View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Working Paper 95 18

UNDERSTANDING THE POSTWAR DECLINE
IN UNITED STATES SAVING: A COHORT ANALYSIS
by Jagadeesh Gokhale, Laurence J. Kotlikoff, and John Sabelhaus

Jagadeesh Gokhale is an economic advisor at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Laurence J. Kotlikoff is a
professor of economics at Boston University and a research
associate at the National Bureau of Economic Research,
and John Sabelhaus is an economist at the Congressional
Budget Office. The authors thank the Office of
Management and Budget for providing critical data on
long-range budget projections, and the Social Security
Administration for furnishing U.S. population projections.
Working papers of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion
and critical comment. The views stated herein are those of
the authors and are not necessarily those of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland, the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, or the Congressional Budget
Office.

December 1995

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Abstract

The rate of saving in the ,United States has declined dramatically in recent
decades. Since 1980, the U.S. net national saving rate has averaged just 4
percent. Since 1990, it has averaged just 2.4 percent-one-quarter
the mean
rate observed in the 1950s and 60s. This paper develops a unique cohort data
set to study the decline in U.S. national saving. It decomposes postwar
changes in U.S. saving into those due to changes in cohort-specific consumption propensities, those due to changes in the intergenerational distribution
of resources, those due to changes in the rate of government consumption, and
those due to demographic changes.
Our findings are striking. The decline in U.S. saving can be traced to one
major factor: The redistribution of resources from young and unborn generations with low or zero consumption propensities toward older generations with
high consumption propensities. Most of the redistribution to the elderly
reflects the growth in Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid benefits.
Although older generations' propensities to consume have increased
significantly, those of younger generations have declined or remained constant
over the last three decades. The increase in older Americans' consumption
propensities may also reflect government policy, namely, the fact that Social
Security benefits come in the form of annuities and that Medicare and Medicaid
benefits are provided to the elderly directly in the form of consumption of
medical goods and services.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

I. Introduction
In 1950, the U.S. rate of net national saving was 12.3 percent.

In 1993,

it was only 2.7 percent.1 The difference in these saving rates illustrates a
dramatic long-term decline in U.S. saving. The national saving rate averaged
9.1 percent per year in the 1950s and 1960s, 8.5 percent in the 1970s, 4.7
percent in the 80s, and just 2.4 percent in the first four years of the 1990s.
The decline in U.S. saving has been associated with an equally dramatic
decline in U.S. domestic investment. Since 1990, net domestic investment has
averaged 3.1 percent per year, compared with 8.2 percent in the 1950s,
7.9 percent in the 1960s and 1970s, and 6.1 percent in the 1980s. The low
rate of domestic investment has limited growth in labor productivity and,
consequently, growth in real wages.

Since 1980, labor productivity has grown

at less than half the rate observed between 1950 and 1979, and total real
compensation (wages plus fringe benefits) per hour has grown at only oneeighth its previously observed rate.
This paper develops a unique cohort data base to study the decline in
U.S. saving. A key feature of these data is that they are bench-marked
against national income accounts and other economic aggregates. Consequently,
they relate directly to the change in net national saving measured by national
income accounts. We use these cohort data within a simple life-cycle framework to decompose postwar changes in U.S. saving into those due to changes in
the intergenerational distribution of resources, cohort-specific consumption
propensities, the rate of government spending, and demographics.
Our findings are striking. Most of the decline in U.S. saving can be
traced to one major factor: a redistribution of resources toward older general

The net national saving rate is defined as net national product less
national consumption (household consumption plus government purchases),
divided by net national product.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

tions, with high propensities to consume, from younger ones (including those
not yet born), with low or zero propensities to consume. Much of the
redistribution to the elderly appears to reflect the growth in government
transfer payments. Older Americans' propensities to consume privately
purchased as well as government-provided goods and services have increased
tremendously.

However, those of younger generations have exhibited an

offsetting decline. As a result, despite the dramatic increase in the elderly
cohorts' consumption propensities, the shift in cohort consumption
propensities alone may not have led to the decline in saving witnessed over
the last three decades.
This paper continues in Section I1 with a brief discussion of related
research.

Section I11 presents some stylized facts about recent trends in

U.S. saving and consumption. Section IV describes our method for decomposing
changes in national saving.. Section V discusses data construction and data
sources in general terms, relegating details to the Appendix.

Section VI

presents our findings, and Section VII draws conclusions.

11. Related Studies
Several recent studies of U.S. saving focus on Americans' personal
saving, defined as saving out of disposable income. Summers and Carroll
(1987) suggest that younger cohorts may be hoping to rely on Social Security
benefits in their retirement and are consequently saving too little on their

own. In contrast, Bosworth, Burtless, and Sabelhaus (1991) compare personal
saving rates in the 1960s, 1970s, and 1980s and conclude that all age groups
The form taken by government transfers--the fact that they are
annuitized and, in the case of health care, are in kind-may help explain the
dramatic rise in elderly Americans' consumption propensities.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

are now saving at lower rates than before. Attanasio (1993) reaches a third
conclusion. He places the blame for current low levels of personal saving on
the failure of a particular subset of cohorts--those born between 1925 and
1939-to

save.

The studies by Bosworth et al. and Attanasio use consumer expenditure
data which directly cover only 80 percent of aggregate consumption. Although
Bosworth et al. impute some missing consumption components, they ignore health
care, as does Attanasio.

This is a significant omission. Health care is a

large and growing component of national consumption. Moreover, as medical
consumption has grown as a share of output, so too has overall consumption.
This suggests that medical consumption, or at least its method of finance, may
play a key role in the decline in the U.S. rate of saving.
Even were all studies of personal saving in agreement, it would be hard
to assess their implications for national saving. From a theoretical perspective, personal saving bears no necessary relationship to national saving.
This point can be understood by considering the standard life-cycle model
under certainty. According to this model, the appropriate measure of
household saving is the propensity of households to consume out of the present
value of their remaining lifetime resources. This propensity will be
invariant to present-value neutral changes in the timing of after-tax income
flows, each of which will produce a different value of personal saving.
For example, an increase in households' current Social Security taxes
that is offset, in present value, by higher projected Social Security benefits
will leave their consumption and, thus, national saving unchanged, but lower
their personal saving. The postwar period has witnessed enormous growth in
Social Security and other government transfer programs. Hence, changes over
time in U.S. personal saving rates could simply reflect the life-cycle pattern

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

of these tax/transfer programs, rather than some underlying change in
household consumption and saving behavior.
The problem with studying national saving via personal saving is actually
deeper than this discussion suggests. The reason is that the tax and transfer
labels of government receipts and expenditure programs are not unique (see,
for example, Kotlikoff [1993]).

Assuming agents are rational, the same fiscal

policy can be relabeled in countless ways with no impact on economic outcomes,
including national saving. But each relabeling will result in a different
measure of personal saving. For example, suppose the U.S. government had
historically labeled Social Security contributions as "loans" to the government rather than as "taxes" and current and past Social Security benefit
payments as "repayment of past loans, plus an old-age tax" rather than as
"transfer payments.~~Doing so would have produced an entirely different
postwar reported path of personal saving, but it would not have altered
national saving, assuming rational consumption and saving behavior.

In 1993,

for example, the measured personal saving rate would have been almost three
times larger than the rate the government actually reported!
Studies that focus directly on household consumption and, by implication, national saving are few and far between.

