View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paper Series

A Model of Bimetallism
François R. Velde and Warren E. Weber

Working Papers Series
Research Department
(WP-98-8)

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

A Model Of Bimetallism∗

François R. Velde
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
fvelde@frbchi.org
Warren E. Weber
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
and University of Minnesota
wew@res.mpls.frb.fed.us
Version 1.1 (September 28, 1998)

ABSTRACT
Bimetallism has been the subject of considerable debate: Was it a viable monetary
system? Was it a desirable system? In our model, the (exogenous and stochastic)
amount of each metal can be split between monetary uses to satisfy a cash-in-advance
constraint, and nonmonetary uses in which the stock of uncoined metal yields utility.
The ratio of the monies in the cash-in-advance constraint is endogenous. Bimetallism
is feasible: we find a continuum of steady states (in the certainty case) indexed by
the constant exchange rate of the monies; we also prove existence for a range of fixed
exchange rates in the stochastic version. Bimetallism does not appear desirable on
a welfare basis: among steady states, we prove that welfare under monometallism is
higher than under any bimetallic equilibrium. We compute welfare and the variance
of the price level under a variety of regimes (bimetallism, monometallism with and
without trade money) and find that bimetallism can significantly stabilize the price
level, depending on the covariance between the shocks to the supplies of metals.
Keywords: bimetallism, monometallism, double standard, commodity money.
∗

If the Federal Reserve Banks of Chicago or Minneapolis do have views on bimetallism, they
are not expressed herein. We thank without implicating Marc Flandreau, Ed Green, Angela Redish,
Tom Sargent.

Introduction
Until the 20th century, most countries used some form of commodity money. Usually,
the commodities were metal, gold and silver, in the shape of coins. A monetary regime
which tries to maintain concurrent circulation of coins made of both metals at a fixed
exchange rate is called bimetallism.
Bimetallism has the been the subject of considerable debate. Much of it occurred
in the 19th century (Darwin 1898, Fisher 1911, Giffen 1892, Laughlin 1896, Shaw 1894,
Willis 1901), and has been revived recently (Chen 1972, Garber 1986, Friedman 1990a,
1990b; Redish 1990, 1995; Oppers 1995, 1996; Dowd 1996; Flandreau 1996, 1997).
Many issues raised in the debate fall under two broad questions. The first concerns
existence: Is bimetallism implementable, sustainable, stable? Defenders of bimetallism
maintain that concurrent circulation of gold and silver is possible for long periods of
time under a wide range of circumstances and that the setting of a legal ratio between
gold and silver coins acts to stabilize the market price of the (uncoined) metals around
this ratio. The opponents of bimetallism maintain that concurrent circulation is not
possible and that bimetallism will, in reality, boil down to a knife-edge alternation
between gold and silver monometallic standards, as the market ratio moves above and
below the legal ratio. The second question concerns welfare properties: Is bimetallism
desirable? The proponents claim that bimetallism reduces fluctuations in the price
level due to shocks to the supplies of the metals. The opponents counter that any
such benefits are small compared to the costs involved in constantly switching between
single standards.
At a theoretical level, the debate is unsettled, primarily because there currently is
no fully developed model of commodity money regimes in which these questions can be
directly answered. Models of commodity money have been proposed by Barro (1978),
Sargent and Wallace (1983), and Sargent and Smith (1997). Models of bimetallism
have been constructed by Chen (1972), Dowd (1996), and Flandreau (1996). All three
of these models analyze bimetallism in a general equilibrium setting that permits both
monetary and nonmonetary uses for both metals. All three also obtain bounds on the
legal ratio necessary for concurrent circulation of the two metals. However, none of
1

them has a fully articulated structure and none analyzes the behavior of bimetallism
under uncertainty.
Chen assumes ad hoc demand functions for the nonmonetary uses of the metals
and obtains the monetary demands from a cash-in-advance constraint similar to the
one we use. However, he does not explicitly have a mint in the model, so that he cannot
analyze the effects of seigniorage on the workings of a bimetallic regime. Dowd has a
structure similar to Chen’s except that rental rates on the metals enter the nonmonetary
demand functions and the CIA constraint, instead of the prices of metals. Flandreau
also has a structure, demand functions, and CIA similar to Chen. His analysis has
three countries, two of which are monometallic with different metals.
Our model modifies the cash-in-advance models of Sargent and Smith (1997) and
Sargent and Velde (1997) by introducing “jewelry,” that is, alternative uses for gold
and silver. The total amount of each metal, which is exogenous and stochastic, can be
split between monetary and nonmonetary uses. Agents derive utility from the stocks
of the metals not in monetary use. The two forms of money are substitutable in the
cash-in-advance constraint at a rate that is endogenous but given to the consumer. We
formally prove the existence of a continuous range of possible ratios, with corresponding
allocations of metal between jewelry and money, and corresponding relative price of the
two metals (market ratio). There is thus a continuum of Pareto-rankable equilibria,
rather than the indeterminacy characteristic of multiple fiat money models (Kareken
and Wallace 1980). This multiplicity has not been formally emphasized. We identify the
condition under which bimetallism gives way to monometallism, and by what process.
We numerically analyze the response of bimetallism to shocks (which are equivalently
viewed as supply or demand shocks) to the metals. We compute equilibria and study the
variability of the price level under alternative monetary arrangements and for various
structure of the stochastic processes affecting the stocks of metals. We also compute
welfare under the different standards for both the certainty and the uncertainty case.
The model formally confirms some of the views of the defenders of bimetallism.
Concurrent circulation is viable over long periods without changes in the legal ratio:
given a legal ratio, stocks of jewelry and coins will adjust in the face of supply or
2

demand shocks to maintain equality with the market ratio. This mechanism operates
as long as there are positive stocks of both coins. Further, bimetallism does provide a
more stable price level, and the reduction in the variance of the price level depends, as
one would expect, on the correlation between gold shocks and silver shocks.
However, we have not been unreservedly converted to bimetallism. The literature had not considered welfare under various regimes. We find that, for preferences
displaying constant elasticity of substitution between the metals, a single standard always yields higher welfare than bimetallism. The computations show that the welfare
loss from bimetallism is significant, and not outweighed by its ‘smoothing’ action.
The paper proceeds as follows. In the next section we present some preliminaries
for understanding issues involved in analyzing bimetallism. Specifically, we provide
some definitions, summarize the relevant history, and give a more complete exposition
of the debate over bimetallism. In the second section we present the general equilibrium
model with two metals and demand for jewelry for a single (world) country. The third
section analyzes the case with no seigniorage: we consider existence and welfare in the
certainty case, as well as in the case where the metals are subject to separate supply and
demand shocks. The fourth section analyzes the case with seigniorage under certainty.
We then conclude.

3

1. Preliminaries

Definitions
We begin by clarifying some of the terminology involved in the discussion of
commodity monies.
Countries can adopt a variety of institutional arrangements to promote the use
of particular commodities as money; the outcome of those arrangements can vary as
well. A country’s regime can be characterized by its underpinning institutions (de jure)
or by the observed outcome (de facto).
The institutions revolve around two main elements: the minting laws and the
legal tender laws. The country can provide for free minting of one metal or both. “Free”
minting usually means unrestricted, not free of charge: the mint, either governmentrun or leased, stands ready to convert metal into coin at a set mint price, expressed
as N coins per kilogram of metal. It was often the case that minting was free but N
coins weighed 1 − σ kg, σ > 0 being the seigniorage rate. The case σ = 0 is called
gratuitous minting. Free minting of at least one metal is a requirement of a commodity
money regime. Free minting of both metals is a necessary, but not sufficient condition
for bimetallism.1
Legal tender laws define the unit of account in which prices and debt contracts
are expressed, and state which coins are legal tender for debts so denominated, for how
many units each coin is tendered, and, possibly, some form of limit on how many coins
of a given type can be tendered.2 In the absence of such such a limit, the coin is said
to have unlimited legal tender.
If both gold and silver have unlimited legal tender at a fixed rate and both are
freely minted, the regime is called a de jure bimetallic or double standard. This system
was in place in several countries in the 19th century, notably the United States and the
1

In practice, many intermediate cases were found, for example with the mint offering to convert
at most a fixed amount of metal per day (restricted minting).
2 The limit can be a number of coins, or a share of the amount tendered.

