View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

M 0

^ 27

A Series of Occasional Papers in Draft Form Prepared by Members 15

A COMPARATIVE STUDY OF THE EFFECT OF LEVERAGE
ON RISK PREMIUMS FOR DEBT ISSUES
OF BANKS AND BANK HOLDING COMPANIES




Anne S. Weaver and Chayim Herzig-Marx




Research Paper No. 78-1

A COMPARATIVE STUDY OF THE EFFECT OF LEVERAGE
ON RISK PREMIUMS FOR DEBT ISSUES
OF BANKS AND BANK HOLDING COMPANIES

By

Anne S . Weaver
and
Chayim Herzig-Marx

Department of Research
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

The views expressed herein are solely those of the authors and
do not necessarily represent the views of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago or the Federal Reserve System. The material con­
tained is of a preliminary nature, is circulated to stimulate dis­
cussion, and is not to be quoted without permission of the authors.

I.

Introduction

Four recent articles have investigated the responsiveness of
capital markets to differences in leverage for banks and bank holding
companies issuing long-term debt.

Despite similar estimating equa­

tions and estimating techniques, the four studies arrived at different
conclusions.

Two studies found that increases in leverage had no

effect on risk premium, the capital market’s summary measure of expect­
ed risk, while the other two studies found that leverage is a statis­
tically significant determinant of risk premium.
The purpose of this paper is to examine the possibility that dif­
ferences in sample composition among the four risk premium studies might
account for the differences in results achieved.

Although the period

of observation, 1970 to 1975, is approximately the same for all four
studies, the types of firms included in the sample differ considerably.
In particular, the papers by Pettway [6], Martin [4], and Beighley [1]
use long-term debt issues that are the obligations either of banks or
of bank holding companies, while the Herzig-Marx paper [2] used bank
obligations only.
In the present paper, we gather a sample of issues that are
direct obligations of holding companies.

Using the estimating equation

in the Herzig-Marx paper, analysis of variance and covariance is applied
to determine whether or not the same econometric model fits bank holding
companies as well.

Specific interest centers on the leverage variable;

that is, do financial markets respond to increased leverage on the part
of banks but not on the part of bank holding companies?




2

In the second section of this paper, a brief review of the four
underlying studies will be presented, highlighting the estimating
equations and the samples used.

In the third section we will describe

the holding company observations added to the Herzig-Marx data set
and the statistical technique used to carry out the test.

The fourth

section presents results of the empirical analysis, and a concluding
section follows.

II.

Review of the Literature

Pettway’s sample consisted of 77 capital notes and debentures
issued between January 1, 1971 and December 31, 1974, 36 issues of
banks and 41 issues of bank holding companies.

All issues were public

placements of subordinated nonconvertible capital notes with fixed
maturity dates and had a stated yield to maturity.

Martin’s sample'*'

eliminated all issues under $4 million and included 84 issues, 65 issued
by holding companies and only 19 issued by banks.

All obligations were

offered publicly between January 1, 1971, and January 6 , 1975.
ranged from 3 to 27 years.

Maturities

Herzig-Marx’s sample included 59 capital

notes issued by 53 banks and offered between 1971 and 1975.

Of the 59

issues, 34 of the notes were issued by holding company affiliated
banks and 22 were placed privately.

Assets of issuing banks ranged

from $32 million to $25 billion, with seven banks under $100 million
in assets.

Mean size of the note issue was slightly under $20 million

with a range from $5 million to $150 million.

Beighley’s study used a

■^•Martin’s sample appears to be composed of seasoned debt issues,
prices being observed at a single point in time. The Pettway and HerzigMarx samples represent newly-issued securities whose prices are observed
as of the date of issuance.




3

sample

of 56 capital notes or straight debentures issued by either the

parent holding company or its lead bank between 1972 and 1974.

There were 35

obligations of parent firms and 21 obligations of lead banks.
Although Pettway and Martin came to similar conclusions, their basic
models were not derived from a specific theory of corporate finance.
Although they both tried to incorporate general principles of risk analysis,
their papers lack the rigorous theoretical basis provided by Merton’s
model in the Herzig-Marx study.