Cutler et al. (1990) is one

example. This study employs an infinite-horizon model to study the response
of household consumption to demographic change. Its findings suggest that
high rates of household consumption and low rates of national saving may
Such relabeling is not simply a hypothetical possibility. The socalled "privatization" of the Chilean social security system amounts, in large
part, simply to relabeling workers' social security contributions as loans
rather than as taxes. Under the Chilean "reform," workers contribute to
pension funds. But the pension funds turn around and lend most of these
contributions to the government, which uses them to make benefit payments to
current Social Security recipients.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

reflect households' projections of higher future per capita income levels
arising from the aging of the U.S. population. However, there are two
critical difficulties with this analysis. First, the assumed intergenerational altruism underlying the infinite-horizon model is strongly rejected by
household and cohort panel data (see Altonji, Hayashi, and Kotlikoff [1992];
Abel and Kotlikoff [1994]; and Hayashi, Altonji, and Kotlikoff [1994]).
Second, the study's results are highly sensitive to the assumption about the
economy's initial position (that is, whether it is initially in a steady
state.)
Boskin and Lau (1988a and 1988b) estimate an aggregate consumption
function taking into account aggregation over different cohorts. Their
results suggest that a decline in saving by generations born after the Great
Depression is largely responsible for the postwar decline in U.S. saving--a
finding at odds with those reported here.

Boskin and Lau's methodology

differs significantly from our approach, so it is hard to say precisely why
the two studies reach such different conclusions.

111. The Postwar Decline in U.S. Saving--Some Stylized Facts

Table 1 reports average values of the net national saving rate for the
1950s, 1960s, 1970s, and 1980s, as well as the first four years of the 1990s.
The net national saving rate is defined as (Y-C-G)/Y, where Y refers to net
national product, C to household consumption, and G to government spending
(purchases of goods and services).

The table also reports rates of government

and household consumption out of output, G/Y and C/Y.

In addition, it reports

our preferred measure of private-sector saving, which we call the household
saving r a t e .

It's defined as (Y-G-C)/(Y-G)--the

share saved of the output

left over to the household sector after the government has consumed (that is,

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

the share of Y-G that is not consumed by the public).

Unlike the personal

saving rate, the household saving rate isn't affected by present-value neutral
changes in the timing of income flows. Nor is it altered by pure changes in
the labeling of government receipts and expenditures, assuming agents are
rational and aren't deceived by the government's choice of words.
As Table 1 indicates, government spending is not responsible for reducing
the rate of national saving. Indeed, the rate of government spending, G/Y,
has declined since the 1970s. Furthermore, government spending in the 1990s
has averaged just 21 percent of output-as

low a rate as any observed in the

five periods. The rate of household consumption spending, on the other hand,
rose from 69.9 percent of output in the 1950s to 76.5 percent in the early
1990s. This increased rate of household consumption was associated with a
decline in the household saving rate from 11.5 percent in the 1950s to
3.1 percent in the 1990s.
Table 2 considers the role of health-care spending in the growth of
household spending. It shows that medical expenditures have increased from
3.9 percent of NNP in the 1950s to 12.8 percent in the 1990s. In the 1950s
health-care spending represented less than 6 percent of household consumption.
So far, in the 1990s, it has represented almost 17 percent.

The increase in

the rate of medical spending was associated with only a modest reduction in
the rate of nonmedical spending. In the 1950s, nonmedical consumption
averaged 66 percent of NNP.

In the 1990s, it averaged 63.7 percent.

Thus,

although the rate of medical consumption rose by 8.9 percentage points between
the 1950s and 1990s, the rate of nonmedical consumption fell by only 2.3
percentage points.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

IV. Decomposing Changes in National Saving
We adopt the life-cycle model under certainty as our framework for
decomposing postwar changes in national saving. In so doing, we don't mean to
belittle other determinants of saving, such as uncertainty and the desire to
bequeath.

Rather, we believe that this model is a useful place to begin

investigating the decline in U.S. saving. We also suspect that the findings
reported here will carry over to more realistic models of saving.
Our interest is in the net national saving rate, which, at time t, is
given by

where St stands for net national saving.
In the standard life-cycle model with certainty and homothetic preferences, each cohort's consumption is proportional to the present value of its
remaining lifetime resources (resources for short).

We denote the per capita

resources of cohort age i at time t as rit. This is the sum of the cohort's
per capita net wealth, nwit, its per capita present value of future labor
earnings (human wealth), hwit, its per capital present value of private and
government employee pension benefits (their pension wealth), pwit, less its
per capita present value of future tax payments net of the per capita present
value of future transfer payments received (their generational accounts),
gait.
Since our empirical analysis attributes all consumption to adult cohorts
age 18 through 100, we write aggregate consumption at time t as the sum of
consumption of individual cohorts4 age 18 through 100, that is, as
Cohorts older than 100 years are grouped together with those age 100.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

(2)

Ct =

100
C aitritPit'
i=18

where i indexes age, ait stands for the average propensity to consume of i
year olds at time t, and Pi,t represents the number of persons who are i years
old at time t. We note for future reference that ait = cit/rit, where cit is
the average level of consumption of those age i at time t.
Our goal is to decompose changes over time in the net national saving
rate into changes in the rate of government spending, Gt/Yt, and changes in
determinants of the rate of household spending, Ct/Yt.

These determinants are

clarified by expressing the rate of household spending as

where Rt stands for the time-t total value of resources of living generations
(that is, Rt=Ciritpit), Pt stands for the total population at time t, and rt
stands for the time-t resources per capita of living generations.
According to (3), changes over time in the rate of household consumption
can be traced to changes over time in four factors: cohort-specific
propensities to consume (the

sits),

the shape of the age-resource profile (the

rit/rts), the age composition of the population (the Pit/Pts), and the
resource-output ratio-the

ratio of total resources of current generations to

current output (Rt/Yt).
In our empirical analysis we compute the values of five factors-the
above four plus government spending--for each of four time periods: 1960-61,
1972-73, 1984-86, and 1987-90.

We then consider how the national saving rate

in each of these periods would have differed had one of the five factors not

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

taken its actual value, but had, instead, taken values observed in other
periods.
This decomposition of changes in life-cycle saving into those due to
changes in demographics, saving behavior, and age-resource profiles has a long
tradition dating to Ando and Modigliani (1963).

Their lessons bear repeating.

First, increases in any cohort's propensity to consume will, all else being
equal, raise the rate of aggregate household spending and lower national
saving.

Second, higher rates of population or real wage growth mean higher

rates of national saving for the following simple reason: In the life-cycle
model, the propensity to consume is predicted to rise with age.

Since popula-

tion and real wage growth raise the respective values of the Pit/Pt and rit/rt
ratios for younger cohorts and lower them for older cohorts, such growth
produces a reweighting of sits, which reduces the rate of household spending
and raises the rate of national saving.
The final lesson is that redistribution across generations can alter
national saving by altering the age-resource profile, the resource-output
ratio, or both.

Government tax/transfer policy can, of course, produce such

redistribution. Consider government redistribution among living generationsspecifically, from the young to the old at time t--that leaves the resourceoutput ratio unchanged.

Such redistribution is accomplished by raising the

present value of taxes net of transfers of young generations (their generational accounts) and reducing the present value of taxes net of transfers of
older generations while leaving unchanged the net tax burden facing current
generations collectively. This policy lowers the values of the rit/rts of the
young and raises them for the old. This raises the weights applied to relatively high values of ait and reduces those applied to relatively low values,
producing a higher rate of aggregate household spending.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Next, consider redistribution from future to current generations that
raises the resource-output ratio but leaves the age-resource profile
unchanged.

This can be accomplished by reducing the generational accounts of

each current generation by just the amount needed to produce the same
percentage increase in its remaining lifetime resources. This policy raises
the rate of household spending by an amount that depends on the resource- and
population-weighted economy-wide propensity to consume (the bracketed term in
equation [ 3 ] ) .