4

Latin Union comprising France. The other three possible cases comprise different forms
of monometallism. If only one metal is freely minted and has unlimited legal tender,
then the regime is strict monometallism. England was on such a standard, based on
gold, from 1816. A regime in which both metals are legal tender but only one is freely
minted is called a limping standard (or a “hunchback standard” by Cernuschi, cited in
Walras 1898, 118). This was the regime in place in several countries after their move
to the gold standard: England from 1774 to 1816, France, Germany and the United
States after 1873. A variant is the system adopted in India after 1893. India went
on the gold standard but without a gold coinage; instead, the government bought and
sold silver rupees for (gold-based) British pounds at a fixed rate. In the third case,
in which both metals are freely minted but only one is legal tender, the coin without
legal tender is called a trade money, and its value in units of account is freely set by
the market. This was the typical regime in Medieval Europe, and also the regime in
place in Germany, Austria and the Netherlands until their move to the gold standard:
the gold coin floated in terms of the silver coin.
It is usually understood that the aim of a de jure bimetallic standard is to ensure
concurrent circulation of both metals at a fixed rate. The outcome may be different,
and a de jure bimetallic regime may be a de facto monometallic regime. Concurrent
circulation may fail, as in England until 1774, where in practice only gold was minted
and circulated; or Mexico until 1905, where only silver circulated. Alternatively, parity
of both metals at the legal rate may fail when official legal tender laws are ignored, and
one of the coins is, de facto, a trade coin. Prussia, in the 1820s, attempted without
success to enforce a fixed rate for its gold coin.
The History
This section briefly sketches the types of regimes adopted by various countries.
In Europe, since the High Middle Ages, silver had always been the basis of the monetary
system, and silver coins or fixed quantities of silver coins (dozens, scores of dozens) were
the units of account in which debts and prices were expressed. In the 13th century gold
coins, which had remained in use in Byzantium and the Muslim world, reappeared in
Western Europe. In the Middle Ages, gold coins fluctuated in value in terms of silver
5

coins. For example, there are daily records of the market value of the gold fiorino in
Florence in the 14th century. Minting institutions, which took shape early, remained
roughly unchanged for centuries: in principle, mints stood ready to convert bullion into
coins at posted prices, always charging seigniorage.
By the 16th century, European governments commonly ascribed legal tender
values to gold coins, and worried about the appropriate ratio to set between the legal
tender value of a weight of gold and that of the same weight of silver (the so-called legal
ratio). It did not escape their attention, however, that the ratio of the market price of
a weight of gold to that of the same weight of silver (the so-called market ratio) varied
over time, and that legal ratios varied across European countries and over time.
0.10

0.1

ratio of cumulated output, gold/silver (log scale)

0.09

0.08

gold stock/silver stock

0.06

market ratio

0.07

0.05

gold/silver market ratio

0.04

0.03

0.01

1500

1550

1600

1650

1700

1750

1800

1850

1900

0.02

Figure 1: Ratio of gold to silver world stocks (left scale, log) and market ratio of silver to gold
(right scale). The market ratio series is only a true market observation after 1687. See Appendix 2 for
sources.

Figure 1 plots the market ratio from 1492 to 1913, and compares it with the es6

timated ratio of the world stocks of gold and silver. It suggests that secular movements
in the latter accompanied changes in the former. Countries found that, if they wanted
to maintain a double standard (and not all did), they had to adjust the legal ratio at
some times.
By the 18th century, a wide variety of monetary arrangements had arisen across
Europe in response to these difficulties. England was on a de facto gold standard
since 1717, and a limping standard since 1774. Spain, Italy and France maintained
bimetallism (albeit at slightly different rates), and in 1792 the nascent United States
adopted bimetallism as well. On the other hand, Germanic, Scandinavian and Slavic
Europe had maintained or returned to medieval silver monometallism, in some cases
with gold as trade money. The East (India and China) was on silver. After the French
Revolutionary and Napoleonic Wars (1792–1816), the situation remained much the
same until the 1870s, except that all European bimetallic countries were all at or near
the French legal ratio of 15.5, while the United States was on de jure bimetallism at a
ratio of 15 until 1837 and 16 thereafter.
The gold discoveries of California (1848), Australia (1851), South Africa (1885)
and the introduction of the cyanide process (1887) induced major disturbances in the
world bullion markets, and reversed the production trend of the previous centuries
in favor of gold, as shown in Figure 1 and Figure 2. Soon, debates flourished over
the choice of a standard. (See the bibliography assembled by Dana S. Horton, U.S.
Senate 1879, 737–78.) An international monetary conference in 1867 endorsed the gold
standard.
In 1871, unified Germany decided to switch from the silver standard to the
gold standard. In 1873, many European bimetallic countries suspended free minting of
silver, and by 1876 all had adopted the gold standard. In 1893, India suspended free
minting of silver, leaving China as the sole major country not on the gold standard.
Figure 3 shows the countries with free coinage of silver, as well as the countries with
free coinage of gold and legal tender laws for gold, as a share of gross world output
from 1820 to 1913. Against the right-hand scale is plotted the silver/gold ratio over
the same period. It is apparent that the switch away from silver and bimetallism was
7

abrupt and widespread.
4 %

annual production / cumulative output

3 %

gold

2 %

1 %

silver

0 %
1800

1820

1840

1860

1880

1900

1920

Figure 2: Annual world production of gold and silver, as a percentage of existing stock. See
Appendix 2 for sources.

The Literature

Bimetallism has the been the subject of considerable debate in the 19th century
(Darwin 1898, Fisher 1911, Laughlin 1896, Shaw 1894, Willis 1901). At the turn
of the century, any textbook dealing with money touched on the subject. With the
simultaneous abandonment of bimetallism by France and the United States in 1873, and
the end of subsequent political agitation after the defeat of William Jennings Bryan’s
bid for the U.S. presidency, the debate was seen as academic, some writers viewing
its disappearance as resolution of the debate against it. More recently, the debate has
8

90 %

French legal ratio

0.065

countries as share of world gross product

70 %

0.06

ratio (right scale)

60 %

0.055

50 %

0.05

40 %

0.045
silver freely coined

gold legal tender, freely coined
30 %

0.04

20 %

0.035

10 %

0.03

0 %
1820

1830

1840

1850

1860

1870

1880

1890

1900

1910

gold/silver market ratio

80 %

0.07

0.025

Figure 3:

Countries with free coinage of silver, and countries with free coinage of and legal tender
laws for gold, as share of world output (monthly, 1820-1913). See Appendix 2 for sources.

been revived (Friedman 1990a, 1990b; Redish 1990, 1995; Oppers 1995, 1996; Dowd
1996; Flandreau 1996, 1997).
In the debates about bimetallism versus either gold or silver monometallism, it
is necessary to distinguish whether the arguments for bimetallism concern a particular
country or whether they concern the world as a whole, or at least a large group of countries. To borrow Laughlin’s terminology, there are advocates of national bimetallism:
a country should adopt bimetallism on its own regardless of what other countries do,
and advocates of international bimetallism: the major trading countries should agree
on a common bimetallic standard. It is likely that the advocates of national bimetallism would have been in favor or international bimetallism, in principle, although
they might have objected to the particular ratio agreed upon. However, it was not
necessarily the case the advocates of international bimetallism would have been in fa9

vor or national bimetallism. In discussing the debate, we will implicitly assume that
advocacy of bimetallism is advocacy of international bimetallism rather than national
bimetallism.
Viability

The question of the viability of bimetallism can be posed in two ways. The
first is whether or not it is possible for gold and silver to be in concurrent circulation
for long periods of time without a change in the mint (legal) ratio. The second is
whether it is inevitable in the long run that the majority of countries would adopt a
gold monometallic standard.
With regard to the issue of long-term concurrent circulation, the conventional
monometallic view against is well stated by Friedman (1990a, 87): “bimetallism is
an unstable and unsatisfactory monetary standard involving frequent shifts between
alternative monometallic standards.” The supply and demand for gold and silver are
continually subjected to shocks which will cause the market ratio of the metals to
differ from the legal ratio. This will cause bimetallic standards to exhibit a knifeedge property caused by the operation of Gresham’s Law, with the type of metal in
circulation switching between gold and silver as the market ratio is either above or
below the mint ratio.
Some proponents of bimetallism argue that the setting of a legal ratio will stabilize the market price at the legal ratio. Given this stability, agents will be indifferent
as to which metal they use as money, so both will be in circulation.
More sophisticated defenders of bimetallism like Irving Fisher (1911) do not
argue that the market ratio must equal the mint ratio under bimetallism. They acknowledge that shocks to supply and demand can cause the market ratio to fluctuate
and that deviations from the market ratio can cause a metal to go out of circulation.
They actually acknowledged that maintaining concurrent circulation of both metals
would require adjustments in the legal ratio. However, their argument is that such
adjustments would only be required infrequently for two reasons. First, there are costs,
10

such as shipping, to arbitraging between the two metals. Such costs mean that small
differences between market and mint ratios will not lead to one metal disappearing from
circulation. Second, the size of shocks to the demand and supply of the two metals
would be small enough relative to each other and hence “we may be tolerably confident
that, if initially successful with the film near the middle position [the stocks of gold and
silver coins close to equal], international bimetallism would continue successful for many
generations. The initial success depends, as has been seen, upon the ratio enacted”
(p. 125). Fisher does concede that “two nations cannot both maintain bimetallism at
two different ratio unless the difference is less than the cost of shipment. One of the
nations would lose the metal which is undervalued and find itself on a monometallic
basis” (p. 124) This is why international bimetallism is important in his view.
The empirical evidence cited by both sides of the debate seems to be France
between 1803 and 1873. The proponents of monometallism argue that the market
ratio deviated from the mint ratio over this period, showing that bimetallism does not
stabilize the market ratio. Further, they argue that when the market ratio fell below
the mint ratio in the late 1840s, France switched from being on a silver monometallic
country to being a gold monometallic one.
The proponents of bimetallism argue that the market ratio actually was relatively stable around the mint ratio during this period. Calculations by Flandreau (1996,
1997) show that, in nineteenth-century France, the market ratio remained with in the
arbitrage bounds (gold-silver points) at which arbitrage would have been possible, and
that both gold and silver were in fact in concurrent circulation. However, even Fisher
(1911, 135-6) admits that “in 1850 bimetallism had almost broken down in France and
would have been succeeded by silver monometallism had not the increased production
of gold reversed the flow.”
With regard to inevitability, the argument of the gold monometallists, at least
as put forward by Laughlin and Shaw, seems to be the gold standard was inevitable
because gold is the preferred medium of exchange by wealthy and commercial advanced countries. Thus, as nations become wealthier and international trade became
more important, the adoption of a gold standard was inevitable. Redish has further
11

argued that the adoption of the gold standard was facilitated by the development of
coinage technology, the steam press, which made token coinage much more difficult to
counterfeit.
Defenders of bimetallism, in particular Fisher, Friedman, and Flandreau, regard
the adoption of the gold standard as being an historical accident. Moreover, Fisher
(1911, 323–4) explicitly acknowledges that it is very probably an irreversible one: “it
is not too much to say that we have hit upon the gold standard by accident. . . . Now
that we have adopted a gold standard, it is almost as difficult to substitute another
as it would be to establish the Russian railway gauge or the duodecimal system of
numeration.”
Welfare

