would have

suggested. The analysis is also suggestive that the type of general purpose target variable
that the old monetary targeting literature sought, probably does not exist at least in terms of
real economic activity. Policymakers will continue to need to mix information according to
their current focus. Mixing models of the sort used in this paper are meant to be preliminary
work in this regard. The early results are intriguing.




-70-

REFERENCES

Bemanke, Ben S., "On the predictive power of interest rates and interest and interest rate
spreads," New England Economic Review, November-December, 1990, pp. 51-68.
Chong, Y. and D. Hendry, "Econometric evaluation of linear macroeconomic models,"
Review o f Economic Studies, 53, 1986, pp. 671-690.
Estrella, A. and G. Hardouvelis, "The term structure as a predictor of real economic
activity," Journal o f Finance, 46, 1991, pp. 555-576.
Friedman, B. and K. Kuttner, "Why does the paper-bill spread predict real economic
activity?" forthcoming in James H. Stock and Mark W. Watson eds., New Research
in Business Cycles, Indicators and Forecasting, University of Chicago Press and the
NBER, 1992.
Kashyap, A., J. Stein, and D. Wilcox, "Monetary policy and credit conditions: evidence
from the composition of external finance," Federal Reserve Board, Working Paper
No. 154, 1991.
Laurent, Robert D., "An interest rate-based indicator of monetary policy," Economic
Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, January/February, 1988, pp. 3-14.
National Bureau of Economic Research, Press Release, January 30, 1991.
Sims, Christopher A., "Interpreting the macroeconomic time series facts: the effects of
monetary policy," manuscript, 1991.
Stock, J. and M. Watson, "Interpreting the evidence on money-income causality," Journal
o f Econometrics, Vol. 40, 1989a, pp. 161-182.
Stock, J. and M. Watson, "New indexes of coincident and leading economic indicators,"
in NBER Macroeconomics Annual, edited by O. Blanchard and S. Fischer, the MIT
Press, 1989b, pp. 351-409.
Strongin, Steven, "Macroeconomic models and the term structure of interest rates," Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago, Working Paper No. 90-14, 1990.
Strongin, Steven, "The identification of monetary policy disturbances: explaining the
liquidity puzzle," Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Working Paper No. 91-24,
1991.




-71-