V. Data Construction and Sources
To decompose changes across our four periods in national saving, we need
the value for each period of the five factors mentioned earlier. T w o of these
factors-the

rate of government spending and the age composition of the

population--are readily available. This is not the case for the value of the

tits

or the r i p , both of which are needed to form the

sits.

The rits are

also needed to form the age-resource profile and the resource-output ratio.
Our procedures for calculating the cits and rits are described in detail
in the Appendix. Briefly, we form these variables or their constituent
components by using cross-section profiles and population data to distribute
aggregate variables by age and sex. Our general method of distributing an
aggregate variable in time t, say Zt, can be understood by considering the
following equation:

In equation (4), zm40t stands for the average value of Z of 40-year-old males
at time t, vmit and vfit stand, respectively, for the ratios of average values

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

of Z of males and females age i at time t to z40mt, and Pmit and Pfit stand,
respectively, for the populations of males and females age i in year t.

Given

the value of Zt from the National Income and Product Accounts (NIPA) or other
sources, the relative age-sex profile of Z (the vmits and vfits) calculated
from a cross-section survey, and the Pmits and Pfits calculated from population data, we can use equation (5) to solve for zm40t. We can then multiply
this value by vmit (vfit) to determine zmit (zfit)-the
males (females) age i in year t.

average value of Z for

Finally, we can form a population-weighted

average of zmit and zfit to produce an average value of Z for age group i at
time t.
In the case of the tits, we use the 1961-62, 1972-73, 1984-86, and 19871990 Consumer Expenditure Surveys and the 1977 and 1987 National Medical
Expenditure Surveys to form relative profiles of total consumption by age and
sex. By total consumption, we mean all components of household consumption
that are included in the NIPA aggregate, including medical care and imputed
rent on owner-occupied housing.

In the process of forming these profiles, we

had to allocate CEX household expenditures to individual adult members in the
household.

In so doing, we first allocated expenditures to all members of the

household, including children, and then allocated children's expenditures to
parents residing with them. Certain allocations were quite obvious, such as
children's clothing. In other cases, we adopted what we believe to be
reasonable rules, which are described in the Appendix. The age-sex relative
consumption profiles for the four periods derived in these calculations are
used, together with period-specific Social Security counts of population by
age and sex, to distribute NIPA values of aggregate household consumption in
each of the four periods.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Turning to the rits, recall that these variables are the sums of
annuitized and nonannuitized resources. We form each of the components of the
rits separately and then add them. By annuitized resources we mean the
present values of future labor earnings (human wealth), Social Security
benefits, private and government employee pension benefits, government healthcare benefits, welfare benefits and other government transfers, and, entering
as negative annuities, the present values of future taxes. Taxes include
labor and capital income taxes, indirect taxes, payroll taxes, and property
and other taxes. Nonannuitized resources refers simply to holdings of net
wealth.
The computation of cohorts' nonannuitized resources for the four periods
involves distributing by age and sex each year's aggregate value of household
net wealth and then averaging over the years defining the four periods. The
computation of each annuitized resource component is more involved. First,
for each year between 1960 and 1993, the national aggregate for a particular
type of payment (or receipt) is distributed by age and sex according to the
cross-section, age-sex relative profile that is applicable to that payment (or
receipt).

For example, aggregate 1965 Social Security benefits are distrib-

uted according to the age-sex relative profile for these benefits in 1965.
This yields estimates of the per capita amounts of the payment (or receipt) by
age and sex for that year. The per capita annuity values for years after 1993
are estimated by either 1) distributing projected aggregate payments or
receipts according to the latest available cross-section relative profile or

2) assuming that age- and sex-specific per capita values equal their respective values in 1993 or some later year, except for an adjustment for productivity growth.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Second, for each generation in a given year t, the present value of all
future per capita payments of a particular type (say, indirect tax payments)
is computed by multiplying these future per capita payments by the generation's projected population in those years, discounting these values back to
year t, and dividing the sum of the discounted values by the number of members
of the generation alive in the base year. This method produces actuarially
discounted present values of the particular receipt or payment for each generation alive in period t. We consider three pretax real discount rates:
6 percent, 8 percent (our base case), and 10 percent.5
As an example of this method for calculating the different components of
annuitized resources, consider our estimate of human wealth (HW).

Our formula

~ is
,
for human wealth in year t of sex x born in year k , H W ~k,

where exsk stands for the average earnings in year s of a member of the generation born in year k and of sex x; pXSk is the population in year s of the
same-sex-specific generation, R=l/(l+r),

where r is the rate of interest; and

D is the maximum age reached. The calculation of exsk is given by

These rates bracket the pretax real rate of return observed, on
average, between 1961 and 1992, where the rate of return in year t is calculated as '[(NWt-Lt-Pt+Ct+Tt)/NWttl] - 1 and NWt is household net worth in
period t, Lt is aggregate labor income excluding contributions to private
pension funds, Pt is pension income including private pensions, government
employee pensions, workers compensation and veterans benefits, Ct is personal
consumption expenditure, and Tt is aggregate net tax payments.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

In (5) and ( 6 ) , Es is aggregate labor earnings in year s and dxsk is the ratio
in year s of the average earnings of the generation born in year k of sex x ,
divided by the average earnings in year s of our reference group-those

who

were age 40 in year s (that is, those for whom k=s-40).
The construction of relative profiles by age and sex, dxtk, is described
in equations (7) and (8):
X

Nk x
x
w
ski 'ski
i=l
2

X

!
S
k
i-1

X
W

ski

and

In (7), jxsk is the weighted average (across cohort members indexed by i) of
labor income. N~~~ is the number of observations in year s of individuals of
sex x born in year k , jXski is the wage and salary income of the ith individual of sex x in year s who was born in year k , and wxSki is the person
weight of this observation. Equation (8) shows the calculation in year s of
the average labor income of members of the generation belonging to sex x who
were born in year k , relative to that of contemporaneous 40-year-old males.
The national aggregates used in our calculations come from the National
Income and Product Accounts (NIPA), the Federal Reserve System's Flow of
Funds, The American Council of Life Insurance, the U.S. Census Bureau's
Current Population Survey, and the Survey of Current Business. The sources for

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

cross-section relative profiles are the CPS, the Survey of Income and Program
Participation, the Consumer Expenditure Survey (CES), the Survey of Consumer
Finances (SCF), the Social Security Administration's Annual Statistical
Supplement, and the Health Care Financing Administration (HCFA).

The computa-

tions also use the historic and projected population counts of the Social
Security Administration.

VI. Findings
- at the Data
A. Lookine

Before decomposing past changes in the U.S. saving rate, it's worth
considering some of the data we've constructed. We begin with figures 1 and 2
which show, respectively, relative profiles by age of total consumption and
nonmedical consumption. Each figure contains profiles for the periods 196061, 1972-73, 1984-86, and 1987-90.

The choice of periods was based on the

availability of CES data. For each period, the average consumption of 40year-olds is normalized to 1.
The figures document a remarkable increase in the relative consumption of
the elderly. This increase is more pronounced if medical care is included in
the measure of consumption, but the increase in the relative consumption of
nonmedical goods and services is also striking. Tables 3 and 4 examine some
of the numbers underlying figures 1 and 2.