The major welfare issues concern price stability and international trade. The
proponents of bimetallism argue that it would provide greater price stability. The
bimetallic argument is given by Fisher (1911, 325) as follows:
As we have seen, by connecting the currencies of both gold and
silver countries, bimetallism, as long as it continues in working order,
has the effect of spreading any variation of one particular metal over the
combined area of gold, silver, and bimetallic countries. If variations occur simultaneously in both metals, they may be in opposite directions,
and neutralize each other more or less completely; while, even if they
happened to be in the same direction, the combined effect on the whole
world united under bimetallism would be not greater than on the two
halves of the of the world under silver and gold monometallism respectively. Even if bimetallism did not enlarge the monetary area, it might
reduce monetary fluctuations.
Walras stated the same argument a bit more succinctly: “In short, bimetallism is as
much at the mercy of chance as monometallism so far as stability of the value of the
monetary standard is concerned; on bimetallism has a few more chances in its favor”
12

(Walras 1977, 359).
The counter argument by some monometallists is that this price stability (called
“compensatory action” by Laughlin) occurs only if one metal drives the other out of
circulation. However, such action requires the (deadweight) loss involved in recoining
the entire stock of money in a country. Giffen (1892, 18) takes a slightly different
approach. He argues that the amount of price fluctuation caused by shocks to the
demand and supply of precious metals is quite small relative to those “constantly
being produced by changes in credit alone.” Further, he seems to have some notion
of monetary neutrality in mind, at least for moderate changes in money, so that he
concludes that “moderate changes in the quantity of money in use, unless they are
suddenly made, are not material.”
Proponents on both sides of the debate seem to agree that it would be best if all
major commercial countries were to agree on a common monetary standard since this
would eliminate the exchange rate uncertainty from international trade. Proponents of
bimetallism argued for an addition benefit of their standard with regard to trade with
countries like Japan and China (and perhaps India), which were likely to remain on a
silver standard for quite some time. Giffen’s response to this argument is that foreign
trade is only a small part of the trade of the country, so that decision of which standard
is best should not be made on this basis.

13

2. A Model of Bimetallism
Time is discrete and without end. There are three goods: a consumption good ct ,
and stocks of gold and silver bullion. Consumption is non-storable, while gold and
silver are durable and do not depreciate. There is an exogenous endowment Xt =
(ξt , Q1,t+1 , Q2,t+1 ) of which ξt can be turned into consumption goods subject to the
constraint
ct ≤ ξ t

(1)

and Qi,t (i = 1, 2) represent the total existing stocks of gold and silver bullion respectively, measured in ounces. The vector Xt is stochastic, and constitutes the only source
of uncertainty. Its probability distribution is known to agents.
Bullion can be in two possible forms: jewelry (by which we mean metal in any
use other than monetary) and coins. Consumers care about consumption and about
the stock of jewelry d1,t and d2,t (measured in ounces) that they own. Accordingly,
preferences are
E0

∞
X

β t [u (ct ) + v (d1,t+1 , d2,t+1 )]

(2)

t=0

where Et denotes the expectations operator conditional on beginning of period t information (namely, the history X0 , . . . , Xt ). The function u is concave, twice differentiable
with u0 (0) = +∞, the function v is concave, twice differentiable.
Coins are needed by the household to meet a cash-in-advance constraint on its
purchases, which are made in a manner to be described shortly. A coin is defined by a
number bi (i = 1, 2), which is in ounces of gold (silver) per coin. Coins are produced
by a competitive firm, which converts jewelry bought from the household into coins
(paying a tax at a rate σi on all new coins). The firm can also convert coins into
jewelry. Both operations are costless but can only be carried out by the firm. Both
types of coins are perfect substitutes in the cash-in-advance constraint at a ratio of
substitution et . Coins of metal 1 are by convention called dollars ($), coins of metal
2 are valued at $ et each. We allow for et to be endogenous, but will also consider
equilibria where it is a constant.
14

At the beginning of a period, the realization of Xt becomes known. At that point,
the household owns the endowment, the stocks of jewelry, and the stocks of coins; the
change in the stock of bullion since the end of the previous period accrues directly to
the stock of jewelry. The household sells its endowment to the firm in exchange for
a claim to the firm’s profit. The shopping session begins: with its coin balances, the
household buys from the firm consumption at the competitively determined price pt
(in $/good), and hi,t ounces of new jewelry at the price qi,t (in $/oz).3 The firm sells
the endowment and the new jewelry to the household in exchange for coins. It then
mints ni,t coins and melts µi,t coins, and finally turns over all profits (in the form of
coins) to the household at the end of the period.
The firm’s profit, in dollars, is
Πt = pt ct + (n1,t − σ1 n1,t ) − µ1,t + q1,t h1,t
+ et (n2,t − σ2 n2,t ) − et µ2,t + q2,t h2,t

(3)

The firm maximizes (3) by choosing each period ct , µi,t , ni,t , hi,t subject to the constraints (1) and
0 ≤ ni,t ,

0 ≤ µi,t ≤ mi,t

hi,t = bi (µi,t − ni,t ) .

(4a)
(4b)

As a result of the firm’s choices, the new stocks of coins are given by:
mi,t+1 = mi,t + ni,t − µi,t .

(5)

In order to encompass various possible monetary arrangements, some particular
variants will be allowed. In particular, the sale of jewelry in one particular metal may
be shut down. This corresponds to an additional constraint on the household: hi,t ≥ 0
for all t. This captures cases where the mint was closed to one metal. To capture
the case of a single standard with a purely token secondary coinage, we may also rule
3

Purchases of consumption and jewelry are simultaneous, so the purchase of jewelry requires
additional coin balances; conversely, the sale of jewelry by the household can be credited against
consumption purchases).

15

out melting down one type of coin (taking it to be intrinsically useless), in which case
hi,t = 0.
The government collects seigniorage and transfers it as a lump-sum Tt to the
household at the end of the period:
Tt = σ1 n1,t + σ2 n2,t .

The household maximizes (2) by choosing sequences for di,t+1 , ct , hi,t , mi,t+1
subject to the laws of motion
di,t+1 = di,t + hi,t + (Qi,t+1 − Qi,t ) ,

(6)

the cash-in-advance constraint
pt ct + q1,t h1,t + q2,t h2,t ≤ m1,t + et m2,t

(7)

and the budget constraint
m1,t+1 + et m2,t+1 ≤ Πt + (m1,t + et m2,t − pt ct − q1,t h1,t − q2,t h2,t ) + Tt

(8)

(taking Πt as given) as well as the constraints
ct ≥ 0 mi,t+1 ≥ 0

(9a)

hi,t ≥ −di,t − (Qi,t+1 − Qi,t ) ,

(9b)

di,0 and mi,0 given.
Market clearing requires that the household and the firm choose the same ct and
hi,t , and that the household choose mi,t+1 such that (5) holds.
Equilibrium
It is now possible to define various monetary systems as sub-classes of equilibria
in this model. In general, an equilibrium is defined as follows:
16

Definition 1.

