View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

83-4
c

0>
E
E

o
u
TD
C
ra

z

flU
C*
c

0>
*E
-*

k_

nj
a
flu
Q
-C
u
kflu
t
/>
a>
a:

A Series of Occasional Papers in Draft Form Prepared by Members'©

A CRITICAL APPRAISAL OF MCKINNON’S WORLD
MONEY SUPPLY HYPOTHESIS
Henry N. Goldstein and Stephen E. Haynes

O
m
73

>
73
73

<
m
00

>
Z

*
O

March 1983

A CRITICAL APPRAISAL OF McKINNON’S WORLD
MONEY SUPPLY HYPOTHESIS

By:
Henry N. Goldstein and Stephen E. Haynes*

*Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago and University of Oregon, respectively.
For helpful comments, the authors are indebted to Peter B. Clark, George G.
Kaufman, Jay H. Levin, J. Carter Murphy, and Joe A. Stone.




1

In a lecture given in 1978, Arnold C. Harberger pointed to the similarity
of inflation rates across 16 industrial countries during each of the three
periods 1952-67, 1967-72, and 1972-78.

Noting the relatively narrow range of

average inflation rates for the middle 12 countries in each period, Harberger
conjectured that the driving force behind this shared inflationary experience
was the common impact of the world money supply under a regime of relatively
fixed exchange rates.

Although the major currencies have been nominally

floating against one another since early 1973, he nonetheless contended that
the concept of a world money supply remained a fruitful notion:
Even though we have had nearly five years of floating
rates, it is my impression that the monetary authorities
of the major countries have behaved with far less in­
dependence than the theorists of floating rates are prone
to assume. Consequently, in terms of the way the inter­
national monetary system has worked since 1973, I would
characterize it as a hybrid, functioning if anything more
like a fixed-exchange rate system than like a textbook
case of floating rates.
Much the same evaluation has recently been made by Ronald McKinnon
(1982).

According to McKinnon, a combination of intense intermittent

speculative pressure, heavy official intervention, and a ,!perfect,f world
capital market has meant that, even under floating exchange rates, the world
money supply has had a significant impact on inflation and output in the
United States.

McKinnon concludes that the Federal Reserve should adjust its

money-growth policies in the light of money supply behavior in other leading
countries.

This behavior, he argues, moves in close correspondence with the

exchange rate between their currencies and the dollar.




Thus, he writes:

The doctrine of domestic monetarism, where the
Federal Reserve System keys on some purely American
monetary aggregate such as Ml and M2 and ignores the
foreign exchanges, is increasingly inefficient for
preventing global inflation or deflation— and for
stabilizing American income and prices.

2

This paper disputes McKinnon's interpretation of the behavior of exchange
rates and national money supplies since the early 1970s.

Its five sections

include (I) a brief graphical restatement of McKinnon's central point; (II)
some criticisms of his analysis; (III) an alternative interpretation of events
under managed floating; (IV) some evidence suggesting that quarterly money
supply growth in other industrial countries has been largely independent of
official intervention activities and has had only a small impact on U.S.
prices and activity levels; and (V) conclusions.
I.

A graphical illustration of McKinnon's model
McKinnon's model has two countries, the U.S. and ROW (rest of the world),

with the dollar and the rowa as national currencies.

The spot and forward

dollar prices of the rowa are denoted by S and F, and interest rates on
dollar-denominated and row-denominated assets by i and i*.

Now, consider an

initial equilibrium where, for simplicity, js, the expected near-term change in
the spot price of the rowa [s ■ E(dS/dt) * (F - S)/S] is zero, the latter
equality holding because F is assumed equal to the expected value of S at the
relevant future date.

Satisfaction of McKinnon's equation (6)
i - i* = s

(Fisher open condition)

then implies that iQ = i*, where the subscript denotes time zero.
there be a sharp exogenous rise in j3.

Now let

According to McKinnon, this development

triggers currency substitution through two channels.

Channel One comprises

direct shifts of working balances from dollars into rowa by large commercial
banks and nonfinancial multinationals.

Channel Two involves indirect currency

substitution which, McKinnon argues, is likely to be much more important than
direct substitution.

It is the discovery and elucidation of this Channel Two

process that represents the key contribution of the McKinnon article.
Figure 1 illustrates this Channel Two process.

As js increases

exogenously, incipient pressure by international bond arbitragers forces




3

interest rates to adjust immediately, so that the spread between i^ and
*
ij

equals the new value of js.

Simultaneously, the forward discount on

the dollar takes a value equal to js.

At the new interest rates imposed by

these powerful expectational forces, transactors in each country find
themselves off their respective money demand curves.