They report ratios of average

levels of total as well as nonmedical consumption of 60-, 70-, and 80-yearolds to the respective levels of 20-, 30-, and 40-year-olds for each of the
four periods. According to the tables, 70-year-olds in 1960-61 consumed about
71 percent of the amount consumed by 30-year-olds in 1960-61, whereas their
consumption now exceeds that of 30-year-olds by 18 percent. In the case of
nonmedical consumption, 70-year-olds consumed about 63 percent of the amount

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

consumed by 30-year-olds in 1960-61, compared with 91 percent now. The
increase in consumption by the elderly, relative to other ages, is equally
dramatic.
The striking increase in the relative consumption of the elderly has
coincided with an equally remarkable increase in their relative resources.
Figure 3 depicts changes in the age distribution of resources (the rit/rts)
across the four time periods.6

Table 5 presents the ratios of the average

resources of persons aged 60, 70, and 80 years to those aged 20, 30, and 40
years.

In 1960-61, the average resources of 70-year-olds were only 56 percent

as large as those of 30-year-olds.

In 1987-90, they were 85 percent as large.

The resources of other older cohorts have also grown significantly relative to
those of younger cohorts over the past three decades.
Figures 4 through 7 show the components of rit/rts: the human wealth
ratio, hwit/rt, nonhuman wealth ratio, nwit/rt, pension wealth ratio, pwit/rt,
and generational account ratio, gait/rt.

Figure 4 indicates a sizable decline

in the human wealth ratio for young cohorts. Indeed, this decline accounts
for most of the overall decline in rit/rt for young cohorts. The reduction in
the ratio of human wealth to resources at these ages is the result of a low
projected rate of labor income growth compared to the 1960s and early 1970s.7
Figure 5 shows profiles of nwit/rt for the four periods.

Interestingly,

although this ratio falls for all cohorts, it falls most precipitously for the
The kinks at age 80 in figure 3 reflect our method of imputing
relative nonhuman wealth for individuals age 80 and above. The small number
of observations at these ages in the Survey of Consumer Finances precludes
forming separate estimates of average nonhuman wealth at these ages. Here, we
assume that the relative nonhuman wealth of those 80 or older equals that of
80-year-olds of the same sex.
Note that our base-case calculations assume a 0.75 percent annual
growth in labor productivity.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

oldest age groups. As figure 3 shows, the overall ratio rit/rt increased for
almost all older cohorts, despite a steep decline in their nonhuman wealth
ratio.

Figure 6 presents the ratio of pension wealth to resources, pwit/rt,

for each of the four periods. As indicated, cohorts of preretirement age
experienced particularly rapid growth in pension wealth over the last three
decades. The increase in pwit/rt accounts for a sizable part of the increase
in rit/rt for these cohorts.
Figure 7 shows changes over time in the ratios of generational accounts
to resources. Note that all cohorts experienced declines in gait/rts between
the early 1960s and late 1980s. However, the reductions are much larger for
cohorts aged 55 and older.

In 1960-61, for example, the present value of net

transfers to 70-year-olds amounted to 4 percent of per capita resources. In
the late 1980s, the corresponding figure was about 25 percent.

Changes in

generational accounts are clearly responsible for most of the rise in the
relative resources of the elderly in the postwar period.
Figure 8 graphs age-specific consumption propensities in each of the four
periods.

In each period, the propensity to consume is roughly constant prior

to about age 60 and then rises steadily. There is a local peak between ages

35 and 45 in the graphs that appears to reflect household expenditures on
child rearing. Note that this local peak occurs at later ages through time-a
result that is consistent with the trend of parents having children at older
ages .
The most notable feature of figure 8, however, is that it documents a
very substantial increase over time in the consumption propensities of older
Americans. Take 80-year-olds, for example, whose propensity to consume rose
from 8.7 percent in 1960-61 to 12.7 percent in 1987-90.

Interestingly, there

is no corresponding increase in the consumption propensities of the young and

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

middle-aged.

As shown in table 6, these findings-that

the consumption

propensities of the older old have risen and that those of the young and
middle-aged have remained relatively constant--are robust to different assumed
values of the discount rate. At a discount rate of 3 percent, for example,
80-year-olds' consumption propensity rises from 8.5 percent in 1960-61 to
11.5 percent in 1987-90 (see figure 9).

At a discount rate of 9 percent, it

rises from 8.9 to 13.8 percent.
Finally, consider figure 10,'which shows changes over the four periods in
the age composition of the U.S. population. The figure indicates a small rise
since the early 1960s in the share of the population over age 65. It also
indicates that there were relatively more adults in their twenties and
thirties in the late 1980s than in the early 1960s, and relatively fewer
adults in their forties and fifties.

B. Decomvosin~Postwar Chan~esin U.S. Saving
Tables 7-12 examine the effect on U.S. saving of changes in the five
factors mentioned above: the age distribution of resources, the resourceoutput ratio, R/NNP, propensities to consume, the age distribution of the
population, and the rate of government spending (G/NNP).

Except tables 9 and

12, which consider the effects of changes in the age composition of the population and the rate of government spending, each table shows results for real
discount rates of 3, 6, and 9 percent.

1 . Changes in the Age-Resource Distribution

Consider first the middle panel of table 7, which incorporates our basecase 6 percent real discount rate. In this panel, as well as all the other
panels in tables 7-12, the numbers along the diagonal are the actual rates of

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

U.S. net national saving that were observed in the periods being studied. The
off-diagonal numbers indicate the saving rate that would have been observed in
the row period had the saving factor in question (in this case, the age
distribution of resources) taken the column period's value.
Take the first number in the last row, 5.12, as an example.

This is the

saving rate that, all else being equal, would have been observed in 1987-90
had the age-resource distribution been the same then as it was in 1960-61.
Since 3.38 is the actual saving rate observed in 1987-90, we conclude that the
saving rate for that period would have been 51 percent larger had the ageresource distribution of the late 1980s matched that of the early 1960s.

A comparison of 5.23 (the last number in the first row of the central
panel of table 7) with 7.85, the actual 1960-61 saving rate, provides another
way to assess the importance of the change in the age-resource distribution.
It shows that the saving rate would have been 33 percent smaller if everything
else had remained as it was in 1960-61 but the age-resource distribution had
changed as it did over the three decades. That is, a change in the age
resource distribution alone would have been sufficient to depress saving
rates.
The corner values in each panel of table 7 indicate that the shifts in
the age-resource distribution among living generations is an important factor
in explaining the much lower actual rates of U.S. saving that occurred in the
late 1980s than in the early 1960s. But, as figure 3 shows, these ageresource profile changes did not occur overnight.

Indeed, the other values of

table 7 show that the shifting age-resource distribution has been responsible
for a steady decline in national saving.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

2. Changes in Average Propensities to Consume
Table 8 shows the effect on the national saving rate of changes over time
in average propensities to consume. The last number in the first column of
the middle panel (2.10) indicates that, other things being equal, the 1987-90
net national saving rate would have been 38 percent lower had 1987-90 consumption propensities equaled those of 1960-61.

This decrease in the saving rate

may seem surprising, given the much larger consumption propensities of elderly
cohorts in 1987-90.

The reason for the decline becomes clear on a closer look

at figure 8: Except for cohorts in their early 40s, the consumption
propensities of most younger cohorts are lower in the late 1980s than in the
early 1960s. The slightly higher consumption propensities of younger cohorts
in the 1960-61 period produce a substantial negative effect on the saving rate
because there are many more young individuals in the population than there are
older ones, and because the consumption propensities of older persons were
much lower in 1960-61 than in 1987-90.