An equilibrium is a collection {mi,t+1 }, {µi,t }, {ni,t } {di,t+1 }, {hi,t }

{pt }, {qi,t }, {et }, such that: (a) the firm maximizes (3) subject to (1), (4); (b) the
household maximizes (2) subject to (6), (7), (8), (9); (c) ct = ξt and (5) holds.
Bimetallism can be defined as existing in certain equilibria, those for which:
(C1) m1,t+1 > 0, m2,t+1 > 0 for all t (both metals circulate as coinage)
(C2) et = et+1 for all t (legal tender laws apply).
Strict monometallism can be defined as an equilibrium satisfying mj,t = 0 for
all t. Monometallism with trade money can be defined as an equilibrium satisfying
(C1) only. The other form of monometallism, where free minting of only one metal is
permitted, can be defined as an equilibrium where the household faces the additional
constraint: hj,t ≥ 0 for some j. If the constraint is hj,t ≥ 0 and mj,t+1 > 0, we have a
limping standard.
First-order conditions
The firm’s first-order conditions are (1), (4) and:
q1,t ≥

1 − σ1
,
b1

µ1,t ≥ 0;

µ2,t ≥ 0;

n1,t = 0 if q1,t >

µ1,t = 0 if q1,t <

µ1,t ≤ m1,t ;
q2,t ≥ et

n1,t ≥ 0;

n2,t ≥ 0;

µ2,t = 0 if q2,t <

µ2,t ≤ m2,t ;

1
b1

µ1,t = m1,t if q1,t >

1 − σ2
,
b2

1 − σ1
b1

(10b)
1
b1

n2,t = 0 if q2,t > et
et
b2

µ2,t = m2,t if q2,t >

(10a)

(10c)
1 − σ2
b2

(10d)
(10e)

et
b2

(10f )

These first order conditions are in the nature of no-arbitrage constraints, as in
Sargent and Smith (1997). They place lower bounds on the prices of jewelry qi,t , bounds
at which new coins are minted (minting points). They also define melting points for
17

qi,t , above which all coins of type i are melted. Also, minting occurs only at the minting
point, and melting only at the melting point or above. The quantity 1/b1 (resp. et /b2 )
is the mint equivalent of coin 1 (resp. coin 2), and (1 − σ1 )/b2 (resp. (1 − σ2 )et /b2 ) its
mint price.
The household’s first-order conditions are (6), (7), (8), (9) and:


qi,t 0
qi,t+1 0
u (ct ) − βEt
u (ct+1 )
vi (dt+1 ) =
pt
pt+1

Et

et+1
−1
et




≤0




u0 (ct+1 )

pt+1


≥0

if m1,t+1 > 0,

if m2,t+1 > 0,
 0



u0 (ct )
u (ct+1 )
et+1 u0 (ct+1 )
, Et
}≤
,
β max{Et
pt+1
et
pt+1
pt

(11a)

(11b)

(11c)
(11d)

with (11d) holding at equality when (7) does not bind, and use of the notation
vi (dt+1 ) = ∂v/∂di(d1,t+1 , d2,t+1 ).
Equation (11a) is an asset pricing equation for jewelry, (11b) and (11c) require
that one currency not be dominated in rate of return by the other if it is held, and
(11d) places a lower bound of 1 on the gross nominal rate of interest.

3. Absence of Seigniorage: σi = 0
We begin with the case where seigniorage is 0. This is not a bad approximation, as
argued above. It allows us to examine the broad dynamics of bimetallism in response
to supply or demand shocks to the metals. We first analyze the steady state under
certainty, and prove that there exists a continuum of bimetallic equilibria indexed by
the ratio e. We also find that, for the CES class of preferences, the equilibria can be
ranked and monometallism always dominates bimetallism. Then we analyze the conditions under which bimetallism gives way to monometallism. Finally, we analyze the
dynamics under uncertainty; for the logarithmic class of preferences we prove existence
of equilibrium and numerically compute equilibria.
18

Steady State Analysis
Shut down the uncertainty for now: Xt = X = (ξ, Q1, Q2 ) for all t. Can we
choose d1 , d2 in such a manner as to support a steady state competitive equilibrium?
In a steady state where both coins are held, (11b) and (11c) implies that et is a
constant. Furthermore, (11a) becomes
qi
vi (d)
=
(1 − β)
u0 (ξ)
p
and (10) with σi = 0 imply q1 = 1/b1 and q2 = e/b2 .
We now have the following equations:
b1 m1 = Q1 − d1
b2 m2 = Q2 − d2

(12a)
(12b)
0

u (ξ)
b1 v1 (d)
u0 (ξ)
p = e (1 − β)
b2 v2 (d)
pξ = m1 + em2
p = (1 − β)

(12c)
(12d)
(12e)

These five equations in the six unknowns e, m1 , m2 , p, d1 , d2 are exactly those identified
by Walras in his Lesson 31 (1977, 337–8), leading him to conclude that “the legislator
can intervene, and either determine one of the six unknowns arbitrarily or introduce
a sixth equation in one way or another. . . . If the legislator exerts his arbitrary power
on quantity, the value will be automatically determined in the market. If he exerts it
on value, then the quantity will be automatically determined by the mechanism of free
competition.”
The system (12) can be reduced4 to:
(Q1 − d1 ) v1 (d) + (Q2 − d2 ) v2 (d) = (1 − β) u0 (ξ) ξ.
4

(13)

Rewrite (12e) as b1 pξ = b1 m1 + (eb1 /b2 )b2 m2 , then use (12a) and (12b) to replace bi mi , (12c)
to replace b1 p and (12d) to replace eb1 /b2 .

19

Equation (13) is the quantity theory equation stated in terms of the weights of gold
and silver coin, each valued at its marginal utility as jewelry. Under the concavity
assumption on the function v, (13) defines a monotone decreasing curve in the (d1 , d2 )
plane. If, moreover,
Qi lim vi (di , Q3−i ) > (1 − β) u0 (ξ) ξ

(14)

di →0

for i = 1, 2, then the curve intersects both lines di = Qi .
Along that curve, the market ratio q1 /q2 = v1 (d)/v2 (d) varies. The legal ratio
b2 /eb1 also varies, since it is pegged to the market ratio by the equilibrium conditions
(12c) and (12d). The range of legal ratios that are compatible with equilibrium, that
is, for which there exists a pair (d1 , d2 ) on the curve, is an interval. Figure 4 shows the
curve for the case:
v (d1 , d2 ) = α1 log (d1 ) + α2 log (d2 ) .

(15)

m2

d2

Q2
b2
x Q2
α2 + x b2

Q2

α2
Q2
α2 + x
α1
Q1
α1 + x

Q1

x Q1
α1 + x b1

dd11

Q1
b1

m1

Figure 4:

Set of steady state equilibria, represented in the (d1 , d2 ) plane (left panel) and in the
(m1 , m2 ) plane.

All the points on the interior of that curve correspond to bimetallic steady states,
with concurrent circulation of both metals and a constant exchange rate. The points
where the curve intersects the lines Qi = di correspond to monometallism, and to limits
e, ē on ratios compatible with bimetallism. In the log preference case, the limits on the
mint ratio are



α1 Q2
α2 Q1



b2
α2 /x
≤
≤
1 + α2 /x
eb1
20



α1 Q2
α2 Q1



1 + α1 /x
α1 /x

(16)

where x = (1 − β)u0 (ξ)ξ. The lower bound corresponds to the silver standard.
We summarize these results.
Proposition 1. There exists a continuum of steady-state equilibria with concurrent
circulation of both metals as money. These equilibria are indexed by the gold/silver
ratio e in a range (e, ē), with 0 < e and ē < +∞ and in each equilibrium the mint
ratio e equals the market ratio. For parameter values satisfying (14), the equilibria for
e such that 0 < e ≤ e (resp. ē ≤ e < +∞) are silver (resp. gold) monometallic.
Each equilibrium corresponds to a different allocation (d1 , d2 ). What are the
welfare properties of the set of equilibria? Holding ξ fixed, we can pose the problem
max v (d1 , d2 )
d1 ,d2

(W )

subject to (13). For two classes of utility functions, we have the following result:
Proposition 2. If preferences over jewelry are of the form v(d1 , d2 ) = a1 dγ11 + a2 dγ22
for 0 < γi < 1, or (a1 dρ1 + a1 dρ2 )1/ρ for ρ < 1, ai > 0 then, among steady states:
1) welfare is minimized at d1 /d2 = Q1 /Q2 ,
2) welfare is maximized by either d1 = 0 or d2 = 0.
For those preferences, the first-order condition for (W) identifies the unique
interior point on the curve defined by (13) that also satisfies d1 /d2 = (Q1 −d1 )/(Q2 −d2 ).
At that point, v1 (d)/v2 (d) = v1 (Q)/v2 (Q) which is the ratio which would prevail in
the absence of monetary uses of the metals, also called the “natural ratio” (Darwin
1890, 20). That point turns out to be a minimizer, not a maximizer. The constrained
optimum is achieved at the bounds, either at d1 =0 or d2 = 0; in other words, with
monometallism.5
5 The proof relies on algebra, using the properties of the utility function. In the CES case,
the main property is that the cross derivative is v12 = −(d1 /d2 )v11 = −(d2 /d1 )v22 ; this, in turn,
allows to express cross third derivatives in terms of v111 and v222 . When the bordered Hessian of the
Lagrangian is computed, exploiting properties of the solution to the first-order condition, it is found
to be always negative.

21

gold= 0.08

5.5
5
4.5

Silver (bn tr oz)

4
double= −0.08

3.5
3
2.5

silver= 0.02
2
1.5
1
0.5

0.05

0.1

0.15
Gold (bn tr oz)

0.2

0.25

0.3

Figure 5: Set of steady state equilibria, log preferences calibrated to 1873 data (see Appendix 2).
The value of utility is indicated next to the location of the gold, silver and double standard (15.5 legal
ratio). The lightly shaded lines are indifference curves.

There is a cost to using a metal as money, which is that it cannot be a source of
utility. With constant elasticity of substitution between the two, one of the two stocks
of metal used in bimetallism is always better employed as jewelry, and replaced by the
other metal for monetary purposes. The price stability properties of bimetallism must
be assessed against this welfare cost.
How big is that cost? For our calibration to 1873 figures (described in the
Appendix 2), moving from bimetallism to a gold standard is the welfare equivalent
of a permanent increase in the gold stock available for non-monetary purposes from
165m to 222m troy oz. The value of the net increase is $1.2bn at 1873 prices, which
amounts to 20% of U.S. GDP or about 1.7% of world output.6 The welfare loss is not
insignificant.
6

U.S. GDP in current dollars from Kausel (1985, table 2). The U.S. represented about 8.7% of
world output at the time and world population was about 1.265bn (Maddison 1995, 182, 226, 227).
The U.S. dollar was set at $21.333 per troy oz in 1837.