Beighley’s model investigated the same

types of problems, but within a different framework of hypotheses, as
will be seen later.

Nonetheless the models do have significant similarities

with the model used in this paper.
All four models use risk premium as the dependent variable.

This

is defined as the difference in yield of a debt issued by a bank and
that of a Treasury security issued at the same time and for the same maturity.
The Pettway model used two capital adequacy ratios as measures of leverage:
deposits and non-capital borrowed funds/total capital (DEPCAP) and total
equity capital/total assets, (EQCAP).

A third measure of default probability,

size of the issuing firm, was also used.

Other variables used were:

amount of the capital note (potential marketability— MKT); maturity of
the note (term structure— MAT); an intercept dummy variable denoting a
holding company versus bank distinction (DUM); and a variable indicating
the number of quarters elapsed between the Comptroller’s ruling that
capital notes could be considered as bank capital for lending and regula­
tory purposes and the date the capital note issue was sold (learning
curve— LCRV).

The regression equation was:

^Beighley's
though more




than

sample
one

also

point

of

appears

to b e

purely

observation was

cross-sectional,

used.

al­

4
(-)
(+)
(-)
(-)
(+)
PREMIUM - aQ + a^EPCAP + a2EQCAP + a3SIZE + a^MKT + a5MAT
(-)
(?)
+ agLCRV + a7DUM.•
Pettway found that the coefficients of the marketability of the
issue, the term to maturity, and the learning curve variable were
highly significant and had the expected signs.

The capitalization

variables were not found to be statistically significant in explaining
risk premium.
Martin incorporated different variables into his model.

Risk

premium was again the dependent variable, but different ratios were
used as a measure of risk.

They were:

earnings per share growth

from 1970-74 (EG); historical earnings before tax/interest on all
long-term debt (EC); remaining number of years to maturity at year
end 1974 (MAT); principal amount of the issue (MKT); parent's debt/equity
ratio as of year end 1974 when holding company issued (PLEV); the
total amount of assets of the issuing organization as of year end
1974 (SIZE); percentage of stockholders' equity/assets (CLEV); and
finally, a dummy variable denoting bank or holding company (HBK).
His equation was
(-)
(-)
(+)
(-)
(-)
(-)
PREMIUM = bQ + bjEG + b2EC + b^MAT + b^SIZE + b^MKT + bgPLEV
(-)
(-)
+ b7CLEV + bgHBK.
Martin found that maturity, marketability, earnings growth,
and earnings coverage were most important, while leverage was not
important and neither was the distinction between holding company
issue and bank issue.
Beighley's paper, although somewhat different from the other
three, tried to determine whether long-term creditors of bank holding
companies viewed firm size, financial structure, and loan losses as




5

measures of perceived risk and whether creditors preferred to lend to
the parent firm rather than to subsidiary firms.
hypothesized to be a function of:

Risk premium was

the dollar volume of assets of

consolidated BHC (SIZE); loan charge-offs net of recoveries over
total loans (LOSS); total debt to book value of common equity for
consolidated BHC (CLEV); total debt to book value of common equity
for the parent firm in the BHC (PLEV); total debt to book value of
common equity for bank of BHC (BLEV); total debt to book value of
common equity for the issuing firm (ILEV); long-term debt to book
value of common equity for consolidated BHC (CLTD); long-term debt to
book value of common equity for parent (PLTD); long-term debt to book
value of common equity for lead bank (BLTD); long-term debt to book
value of common equity of issuing firm (ILTD); and a dummy variable
equaling 1 if issue is obligation of parent, 0 if otherwise (ISS).
(-)
(+)
PREMIUM = cQ + c-^SIZE + c2LOSS
(+)

(+)

(+>
(+>
(+>
+ c3CLEV + c^PLEV +
(+ )

(+)

(+>
c^BLEV +

(? )

+ c y CLTD + cgPLTD + cgBLTD + c10ILTD + c u I S S .

Beighley concluded that firm size, realized loan losses, and
financial structure are important and that stockholders seem more
concerned about the total leverage structure of the consolidated
holding company.