The last number in the first row of

table 8 (9.46) shows that a change in cohort consumption propensities alone
would have led to higher saving rates in the late 1980s.
The conclusion that the steep increases in older generations'
propensities to consume are more than offset by the declines in those of
younger generations is robust for lower discount rates but not for higher
ones. A lower discount rate of 3 percent reduces the 1987-90 profile of
consumption propensities by more than it lowers that for 1960-61, because the
degree of annuitization of wealth is much greater, especially for older
cohorts in the late 1980s.

Hence, as a comparison of figures 8 and 9 indi-

cates, using a 3 percent instead of a 6 percent discount rate produces a

See Auerbach et al. (1994).

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

larger decline in the profile for 1987-90 than for 1960-61.

As a result, the

saving rate is even lower if the 1960-61 consumption propensities profile is
used in place of the 1987-90 profile. The reverse argument holds for a higher
discount rate. Hence, at a 9 percent interest rate, the saving rate would
have been larger had the 1960-61 consumption propensities prevailed in the
1987-90 period.

3. Changes in the Population Distribution
Table 9 shows the effect on U . S . saving rates of changes over time in the
age composition of the population. As we have noted, had the 1960-61 age
distribution of the population prevailed in 1987-90, the U . S . saving rate
would have been 2.44 percent rather than 3.38 percent. This result can be
understood by recalling that the propensity to consume rises with age and, as
shown in figure 10, the age distribution of the early 1960s featured relatively more middle-aged Americans and relatively fewer younger Americans than
did the age distribution of the late 1980s.

4. Changes in the Resources-Income Ratio
Table 10 shows the impact of changes over time in the ratio of resources
to income. The last number in the first column of the middle panel (8.34)
indicates that saving rates would have been two and a half times as large if
the 1960-61 R/NNP ratio had prevailed in 1987-90.

Table 11 reports this ratio

and its components for the four periods and for the three discount rates.

For

the base case (r=6 percent), R/NNP increased from 12.72 to 13.62 between 19606 1 and 1987-90.

An increase in this ratio raises the rate of consumption out

of income and reduces the net national saving rate.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

The decomposition of the change in R/NNP in table 11 shows that increases
over time in the ratios of human and nonhuman wealth to net national product
(HW/NNP and NHW/NNP, respectively) are not responsible for the increase in
R/NNP.

Rather, it is partially the increase in the ratio of pension wealth to

income (PW/NNP), but primarily the decline in the ratio of aggregate generational accounts to income (GA/NNP), that causes the rise.

In other words, the

government's intergenerational redistribution of resources, particularly the
redistribution from future to living generations, is primarily responsible for
the increase in the resource-income ratio, which, in turn, appears to be the
single most important cause of the decline in U.S. national saving.

5. Changes i n t h e Government Spending Rate
Table 12 considers how changes in the government spending rate, G/NNP,
have affected national saving. This rate fell slightly from 21.6 percent in
1960-61 to 21.2 percent in 1987-90.

The numbers in the middle panel show that

had G/NNP in 1987-90 taken on its 1960-61 value, the 1987-90 U.S. saving rate
would have been 12 percent smaller; in other words, the rate of government
spending in the late 1980s is not responsible for the low rate of national
saving during that period.

6 . The Case o f No Annuity Markets

The foregoing discussion assumes that individuals can convert future
income flows into currently disposable resources at actuarially fair discount
rates-that

is, the pretax rate of interest plus the probability of death

conditional on age.

This is equivalent to assuming the existence of explicit

or implicit actuarially fair annuity insurance. To investigate the robustness
of the results to this assumption, we now consider the opposite assumption-

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

that no annuity insurance is available. The appropriate rate for discounting
future flows under this assumption is simply the pretax rate of interest.
Table 13 indicates that the no-annuity-insurance assumption does not
materially affect the results of tables 7 through 12.'

Applying the 1960s'

propensities to consume to the cohort-specific resource levels of the late
1980s reduces the saving rate in the late 1980s from 3.4 percent to 2.42
percent rather than to 2.10 percent as in the previous case. The effects on
national saving of switching the age-resource distribution and the resourcesto-income ratio are almost identical to earlier cases: With the 1960-61 ageresource distribution, the saving rate would have increased from 3.4 percent
to 5.07 percent instead of to 5.12 percent.

Finally, using the 1960-61

resources-to-income ratio increases the saving rate from 3.4 percent to 8.09
percent instead of to 8.34 percent as earlier.

VII. Conclusion
This paper traces the dramatic postwar decline in U.S. saving to one main
cause: government redistribution from young and as yet unborn generations to
older ones. Without this factor, the current U.S. rate of national saving
would be at least thrice as large.

The increase in the rate at which older

generations consume their resources has been offset by the decline of younger
generations' consumption propensities. However, the increase in the relative
resources of older Americans has led to a remarkable increase in their
relative consumption. Today's 70-year-olds are consuming, on average, roughly
one-fifth more than are 30-year-olds.
consuming only two-thirds as much.

Were this the early 1960s, they'd be

The increase in the relative consumption

All the results of table 13 use the base-case value of r=6 percent.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

of the elderly remains dramatic, even if one considers only nonmedical
consumption.
The fact that propensities to consume are not systematically larger,
indeed are smaller, for most young and middle-aged cohorts in the late 1980s
than in the early 1960s indicates that "spendthrift" young and middle-aged
Americans are not to blame for the decline in U.S. saving. This is not to say
that young and middle-aged Americans are saving enough. Given the severe
imbalance in long-run U.S. fiscal policy, they need to save significant sums
simply to safeguard themselves against future tax increases or reductions in
transfer payments (Auerbach and Kotlikoff, 1994).
Since there is every reason to believe that U.S. intergenerational
redistribution will continue apace, at least through the turn of this century,
there is little doubt that U.S. saving rates will remain extremely low or
decline even further. Anemic U.S. saving rates will spell anemic rates of
U.S. domestic investment, labor productivity growth, and real wage growth.
This is the unfortunate legacy of the uncontrolled intergenerational
redistribution that has been fueling ever higher rates of U.S. consumption.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Appendix: Data Sources and Construction

Labor Income

Aggregate labor income between 1960 and 1993 is c a l c u l a t e d a s l a b o r ' s s h a r e of
NIPA-reported n a t i o n a l income.

For each of these y e a r s , l a b o r ' s s h a r e of

n a t i o n a l income i s c a l c u l a t e d under t h e assumption t h a t i t s s h a r e of propriet o r s h i p income is t h e same as i t s share of n a t i o n a l income. lo R e l a t i v e
p r o f i l e s of l a b o r income by age and sex a r e c a l c u l a t e d f o r each year between
1963 and 1987 using t h a t y e a r ' s CPS d a t a .

The 1963 p r o f i l e i s used t o

d i s t r i b u t e aggregate l a b o r income f o r years p r i o r t o 1963, and t h e 1987
p r o f i l e i s applied f o r years a f t e r 1987.

Per c a p i t a labor income f o r years

beyond 1993 i s projected under t h e assumption t h a t , except f o r an adjustment
f o r growth, cohorts of a given age and sex earn the same average l a b o r income
i n f u t u r e years a s cohorts of t h a t age and sex earned i n 1993.

For example,

males who a r e age 50 i n 1994 assumed t o e a r n t h e same amount on average, a p a r t
from an adjustment f o r growth, a s males who were age 50 i n 1993.
adjustment i s 1 . 2 percent per y e a r .

The growth

Thus, t h e projected average earnings of

males aged 50 i n , say, 1996 equals t h e corresponding 1993 average f o r males
aged 50, m u l t i p l i e d by ( 1 . 0 1 2 ) ~ .