22

Dynamics under Certainty

The analysis so far assumes constant stocks of gold and silver. If the two stocks
of money grow at the same rate, the analysis is easy to modify, and the previous results
hold around the trend, rather than the constant values of the stocks. If the stock of
one metal grows at a rate higher than the other other, the effect is to shift the curve in
Figure 4 to the right. Suppose the faster growing metal is metal 1. Since equilibria for
a fixed e lie along a positively sloped ray from the origin, shifts imply that increases in
metal 1 will lead to increased amounts of jewelry of both metals. Thus, coins of metal 2
are being melted, and it is easy to show that coins of metal 1 are being minted to take
their place in transactions. Eventually this process will lead to all of metal 2 being
used as jewelry. (The ray must eventually intersect the Q2 upper bound to the left
of the curve.) In other words, when metal 1 grows faster than metal 2, e continually
increases, so that eventually it must become larger than e. Thus, unless the legal ratio
is changed, the economy will ultimately end up having the faster growing metal as
its de facto monetary standard. Figure 1 shows that the growth rate of gold stocks
increased markedly above that of silver stocks in 1850. Were that change to persist
long enough, the gold standard ultimately had to prevail, unless bimetallic countries
were willing to countenance a lower gold/silver ratio, and implement the change in a
coordinated manner.
But was that change in relative growth rates of silver and gold stocks the cause
for the collapse of bimetallism in 1873? Figure 6 plots the upper and lower bounds
defined in (16) under log preferences calibrated to 1873 figures (see Appendix 2). We
see the market ratio reaching the upper bound (corresponding theoretically to the gold
standard equilibrium) by the late 1890s; and indeed, at that time almost all countries
had abandoned bimetallism, as shown in Figure 3. However, the French legal ratio of
15.5:1 lies within the bounds well into the twentieth century, indicating that no change
in the legal ratio would have been required for the world to have concurrent circulation
of gold and silver coins for a long time, or in in Fisher’s (1911, 125) words, to “continue
successful for many generations.” The figure also confirms Fisher’s analysis that even
though the legal ratio might have to be changed from time to time to keep both coins
23

70
gold standard

60
50
40

silver/gold ratio

30

natural ratio

20
15.5
market ratio

10
9
8

silver standard

7
6
5
4

1820

1830

1840

1850

1860

1870

1880

1890

1900

1910

1920

Figure 6: Upper and lower bound on the legal ratio, 1816–1913.

in circulation, these changes would be relatively infrequent if the ratio was chosen close
to the middle of the band.
Dynamics under Uncertainty
We now consider the case in which the stocks of the two metals are subject
to stochastic shocks. For the specific case of log preferences we prove existence of
a bimetallic equilibrium with concurrent circulation of both metals and we present
simulation results on welfare and price stability. We also consider the case of trade
money.
Condition (C1) requires concurrent circulation of both coins. When (C1) is satisfied but et is free to vary, we call the resulting equilibrium a trade-money equilibrium.
When (C2) is imposed as well, we have a bimetallic equilibrium. We first impose (C1),
to derive conditions that are common to a trade money and a bimetallic equilibrium;
later, we impose (C2).
24

Condition (C1), combined with the firm’s first-order conditions (10), implies
that q1,t = 1/b1 and q2,t = et /b2 . In turn, this transforms (11a) into:
 0

u0 (ct )
u (ct+1 )
b1 v1 (dt+1 ) =
− βEt
pt
pt+1


0
u (ct )
b2
et+1 u0 (ct+1 )
v2 (dt+1 ) =
− βEt
et
pt
et
pt+1

(17a)
(17b)

which implies that (11d) always holds.
By (11b) and (11c), (C1) also implies that the rates of returns on the two monies
be equal, in the sense that:

Et




u0 (ct+1 )
et+1 u0 (ct+1 )
= Et
.
pt+1
et
pt+1

(18)

Equations (17) and (18) also imply that the market ratio, or relative price of gold and
silver jewelry, equals the relative price of gold and silver coin:
b2
v1 (dt+1 )
=
.
v2 (dt+1 )
et b1

(19)

Equations (4b), (5), (6) and (7) imply
pt ct =

1
et
(Q1,t+1 − d1,t+1 ) +
(Q2,t+1 − d2,t+1 ) .
b1
b2

(20)

In equilibrium, ct = ξt . The dynamical system consists of et−1 , d1,t , d2,t , pt and
the equations (17a), (18), (20) and (17b) or (19). Using (20) to replace pt and (19) to
replace et , we can reduce the system to a difference equation in dt only.
If we add condition (C2) and make et a constant, (18) is always satisfied. Equation (19) allows us to express d2,t+1 as a function of d1,t+1 . Then the dynamical system
becomes d1,t+1 and pt with equations (20) and (17a).
Existence of Equilibrium (Log Case)
With the preferences (15), (19) becomes
d2,t+1 =

α 2 b2
d1,t+1
α1 eb1
25

(21)

and (20) becomes
pt =

1
(Q1,t+1 /b1 + eQ2,t+1 /b2 − ad1,t+1 )
ξ

(22)

with and a = (1 + α2 /α1 )/b1 . Let zt = Q1,t+1 /b1 + eQ2,t+1 /b2 . Equation (17a) is now


c
1
1
(23)
−
= βEt
zt − ad1,t+1 d1,t+1
zt+1 − ad1,t+2
with c = b1 α1 /[ξu0 (ξ)]. We want to solve for a policy function d1,t+1 = d(zt ) satisfying
(23).
The proof of existence is given in the Appendix. It is a constructive proof:
we transform (23) into a fixed point equation for a monotone operator T defined on a
suitable subset F of a functional space C(Z), and apply a fixed-point theorem to ensure
existence and a computational method. We take e to be a parameter throughout. In
particular, the functional space and the operator will depend on e. The proof requires
an assumption which represents a joint restriction on the process for Qi,t+1 and the
legal ratio. In the special case, analyzed in the previous section, where Qi,t+1 = Qi ,
Assumption 1 becomes e ∈ [e, ē] (which proves, incidentally, that the assumption is
not vacuous). It is clear that the stochastic analogue of the bounds we found in the
certainty case must involve the properties of the shock process other than its mean.
Proposition 3. If preferences over jewelry satisfy (15) and Assumption 1 holds, then
there exists an equilibrium.
Numerical Simulations
The existence proof of Proposition 3 provides us with an algorithm for computing
a solution, namely, finding a fixed point of the operator defined by (29). We use log
preferences over jewelry as in (15) calibrated to match 1873 data as above.
We compute equilibria under various monetary regimes: the double standard
(bimetallism), gold standard and silver standard. We also consider the case of an endogenous, time-varying et , which can be viewed as a single standard with free minting
of the other metal into trade money. The numerical method for this last case is essentially the same; however, there appears to be many fixed points, depending on the
26

starting value (d1 (z), d2 (z)) chosen. In particular, a starting value with d2 (z) = γd1 (z)
results in an equilibrium with et fluctuating around (b2 /b1 )(α2 /α1 )(1/γ). This is not
surprising, given the multiplicity of steady states. In our numerical computations, we
choose a starting value such that the mean of et is the same as the constant e we find
in the bimetallic case.7
We also make various assumptions about the processes {Qi,t }. Throughout, we
Q
assume that the vector Qt = [ 1,t ] follows a VAR process Qt = AQt−1 + t , with
Q2,t
0.9 0
A=(
). In the variance-covariance matrix of t , both the size of the variances
0 0.9
and the correlation between the innovations are varied, so as to change the coefficient
of variation of Qi,t and the correlation between Q1,t and Q2,t .
We consider welfare as well as the variability of the price level. The latter is
measured by the coefficient of variation (standard deviation divided by mean) of the
price level pt , compared to the coefficients of variation of the shocks to Qi,t .
We begin with the case where the shocks to gold and silver are of the same
size (that is, same coefficient of variation). Figure 7 plots price variability and welfare
for positive, zero and negative correlation between silver and gold shocks. It clearly
shows that bimetallism displays a more stable price level than either the gold or silver
standard. Welfare under bimetallism, as Proposition 2 shows for steady states, is lower
than under either standard. It appears that welfare is not very sensitive to the size
of the shocks, so that the ranking of steady states (both ordinal and cardinal) varies
little.
We should note that, in our model, there can be no welfare costs of inflation:
all welfare effects of the choice of monetary standard arise because metal not used as
money yields utility. The model thus cannot capture the welfare gains that may arise
from stabilizing the price level.
Figure 8 shows the results that obtain when the shock to one metal is 2.5 times
as large as the shock to the other. The upper part of the panel corresponds to the
7

The Matlab code is available at <http://???>.