U.S. transactors now

want to hold M^ of dollar balances but the U.S. money supply remains at
*

Mo ; similarly, ROW transactors want to hold

of rowa balances but

it

only M

currently exists.

U.S. transactors respond by trying to switch

out of cash balances and into dollar-denominated bonds; and ROW transactors by
trying to switch out of rowa denominated bonds and into rowa cash balances.
The result is to push (i - i*) just barely below s , which induces
international bond arbitragers— sensitive to even the slightest expected
uncovered yield differential — to switch out of dollar bonds and into rowa
bonds .

Thus, McKinnon concludes:
Massive capital flow can be easily induced even when the
interest differential remains 'correctly* aligned to reflect
accurately the change in expected exchange depreciation.

Figure 1
Equilibrium and disequilibrium in the two
national markets for money balances

T h e U n ited States




The Row

4

What is the response of the central banks to these capital flows?
McKinnon assumes that the ROW central bank intervenes to peg the spot exchange
rate in the immediate short run*

As a result it creates new high-powered

balances in rowa on a scale sufficient to increase M* to the amount demanded
*
at the lower interest rate, i^.

Moreover, the ROW central bank does not try

to check this externally induced money-supply expansion through open-market
sales or reserve requirement increases.

Indeed, any attempt to sterilize the

domestic monetary base effects of these speculatively induced capital inflows
would be foiled by perfect capital mobility— a key assumption of McKinnon1s
model.

In the United States, however, the monetary authorities, according to

McKinnon, do sterilize.

Indeed, such sterilization occurs automatically

insofar as the ROW bank uses its dollar accruals to buy U.S. government
securities rather than increase its dollar deposits at the Federal Reserve.
With respect to Figure 1, this sterilization means that dollar-denominated
transactions balances actually held amount to M^ whereas balances demanded
*
amount to Mj.

This disequilibrium is presumably resolved by persisting

attempts by U.S. transactors to acquire both bonds and goods, with resultant
lagged expansionary pressures on the world economy.
responds, the M

d

and M

*d

As nominal world income

curves eventually shift to the right by amounts

sufficient to restore equilibrium in the combined "markets" for the two
national money supplies.
Sterilization by the Federal Reserve represents a key policy mistake,
according to McKinnon.

For it implies that an exogenous shift in exchange

rate expectations, as indicated by an increase in the value of the parameter
js, leads to the creation of an excess supply of world money.

In a dynamic

context, what the Fed authorities have failed to perceive is that the more
rapid growth of foreign money balances (stemming from speculatively




5

induced capital flows out of the dollar) needs to be balanced by a slower
growth of U.S. money balances.

By focusing only on the growth rate of U.S.

money the Fed has aimed at the wrong target.
For two reasons, McKinnon argues, targeting on U.S. money alone was not
such a serious problem under the fixed exchange rates of the 1950s and 1960s.
First, the dollar then dominated the supply of "international money,11 as most
leading foreign currencies were nonconvertible on capital account.

Second,

most exchange rates were convincingly fixed so that expected exchange-rate
fluctuations leading to international money substitution were minimal.
the last 12 years, however, circumstances have differed.

During

Managed floating,

more volatile exchange rate expectations, and a secular decline in the share
of dollars in world money have all increased international currency
substitution.
McKinnon uses his model to explain "the two explosions in world money
supply in 1971-72 and again in 1977-78" when, he argues, js took on large
positive values.
1981-82.n

In addition, he uses it to explain "the Great Deflation.*of

He claims that there was an exogenous fall in js, in 1980, in

response to expectations of Reagan’s election and a new deflationary U.S.
policy, as well as to events in Poland and the election of a socialist
government in France.

As the dollar surged in response to these events,

central banks in Switzerland, Germany and Japan became large net sellers of
dollars, 11thus contracting that part of world money (Ml) denominated in Swiss
francs, marks, and yen."

With no offsetting U.S. monetary expansion, a sharp

deflation was imposed on the world economy.
II.

Questions about the McKinnon Model
1.

McKinnon assumes that huge amounts of uncovered funds move in

response to very small differentials in expected yields.




Such sensitivity

6

seems implausible for uncovered capital movements.

Though international

borrowers and lenders may well "take a view" regarding the probable level of
the spot rate in the near future, it seems unlikely that they would expose
themselves to large adverse swings in the exchange rate merely to obtain a 10
or 20 basis-point incremental expected return.

In brief, for risk-adverse

transactors, the uncertainty of this expected incremental return seems likely
to outweigh the appeal of its small expected value.*
2.

To illustrate his model, McKinnon provides the following numerical

example:
[S]uppose s^ increases from zero to 6 percent because the American
Secretary of the Treasury opines that the dollar is overvalued.
The "perfect" international bond market quickly adjusts to these
new exchange-rate expectations; the incipient arbitrage
pressure to move out of dollar bonds into rowa bonds
causes interest rates to adjusj immediately; i rises by
three percentage points, and i falls by three percentage
points.
But with js defined as "the expected change in S, averaged into the near
future of 1several weeks,1" a six percent rise in the spot dollar price of
rowa over the next four weeks (taking "several" as four) implies a forward
premium and an interest-rate spread of 72 percent per annum.

As no such

premia or interest-rate spreads have been observed among the OECD currencies
since the advent of managed floating.

We surmise either that the exchange-

risk considerations just noted prevent the existence of perfect capital
markets (in the sense of McKinnon) or that an expected rate change approaching
6 percent over the next "several weeks" never In fact materializes for these
currencies (perhaps because management of the float is flexible enough to
avoid such strong one-way expectations).
To make the Fisher Open Position consistent with observed interest
differentials of two to 10 per cent per annum would require assigning js a
monthly value of 0.16 to 0.83 percent.




Such values seem implausibly small

7

given the state of the markets during periods of particularly strong one-way
pressure.
3.

A more serious empirical question is associated with the recent

period of strong dollar appreciation.

From mid-1980 to mid-1982, the dollar

appreciated substantially against almost all other leading currencies.
was a leading example.

The DM

As the Bundesbank leaned against the wind during this

period, its external reserves, exclusive of gold, fell from $52.5 billion at
end-1979 to $41.0 billion at end-July 1982.

If the market expected the DM to

depreciate during this period, as McKinnon assumes, his model requires that
short-term DM yields exceed short-term dollar yields.

But in fact, except for

a brief period in mid-1980, rates on dollar assets remained well above rates
on comparable DM assets.

Indeed, German interest rates have been

substantially and consistently below U.S. interest rates both when the DM was
strong against the dollar (1977-1979) and when it was weak against the dollar
(1980 to mid-1982).

One does not have to search hard for an explanation: the

greater expected inflation in the United States than in Germany.

Similar

bilateral comparisons, contrary to McKinnon1s model, could be made between the
U.S. and Switzerland, the U.S. and Japan, and the U.S. and the Netherlands.
In other words, consistent with empirical evidence in Solnik (1982),
satisfaction of nthe Fisher closed condition" may well have prevented
satisfaction of the "Fisher open condition" in a world where exchange rates
were not expected to move in strict accordance with relative changes in
national price levels.
Ill. An alternative view
An alternative assessment of the managed floating rate experience since
1973— presented in somewhat dogmatic fashion as a foil to the McKinnon
view— runs as follows:




8

(1)

By and large, ROW central banks do "take a view11 regarding the

appropriate level and rate of change of the dollar price for their currencies.
If the rate begins to diverge from the level they think appropriate, they will
usually intervene.

But they will only lean against the wind— they will not

prevent market pressure from moving the rate.

2

Accordingly, we disagree

with Harbergerfs perception that since 1973 the hybrid international monetary
system has functioned "more like a fixed-exchange rate system than a textbook
case of floating rates."
(2)

The central banks also have short-run interest rate and money-supply

targets, which they vary in response to changes in domestic demand conditions
and exogenous inflationary shocks.

By and large, the central banks try to

neutralize the effects of their dollar accruals or sales on their domestic
monetary base, but if the exchange market pressure is intense they may choose
to alter their earlier domestic money-growth and interest-rate targets at the
same time that they back away from (yet resist) that pressure.

Such a

response makes good economic sense because the exchange-rate trend influences
prices and real demand in a way that offsets the effects of the faster or
slower monetary growth induced by their intervention.

During 1977-78, for

example, Germany experienced low inflation relative to her major trading
partners together with considerable slack capacity.

As the DM strengthened,

the Bundesbank absorbed substantial amounts of dollars from the exchange
market.

Its policy of only partially sterilizing, hence allowing the domestic

money supply to grow well above the earlier target range, seems sensible given
that faster money growth was accompanied by a sharply rising DM in the foreign
exchange market.