'O~he share of labor. income i n n a t i o n a l income i s a , where a s a t i s f i e s C
= aNI.
I n t h i s equation, C i s compensation paid t o employees l e s s
employer c o n t r i b u t i o n s t o employee pension p l a n s , P I i s p r o p r i e t o r s h i p income,
and N I i s n a t i o n a l income. The c a l c u l a t e d values of a a r e q u i t e s t a b l e over
t h e period 1960-1992, ranging between 0.76 and 0.82.

+ aPI

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Pension Benefits

Pension benefits include private pension benefits, workers compensation,
veterans benefits, and government employee pension benefits. Aggregate
pension benefits for the years 1960-1988 are taken from Park (1992).

Here,

the NIPA estimates are used primarily because estimates based upon administrative reports are generally deemed more reliable than those based upon
household surveys. The estimates for years after 1988 were derived by
applying the average growth rate of real benefits between 1984 and 1988 to the
1988 figure. The aggregates for the other three types of benefits are taken
from SCB.

The relative profiles for all four types of pensions are computed from the
March CPS.

This survey contains information on pension income from a variety

of sources including company or union pensions, workers compensation, veterans
benefits, and government employee pensions, and receipts from annuities and
other regular contributions. For all categories retirement, disability, and
survivor benefits are included. Separate profiles were obtained for each of
the years between 1970 and 1992. The 1970 profile was used to distribute the
aggregates in years prior to 1970. For years after 1992, it is assumed that
real average pension benefits at a given age and sex-equal their 1992 values
adjusted for our assumed 1.2 percent rate of growth.

Social Securitv Benefits

Aggregate Social Security benefits between 1960 and 1993 are those reported in
the NIPA.

Between 1993 and 2030 we use the Office of Management and Budget's

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

(OMB) projections (on a NIPA basis) of Social Security benefits.

Aggregate

Social Security Old Age, Survivor, and Disability Insurance (OASDI) benefits
after 2030 equal the 2030 aggregate adjusted for growth. The growth rates
applied in this case are those embedded in a special Social Security Administration projection of total benefit payments for the years after 2030. This
projection incorporates Social Security's intermediate economic and
demographic assumptions with one exception: The productivity growth rate is
assumed to equal 1.2 percent.

The SSASS reports average benefits by age and sex by type of benefit as well
as the total number of recipients in each age-sex category. These data were
used to form population-weighted per capita OASDI benefit profiles by age and
sex. Relative profiles for OASDI benefits for each year from 1960 through
1990 were obtained from that year's SSASS. For years after 1990 we use the
1990 relative profile of Social Security benefits by age and sex.

Medicare and Medicaid Benefits

Aggregate Medicare and Medicaid payments from the inception of these programs
through 1993 are reported by NIPA.

OMB provided us with unpublished projec-

tions (on a NIPA basis) of aggregate Medicare payments for the years 1994
through 2030. In the case of Medicaid, we applied OMB's projected annual
growth rates for grants in aid to state and local governments between 1994 and
2030 to the 1993 aggregate NIPA value of Medicaid. Beyond 2030, both Medicare
and Medicaid payments are assumed to grow in accordance with demographic
change and our assumed productivity growth rate. Relative profiles of
Medicare and Medicaid benefits are based on HCFA data on average benefits by

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

age and sex.

I n t h e case of Medicare, t h e d a t a a r e a v a i l a b l e only by five-

year age groups.

Unemplovment Insurance. Aid t o Families with Dependent Children, Food Stamps.
and General Welfare Benefits

Aggregate v a l u e s of t h e s e f e d e r a l , s t a t e , and l o c a l t r a n s f e r s a r e r e p o r t e d by
NIPA.

S t a t e and l o c a l supplemental s e c u r i t y income a s w e l l a s t r a n s f e r s f o r

employment and t r a i n i n g a r e d i s t r i b u t e d according t o t h e r e l a t i v e p r o f i l e f o r
AFDC.

General welfare b e n e f i t s include f e d e r a l black-lung b e n e f i t s , s t a t e

general a s s i s t a n c e , s t a t e energy a s s i s t a n c e , education b e n e f i t s , and o t h e r
f e d e r a l , s t a t e , and l o c a l t r a n s f e r s .

The aggregate amount of earned income-

t a x c r e d i t was d i s t r i b u t e d according t o t h e r e l a t i v e p r o f i l e f o r food stamps.
P r o f i l e s f o r unemployment insurance, food stamps, AFDC, and general welfare
a r e computed from the 1983 S I P P .

These r e l a t i v e p r o f i l e s were used t o

d i s t r i b u t e t h e i r r e s p e c t i v e aggregate expenditures f o r a l l of t h e y e a r s
between 1960 and 1993.

For f u t u r e years we assume t h a t t h e age- and sex-

s p e c i f i c v a l u e s of each of these types of t r a n s f e r payments keep pace with
p r o d u c t i v i t y growth.

Labor Income Taxes

Aggregate f e d e r a l , s t a t e , and l o c a l income taxes f o r 1960 through 1993 a r e
r e p o r t e d i n NIPA.

For 1993 through 2030 we use OMB's p r o j e c t i o n s of f e d e r a l

income t a x revenues.

S t a t e and l o c a l income taxes f o r 1993 through 2030 a r e

p r o j e c t e d using OMB's GDP f o r e c a s t and assuming t h a t t h e same r a t i o of s t a t e

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

and local income taxes to GDP prevails between 1993 and 2030 as prevailed in
1993.

Aggregate labor income taxes in each year are calculated as the product of
total federal, state, and local income taxes and labor's share of national
income. We distribute aggregate labor income taxes based on the CPS profiles
of labor income described above. After 2030 we assume that age- and sexspecific values of labor income taxes keep pace with productivity growth.

Pavroll Taxes

The NIPA reports aggregate values of payroll taxes from 1960 through 1993.
The OMB provided us with projections of aggregate federal payroll taxes from
1994 through 2030. Aggregate state and local payroll taxes for 1994 through
2030 were calculated based on OMB's projection of GDP between 1994 and 2030
and the assumption that the 1993 ratio of state and local payroll taxes to GDP
prevails through 2030. Aggregate payroll taxes in the years 1960-2030 are
distributed by age and sex according to 1963 through 1992 CPS profiles of
covered earnings (labor earnings subject to Social Security payroll taxes). 11
Age- and sex-specific values of payroll taxes beyond 2030 are assumed to equal
their 2030 values adjusted for growth.

Excise and Sales Taxes
l1 Unfortunately, the data do not permit the calculation of separate
profiles for state and local payroll taxes, which aren't necessarily subject
to earnings ceilings. However, non-Social Security payroll taxes are a small
fraction of the total (less than 30 percent), so the bias associated with
profiles of earnings covered by Social Security is likely to be quite small.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

The NIPA i s our source f o r aggregate excise-tax
sales-tax revenues from 1960 through 1993.

( i n c l u d i n g property t a x ) and

For t h e period 1994-2030 we use

OMB p r o j e c t i o n s of f e d e r a l excise- and sales-tax

revenues.

S t a t e and l o c a l

excise- and s a l e s - t a x revenues between 1994 and 2030 a r e c a l c u l a t e d using the
1993 r a t i o of t h e s e revenues t o GDP and applying O M B ' s GDP f o r e c a s t s through.
2030.

R e l a t i v e age-sex p r o f i l e s of excise and s a l e s taxes were c a l c u l a t e d from t h e
1960-61,

1972-73,

1984-86, and 1987-90 Consumer Expenditure Surveys (CEX).

Separate p r o f i l e s were constructed f o r tobacco, a l c o h o l , and property t a x e s ,
and f o r a l l o t h e r s a l e s and excise t a x e s .
years p r i o r t o 1966.
through 1978.