27

15
Corr( Q ,Q )= 0.5
1

gold

2

10

gold

0.1

silver

silver

0

trade
trade

double

5

−0.1

double
Corr( Q1 ,Q2)= 0.5

0

5

10

15

−0.2

20

5

10

15

20

15
Corr( Q1 ,Q2)= 0.0

gold

0.1
gold

10

Welfare

Standard Deviation of Price Level (as % of mean)

0

silver
trade

5

silver

0
trade

−0.1

double

double
Corr( Q ,Q )= 0.0
1

0

0

5

10

15

−0.2

20

2

5

10

15

20

15
Corr( Q1 ,Q2)= −0.5

0.1

gold

gold
silver

10
0

silver

5

double

trade

−0.1

double

trade
Corr( Q ,Q )= −0.5
1

0

0
5
10
15
20
Standard Deviation of Shock to Q as % of mean

5
10
15
20
Standard Deviation of Shock to Q as % of mean

i

Figure 7:

2

−0.2

i

Variance of price level and welfare for various correlation coefficients between Q1,t and

Q2,t .

28

Shock to Silver twice as large
15

0.15
0.1

10

0.05
silver

gold

silver

0
5

trade

−0.05

gold

double

double

−0.1

trade

0
2
4
6
8
10
2
4
6
8
10
Standard Deviation of Shock to Gold as % of mean
Standard Deviation of Shock to Gold as % of mean
Shock to Gold twice as large
15

0.15
0.1

10

gold

0.05
Welfare

Standard Deviation of Price Level (as % of mean)

0

gold

trade

5

silver

0
−0.05

silver

−0.1

double

0

0
2
4
6
8
10
Standard Deviation of Shock to Silver as % of mean

double
trade

2
4
6
8
10
Standard Deviation of Shock to Silver as % of mean

Figure 8: Variance of price level and welfare for asymmetric shocks to Q1,t and Q2,t .

case where the shocks to silver are larger. The ordering of price level stability across
monetary regimes is what one would expect.
Figure 7 indicates that the coefficient of variation of the price level is roughly
linear in the coefficient of variation of the shocks to Qi,t (assumed equal for the two
metals). It is therefore enough to examine the ratio of the former to the latter, which
one can think of as a kind of “pass-through” coefficient, expressing how much of the
variability in metal stocks passes through to the price level. Figure 9 plots the average
pass-through coefficient for the three monetary regimes as the correlation between gold
29

0.6
gold

0.5

Average pass−through coefficient

silver

0.4

trade−money
0.3

double

0.2

0.1

0
−1

−0.8

−0.6

−0.4

−0.2
0
0.2
Correlation of Q and Q
1

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

2

Figure 9: Pass-through coefficient (defined as ratio of the coefficient of variation of the price level
to that of the shocks to metal stocks) for various degrees of correlation between the metal shocks.
and silver shocks varies from −0.95 to +0.95 (gold and silver shocks are assumed to be
equal, and the pass-through coefficients were computed for coefficients of variation of
metal shocks ranging from 1% to 20%). Figure 9 shows, in effect, how much bimetallism
reduces price level variability when compared to single standards.
As one would expect, bimetallism is most effective at stabilizing the price level
when shocks to the two metals are negatively correlated. As Walras stated (1977, 359):
“The bimetallic standard preserves a certain relative stability of value in cases where
the monometallic standards would have varied in opposite directions. It varies as much
as these monometallic standards in cases where they would both have moved in the
same direction.”
The gain over the gold standard ranges from 75% to 15%. In the period 1873–
1913, the correlation between production shocks to the two metals was 60%: for that
value of the correlation, the reduction in the coefficient of variation of the price level is
about 30%, when compared to the gold standard.

30

4. Positive Seigniorage: σi > 0
In this section, we consider the case with positive seigniorage. We only analyze the
steady state and the dynamics under certainty. The main purpose of this section is to
see to what degree seigniorage affects the model, and how the dynamics of minting and
melting change with the size of the disturbances to the stocks of metal.
Steady State
When we introduce seigniorage, the analogue to (13) is:
x max{

1 − σ1 ∗ 1 − σ 2
1
1
,e
} ≤ (Q1 − d1 ) + e∗ (Q2 − d2 ) ≤ x min{ , e∗ }
v1
v2
v1
v2

(24)

where e∗ = e(b1 /b2 ) (recall that b1 and b2 are arbitrary) and x = (1 − β)u0 (ξ)ξ. Thus,
the result of introducing positive seigniorage is to “fatten” the curve in the right panel
of Figure 4 as shown in Figure 10.
A necessary condition for (24) to hold is that
max{1 − σ1 , (1 − σ2 ) e∗

v1
v1
} ≤ min{1, e∗ }.
v2
v2

(25)

This places bounds on the variations in the market ratio v1 /v2 : it cannot vary outside
of the interval [(1 − σ1 )/e∗ , 1/(1 − σ2)e∗ ]. Instead of being pegged to the legal ratio, the
market ratio can now fluctuate within a band around the legal ratio 1/e∗ ; the width of
the band depends only on seigniorage rates.
In the log utility case, we can compute analytically the area in the (m1 , m2 )
plane that satisfies (24). Specifically, condition (24) becomes:
[(1 − σ1 ) (1 − β) u0 (ξ) ξ/α1 + 1] d1 + ed2 ≤ Q1 + eQ2 ≤ [(1 − β) u0 (ξ) ξ/α1 + 1] d1 + ed2
d1 + [(1 − σ2 ) (1 − β) u0 (ξ) ξ/α2 + 1] ed2 ≤ Q1 + eQ2 ≤ d1 + [(1 − β) u0 (ξ) ξ/α2 + 1] ed2
which translates into four linear inequality constraints on d1 and d2 for each value of
e. In the (m1 , m2 ) plane, for a given e these constraints define an area shown by the
heavily shaded area in Figure 10. Thus, for a given e there is a multiplicity of steady
31

m2
x Q2
α2 + x b2

Q2
b2
melt coin 2

A
(1 − σ2 )x Q2
α2 + (1 − σ2 )x b2

mint coin 2

melt coin 1
mint coin 1

−e

Q2
b2

m1
(1 − σ1 )x Q1
α1 + (1 − σ1 )x b1

−

Figure 10:

Q1
b1

x Q1
α1 + x b1

1 Q1
e b1

Locus of steady state equilibria under positive seigniorage, shown in the (m1 , m2 )

plane.

state equilibria, each corresponding to a different (m1 , m2 ). The lightly shaded area
in the Figure shows for fixed stocks of the metals, the (m1 , m2 ) pairs that satisfy the
constraint for at least one value of e.
Point A on Figure 10 is where e = v2 /v1 , that is, where legal ratio and market ratio coincide. As e varies, point A traces a curve in the three-dimensional space
(m1 , m2 , e) whose projection onto the plane (m1 , m2 ) is exactly the hyperbola of Figure 4.
Dynamics under Certainty

In this section, we discuss one-time changes in the stocks of metal. The mechanics of the model conform well to the intuition garnered in the zero seigniorage case, but
32

go beyond, and allow a clear view of the sequence and timing of minting and melting
of the two metals.
Let us assume ξt = ξ and study the effect of changes in Qi,t over time. Out of
steady state, equation (11a) will dictate the dynamics. The complete set of equations
for this version of the model is:
di,t+1 + bi mi,t+1 = di,t + bi mi,t + (Qi,t+1 − Qi,t )
qi,t
qi,t+1
vi (dt+1 )
=
−β
0
u (ξ)
pt
pt+1
m1,t + et m2,t = pt ξ − q1,t b1 (m1,t+1 − m1,t ) − q2,t b2 (m2,t+1 − m2,t )


et
et
λt
−1 =
ν2,t − ν1,t
et+1
et+1
1 − σ1
1
≤ q1,t ≤
b1
b1
et
et (1 − σ2 )
≤ q2,t ≤
b2
b2

(26a)
(26b)
(26c)
(26d)
(26e)
(26f )

We consider a one-time change in Q1,t0 , the existing stock of bullion of metal 1.
Assume that the economy was in steady state for t ≤ t0 , and that it will be in a new
steady state for t ≥ t0 +1; values of the variables in the new steady state will be denoted
by a tilde˜when they differ from the old steady state. We consider progressively larger
changes. In each case, we compute the new steady state values, then use (26b) to
compute the price of metal in t0 and check whether it is within the bounds imposed by
(26e) or (26f ), or equal to one of the bounds.
First, consider changes in Q1,t that are compatible with no minting. This means
that the whole change in Q is absorbed by jewelry, that is, d˜1 = d1 + ∆Q1 . In the new
steady state, m1 and m2 are unchanged, so p is unchanged, and
q̃1 =

p v1 (d1 + ∆Q1 , d2 )
.
1−β
u0 (ξ)

Using (26b) written at t = t0 , we find that
q1,t0 = β

v1 (d1 + ∆Q1 , d2 )
q̃1
+
= q̃1 .
p
u0 (ξ)
33

Writing (26e) at t = t0 , we find:
1
1 v1 (d1 + ∆Q1 , d2 ) (m1 + em2 )
1 − σ1
≤ .
≤
0
b1
1−β
u (ξ) ξ
b1

(27)

This places upper and lower bounds on ∆Q1 . If ∆Q1 exceeds those bounds, then either
minting (for ∆Q1 > 0) or melting occurs.
When minting occurs, the new steady state has same m2 but a different m̃1
which will have to be computed. Let m̃1 = m1 + ∆m1 . The new stock of jewelry is
d˜1 = d1 + ∆Q1 − b1 ∆m1 ,
the price level is p̃ = (∆m1 + m1 + em2 )/ξ, and

q̃1 =

p̃
1−β



v1 d˜1 , d2
u0 (ξ)

.

At t0 , by assumption q1,t0 = (1 − σ1 )/b1 and pt0 is found with equation (26c):
pt0 =

1
[m1 + em2 + (1 − σ1 ) ∆m1 ] .
ξ

Equation (26b) written at t0 now gives


d˜1 , d2

1 v1
1 − β u0 (ξ)


=

1 − σ1
b1 pt0

or
(1 − σ1 ) (1 − β) u0 (ξ) ξ = v1 (d1 + ∆Q1 − b1 δm1 , d2 ) b1 [m1 + (1 − σ1 ) ∆m1 + em2 ]
which is an equation in ∆m1 and ∆Q1 : for each value of the latter, we can solve for
the value of the former. The elasticity of the stock of money m1 to a supply shock to
Q1 can be computed to be


d1
m1
b1 m1
− (1 − σ) 1
Q1
Q1 m1 + em2

where 1 is the elasticity of demand for jewelry of type 1.
34

−1

When the supply shock is large enough to induce minting, the money supply
changes, and so does the price level: this means that the price of the other metal
increases as well. For large enough values of ∆Q1 , q2,t0 will reach its upper bound in
(26f ), that is, the melting point for metal 2. This leads to the third possible case,
minting of 1 and melting of 2. Following the same procedure, ∆m1 and ∆m2 are found
to be the solutions to
 
(1 − σ1 ) (1 − β) u0 (ξ) ξ = v1 d˜ b1 [m1 + (1 − σ1 ) ∆m1 + e (m2 + ∆m2 )]
 b
1
[m1 + (1 − σ1 ) ∆m1 + e (m2 + ∆m2 )] .
(1 − β) u0 (ξ) ξ = v2 d˜
e

m2
melt coin 2

C
mint coin 2

B

A

m1

mint coin 1
melt coin 1

Figure 11: Effect of a permanent increase in Q1 .

The market ratio is now (1 − σ1 )/e∗ , which is the ratio of the mint price of
gold to the mint equivalent of silver. It is kept fixed at that value for any ∆Q1 : this
means that, while d1 increases (because only part of the increase in gold is minted), d2
35

increases as well, at the appropriate rate to maintain a constant market ratio, at the
lower bound of the interval defined by (25).
Figure 11 illustrates these three possibilities (small, medium or large increase
in Q1 ) in terms of a diagram similar to Figure 10 . The diamond formed by the solid
lines in Figure 11 is the locus of possible (m1 , m2 ) pairs that could be equilibria for
the initial stocks of Q1 and Q2 . The effect of an increase in Q1 is to shifts minting and
melting lines of coin 1 to the right, so that the new locus of possible (m1 , m2 ) equilibria
is given by the shaded area.
Now suppose that the initial equilibrium in the economy was given by point like
point A. Since this point also lies in the shaded area, this point is also an equilibrium
after the increase in Q1 . Thus, although the increase in Q1 decreases the market ratio,
it does not move it to the point where minting of metal 1 would occur, and there is no
effect on the money supplies. This would correspond to the case of a small increase in
Q1 .
However, if the initial equilibrium were at point like point B, this point is no
longer an equilibrium after increase in Q1 . The above results show that the economy
will move to the new equilibrium by minting some of the increase in Q1 , leading to an
increase in the supply of m1 , a horizontal rightward move in Figure 11 shown by the
arrow from point B..
The third case occurs when the initial equilibrium is at a point like point C, a
point which once again is not an equilibrium after the increase in Q1 . In this case,
however, the economy cannot reach the shaded region by moving horizontally from C.
Instead, the melt-coin2 line is reached before the shaded area is, so that some of coin
2 is melted as some metal 1 is minted.
Dynamics under Uncertainty
The intuitions from the previous section permit us to envision what the properties of the model will be under uncertainty. For small shocks to either metal, only
jewelry will vary; the stocks of money will be constant and the price level unaffected.
36

For large enough shocks, one or both money stocks will change; when both metal stocks
change, the behavior of the variables will be much as in the zero-seigniorage case.
The effect of seigniorage, then, is to make the price level even smoother: only
the larger shocks will have any effect. Of course, the gains of smoothing the smallest
variations might not be that important. In terms of welfare, there is no reason to
expect the welfare rankings to be overturned.

Conclusion
Giffen, a strong opponent of bimetallism which he called “rotten throughout, and of
bastard origin altogether” (Giffen 1892, 113), made very clear his theory of money:
“a particular commodity is selected to perform the function of a common measure of
value; but it is and remains a commodity. . . . Gold remains gold, silver remains silver,
cattle remain cattle, and so on, while they perform this function of money; and they
remain subject to exactly the same laws of exchange after they are used as money
as before” (p. 194). Thus, “gold and silver being commodities subject to different
conditions of production and demand, the declaration by law or custom that a bargain
may be made in one or the other at a ratio, necessarily means that, except at a moment
when the market ratio may happen to coincide with the legal ratio, the bargain will be
understood to be made in the metal which may be obtained at a cheaper rate than the
ratio” (p. 203). One way to read Giffen is with a standard general equilibrium model,
in which one, and only one numeraire may be chosen. Bimetallism, in this model, is
an attempt to set two numeraires.
In our model, we give bimetallism a chance. To do this, we rely on the cash-inadvance assumption. We know that this departure from standard general equilibrium
gives positive value to otherwise worthless fiat money. In a commodity money model,
where “conditions of production and demand” are applicable, it gives rise to enough
multiplicity that bimetallism becomes feasible. The cash-in-advance assumption, which
embodies the assumptions of the “quantitative theory of prices,” thus allows us to
formalize Fisher’s view of bimetallism. Interestingly, we are also able to recover Walras’
37

conclusion that bimetallism has one more unknown than equations. Walras, the father
of general equilibrium, thus sides against Giffen.
The model delivers many assertions and insights of the bimetallist literature: the
multiplicity of equilibria suggests that the government can indeed stabilize the market
ratio around any legal ratio it chooses, and movements in and out of bullion will serve
to maintain equality between the two ratios. We also find that the price stabilization
effects are present, as emphasized by Friedman and Fisher, and are able to quantify
them (see Edgeworth 1897 for an early attempt at the same goal). Our most novel
finding, which could not be made outside of a properly specified general equilibrium
model, is that bimetallism is always dominated by one or the other single standard,
and the welfare loss is quantitatively significant.
Presumably, Fisher and Friedman had reasons to believe that price stabilization
brought welfare gains. In this model, inflation has no costs, and reducing it or its
variance has no benefit. One conclusion might be that the model is not the right one to
assess Friedman’s support of bimetallism. But the welfare loss from bimetallism arises
in non-stochastic steady states, and it is hard to think of plausibly large welfare costs
from constant and perfectly known inflation. Also, our model does allow for welfare
gains from a reduced price level variance: a stable price level means a stable marginal
utility of jewelry, that is, a stable jewelry stock which is desirable when preferences are
concave.8 But the numerical simulations show that these welfare gains are small.
One obvious extension is to estimate the model, rather than calibrate it, and
test it properly. Beyond that, there are many open questions: we need a multi-country
version of the model to address the controversies more fully. In particular, we do not
provide a good explanation for the simultaneous abandonment of bimetallism by so
many countries in 1873. One approach might be to embed the choice of standard
in a simple game, since many explanations of the events of 1873 have the flavor of
non-cooperative game theory.

8

Walras (1898,7–9) questions why that particular marginal utility should be made constant.

38

Appendix 1
Let the exogenous state z = Q1 /b1 + eQ2 /b2 take values in Z = [z, z̄] according to the
probability distribution π(z, dz 0 ). The underlying stochastic processes Qi are assumed
to take values in [Qi , Q̄i ]. Define C(Z) to be the space of bounded continuous functions
on Z.
Define f (y, x) = 1/(y − ax) and g(y, x) = 1/(y − ax) − c/x. The function f (y, ·)
is defined over [0, y/a), continuous, strictly increasing, and such that f (y, 0) = 1/y
and limx→y/a f (y, x) = +∞. The function g(y, ·) is well defined on (0, y/a), continuous, strictly increasing; moreover, the following is true: limx→0 g(y, x) = −∞
and limx→y/a g(y, x) = +∞. Let h(y, x) such that g[y, h(y, x)] = x: h(y, ·) is welldefined on R+ for all y, continuous, strictly increasing, with h(y, 0) = y/(a + 1/c),
limx→+∞ h(y, x) = y/a.
The subset on which the operator will apply is F ⊂ C(Z), the subset of functions
d(z) such that 0 ≤ d(z) ≤ l(z) for all z ∈ X. The function l(z), which corresponds to
the restriction that di,t+1 ≤ Qi,t+1 , is an element of C(Z) defined by
d (z) ≤ b1 min{b1 z −

eb1
eb1 α1
Q2 } = l (z) .
Q̄2 ,
b2
b2 α 2

Clearly, F is closed and bounded. To ensure that T (F ) ⊂ F , we will make the following
assumption.
Assumption 1. The stochastic process {Q1,t+1 , Q2,t+1 }t≥0 and e are assumed to be
such that, for all z ∈ X:
c
1
−
≥β
z − al (z) l (z)

Z

π (z, dz 0 )
.
z 0 − al (z 0 )

(28)

The function l(z) satisfies l(z) < z/a. In other words, f [z, d(z)] is well defined
and finite everywhere for d ∈ F ; moreover, by Assumption 1, E(f [z, d(z 0 )]|z) is welldefined. The function l has a meaningful important role: when d(z) = l(z), one of the
stocks of money is set to 0, which corresponds to de facto monometallism.
39

Finally, define the operator
T d (z) = h [z, βE (f [z, d (z 0 )] |z)] .

(29)

By the above arguments, T is well-defined on F , and is clearly continuous and monotone; and for d(z) = 0̄, T (0̄) ≥ 0̄. Also, T maps F into itself by monotonicity of f (y, ·)
and h(y, ·), the upper bound on all elements of F , and Assumption 1. It remains to
show that T (F ) is an equicontinuous family of functions: this follows from the uniform
bounds on g(y, ·). By the Monotone Operator Theorem (Stokey and Lucas 1989, 528),
T has a fixed point in F , and the sequence T n (0̄) converges to that fixed point.

Appendix 2

Figure 3
The market ratio data is given by Soetbeer (U.S. Senate 1887). The information on the monetary systems of countries in the 19th century comes from a variety of
sources, including the Reports of the Director of the U.S. Mint (various years). Countries’ shares of world output are computed on the basis of the data and methods in
Maddison (1995), adjusting for current borders and interpolating between the years
1820, 1870, 1900 and 1913. Not all countries are included, but those that are account
for 88% of world output in 1820 and 96% in 1913.
Figures 1 and 2
The data on production of gold and silver from 1493 to 1927 come from Soetbeer’s studies (U.S. Senate 1887, 76) and the papers by Ridgway and Merrill (Bureau
of Mines 1929, 1930). Those figures are the ones used most commonly in the literature
(Rockoff 1984, Friedman 1990; Kellenbenz 1981 assesses the Soetbeer figures). The
stock of gold in 1492 is estimated from production data for gold in prior times (Quiring
1948, 138, 197) with a 1% depreciation rate assumed. The figure is 297 tons, close to
an estimate of 300 tons reported by Quiring (1948, 203). For silver, we also use the
40

production figures in prior times (Patterson 1972). Patterson gives a stock of 5,000
tons around 1300 and vague indications on the production rates in the late Middle
ages. Based on these, and on Nef (1941), the rate is assumed to decline from 50 tons
per year in 1300 to 15 in 1450, and to rise again to 50 by 1500. The resulting estimate
of the silver stock in 1492 is 3,600 tons. Needless to say, production rates increased so
much after 1492 that the stock estimates for the late 19th century are not sensitive to
these assumptions.
Calibration
The numbers used for calibration of the model are as follows. Total stocks of gold
and silver in 1873 are computed as just explained. Monetary stocks of gold and silver
are taken from Kitchin’s estimates (League of Nations 1930, reproduced in Warren and
Pearson 1933, 78; see Rockoff 1984, 621–2 for an assessment) and Drake (1985, 208)
respectively. The legal ratio is 15.5. The parameters of the utility function α1 and α2
are chosen so that

α 2 Q 2 − d2
α 1 Q 1 − d1
+
=1−β
x
d1
x
d2
α2
d1
α1
−
15.5 = 0
x
x
d2

with Q1 = 0.303, Q2 = 5.83, Q1 − d1 = 0.138, Q2 − d2 = 2.40 (all quantities measured
in bn troy oz). We find α1 /x = 0.0269 and α2 /x = 0.0360.

References

Barro, Robert J. “Money and the Price Level under the Gold Standard.” Economic
Journal 89 (March 1978): 13–33.
Chen, Chau nan. “Bimetallism: Theory and Controversy in Perspective.” History of
Political Economy 4 (Spring 1972): 89–112.
Dowd, Kevin. “The Analytics of Bimetallism.” Manchester School of Economic and
Social Studies 64 (September 1996): 281–97.

41

Darwin, Leonard. Bimetallism: A Summary and Examination of the Arguments for and
against a Bimetallic System of Currency. New York: D. Appleton & Company,
1898.
Drake, Louis S. “Reconstruction of a Bimetallic Price Level.” Explorations in Economic
History 22 (April 1985): 194–219.
Edgeworth, Francis Y. “Miscellaneous applications of the Calculus of Probabilities.”
Journal of the Royal Statistical Society 60 (September 1897): 681–98.
Fisher, Irving. The Purchasing Power of Money, its Determination and Relation to
Credit, Interest and Crises. New York: MacMillan, 1911.
Flandreau, Marc. “As Good as Gold? Bimetallism in Equilibrium, 1850–70.” In
Monetary Standards and Exchange Rates, edited by Maria Cristina Marcuzzo,
Lawrence H. Officer and Annalisa Rosselli. London and New York: Routledge,
1997.
Flandreau, Marc. “The French Crime of 1873: An Essay on the Emergence of the International Gold Standard, 1870–80.” Journal of Economic History 56 (December
1996): 862–97.
Friedman, Milton. “Bimetallism revisited.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 4 (Fall
1990a): 85–104.
Friedman, Milton. “The Crime of 1873.” Journal of Political Economy 98 (December
1990b): 1154–94.
Garber, Peter M. “Nominal Contracts in a Bimetallic Standard.” American Economic
Review 76 (December 1986): 1012–1030.
Giffen, Robert. The Case against Bimetallism. London: George Bell & Sons, 1892.
Kareken, John H. and Neil Wallace. “On the Indeterminacy of Equilibrium Exchange
Rates.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 96 (May 1981): 207–222.

42

Kellenbenz, Hermann. “Final Remarks: Production and Trade of Gold, Silver, Copper
and Lead from 1450 to 1750.” In Precious Metals in the Age of Expansion:
papers of the XIVth International Congress of the Historical Sciences, edited by
Hermann Kellenbenz. Stuttgart: Klett-Cotta, 1981.
Laughlin, James Laurence. The History of Bimetallism in the U.S.. New York: D.
Appleton and Company, 1896.
League of Nations. Interim Report of the Gold Delegation of the Financial Committee.
Geneva, 1930. II. 26.
Maddison, Angus. Monitoring the World Economy, 1820–1992. Paris: Development
Center of the OECD, 1995.
Nef, John U. “Silver Production in Central Europe, 1450–1618.” Journal of Political
Economy 49 (August 1948): 575–91.
Oppers, Stefan E. “A Model of the Bimetallic System.” International Monetary Fund:
Working Paper 95/144, 1995.
Oppers, Stefan E. “Was the Worldwide Shift to Gold Inevitable? An Analysis of the
End of Bimetallism.” Journal of Monetary Economics 37 (February 1996): 143–
62.
Patterson, C. C. “Silver Stocks and Losses in Ancient and Medieval Times.” Economic
History Review 2d ser., 25 (May 1972): 205–35.
Quiring, Heinrich. Geschichte des Goldes: die Goldenen Zeitalter in ihrer kulturellen
und wirtschaftlichen Bedeutung. Stuttgart: Ferdinand Enke Verlag, 1948.
Redish, Angela. “The Evolution of the Gold Standard in England.” Journal of Economic
History 50 (December 1990): 789–805.
Redish, Angela. “The Persistence of Bimetallism in Nineteenth-Century France.” Economic History Review 48 (November 1995): 717–36.

43

Rockoff, Hugh. “Some Evidence on the Real Price of Gold, Its Cost of Production, and
Commodity Prices.” In A Retrospective on the Classical Gold Standard, 1821–
1931, edited by Michael D. Bordo and Anna J. Schwarz. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 1984.
Sargent, Thomas J. and Bruce D. Smith. “Coinage, Debasements, and Gresham’s
Laws.” Economic Theory 10 (August 1997): 197–226.
Sargent, Thomas J. and François R. Velde. “The Big Problem of Small Change.”
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago: Working Paper 97-8, 1997.
Sargent, Thomas J. and Neil Wallace. “A Model of Commodity Money..” Journal of
Monetary Economics 12 (July 1983): 163–87.
Shaw, William Arthur. The History of Currency, 1252 to 1894. London: Wilsons &
Milne, 1896.
Stokey, Nancy L. and Robert E. Lucas, Jr. Recursive Methods in Economic Dynamics.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1989.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Mines. Summarized Data of Gold Production
by Robert H. Ridgway, Economic Paper 6. Washington, D.C.: GPO, 1929.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Mines. Summarized Data of Silver Production by Charles W. Merrill, Economic Paper 8. Washington, D.C.: GPO, 1930.
U.S. Senate. The International Monetary Conference of 1878. Proceedings and Exhibits, Followed by the Report of the American Commission and an Appendix
Containing Correspondence Submitted to the Department of State by Mr. Fenton, and the Historical Material for the Study of Monetary Policy Contributed
by Mr. Horton. 45th Cong., 3d sess., 1879. Ex. Doc. 58
U.S. Senate. Report Made by Edward Atkinson, of Boston, Mass., to the President
of the United States upon the Present Status of Bimetallism in Europe. 50th
Cong., 1st sess., 1887. Ex. Doc. 34
Walras, Léon. Éléments d’Économie Politique Appliquée. Lausanne: F. Rouge, 1898.
44

Walras, Léon. Elements of Pure Economics. Translated by William Jaffé. Fairfield, NJ:
Augustus M. Kelley, 1977.
Warren, George F. and Frank A. Pearson. Prices. New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc,
1933.
Willis, Henry Parker. A History of the Latin Monetary Union: A Study of International
Monetary Action. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1901.

45