He also inferred that debt holders were concerned

with long-term debt of the holding company and somewhat concerned
about the financial structure of the lead bank.

Debt holders were

also found to be indifferent to whether the debt was located in the
parent or the lead bank.
The Herzig-Marx model tries to give empirical treatment to Merton’s
work[5] on the valuation of risky corporate securities.

The basic

theory is that at a given point in time, for securities of a given
maturity, risk premium is a function of only two variables:




debt to

c&ILEV

6

firm value ratio and the volatility of the firm's operations.

The

dependent variable, risk premium, is a function of the following
independent variables in the Herzig-Marx model:

term to maturity

(TERM); riskless rate of return (MKT RATE), defined as the yield to
maturity of a Treasury security maturing at the same time as the risky
security; investor confidence, defined as the difference between yield
of a portfolio of medium grade bonds and the yield of a portfolio of
highgrade bonds as found in Barron's (SPREAD).

To substitute for the

present value of Merton's debt to firm value ratio the model used the
ratio of book value of interest bearing liabilities to book value of
assets (BORROW).

A regression of the capital asset pricing model

using annual returns to each bank on annual returns to the market
portfolio was the approximation of the systematic component of the
variance of a bank return used to proxy volatility in the Merton model
(EARNVAR).

Gross rate of return on income-earning assets (EARNG) was

used to categorize risk class of the firm.

The size of the debt issue

(ISSUE) was also included as a measure of marketability.

The regression

equation was
(+)

(+)

(+)

(-)

(?)

PREMIUM = dQ + d^BORROW + d2EARNVAR + d3TERM + d^MKT RATE + d5SPREAD
(+)
(-)
+ dgEARNG + d?ISSUE.
Herzig-Marx concluded, in agreement with Beighley but contrary to
Pettway and Martin, that financial markets do demand a higher risk
premium for banks that are more highly leveraged.

All signs except

for EARNVAR were predicted correctly and longer terms to maturity were
found to elicit a higher risk premium.

Also found highly significant

was EARNG, indicating that debt issued by firms in higher risk classes
requires higher premiums.




7

III.

Details of Present Study

Sample
In this study we expand the sample used by Herzig-Marx to include
78 newly issued capital notes offered by holding companies from January
1972 to December 1975.

The primary source of information was a list

published by Irving Trust Company [3].
placed privately.

Of the 78 issues, only 15 were

There were thirty-two issuances in 1972, sixteen

in 1973, thirteen in 1974, and seventeen in 1975.

The size of the

issue varies from $1.5 million to $150 million, terms to maturity from
1.5 years to 30 years, and asset size of the issuing company from
less than $1 billion to well over $100 billion.

Data
Balance sheet and income data are taken from Moody’s Bank and Finance
Manual for December 31 of the year prior to the year of issue.
two possible sources of error.

There are

Since only 15 of the 78 notes were issued

privately the probability of error due to frequent non-disclosure of final
selling price is slight; however, it could entail some measurement error.
For publicly placed issues the price reported was usually the price of
the original offer to the public regardless whether the whole issue was
sold at that price.

This also could be a source of error due to sampling

technique.
When only the month, but not the exact day of issue is known it
is assumed that the issue was placed on the 15th day, or the closest
business day to the 15th should the 15th be a weekend day.




BORROW, the leverage variable, is measured on a consolidated basis.

8

IV.

Results

The equation estimated is the same as that used in the Herzig-Marx
study with the exception of EARNVAR.
related grounds:

This variable was deleted on three

its sign was counter to expectation; it was not statis­

tically significant; and since it was insignificant and of the wrong sign,
the enormous time and effort required to calculate this variable was deemed
unjustified.
Referring to Table 1 we see that when the basic regression model
is run (Total Sample) all variables are significant except for BORROW, and
all signs are predicted correctly.

By dividing the sample into two

groups, one consisting only of banks (1-59), and the other only of holding
companies (60-137), we find a few changes in the significant variables.
The bank only subsample is identical to the Herzig-Marx sample.

In the

holding company subsample, we find SPREAD is marginally significant,
with ISSUE and PRIVATE becoming highly significant. All signs are as expected.
As suspected the leverage variable (BORROW) is not significant in the holding
company subsample while it is significant in the bank only sample.

Since

Pettway's and Martin's samples, which are dominated by bank holding com­
panies, find leverage to be insignificant, it is reasonable to conclude that
differences in sample construction produced divergent results.
Using the two subsamples described above we conducted an analysis of
variance for differential intercepts.

We find no significant difference of

intercepts in the two subsamples (F = 1.51).

Since this procedure is equiva­

lent to incorporating an intercept dummy variable into the regression
equation, it confirms the same finding by Pettway, Martin, and Beighley, all
of whom used intercept dummies.
Continuing our analysis of covariance, we add an intercept dummy
variable (HC) denoting holding company versus non-holding company affiliation




9

and rerun the entire sample.

By netting out the effect of differential

intercepts, we test for differential slope coefficients between the two
subsamples.

An F-test again failed to reveal any significant differences

(F = 1.49).
Next, a test is performed to see if the localized effect of the
HC variable might not have been picked up in the analysis of covariance
(see Table 3, which reports only variables involving HC).

This is done

by entering slope dummies into the regression equation yielding the
following equation:
(+)

(+)

(-)

(?)

(+)

PREMIUM = eQ + ejBORROW + e2TERM + e3MKT RATE + e4SPREAD + e5EARNG

(-)

(?)

(?)

(?)

(?)

+ eglSSUE + eyPRIVATE + egHC*BORROW + egHC*TERM + e10HC*MKTRATE
(?)

(?)

(?)

(?)

(?)

+ e11HC*SPREAD + e12HC*EARNG + e13HC*ISSUE + e14HC*PRIVATE + e-^HC
Since terms that are not interactive with HC denote bank issues, these
coefficients will again be identical to the Herzig-Marx results.

Testing

for significance of individual variables, we began removing the most
insignificant holding company variables.

When HC*TERM, HC*SPREAD, HC*ISSUE,

and HC*PRIVATE are removed all banking variables become significant, and
HC*MKT RATE becomes significant.

3

When HC*TERM is returned to the regression

HC*EARNG is added to the significant variables.

When only HC*ISSUE and

HC*PRIVATE are deleted from the equation all bank variables remain significant
except SPREAD, and the only significant holding company variable is HC*EARNG.
At no time does R^ go above .38, but the F test goes from 8.17 when all
four insignificant variables are removed, to 6.62 when only the latter
two are omitted.

This score is equal to the F test when all 16 variables

are included in the equation.

% o t e that TERM, SPREAD, ISSUE, and PRIVATE reflect indenture provisions,
investor confidence, and the possibility of private or public placement,
which are features common to nearly every long-term borrower in the market.
We would thus be extremely surprised if these variables affected risk pre­
mium differently for banks and bank holding companies.




10

The most interesting finding from this analysis of the interactive
terms is that the coefficient of HC*B0RR0W is never statistically signif­
icantly different from zero.

Thus, although the difference between the

two original subsamples is not statistically significant, it is nonetheless
different enough to derive conflicting results on the key issue of leverage.
We further examine the sample by reorganizing the groups.

Running the re­

gression equation for a group consisting both of banks affiliated with hold­
ing companies and of holding companies themselves (26-137), we find that
all variables except BORROW are significant.

Looking only at independent,

non-affiliated banks (1-25) we find that MKT RATE, EARNG, and PRIVATE are
significant.

Lastly, TERM becomes the only significant variable in the

regression model when observing only banks with holding company affiliation
(26-59)-

At this point PRIVATE changes its sign invalidating our prediction.

Using this information we perform another analysis of covariance using
two groups— those banks with holding company affiliation (26-59) and the other
group of holding companies themselves (60-137).

Comparing the residuals, we

again find no significant difference between the subsamples.




11

V.

Conclusion

Four recent articles have examined the relationship between bank
leverage and the market-determined risk premium on long-term bank debt.
Despite using similar methodologies, the studies came to radically diver­
gent conclusions, two finding leverage to be significant and two finding
leverage to be insignificant in determining risk premium.

The present paper

originates from this divergence and seeks to account for the differences
in results among the studies.
Because methodology and period of observation were substantially the
same for all four papers, differences in results could only have arisen
from differences in sample construction or estimating equations.

A detail­

ed, variable by variable comparison of regression equations was not under­
taken in the present study since the equations estimated were overall quite
similar.

The most prominent difference among the four studies was the type

of issuing firms included in the sample.

Both studies finding leverage to

be insignificant in explaining risk premium allowed both banks and bank
holding companies into the sample, while one of the studies finding leverage
to be important used only banks.

The other study finding leverage to be

important allowed both banks and bank holding companies to enter the re­
gression model.

The basis of the present paper is an attempt to discern

whether differences in sample construction could have produced such divergent
results on the important question of the effect of leverage on market valua­
tions of securities.
On purely statistical grounds, the answer would seem to be "No."

No

significant difference, in a statistical sense, emerges from the analyses
of variance and covariance for subsamples of banks and bank holding companies.
On the other hand, since leverage is statistically significant in explaining




12

risk premium when only bank issues are examined, but is statistically in­
significant when holding companies alone are analyzed and when holding com­
pany issues are added to the bank issues, it is clear that markets evaluate
holding companies and banks somewhat differently.

Further attempts to infer

what variables of the valuation model display significantly different
coefficients for the two subsamples (banks and bank holding companies) meet
with moderate success, but no difference is found for leverage.
The sample used in this paper, 59 bank issues and 78 holding company
issues, is larger than the sample used for any of the four previous studies
and probably includes most of the other studies1 observations.

Although

statistical tests fail to indicate that the regression model fits the two
subsamples differently, a more detailed examination of the underlying data
is enlightening .

Figure 1 is a plot of leverage (BORROW) against risk pre­

mium for the sample employed in this study.

The letter "A" denotes an ob­

servation on a bank issue, while the letter "B" denotes a holding company
issue.

Ellipses have been drawn over the scatters of points for the sub­

samples .
The ellipses depict clearly why we obtained our results on leverage
and risk premium.

The partial relationship between leverage and risk premium

for banks is evident, while this relationship for holding companies has no
slope.

The fact that holding company observations are concentrated in a

horizontal band is sufficient to randomize the leverage-risk premium relation­
ship when the two subsamples are lumped together.

Finally, the extensive

overlap between the two scatters of points shows why the coefficient of
HC*BORROW is not significantly different from zero.
Figure 1 indicates that the distribution of risk premium is approximately
the same for bank and bank holding company issues.




Means and standard

13

deviations calculated for the subsamples confirm this.

Noteworthy is

the fact that mean values of leverage are significantly different (see
Table 4), and that, in addition,*holding company issues display much

Table 4
Mean and Standard Deviation
for Leverage and Risk Premium

Leverage
HCs
Banks
mean
st. dev.
no. obs.

43.40
11.13
59

55.43
7.99
78

smaller variance of leverage.

Risk Premium
HCs
Banks
1.33
0.48
59

1.35
0.64
78

This feature is especially interesting in

view of the often-heard contention that bank risk premiums should not be
expected to respond to differences in leverage since there is so little
variation across banks.

It turns out, by comparison, that banks display

much wider variations in leverage than do holding companies (consolidated
basis).
In sum, a review of the results of available literature indicates
that banks and holding companies are thought to be evaluated similarly
by financial markets, but previous studies encompassing both types of
firms within the same sample have used only simple intercept dummy vari­
ables to test this difference.

Analysis of covariance also fails to turn

up significant subsample differences; but when the slope dummy variable
technique is used, significant differences are found (by deleting certain
slope dummies whose coefficients can be expected to be insignificant). Thus,
the slope dummy analysis suggests that financial markets do evaluate hold­
ing companies differently from banks.




14

On the key issue of leverage, however, no significant difference emerges
Our examination of the underlying data, using a sample more extensive than
any of the four previous studies, reveals that the distribution of the
leverage variable probably accounts for the results obtained by previous
researchers.

Whether this finding, too, is a quirk of our sample, and would

not be sustained by the underlying population, is a question we cannot answer
Given the evident importance of the relationship between leverage and market
valuation, both for regulators and for students of financial markets, con­
tinued research comparing banks and bank holding companies is worthwhile.







References

H. Prescott Beighley, "The Risk Perceptions of Bank Holding Company
Debtholders," Journal of Bank Research, Summer 1977.
Chayim Herzig-Marx, "Bank Soundness and Risk Premiums on Bank Debt,"
Unpublished paper, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 1977.
Irving Trust Company, Report of Debt Securities Issued by Commercial
Banks and Bank Holding Companies, Corporate Financial Counseling
Department, yearly.
Michael J. Martin, "Risk Premiums and Bank Bond Investors," Atlantic
Economic Journal, July 1977.
Robert C. Merton, "Op the Pricing of Corporate Debt: The Risk Structure
of Interest Rates," Journal of Finance, May 1974.
Richard H. Pettway, "Market Tests of Capital Adequacy of Large Commercial
Banks," The Journal of Finance, June 1976.

Table 1

BORROW
1-137
TOTAL

SAMPLE

1-59
ALL BANKS
60-137
HOLDING COMPANIES

(+)

TERM

(+)

MKT RATE

(-)

SPREAD

(?)

EARNG

(+)

.0828694

.604535
(1.57078)

.0183550
(3.62290)*

-.290117
(-3.82072)*

.017 6 3 9 6
(3.18606)*

.0234259
(3.40858)*

(-4.13510)*

(1.19015)

. 2 07605
(2.95915)*

.0103232
(1.22857)

-.119070
(-.880216)

.954483
(1.99276)

.0468640
(1.06 8 0 1 )

.00846078
(1.03125)

-.380378

.84749
(3.57490)*
.399448

(3.59927)*

ISSUE

(-)

-.00575867
(-4.61815)*
-.00439282

PRIVATE

(+)

.367048

R

2 ,
/d.f.

. 3 6 3/129

F test/
variance
of the
regression

12.07/.2123

(3.58191)*
. 2 9 0361
(2.15006)*

.403/51

6.59/.1376

(-2.08087)*
-.0065519
(-3.6445)*

.432284
(2.64200)*

.38 5 / 7 0

7.87/.2554

.605087
(2.65677)*

.471/17

4.05/.1520

.329/26

3.32/.1269

. 3 5 9/104

7.104/.2212

Table 2
1-25
INDEPENDENT

BANKS

26-59
BANKS AFFILIATED
WITH HOLDING

.014052

.0198618

(1.33166)

(1.55623)

.00968451
(1.17639)

.0299974
(3.57227)*

-.608346
(-4.10884)*

.700930
(1.12890)

.41 9 0 7 8
(3.06872)*

-.00400667
(.477537)

-.180246
(-1.44144)

.329513
(.788298)

.0896126
( . 827285)

-.00295829
(-1.30240)

-.230759
(-2.62928)*

.102598
(3.30706)*

. 0 6 94337
(2.57806)*

-.00555701
(-4.19226)*

-.00498334
(-.0260762)

COMPANIES
26-137
ALL ORGANIZATIONS
AFFILIATED WITH
HOLDING COMPANIES

.00464886
(1.10575)

^ S i g n i f i c a n t at the .975 level,
t - r a t i o s s h o w n in p a r e n t h e s e s .




.0174638
(3.10083)*

.347583
(2.80139)*

TABLE 3

HC

HC*BORROW

HC*TERM

HC*MKT RATE

HC*SPREAD

HC*EARNG

-.626449
(-.611239)

-.0091788
(-.917620)

-.0131027
(-1.16038)

.261308
(1.57880)

.555035
(.933858)

-.160741
(-1.70285)

-1.15906
(-1.19526)

-.00808499
(-.828311)

*Significant at the .975 level,
t-ratios shown in parentheses.




.344430
(2.46536)*

-.161616
(-1.85802)

HC*ISSUE

HC*PRIVATE

-.0021590
(-.709255)

.141924
(.642218)




RISKPREM