The 1960-61 p r o f i l e s were used f o r

The 1972-73 p r o f i l e s were used f o r t h e years 1967

The 1984-86 p r o f i l e s were used f o r the years 1979 through 1986,

and t h e 1987-90 p r o f i l e s were used f o r 1987 and beyond.

Age- and sex-specific

values of s a l e s and e x c i s e taxes beyond 2030 a r e assumed t o equal t h e 2030
values a d j u s t e d f o r growth.

C a ~ i t a lIncome Taxes

Aggregate c a p i t a l income taxes between 1960 and 2030 a r e c a l c u l a t e d a s
c a p i t a l ' s s h a r e of n a t i o n a l income, m u l t i p l i e d by a c t u a l o r p r o j e c t e d values
of aggregate f e d e r a l , s t a t e , and l o c a l income-tax

revenues.

f o r c a p i t a l income taxes come from the 1962 and 1983 SCFs.

Relative p r o f i l e s
These p r o f i l e s a r e

based upon weighted average n e t worth holdings by age and s e x , where t h e
weights a p p l i e d a r e SCF person weights.

This procedure could be applied only

t o i n d i v i d u a l s aged 80 o r l e s s because of t h e paucity of d a t a f o r o l d e r indi-

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

viduals. The profile of average net worth holdings by age and sex were
smoothed and extrapolated through age 100 using a 4th order polynomial.
Age- and sex-specific values of capital income taxes after 2030 are assumed to
equal the 2030 values adjusted for growth.

Non Human Wealth

Age- and sex-specific values of nonhuman wealth (NHW) in each year between
1960 and 1993 are constructed by distributing by age and sex each of these
years' levels of total private net wealth. Aggregate private net wealth for
these years is reported in the FOF.12 The relative profiles of wealth
holdings by age and sex are calculated by using data from the 1963 and 1983
SCF. The 1963 profiles are used for years prior to 1963 and the 1983 profile
for years after 1983. The profiles for intermediate years are constructed by
linearly interpolating between the 1963 and 1983 profiles.

- Averape Consumption bv Age and Sex
Determining

The data used for determining average consumption by age and sex for the years
1960-61, 1972-73, 1984-86, and 1987-90 are the National Income and Product
Accounts (NIPA), the 1960-61, 1972-73, and 1984-90 Consumer Expenditure
Surveys (CEX), and the 1977 and 1987 National Medical Expenditure Surveys
(NMES).

Aggregate NIPA household consumption expenditure was allocated to

adults based on four relative profiles of consumption by age and sex-one

for

Our aggregates are net of the FOF's estimate of the value of residential structures, plant, and equipment owned by nonprofit institutions.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

the years 1960-61, one for the years 1972-73, one for the years 1984-86, and
one for the years 1987-90.

To use the 1960-61 CEX, we first needed to impute particular demographic
information to households. The reason is that the 1960-61 CEX provides only
general information about the ages and sexes of household members other than
the head and spouse. Our imputation used a statistical match with the 1960
Decennial Census.

Specifically, we sorted the Census data by a set of vari-

ables that are also available in the CEX. These include demographic variables, such as the number of children under age 18 and the ages and sexes of
the household head and spouse, household income, the sex and marital status of
the head, an urban versus rural indicator, region, and housing tenure. For
each 1960-61 CEX household with members other than the head and spouse, we
then randomly selected a Census household from the set of Census households
with the same matching data. The ages and sexes of the Census household
members other than the head and spouse were then attributed to the CEX
household.

Each of the four relative age-sex consumption profiles was formed in a similar
manner.

First, we divided the NIPA consumption aggregates into 35 separate

components. For most of these components, such as clothing, there are
corresponding data in the CEX that can be used to distribute the aggregate
values.

For three other components, imputed rent, financial services, and

expenditures by charitable institutions, there is no corresponding direct
measure in the CEX, but there are other CEX variables (e.g., house value in
the case of imputed rent) that can be used for distribution purposes. This is

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

not the case for the health-care component of aggregate NIPA consumption, so
we use the NMES to distribute health care.

The second step in forming age-sex consumption profiles involved benchmarking
the distribution data to the relevant component of the NIPA consumption
aggregate. Take NIPA clothing, for example. For this component, we divided
NIPA clothing by the total CEX clothing expenditure, where the total was
computed using the CEX household weights. The resulting ratio was used to
rescale the clothing expenditure of each household in the CEX.

Separate

rescaling of clothing was done for each of CEX surveys used in the study based
on the contemporaneous NIPA value of clothing. This procedure was used to
rescale the CEX data for each of the NIPA components for which there are also
direct CEX measures.

In the case of the NIPA aggregate for imputed rent, we calculated the ratio of
NIPA aggregate imputed rent to total CEX reported house values, again
computing the total using the CEX household weights. We then multiplied each
household's reported house value by this ratio to produce a NIPA-benchmarked
estimate of the household's imputed rent. The same procedure was used in the
case of financial services, expenditures by charitable institutions, clothing
provided by the military, food produced and consumed on farms, and net foreign
remittances except that, instead of house value, we used, respectively,
checking plus saving accounts, charitable contributions, number of household
members in the military, a dummy variable equal to 1 if the household owned a
farm and 0 otherwise, and total other consumption.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

In the case of health-care expenditures, we benchmarked the NMES data using
NIPA's five broad components: physician's services, hospital services, private
health insurance, prescriptions, and other medical.

Specifically, we formed

the ratio of each of these components to the corresponding NMES totals (based
on the NMES population weights) and then rescaled the NMES data based on these
ratios. We used the 1977 NMES for the years 1960 and 1961 as well as 1972 and
1973, and the 1987 NMES for the years 1984 through 1990.

In the third step, we allocated our rescaled (NIPA-benchmarked) actual or
imputed CEX data to individuals within the CEX household.

(This was not

necessary for the NMES, which takes the individual as the unit of observation.)

For certain types of expenditures, the method of allocation was fairly

clear.

For example, boys' clothing expenditures was divided evenly among the

household's male children, and pipe tobacco was divided evenly among the
household's adult males. For other types of expenditures, we developed
particular rules. Housing expenditures, including imputed rent, was allocated
evenly to the head and spouse. And food, vacations, and other not readily
allocable expenditure items, were divided evenly among the household's adult
equivalents, where each adult was given an equivalency factor of 1 and each
child under 18 was given a factor that increased linearly from .3 for newborns
to 1 for 18-year-olds.

The fourth step entailed using the NIPA-benchmarked NMES data to calculate
age- and sex-specific weighted average values of each of the five different
types of health expenditures. These values were then attributed to individual
members of the CEX households based on their ages and sexes. In this step we
also allocated to individual members of the CEX households, based on their

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

ages and sexes, average values of privately paid educational expenditures.
These average values were determined by calculating average elementary and
secondary school expenditures per child age 5 through 18 and average college
expenditures per person age 18 through 24.

In the fifth step, we reallocated all of the CEX children's expenditures,
including their imputed health expenditures, evenly to the head and spouse.
We then combined these NIPA-benchmarked, CEX actual or imputed data for
particular years (1960 and 1961, 1972 and 1973, 1984-1986, and 1987-1990) to
form the ratios of the average value over these years of total expenditures of
adults (those age 18 and older) of a particular age and sex to that of 40year-old males.

This provided our four age-sex relative consumption profiles.