For as the Bundesbank noted in its 1978 Report;

Both at the beginning of the year [1978]
and in the autumn new monetary unrest

9

associated with the temporary weakness of
the U.S. dollar and to some extend also
with tensions in the European narrower
margins arrangement (the "snake11) , resulted
in a rapid appreciation of the Deutsche
Mark in international foreign exchange
markets. In order to slow down this upward
movement, which far exceeded the price and
costs differential between Germany and
other countries, and at the same time to
mitigate the dampening effect of an
excessive appreciation on domestic
activity, the Bundesbank took considerable
amounts of foreign currency out of the
market....In these circumstances the
Bundesbank was forced to adhere to a
relatively easy domestic monetary policy.
Both factors— the massive inflows of funds
from abroad and the stance of domestic
monetary policy— led to an expansion of the
money growth target for 1978. As long as
the trend of business activity remained
fairly flat (as in the early part of last
year) and as the sharp appreciation of the
Deutsche Mark automatically restrained the
increase in domestic costs and prices, it
was possible to tolerate the faster
expansion of liquid funds in Germany; in
fact, any application of the monetary
brakes during that period would probably
have had an adverse effect on the economy
as a whole, [our italics] (p. 1)
(3)

Slower monetary growth in the non-U.S. industrial countries during

1980-82 represented a response to cost-push pressures caused by the second oil
shock and a strengthening dollar; it was not caused by an inability to offset
the domestic-base effects of dollar sales in the exchange market.

3

Indeed,

these effects were more than fully offset in that money growth remained
positive even though the central banks were net sellers of dollars in the
exchange markets.
(4)

We have argued that large Channel Two capital flows are implausible.

We suspect that Channel One capital flows are also unimportant. Aside from
compensating balances, sophisticated multinational concerns are unlikely to
hold significant amounts of transactions balances in any currency if these




10

balances yield either zero or small explicit interest returns.

Such

transactors might well choose to go long or short in a given currency for
speculative reasons, but in so doing they would prefer to acquire an
interest-earning asset.
IV.

Some Evidence
In this section we present three sets of evidence which seem consistent

with our assessment of the post-1973 international monetary system and
inconsistent with that of McKinnon and Harberger.
(1)

Cumulative money growth and price-level changes in 10 countries

Harberger?s perception of a common worldwide inflationary process
persisting well after the breakdown of the Bretton Woods arrangements rested
on the proposition that exchange rates among the leading currencies were
really more fixed than floating.

McKinnon's analysis of the importance of the

world money supply under floating rates would seem to rest on much the same
proposition.

This proposition implies that prices rise over time by roughly

the same margin in all "participating countries" as the common world money
supply percolates through a relatively fixed exchange rate structure.

The

proposition would, however, seem to be contradicted if marked divergences in
rates of growth in national monetary supplies were associated with
corresponding divergences in price-level behavior.

For then one would have to

infer (given an absence of ever-intensifying trade restrictions) that
exchange-rate adjustments were such as to bottle up the price-level effects of
above-average or below-average money growth within national boundaries.
evidence on this issue is provide by Figure 2.

Some

The horizontal axis measures

the percentage increase in Ml from end-1975 to end-1981; the vertical axis,
the percentage change in the CPI from 1975 (average for the year) to June




1982.

The scatter seems to support the bottling up thesis over the spillover

thesis inherent in essentially fixed exchange rates.
Figure 3 plots the percentage change in the CPI against the percentage
change in the narrow money supply for the same ten countries for a period of
comparable length in the 1960s, when exchange rates were pegged.

In this

earlier period, it seems clear that significant differences in money supply
growth were not accompanied by corresponding differences in cumulative
price-level movements.

To a first approximation, "the law of one price"

coupled with fixed exchange rates appears to have prevented national inflation
rates from diverging substantially from one another.

Figure 2
Money and Inflation in 10 countries
under floating exchange rates
percent change in C .P .I., 1976 to mid-1982

2001----

Italy
175

150

•

U.K.

125

France
100

Canada
U.S.

75

Belgium #

Nether,ands

50

#

•
Japan

^

Germany

Switzerland

I
20

I____ L
40

60

J____ L
80

100


http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/ Percent increase in m oney supply (M1), end 1975 to end 1981.
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

I

I

120

140

I
160

1
180

I
200

12

Figu re 3
M oney and In flatio n in 10 co u n tries
in the 1960s
percent change in C.P.I. ,1963 to 1969

100 I

75

50
Netherlands
U .K .

25

Japan

Belgium

I

Italy

France

Canada

u.s.®
Switzerland

Germany

0

-25

j ______i_______ i
20

40

60

i
80

Percent increase in m oney supply ( M 1),end




i
100

1962-1968

i

i

120

140

i
160

i

i

100

200

13

Figures 2 and 3 compared cumulative changes in national price levels for
periods of equal length under fixed and floating rates.

Table 1 shows two

measures of dispersion in annual inflation rates for the same 10 countries for
the two different policy regimes, giving mean values of the annual range and
annual standard deviation of their inflation rates.

Both measures show a

marked increase in the dispersion of annual inflation rates after the adoption
of floating rates, again suggesting an increase in policy independence under
that regime.

4

Table 1: Alternative Measures of Dispersion in Annual
Inflation Rates across Ten Industrial Countries: Fixed
Rate Period vs. Floating Rate Period
Fixed Rate Period
(1960-70, inclusive)

Floating Rate Period
(1974-81 inclusive)

Mean of the Annual Range
Mean of Annual Standard Deviations

4.64 % p.a.
1.42 % p.a.

14.89 % p.a.
4.48 % p.a.

Mean of the Annual Means

3.20 % p.a.

9.66 % p.a.

Source:

2.

International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics,
Yearbook, 1982. The inflation rates used are year-to-year
percentage changes in the consumer price index for the United
States, Canada, Japan, Belgium, France, Germany, Italy,
the Netherlands, Switzerland, and the United Kingdom.

Co-variation in international reserves and domestic money growth
Various accounts of official intervention in the foreign exchange markets

during the 1970s and early 1980s would seem to suggest that above average
official purchases of dollars in the t-th quarter ought to be associated with
above average rates of growth in the Ml money supply in that quarter or the
next, and vice-versa.
On this point, McKinnon observes:




Central banks often take offsetting actions— through
open-market operations, changed reserve requirements,
or rediscounting— to sterilize the domestic monetary
impact of...official interventions.
...[But] clearly, sterilization would make it
much more difficult for ROW bank to meet its exchange-

14

rate target. Morever, Hans Genberg and Swoboda (1981)
provide evidence that when sterilization occurs in
Europe and elsewhere, it is only partial. Hence, let
us assume for analytical purposes that ROW bank does
not sterilize: A* is constant as foreign exchange in­
tervention takes place,
(p. 328)
To what extent does this analytically convenient assumption by McKinnon
match reality?

To test this sterilization assumption, we ran a regression for

each of the nine leading OECD industrial countries (other than the United
States) of the following form:
Ain 11 = a + a, Ain
t
o
i
where Ain

t

+ a_ Ain R ,
l
t—1

*= percentage change in domestic money growth during the t-th
quarter

Ain Rt = percentage change in international reserves (less gold)"* in the
t-th quarter
Ain R^ j = percentage change in international reserves (less gold) in
quarter (t-1 ).
For the 50 quarters ending in mid-1982 the results are summarized in Table 2.

Table 2: Regression Results for AlnM„ ■ a +a,Aln R^ + a_ Ain R^ .
------------ ---------------t
o 1
t
2
t- 1
for I/1970-II/1982
Size of significant
coefficient on:
Country
Canada
Switzerland
Belgium
Netherlands
Italy
France
Germany
Japan
U.K.

_2
R
.01
.17
.04
.18
.01
.00
.01
.13
.04

Ain Rfc*

Ain R

.
t-1

mmmrnrn

.09 (2.73)
—
.03 (3.03)
—
—
—
.02 (2.37)
——

—
—
—

—
—
—
—

*t-value in parentheses.
It would appear that large quarterly percentage changes in national money
supplies are not tightly linked to large quarterly percentage changes in




15

international reserves since almost all the R

2

values for these equations are

extremely low and the coefficients on Ain Rfc, even when statistically
significant, are so small numerically^.

By one means or another, the

central banks of these nine countries appear to have been able to neutralize
the effects of large changes in international reserves on their Ml money
supplies.^

This evidence is consistent with Laney and Willett (1982), who

conclude that increases in international reserves were not the dominant
explanation for the global monetary expansion during the 1970s.
3.

Some St. Louis regressions
In this section, we report various regressions that seek to test whether

the weighted average growth rate of money supplies in industrial countries
outside the United States (ROW money) has had a significant influence on
either the U.S. rate of inflation or U.S. real output.
We follow McKinnon in measuring the growth rate of world money.

For this

purpose, he assumes that the world consists of ten industrial countries— the
United States, Canada, Japan, the U.K., Germany, France, Italy, the
Netherlands, Belgium, and Switzerland.

For any given quarter, growth rates in

these countries' respective narrowly defined seasonally adjusted money
supplies— as given on line 34b of International Financial Statistics— were
computed, weighted by their relative GNP Levels as of a particular year, and
then summed.

McKinnon used GNP weights for 1970, the mid-year of the two

decades of data presented in his article; we have used 1976 weights, as 1976
g

is the mid-year for most of our regressions.

We constructed a

corresponding series for the growth rate of Rest-of-World money (ROW money) by
simply omitting the U.S. component from the world money index and rescaling
9
the remaining weights to make them again sum to one.
World money growth and U.S. inflation




16

A number of reduced form regressions published by economists at the
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis show that quarterly U.S. inflation during
the 1970s can be well explained statistically by a regression of the GNP
deflator on (i) lagged U.S. money growth over the past three years; (ii)
changes in relative energy prices; (iii) changes in relative food prices; and
(iv) dummy variables to capture the effects of wage and price controls.^
McKinnon’s contention that monetary developments in the ROW have had powerful
effects on the U.S. economy can be tested by using the St. Louis approach.
Specifically, suppose that we run regressions for the floating-rate period,
II/1973-II/1982, using moving averages of past U.S. money growth and world
money growth as alternative variables— would world money growth prove to be
the better explanatory variable, as McKinnon's argument clearly implies?

And

suppose that we run a regression that includes moving averages of both U.S.
money growth and ROW money growth as explanatory variables— would ROW money
growth prove to be statistically significant and would its inclusion
appreciably improve the explanatory value of the equation?

Tables 3 and 4

below show the results of alternative regressions with these specifications.
The equations in Table 3 cover the floating-rate period, per se,
II/1973-11/1982; those in Table 4, the slightly longer period, I/1970-II/1982.
The results for both periods are quite similar.

Comparing equations (1)

and (2), we see that U.S. money growth is highly significant in both periods,
whereas world money growth is only significant for the longer period.

For

each period, the explanatory power of the equations using world money is
markedly lower than the equation using U.S. money.

Morever, the estimated

coefficients for world money growth are well below unity in both cases,
whereas the coefficients on U.S. money growth— 1.09 for the shorter period and
1.12 for the longer period— are not significantly different from unity.




Table 3:

Equation

Estimate of Alternative Money Price Relationships for the Unites States, II/1973-II/1982

Constant

MUS3

(i)

-.003
(-.039)

1.091
(3.56)

(2)

.024
(.751)

(3)
(

NOTE:

-.019
.636)

MW3

MR0W3

.479
(1.26)
1.155
(3.61)

.145
(.782)

ENER

DUMC

DUMA

DW

R^

.035
(1.43)

—

.042
(2.28)

2.15

.519

.397

.069
(2.57)

—

.018
(.892)

1.37

.326

.470

.037
(1.49)

—

-.040
(2.12)

2.17

.531

.400

SE*102

The dependent variable is the annualized percentage change in the GNP deflator for the quarter. MUS3
is the average annual rate of change in the U.S. money supply (Ml) over the previous 12 quarters.
MW3 is the average annual rate of change in the world money supply, as defined in the text, over the
previous 12 quarters. MR0W3 is the average annual rate of change in the ROW money supply as defined
in the text over the previous 12 quarters. ENER is the average annual rate of change in an index of
energy prices divided by the GNP deflator over the current and previous five quarters. DUMC is the
price control dummy (equal to one over 11/1971— 1/1974, zero elsewhere). DUMA is the post-pricecontrol dummy (equal to equal to one over II/1974-IV/1974).




Table 4:

Equation

Estimates of Alternative Money Price Relationships for the United States, I/1970-II/1982

Constant

MUS3

(1)

-.003
(-0 .212)

1.120
(4.25)

(2)

.005
(.205)

(3)

-.026
(-1.158)




MW3

MR0W3

.699
(2.57)
1.136
(4.37)

.208
(1.44)

DUMA

DW

R2

-.010
(-1.80)

.032
(2.87)

2.03

.624

.375

.077
(3.28)

-.023
(-2.98)

.006
(.530)

1.39

.527

.420

.046
(2.08)

-0.164
(-2.32)

.025
(2.14)

2.10

.644

.369

ENER

DUMC

.041
(1.85)

SE’102

oo

19

Equation (3) is also quite similar for both periods.

The growth rate in

ROW money is statistically insignificant whereas the growth rate for U.S.
money is highly significant and its coefficient is little changed in numerical
size from that estimated in equation (1).

Overall, the addition of ROW money

adds virtually nothing to the ability of this simplified version of the St.
Louis equation to explain U.S. inflation.
U.S. real economic activity and ROW money
As Hilton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz (1963), William Poole (1975), and
Leonall C. Anderson and Keith M. Carlson (1970) have shown, fluctuations in
real U.S. economic activity are linked to significant changes in U.S. Ml
growth from its recent trend.

More recently, Batten and Hafer (1982) have

argued that the same sort of relationship holds for Britain, West Germany, and
Italy.

Is it possible that deviations from trend in world money growth have

an even stronger link to the growth rate of real U.S. GNP?

And if we were to

put the U.S. monetary deviation variable and the ROW monetary deviation
variable into the same regression equation, would both prove to be
significant, and would the regression equation have significantly greater
explanatory power than the equation without the ROW money-growth variable?
McKinnonfs analysis

suggests positive answers to these questions.

To test this implication of his analysis, we ran the regressions shown in
Table 5.

Equations (1) and (2) show virtually no difference in their ability

to account for fluctuations in U.S. real GNP.

On the other hand, when the

variables MUS-dev and MROW-dev are both included in a regression equation
aimed at

explaining U.S. real output deviations, as in equation (3), the U.S.

monetary variable remains significant and with a much larger coefficient than
the ROW monetary variable; and, indeed, MROW-dev is not statistically
significant.




As with the earlier regressions seeking to explain U.S.

Table 5:

Equation

Money-growth deviations and U.S. real GNP:

Constant

MUS-dev

(i)

.012
(A.48)

.130
(2.19)

(2)

.012
(4.41)

(3)

.012
C4.35)

NOTE:

MW-dev

alternative specifications I/1970-II/1982

MROW-dev

.144
(2.11)
.124
(2.09)

.049
(1.06)

ENER

DW

Ri

SE*102

-.038
(-2.72)

1.97

.370

.985

-.032
(-2.13)

2.02

.365

.992

-.033
(-2 .20)

2.08

.389

.987

The dependent variable is the annualized percentage growth rate in U.S. real GNP, seasonally
adjusted. MUS-dev is the two quarter growth rate for Ml over the current and past quarter less the
12-quarter moving average of Ml; MW-dev is a similar variable for world money; MROW-dev is a similar
variable for Rest-of-World money; ENER is the average annual rate of change in the index of energy
prices divided by the GNP deflator over the current and previous five quarters.
(The variables DUMC
and DUMA, as defined in Table 3 above, were also included in the regressions, but their coefficients
were had very small t-values and are not reported.)




21

inflation, the inclusion of ROW money does not significantly improve the
explanatory power of the regression.
V.

Conclusion
McKinnon has advanced an imaginative interpretation of macroeconomic

events during the past decade of managed floating.

In a number of important

respects, however, his interpretation seems strikingly at odds with the
empirical evidence.

We conclude that a combination of sterilization

techniques and exchange-rate adjustments have provided central banks in the
leading industrial countries with far more independence from monetary
developments elsewhere than McKinnon’s analysis suggests.

Whether or not this

judgment is correct, money supply developments in other leading industrial
countries do not appear to have had a significant impact on U.S. inflation or
on fluctuations in U.S. output since the advent of managed floating.

Contrary

to McKinnon, the evidence does not suggest that the Federal Reserve should
alter its monetary stance in the light of monetary policies in the other
leading industrial countries.
Acceptance of this proposition does not mean that the U.S. monetary
authorities should ignore the behavior of the dollar in the exchange markets.
An exceptionally strong DM led the Bundesbank to permit faster German monetary
growth in 1978; for the same reasons, one can argue that an exceptionally strong
dollar should have persuaded the Federal Reserve to expand U.S. money by more
than it did during 1981-82.

But such a judgement— whether valid or not--does

not rest on the proposition that external money growth is an important
determinant of U.S. economic activity under managed floating.




22

Footnotes

Solnik (1982) has recently tested whether international interest-rate
spreads for the period 1971-1980 can be better explained by expected exchange
rate changes or by differences in domestic economic policies. He finds "much
more support for a domestic model of interest rate determination.11 "This
result," he notes, "could be explained by international market inefficiencies
but more probably [is explained] by the fact that exchange rate variations are
so unpredictable that their expectations play a little role in setting
differences between national interest rates."
2

For a confirming view citing a number of empirical studies, see
Wonnacott (1982, p. 3).
3
On this issue, see the comments by H. Lehment (1982) and K. Shigehara
(1982).
4
The mean annual coefficient of variation is 0.43 for the fixed rate
period and 0.48 for the floating rate period. This particular measure of
dispersion, however, seems irrelevant. As between any two countries,
adjustments in the exchange rate to maintain competitiveness, and in nominal
interest rates to maintain a real interest-rate differential, depend on the
absolute difference between their inflation rates and not on whether average
inflation in the two countries is high or low. The same consideration would
apply across 10 countries as well.
^Reserves, less gold, are in U.S. dollars, as taken from line ll.d in
the relevant country pages of International Financial Statistics. To the
extent that these countries held their official reserves in dollars, quarterly
changes in this variable are free from exchange-rate valuation effects. Such
quarterly changes will fail to correspond to official-intervention efforts,
however, insofar as they reflect (a) the issuance or retirement of non-dollar
denominated securities abroad by the United States; (b) the issuance or
retirement of foreign-currency denominated securities by foreign government
agencies, where the proceeds (or repayments) were not funnelled through the
foreign exchange market; (c) certain swap transactions between the U.S. and
other monetary authorities; (d) SDR allocations.
^Many studies have regressed changes in the central bank domestic
assets on changes in reserves in an attempt to estimate the "sterilization
coefficient." Such an approach ignores the fact that monetary authorities
outside the U.S. typically sterilize through direct controls and changes in
reserve requirements rather than through open market operations.
^These regressions* in Table 2 are of course subject to simultaneous
equations bias insofar as attempted changes in the domestic money supply
through domestic policy actions are offset by reserve flows (see, for example,
Laney and Willett (1982, pp. 143-46)). However, McKinnon explicitly argues
that a large share of money supply changes stem from exogenous changes in
reserves which are incompletely sterilized. If one accepts the exogeneity of
reserve flows, the estimates in Table 2 are not biased for this reason.




23

Selecting a particular year for weighting purposes imposes the danger
that an atypical pattern of exchange rates in that year might significantly
bias computations of the world money supply growth rate for other years. The
following computations indicate, however, that the choice of year does not
change the weights markedly:
Country

1970 weights

1976 weights

.517
.043
.104
.065
.099
.080
.049
.017
.014
.011

.440
.050
.143
.058
.114
.090
.048
.023
.017
.017

U.S.
Canada
Japan
U.K.
Germany
France
Italy
Netherlands
Belgium
Switzerland

1981 wei
.432
.040
.166
.075
.101
.085
.051
.020
.014
.014

An important preliminary question is whether there is any statistical
evidence of a "causal relationship" between U.S. money growth and ROW money
growth. To answer this question, we tested the joint time series properties
of these two variables using cross correlation functions and Box-Tiao
schematic representations. Neither variable appeared to cause the other in a
statistical sense. The Box-Tiao schematics for partial autocorrelation are
shown below:

Lag
MUS3
MR0W3

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

+ .......................................... - ..................
. +
...........................................................

^ I n particular, a study by Carlson (1980) for the period I/1970-IV-79,
which used distribution lags on U.S. money growth (Ml) and relative energy
prices, exhibits an R Z of .728, significant t-values for almost all the
explanatory variables, and a Durbin Watson statistic of 2.18.
(The sum of
Carlson's coefficients on money growth for the current and past 12
quarters— the elasticity of current inflation with respect to recent
cumulative money growth— totals 1.16 and has a t-value of 3.3.) A similar
study by Bordo and Choudhri (1982), explaining U.S. inflation from 1/1971IV/1980, uses a simple average of money growth rates for the previous 12
quarters in place of a distributed lag specification; it yields a money growth
elasticity of 1.55, an R of .71, and a DW statistic of 1.88.




24

REFERENCES

Anderson, Leonall C. and Keith M. Carlson , "A Monetarist Model for Economic
Stabilization, " Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, April 1970,
52, 7-25.
Batten, Dallas S. and R. W. Hafer, "Short-Run Money Growth Fluctuations and
Real Economic Activity: Some Implications for Monetary Targeting,"
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, Vol. 64, No, 5, May 1982,
15-20.
Bordo, Michael D. and Ehsan U. Choudhri, "The Link Between Money and Prices
in an Open Economy: The Canadian Evidence form 1971 to 1980," Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, August/September 1982, 64, 13-23.
Carlson, Keith M . , "The Lag from Money to Prices," Federal Reserve Bank of
St. Louis, Review, October 1980, 62, 3-10.
Deutsche Bundesbank, Annual Report, 1978.
Friedman, Milton and Anna J. Schwartz, "Money and Business Cycles, "
Review of Economics and Statistics, February 1963, 45, 32-78.
Harberger, Arnold C., "A Primer on Inflation," Journal of Money, Credit, and
Banking, November 1978, 10, 505-21.
Laney, Leroy 0. and Thomas D. Willett, "The International Explosion and World­
wide Inflation: The Evidence from Sterilization Coefficient Estimates,"
Journal of International Money and Finance, Dec. 1982, 1, 141-52.
Lehment, Harmen, "Economic Policy Response to the Oil Price Shocks of 1974 and
1979: The German Experience," European Economic Review, May/June 1982, 18
235-42.
McKinnon, Ronald I., "Currency Substitution and Instability in the World Dollar
Standard," American Economic Review, June 1982, 72, 320-33.
Poole, William, "The Relationship of Monetary Decelerations to Business Cycle
Peaks: Another Look at the Evidence," Journal of Finance, June 1975, 30,
697-712.
Shigehara, Kumihara, "Absorption of the two oil shocks: The French case,"
European Economic Review, May/June 1982, 18, 249-61.
Solnik, Breno, "An Empirical Investigation of the Determinants of National
Interest Rate Differences," Journal of International Money and Finance,
December 1982.
Wonnacott, Paul, U.S. Intervention in the Exchange Market for DM, 1977-80.
Princeton Studies in International Finance, No. 51, December 1982.