We used our four age-sex relative consumption profiles and our age- and sexspecific population data to allocate total NIPA consumption over the four
periods by age and sex. This procedure may appear to represent an unnecessary
second round of benchmarking of aggregate NIPA consumption, but in so doing we
assure ourselves that our final calculated values of average consumption by
age and sex are consistent with the Census population data used to calculate
age- and sex-specific values of average remaining lifetime resources. In
particular, they avoid under- or overestimates of average age- and sexspecific consumption that would arise if the CEX household weights were
systematically too high or too low.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

References
Abel, Andrew and Laurence J. Kotlikoff, "Intergenerational Altruism and the
Effectiveness of Fiscal Policy -- New Tests Based on Cohort Data," in Savings
and Bequests, Toshiaki Tachibanaki, ed., Ann Arbor, Michigan: The University
of Michigan Press, 1994, pp. 167-96.
Altonji, Joseph, Fumio Hayashi, and Laurence J. Kotlikoff, "Is the Extended
Family Altruistically Linked? New Tests Based on Micro Data," American
Economic Review, December 1992, pp. 1177-98.
Ando, Albert and Franco Modigliani, "The 'Life Cycle' Hypothesis of Saving:
Aggregate Implications and Tests," American Economic Review, vol. 53, no. 1,
1963, pp. 55-84.
Attanasio, Orazio P., "A Cohort Analysis of Saving Behavior by U.S.
Households," NBER working paper no. 4454, September 1993.
Auerbach, Alan J., Jagadeesh Gokhale, Laurence J. Kotlikoff, John Sabelhaus
and David N. Weil, "The Annuitization of Americans' Resources: A Cohort
Analysis," Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Working Paper No. 9413, November
1994.
Auerbach, Alan J. and Laurence J. Kotlikoff, "The U.S.' Fiscal and Saving
Crises and Their Implications for the Baby Boom Generation," forthcoming in
Retirement in the 21st Century: Readv or Not?, Employee Benefit Research
Institute, 1994.
Boskin, Michael J. and Lawrence J. Lau, "An Analysis of Postwar U.S. Consumption and Saving: Part I, The Model and Aggregation," NBER Working Paper
No. 2605, June 1988a.
Boskin, Michael J. and Lawrence J. Lau, "An Analysis of Postwar U.S. Consumption and Saving: Part 11, Empirical Resultd," NBER Working Paper No. 2606,
June 1988b.
Bosworth, Barry, Gary Burtless, and John Sabelhaus, "The Decline in Saving:
Some Microeconomic Evidence," Brookinps Papers on Economic Activity, vol. 1,
1991, pp. 183-241.
Cutler, David M., James M. Poterba, Louise M. Sheiner, and Lawrence H.
Summers, "An Aging Society: Opportunity or Challenge?" Brookin~sPapers on
Economic Activity, 1990, pp. 1-73.
Hayashi, Fumio, Joseph Altonji, and.LaurenceJ. Kotlikoff, "Risk Sharing
across and within American Families," revised mimeo 1994.
Kotlikoff, Laurence J., "From Deficit Delusion to the Fiscal Balance RuleLooking for an Economically Meaningful Way to Assess Fiscal Policy, Journal of
Economics, Supplement 7, 1993, pp. 17-41.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Park, Thae S. "Total Private Pension Benefit Payments, 1950-88" in Trends in
Pensions 1992, U.S. Department of Labor, Pension and Welfare Benefits Administration, 1992.
Summers, Lawrence H. and Chris Carroll, "Why Is U.S. National Saving So Low?"
Brookings P a ~ e r son Economic Activitv, vol. 2, 1987, pp. 607-635.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 1
Saving and Spending Rates

Period

Net National
Saving
Rate
(Y-C-G ) /Y

Government
Spending
Rate

Household
Consumption
Rate

Household
Saving
Rate
(Y-G-C ) / (Y-G)

Source: Authors' calculations based on National Income and Product Accounts.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 2
The Growth of Household and Medical Consumption

Rate of
Household
Consumption

Rate of
Medical
Consumption

Period
1950-59

Source: Authors' calculations based on National Income and Product Accounts.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 3
Consumption of the Elderly Relative to the Young

Age 60/Age 20
Age 70/Age 20
Age 80/Age 20
Age 60/Age 30
Age 70/Age 30
Age 80/Age 30
Age 60/Age 40
Age 70/Age 40
Age 80/Age 4 0
Source: Authors' calculations.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 4
Nonmedical Consumption of the Elderly Relative to the Young

Age 60/Age 20
Age 70/Age 20
Age 80/Age 20
Age 60/Age 30
Age 70/Age 30
Age 80/Age 30
Age 60/Age 4 0
Age 70/Age 40
Age 80/Age 40
Source : ~ u t h o r s' calculations.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 5
Resources o f the Elderly Relative t o the Young ( r = 6 percent)

Age 60/Age 20
Age 70/Age 20
Age 80/Age 20
Age 60/Age 30
Age 70/Age 30
Age 80/Age 30
Age 60/Age 40
Age 70/Age 40
Age 80/Age 40
Source: Authors' c a l c u l a t i o n s .

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 6
Propensities to Consume at Selected Ages and Discount Rates

r = 3 percent

r = 6 percent

r = 9 percent

Source: Authors' calculations.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 7
The Impact of the Changing Age-Resource Distribution
on the Net National Saving Rate

resource distribution in period

Period
r

=

3 percent

r = 6 percent

r

=

9 percent

Source: Authors' calculations.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 8
The Impact of Changing Propensities to Consume
on the Net National Saving Rate
propensities to consume in period
Period
r

=

3 percent

r = 6 percent

r

=

9 percent

Source: Authors' calculations.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 9
The Impact of Changing Population-Age Distribution
on the Net National Saving Rate
population-age distribution in period
Period

1960-61

Source: Authors' calculations.

1972-73

1984-86

1987-90

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 10
The Impact of the Resources-to-Income Ratio
on the Net National Saving Rate
resources-to-income ratio in period
Period

1960-61

r = 3 percent

r

r

=

6 percent

9 percent

Source: Authors' calculations.

1972-73

1984-86

1987-90

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 11
Decomposing Changes in R / N N P ~
1960-61
r

=

3 percent

r

=

6 percent

1972-73

1984-86

1987-90

r = 9 percent

a ~ / ~ +~ NHW
~ += PW[ - ~GA]/NNP
~
where NNP=net national product, R=total
resources, HW=human wealth, NHW=nonhuman wealth, PW=pension wealth, and
GA=generational account.
Source: Authors' calculations.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 12
The Impact of the Rate of Government Spending
on the Net National Saving Rate
government spending rate in period
Period

1960-61

Source: Authors' calculations.

1972-73

1984-86

1987-90

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 13:
Changes in the Net National Saving Rate:
The Case of No Annuity Insurance (r

=

6 percent)

Impact of Changing Resource Distributions
resource distribution in period
Period

1960-61

1972-73

1984-86

1987-90

Impact of Changing Consumption Propensities
propensities to consume in period

Impact of Changing Resources-to-Income Ratio (R/NNP)
R/NNP in period

a ~ e efootnotes to table 11 for definitions.
Source: Authors' calculations.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

FIGURE 3: COHORT RESOURCES PER CAPITA I PER CAPITA RESOURCES

AGE

SOURCE: AUTHORS' CALCULATIONS.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

FIGURE 5: COHORT NONHUMAN WEALTH PER CAPITA 1 PER CAPITA RESOURCES
0.7

0
18

23

28

33

38

43

48

53
AGE

SOURCE: AUTHORS' CALCULATIONS.

58

63

68

73

78

83

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

FIGURE 6: COHORT PENSION WEALTH PER CAPITA 1 PER CAPITA RESOURCES

SOURCE: AUTHORS' CALCULATIONS.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm