View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

\

Working Paver 9019

TASTES AND TECHNOLOGY IN A TWO-COUNTRY
MODEL OF THE BUSINESS CYCLE: EXPLAINING
INTERNATIONAL CO-MOVEMENTS

by Alan C. Stockman and Linda L. Tesar

%
'

Alan C. Stockman is a professor of economics
at the University of Rochester, and Linda L.
Tesar is an assistant professor of economics
at the University of California, Santa Barbara.
For helpful comments, the authors would like
to thank Mark Bils, Mary Finn, and workshop
participants at the University of Chicago,
the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Washington
University, the Rochester Conference on the
International Transmission of Business Cycles,
and the NBER Summer Institute. They would
also like to thank Rick Pace, Mike Pakko, and
Kazimierz Stanczak for research assistance.
Mr. Stockman gratefully acknowledges research
support from the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
and the National Science Foundation. Both authors
acknowledge research support from the University
of Rochester Workshop on International Markets,
supported by a grant from the Alfred P. Sloan
Foundation.
Working papers of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland are preliminary materials circulated
to stimulate discussion and critical comment.
The views stated herein are those of the authors
and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of-Governors
of the Federal Reserve System.
April 1991

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

1
1.

Introduction
This paper develops a two-country real business cycle model and confronts

it with an extensive set of empirical observations.

In particular, we examine

the model's consistency with the behavior of international as well as domestic
variables, the cyclical behavior of relative prices and the model's implications
for economic aggregates at the sectoral level.

This line of research is

motivated by a desire to understand the international transmission of business
cycles and changes in international competitiveness as reflected in the behavior
of relative prices, such as real exchange rates and the terms of trade. We also
hope to extend our understanding of business cycles in closed economies by
studying a broader and different set of

observation^.^

Studies of cyclical fluctuations in a closed-economy setting have
identified several pervasive features of the business cycle: investment,
consumption andwork effort are stronglyprocyclical, investment is more volatile
than output, and the time-path of consumption is generally smoother than that of
output. These observations characterize business cycles not only in the United
States, but also in the larger set of industrial countries (see Dellas, 1986;
Backus and Kehoe, 1988; Gerlach, 1988 ; Baxter and Stockman, 1989 ; and this paper,
Section 2).
These closed-economy features of business cycles have received much
attention in the literature. However, there are several open-economy features
of the cycle that a model of the international transmission of business cycles
should explain.

In Section 2, we discuss these open-economy aspects of the

'we hope to extend this research in the future to explain differences in
business cycles across countries; some of these differences are apparent in the
data tables at the end of this paper.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

business cycle and present evidence on the cyclical behavior of the trade
balance, the current account, the correlation between savings and investment and
the

cross-country correlations

of

consumption, output

and

changes

in

productivity.
Disaggregation of the standard one-sector real business cycle model into
a two-sectormodel with production of traded and nontraded goods helps to account
for some of these international observations; in particular, the incorporation
of nontraded

goods helps

to

explain the

low cross-country consumption

correlations and the high correlation between savings and investment (Tesar,
1990).

This disaggregation also introduces a number of new dimensions for

evaluating the model.2 Thus, we present evidence on the cyclical behavior of
consumption, output, investment and work effort in the traded- and
nontraded-good-producingsectors, and examine the correlations between these
variables across sectors.
Finally, we confront the model with data on prices as well as quantities,
including the terms of trade, the real exchange rate and the relative price of
nontraded goods.

Some theoretical models of exchange rates (Stockman, 1980,

1987a; Lucas , 1982) suggest that real disturbances like those emphasized in real
business cycle models are the main cause of changes in real (and nominal)
exchange rates.

Our current paper attempts to provide the foundations of a

quantitative analysis of neoclassical international finance that integrates
equilibrium models of exchange rates with neoclassical models of business cycles

2 ~ h i spaper does not formally test hypotheses about the model, because the
model is clearly false in ways that will become apparent. Our research is
instead intended to describe the areas of success and failure of a simple
neoclassical model, which we consider a necessary step to further theoretical and
empirical analysis.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

and their international transmission.
The empirical evidence is summarized in Section 2. We then describe our
basic two-sector, two-country, neoclassical model in Section 3.

In Section 4,

we discuss calibration of the model3 and the implications of the model when it
is subjected to productivity shocks, as measured by Solow residuals.
We find that when the basic model is driven by technology shocks or Solow
residuals, it has several implications that are glaringly at odds with empirical
observations.

Although the model performs quite well in most dimensions, it

fails to replicate observations on the correlation of consumption across
countries and the co-movements of prices and quantities. We argue that the model
cannot satisfactorily account for those observations without a different source
of exogenous disturbances - - disturbances that look like shocks to tastes (or
possibly shocks to fiscal policies, which have similar effects).
When the model is extended to include random shocks to preferences (Section

5), we find that most of these glaring inconsistencies ~ a n i s h . ~
Though there
are some features of the data that the model cannot explain, in an overall sense
the model is consistent with most of the empirical evidence. We conclude from
this study that shocks to technology and t a s t e s (or something essentially
equivalent) are required to explain the main features of business cycles and

3 ~ e
calibrate the model and simulate it in order to study its main areas
of consistency or inconsistency with empirical observations. Although the model
turns out to be remarkably successful in most ways, there are several places
where it clearly misses some important element. As a result, we do not formally
estimate or test hypotheses about the model; that is reserved for the future,
after additional theoretical work and model development.
4~enzivinga(1987) has previously studied taste shocks in a real business
cycle model. Benhabib, Rogerson and Wright (1990a,b) have recently studied a
real business cycle model with "productivity" shocks to household production,
which are very much like shocks to preferences.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

4

their international transmission. This paper shows some of the characteristics
that such taste shocks must have in order to successfully match the data. The
paper also highlights some interesting puzzles that should be the focus of future
research.

2. Empirical Regularities
We focus attention on annual data for the seven largest industrial
countries:

Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, the United Kingdom and the

United States.

A major source of our data is the International Sectoral Data

Base, compiled by the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
(OECD).

We also draw on data from the OECD Main Economic Indicators and the OECD

Quarterlv Accounts.

A complete description of the data sources appears in

Appendix A.
All empirical estimates referred to in the text of this paper are based on
data detrended using the Hodrick-Prescott filter. Results based on data filtered
by first-differencing appear in Appendix B.

To get a sense of the effect of

applying the Hodrick-Prescott filter, Figures 1 and 2 show the raw time series
and the Hodrick-Prescott-filtered time series of U.S. output of traded and
nontraded goods.

The International Renularities
There are several features of the data that a model of the international
transmission of business cycles should explain.

First, the correlation of

output growth across countries is large and positive.

Part A of Table 1 shows

the cross-country correlations of output based on data detrended using the
Hodrick-Prescott filter: The top number in each element of the table shows the

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

5
correlation between aggregate output in the two countries, the middle number
shows the cross-country correlation between traded-good outputs, and the bottom
number shows the correlation between nontraded-good outputs. The correlations
between aggregate outputs are positive and range from 0.437 between Canada and
Japan to 0.858 between the United States and Germany, with an average of 0.69.
The sectoral correlations are slightly lower on average than the aggregate
correlations.
Second, the cross-countrycorrelations of consumption are positive but
generally smaller than the cross-countrycorrelations of output. Table 2 reports
cross-country correlations of consumption based on data from International
Financial Statistics

(m), published

by IMF, and data reported by the OECD.

Despite the high correlations between output growth rates across countries, the
correlations between consumption growth rates are surprisingly low, particularly
in the IFS data. In the OECD data, the correlation between aggregate consumption
ranges from 0.028 between the United States and France to 0.822'between Japan and
France;

the

average

is

0.50.'

The

cross-country correlation between

consumptions of nontraded goods is smaller on average (0.30) than that between
consumptions of traded goods (0.42), though on a country-by-countrybasis this
ordering is sometimes reversed.
The low cross-country correlations of consumption pose a problem for twocountry neoclassical models which assume that financial markets are well
integrated. In many such models (with complete markets and without distortions),
consumption is perfectly (or nearly perfectly) correlated across countries.

5 ~ Part
n
B of Table 2, the top figure in each cell is the cross-country
correlation between aggregate consumptions, the second figure is between private
final consumptions, the third is between consumption of traded goods and the
fourth is between consumption of nontraded goods.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

6
Backus, Kehoe and Kydland (1989) study a one-sector, two-country model in which
consumption is imperfectly correlated across countries because leisure and
consumption are good substitutes in utility.

In this setting, a persistent

productivity shock in the home country raises the domestic marginal product of
labor and reduces leisure.

Because leisure and consumption are substitutes,

equilibrium consumption in the home country rises more than in the foreign
country (or falls less), breaking the close link between foreign and domestic
consumption. This is one of several mechanisms that break the link between home
and foreign consumption in our model. The fact that consumption is less closely
correlated across countries than is output is related to the much-discussed
positive relation between national saving and investment (Feldstein and Horioka,
1980; Tesar, 1990; Baxter and Crucini, 1990).
Third, Solow residuals are positively correlated across countries, but are
less positively correlated than outputs (see also Costello, 1990).

residuals for each sector i (i

=

The Solow

aggregate, traded and nontraded) are

where ai is the labor share in each sector, and output, capital and labor are
detrended series. (The estimates of the labor shares used in the calculation of
the Solow residuals are shown in Table 3.)
country correlations of Solow residuals.

Part B of Table 1 reports crossThe Solow residuals are generally

positively correlated, but are notably smaller than the output correlations for

6~ackus,Kehoe and Kydland (1989) and Tesar (1990) also present evidence
on the cross-country correlations of consumption and output.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

all pairs of countries except the United States and Canada. The average crosscountry correlation of aggregate Solow residuals is 0.33, compared to 0.64 for
output. The average cross-country correlations of Solow residuals for the traded
and nontraded sectors of the economy are 0.27 and 0.25, respectively, while the
corresponding average output correlations are 0.56 and 0.58.'

This evidence

casts doubt on the view that positively correlated Solow residuals are the sole
explanation for international co-movements of output. It suggests either that
other

exogenous disturbances help

to

create the

stronger cross-country

correlation of output, or that a model must endogenously amplify the effects of
the underlying disturbances to productivity.
Fourth, the balance of trade surplus and current account surplus are
countercyclical (see also Backus, Kehoe and Kydland, 1989).

The second and third

columns of Table 4 show the correlations between the trade balance or current
account and aggregate output for five countries. The average correlations are
-0.34 and -0.43, respectively. Because the trade balance can be negative, and
we want to compare results using the Hodrick-Prescott filter with results using
the growth-rate filter, we define the trade balance as detrended exports minus
detrended imports rather than as the detrended difference.
definition consistently in the data and in the model.

We employ this

We define the current

account in a similar manner:

7~nterestingly,the correlations between the Solow residuals of Canada and
the United States are higher than the output correlations at both the sectoral
and the aggregate level.
This suggests that models of the international
transmission of the business cycle calibrated to the United States and Canada are
likely to lead to very different conclusions than those incorporating a larger
number of the OECD countries.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

where exports, imports, savings and investment are detrended series.'

The

degree of countercyclicality of the trade balance and the current account is
sensitive to the method of detrending.

(This can be seen by comparing the

figures in Table 4 to those in Table B3 in Appendix B.)'
The first column of Table 4 shows the well-documented, strongly positive
correlation between savings and investment. The last two columns of Table 4 show
the correlations of the terms of trade with output and the trade balance. These
relations are mixed, appearing to be strongly positive in some cases and strongly
negative in other cases.
A summary of the relationships between the real exchange rate and
consumption, output and the trade balance appears in Table 5. We define the real
exchange rate as the ratio of the home Consumer Price Index to the foreign

8~nless otherwise noted, the trade balance and the current account are
treated as in equations (2.2) and (2.3).
This treatment of the data is
consistent with the time series produced by the simulations in Sections 4 and 5.

'
A countercyclical trade balance may seem to contradict the implications of
a model based on productivity shocks. In the case of purely temporary changes
in productivity, consumption-smoothingwould suggest that the country with high
productivitywill increase its net exports. However, persistent shocks raise the
marginal product of capital, which raises investment in the high-productivity
country. If the increase in investment exceeds the increase in output, then the
country with a positive productivity shock initially reduces its net exports.
Eventually, as the exogenous disturbance dies out, the country's net investment
falls and its net exports rise (see Backus and Kehoe, 1988).
In our model, the presence of nontraded goods also contributes to a
countercyclical trade balance. Because there is some complementarity between
traded and nontraded goods, an increase in the output of the nontraded good in
the home country will increase consumption of the nontraded good and increase
demand for the traded good (see Tesar, 1990).

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

9

Consumer Price Index."

There appears to be no consistent co-movement between

these macroeconomic aggregates and the real exchange rate.''

Table 6 reports

standard deviations of the terms of trade, the Consumer Price Index, the trade
balance and the current account.
The presence of nontraded goods provides part of the explanation for the
cyclical behavior of some of these international variables.

Consumption of

nontraded goods breaks the strong link between foreign and domestic consumptions
and contributes to the countercyclical behavior of the trade balance. Nontraded
capital goods help to explain the strong link between domestic investment and
national savings (Tesar, 1990).

This disaggregation also introduces a number of

new dimensions for evaluating the usefulness of our model.

Empirical Renularities within Countries
Perhaps the most striking feature of the data for the seven industrialized
countries is the large share of nontraded goods in their economies.

Following

Kravis, Heston and Summers (1982) as closely as possible, we categorize the 10
sectors reported by the OECD Intersectoral Data Base into traded and nontraded
industries. Table 7 shows the sectors included in the two categories and reports
the share of each of the 10 sectors in 1984 GDP.

Nontraded goods account for

l0l'he rows of Table 5 refer to the output (consumption or trade balance)
of country i, while the columns are the real exchange rates, defined as the ratio
of the Consumer Price Index of country i to that of country j.
lllt is difficult to draw conclusions about the cyclical behavior of the
terms of trade and the real exchange rate in either Hodrick-Prescott-filtered
data or first-differenced data. However, it may be possible to use the results
from specific countries in a study calibrated to a particular pair of countries.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

about half of output.12
reported by

This corresponds closely with the 52 percent share

Kravis, Heston and Summers for their 10-country sample of

industrialized countries.13
Table 8 shows the standard deviations of output, the capital stock, work
effort, investment and the estimated Solow residuals. Part B of the table shows
the standard deviations of these series relative to the standard deviations of
output in each sector. The standard deviations of the Solow residuals in each
industry are approximately the same magnitude as the standard deviations of
output in that industry, and are higher in the traded than in the nontraded
sector. Investment is two to three times as variable as output in most countries
and in both industries, while labor is less variable than output. Interestingly,
fluctuations in the capital stock appear to be much larger in the nontraded-goodproducing industry than in the traded-good-producing industry.l4
The shares of nontraded goods in private final consumption in the seven

1 2 good
~
case can be made that most retail services - - retail and wholesale
trade, and services of restaurants and hotels - - should be considered nontraded
goods. We include value added of retail and wholesale trade in the traded-good
category to be consistent with Kravis, Heston and Summers. They, however, treat
restaurants and hotels as nontraded goods. We include restaurants and hotels in
our measure of traded goods because the data are not reported for all countries,
and the share of restaurants and hotels in total GDP is small enough (less than
3 percent) that this should have little effect on the overall results. Kravis,
Heston and Summers also treat public transportation and communication as
nontraded goods. We treat them as traded goods because we lack data to separate
these categories from private automobile purchases, which is the largest
component of the transportation category.

13see World Product and Income: International Com~arisonsand Real GDP,
Tables 6-10, p. 194.
14~otethat this is true of the capital stock series but not generally of
the investment series. This may be due to the method used by the OECD to
estimate the gross capital stock from investment time series. In assessing the
simulation results, we will focus on the investment data rather than on the
capital data.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

OECD countries are shown in Table 9. We estimate these shares in two ways. One
estimate treats services and nontraded goods as equivalent. The second measure
is based on a breakdown of private consumption expenditure by type, following as
closely as possible the decomposition specified by Kravis, Heston and Summers.
When services are used as a proxy, the data indicate that nontradables are a
large and growing component of consumption. By the 1980s, services accounted for
roughly 50 percent of private final consumption, while the second measure of
nontradables indicates a share closer to one-third.15 The second measure is a
smaller number because several of the categories consideredby Kravis, Heston and
Summers to be nontradables are not reported by the O E C D . ~ ~ he measure for the
United States is based on data from Citibase, which include all of the relevant
categories (see footnote [f] in the table) and are consistent with the measure
based on services.
Finally, the standard deviations of consumption by sector are provided in
Table 10. For five of the six countries, consumption of the traded good appears
to be more volatile than consumption of nontradables.

Interestingly, a

comparison of the data in Tables 10 and 8 suggests that consumption of traded
goods is nearly as volatile or, in some cases, even more volatile than output of

150ne problem with using services as a proxy for nontradables is that trade
in some types of services has been increasing. In the United States, there is
evidence that trade in services has expanded at a rate faster than the increase
in output of services. However, most services were generally nontraded in the
sample covered by this paper.
1 6 ~ h esecond measure of nontradables includes the categories "rent, fuel
and power" and "transportation and communication" reported by the OECD. To the
extent that transportation includes the purchase of automobiles, inclusion of
this category clearly overstates the importance of nontradables in private
consumption. However, since the other categories included in the Kravis-HestonSummers definition of nontradables are unavailable, we believe that the overall
figure underestimates, rather than overestimates, the share of nontradables in
consumption.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

12
traded goods.
The large proportion of nontraded consumption and output is consistent with
the relative importance of trade in these economies. On average, trade is about
20 percent of aggregate output (see Table 11).

In contrast, a simple model in

the tradition of Lucas (1982), abstracting from nontradables, would predict that
trade is half of output. Investment is approximately 20 percent of output.
The inclusion of nontraded goods in our theoretical model allows us to
consider the co-movements of variables across sectors over the business cycle.
The third column of Table 12 shows the correlation between the price of nontraded
goods (relative to traded goods) and the ratio of consumption of nontraded to
traded goods.

We find the correlation to be negative, with the six-country

average at -0.42."

The magnitude of this correlation proves to be a problem

for the model based on productivity shocks alone: In such a setting, an increase
in productivity causes an increase in consumption of the good and a large drop
in its relative price. The small but positive correlation between the relative
price of nontraded goods and the relative output of nontraded goods runs counter
to models based on productivity shocks or on taste shocks. Table 12 also reports
a strongly positive correlation between consumptions and outputs across
sectors.

3. A Two-Sector. Two-Country Model
In this section, we develop a two-sector,two-countrymodel to account for

17The corresponding number for data using the growth-rate filter is -0.2.
18~ableB9 in Appendix B shows the correlations between consumption and
investment with output inHodrick-Prescott-filtered data and in first-differenced
data. Some of these data will be used in evaluating the simulation results.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

13
the cyclical properties of the data outlined in Section 2. Our research builds
on the work in several recent papers on international real business cycles
(Dellas, 1986; Backus, Kehoe and Kydland, 1989 ; Ahmed, Ickes, Wang and Yoo, 1989 ;
Schlagenhauf, 1989; and Baxter and Crucini, 1990).
In this paper, countries are assumed to be linked via trade in some types
of consumption goods and trade in financial assets. The model is based on Lucas
(1982) as extended to include nontraded goods in Stockman and Dellas (1989), and
adds production and investment. We assume that each country is specialized in
the production of a tradable commodity and that it produces a nontraded good for
domestic consumption and investment. We study the implications of the model for
both the behavior of aggregate macroeconomic variables

--

including quantities

and relative prices - - and the co-movements of variables across sectors and
across countries.

Rather than emphasizing the differences in countries'

production structures or factor endowments, we focus instead on the large degree
of symmetry in the cyclical behavior of the industrialized countries.

To do

this, we calibrate the model to an "average" industrialized country. Our model
can be thought of as an attempt to capture the dynamic interactions between two
similar industrialized economies.
In this setup, each country produces two goods:

one for trade in

internationalmarkets,and a second for domestic consumption and investment. The
home country is specialized in the production of good 1 (denoted by Y Tt ,which
it produces by combining domestic labor and a capital good specific to that
industry :

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Output of the traded good is subject to a random disturbance of total factor
productivity, A ~ . The economy grows at a constant rate of Y through laboraugmenting technical progress; we assume that the productivity shocks are
transitory deviations from this steady-state growth path.

Capital depreciates

at a rate of 6 , so capital and investment are related by:

The steady-state level of investment is then related to the trend growth rate and
the depreciation rate:

Production of the nontraded good in the home country requires inputs of
labor and a specialized capital good, and is also subject to random disturbances
to productivity:

Investment and capital in the nontraded-good sector are related by:

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

We assume equal rates of technical progress and depreciation of the capital
stocks in the two industries.
Labor is mobile between the traded-good and nontraded-good sectors. We
normalize each

country's population

and

the

endowment

of

time

of

the

representative household in each country at one, so the labor constraint is

The foreign country has symmetric technologies for producing its traded and
nontraded goods, and faces a similar labor constraint.
The representative household in the home country derives utility from the
consumption of the good produced by domestic firms, cl, the good produced by
foreign firms, c2, the nontraded good, d, and leisure, L.

At date t, the

household chooses a lifetime (contingent) plan of consumption and work effort to
maximize its expected lifetime utility subject to a wealth constraint:19

19we assume that the household faces a complete contingent claims market.
More specifically, contracts can be written contingent on outcomes in both the
traded- and nontraded-good industries, which allows the household to insure
partially against fluctuations in leisure and in the local supply of nontraded
goods. The household's wealth constraint has the obvious form for complete
contingent markets. Rather than solving for the equilibrium directly, we solve
a social planning problem corresponding to the competitive equilibrium in which
the countries are assumed to have equal wealths.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

In a similar way, the representative consumer in the foreign country chooses
plans for

(

*

*

cl, c2, d*, L * )to maximize lifetime utility subject to its wealth

constraint.
In equilibrium, the world supply of each good must be exhausted by world
consumption and investment demand for each good.

In the market for the home-

produced traded good, output must be equal to consumption of the home good in the
two countries, plus investment of the good in next period's production:

Equation ( 3 . 8 ) is the symmetric market-clearing condition for the foreignproduced traded good:

The equilibrium conditions for the nontraded-good industries require that
the domestic supply of the good be exhausted by domestic consumption and
investment demand:

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Y * = d,NT* + I : ~ * .

We can solve for the equilibrium allocations of consumption, leisure, work
effort and capital inputs by considering the problem facing a social planner who
maximizes the expected lifetime utilities of the two representative agents
subject to world market-clearing conditions. That is, the planner chooses the
levels of consumption and investment of each good to maximize:

subject to equations (3.8) through (3.11).

The multiplier on the home country's

utility function, o,is the home country's share of world wealth. We abstract
from effects deriving from differences in country size or wealth by setting o
equal to one-half.20
The disturbances to technology are assumed to follow an AR(1)

process:

, A fl
~ ~presents
*]
a 4x4 matrix describing the
where A is the vector [ A ~ , A ~ ~ , A ~ *and

20~gentsare assumed to trade contingent claims to pool the world supply
of traded goods. National savings (abstracting from capital gains and losses)
in the home country are defined as:

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

18
autoregressive component of the disturbance. The contemporaneous component of
the shock is described by the vector [ E T t E N T t ET*
elements of

E

ENT* ]

.

The variances of the

reflect the exogenous disturbances to each sector.

The

covariances between the elements of E reflect the extent to which the shocks are
common to industries or countries or are global in nature.
We solve for the nonstochastic steady state of the model and approximate
the dynamics of the model in response to exogenous shocks by linearizing the
first-order conditions around the steady state, as described in King, Plosser and
Rebelo (1988).

This approximation yields a system of first-order-difference

equations in the capital stocks and the exogenous disturbances; we solve this
system for the sequences of prices and capital stocks that are consistent with
the transversality conditions. The complete social planner's problem and the
system of linearized first-order conditions appear in Appendix C.

4. Calibration of the Model and Results
To compare our theoretical model with the empirical evidence discussed in
Section 2, we choose specific functional forms to describe preferences and
technology, and estimate parameters for these functional forms consistent with
the steady-statebehavior of an "average" industrialized country. To capture the
dynamics of these economies, we calculate the Solow residuals for a sample of
five countries, including Canada, Germany, Italy, Japan and the United States,
for the years 1970-1986. We then use the properties of these estimated Solow
residuals to run simulations of our theoretical economy.
The parameter values used in the simulations are summarized in Table 13.
We calibrate the model to moments of annual data. The growth rate of aggregate

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

19
output is 2.73 percent per annum, the average trend growth of our five-country
sample in the 1970-1985 period.21 The depreciation rate of capital is set equal
to 10 percent per annum.

The technologies used to produce the traded and

nontraded goods are assumed to be Cobb-Douglas:

where ai equals the average labor share in the seven countries appearing in
Table 14.22 The value of the output of the nontraded-good-producing industry
( f l T y N T )is set equal to the value of the output of the traded-good-producing
industry (PTY T ) so that nontraded goods comprise half of output, consistent
with the figures in Table 2. These restrictions imply a steady-state allocation
of work effort of 52.1 percent to the traded-good industry and 47.9 percent to
the nontraded-good industry.
We assume that preferences of the representative household in the home
country take the form:

21This is the average of the trend components for the five countries when
the trend is calculated with the Hodrick-Prescott filter. The average annual
growth rate for the five countries is 3.07 when calculated from first-differenced
data.
22~able 14 shows the labor shares in the traded- and nontraded-goods
industries. Interestingly, for five of the seven countries, the traded-goodproducing sector appears to be more labor intensive than the nontraded-goodproducing sector.
Italy and Japan have the lowest labor shares in both
industries, while the United States and the United Kingdom have the highest labor
shares.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

This form ensures the existence of a steady state (namely, an allocation of time
to work effort and leisure that is constant over time) with continuing laboraugmenting technical change.
Following Kravis and Lipsey (1987, footnote 12, p. 130), we estimate the
elasticity of substitution between traded and nontraded goods from the crosssectional data provided in the World Bank's Income Comparison

We

find that there is a low degree of substitutability in consumption, with an
elasticity of substitution [l/(l+p)]

of 0.44. The rate of time discount is set

equal to 0.96 and the intertemporal elasticity of substitution (l/o) is set equal
to 0.5.24 The intertemporal elasticity of substitution in leisure (l/a) is set
equal to -3.173,which is consistent with a steady-state allocation of 20 percent
of the time endowment to work effort and 80 percent to leisure.
These parameters determine the steady-state shares of consumption and
investment in output of the two goods.

The remaining parameter value to be

chosen is the share of domestic goods in the domestic consumer's

total

consumption bundle. This share is difficult to estimate directly from the data;
however, under the assumption of complete specialization, the share can be
inferred from data on trade flows between the industrialized countries.

As

2 3 ~ ecalculate the elasticity of substitution between traded and nontraded
goods in a sample of 30 countries using data on per capita GDP (World Product and
Income, p. 12), expenditure shares on traded and nontraded goods (ibid, p. 194)
and price indices for traded and nontraded goods (ibid, p. 196).
24~ifferent values of o result in the expected changes in aggregate
consumption and investment behavior, but have little impact on the features of
the data studied here.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

21

discussed in Section 2, since investment is about 20 percent of GDP, about half
of investment is allocated to the nontraded-good industry, and nontraded goods
are about half of GDP, 40 percent of GDP remains for consumption of traded goods.
With perfect pooling of traded goods, this implies that trade is 20 percent of
GDP, which is consistent with the data. The volume of trade implied by our model
is

Trade = (112)0 (1-ST),

GNP

where "trade" is defined as the average of exports plus imports and

ST is the

investment share in total output of the domestic traded good. Referring back to
Table 11, the bottom rows indicate the trade flows implied by different trade
shares.

Interestingly, a share equal to 0.5, i.e., equal shares of the home-

traded good and the foreign-tradedgood in each country's consumption bundle, has
the closest fit to the volume of trade in these c o u n t r i e ~ . ~ ~
The technology shocks to the two industries display a low degree of
persistence when

calculated from

Hodrick-Prescott-filtered data.26

The

estimated autocorrelation matrix for the vector of shocks [AT,ANT,AT*,ANT*]
is

250ur model does not address the fact that the share of trade in GDP has
been growing over time in most countries, but treats the volume of trade in
output as a constant. Our model does, however, suggest that in the presence of
nontraded goods and specialized production, the long-run share of trade in output
is likely to level off at a number significantly less than one-half.
2 6 ~ h eestimated autocorrelation and variance - covariance matrices based on
data that are log-linear detrended are reported in Appendix D.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

The degree of autocorrelation is quite low, especially in the traded-good
industry.

The estimated variance-covariance matrix of the contemporaneous

component of the shock is

The disturbances to the traded-good industry are nearly twice the magnitude of
the shocks to the nontraded-good industry.

There is little evidence that

disturbances are readily transmitted abroad, and no evidence that industryspecific disturbances are more prominent than country-specificdisturbances. The
correlation between innovations to the traded-good sectors in the two countries
is 0.33, while the correlation between innovations to the nontraded-good sectors
is 0.14. Country-specific innovations (across sectors within a country) appear
to be slightly more significant, with a cross-sector correlation of 0.46.
The results of simulations of the model given these disturbances to
technology are shown in Table 14. The numbers in the column labeled "Data" are
five- country averages of the standard deviations or correlations presented in the
tables referenced in Section 2. We will evaluate our model in terms of these
cross-countryaverages. Centered 95 percent confidence intervals for those data

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

appear in parentheses.27
The results marked Case 1 show the implications of the model driven by
Solow residuals as technology shocks.

The standard deviations of aggregate

variables match the data fairly closely, though the standard deviation of
consumption is only three-fourths its size in the djlta (this is well within the
centered two-standard-deviationband).

The standard deviations of traded-good

aggregates indicate two types of problems: Investment in the traded-good sector
is roughly 30 percent too volatile, and the standard deviation of consumption is
much too small (only one-third of its mean in the data).

The standard deviation

of output of nontraded goods is larger in the model than in the data, while the
standard deviation of consumption of nontraded goods is again well below its mean
in the data. In general, the model matches the standard deviations of the data
reasonably well ; however, the model implies a much lower variability in
consumption than appears in the data.28
The model delivers a good approximation of the correlation between
consumption and output, though it overpredicts the correlationbetween investment
and output.

It also matches the correlation between consumption of traded and

nontraded goods. Although the model implies a correlation of output in the two
sectors that is smaller than the mean in the data, the result is within the twostandard-deviationband.
Table 14 also shows that the correlation between the aggregate average
product of labor (APL) and output is, on average for the five countries, 0.76.

27These intervals ignore sampling error in estimating the moments reported
in the earlier tables. The cases with asterisks are those in which an outlying
observation has been omitted.
28~aste shocks are an obvious potential solution to this problem, as we
demonstrate below.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

This correlation ignores variation in hours worked, so it overstates the
appropriate correlation by about 10 percent.29 The model implies a correlation
of 0.69, thereby matching this feature of the data. This is an important result
because the correlation impliedby mostclosed-economy real business cycle models
is too high to match the data.

I

The model fails when it is confronted by price data.

The model predicts

that the correlation between the relative price of nontraded (to traded) goods
and the relative consumption of nontraded (to traded) goods is minus one; the
correlation is -0.42 in the data, with a two-standard-deviationband between
-0.12 and -0.71. The technology shocks driving the model act mainly as relative
supply shocks, leading to shifts in supply curves along rather stable (relative)
demand curves. The data suggest a combination of shifts in the relative supply
and the relative demand curves.

The same problem arises in matching the

correlation between the relative price and relative outputs of traded and
nontraded goods.

29There are several reasons that the 0.76 correlation (which is a fivecountry average) is above the 0.33 correlation for the United States shown in
Prescott (1986).
First, Prescott excludes farm labor, though farm output is
included in overall output. Second, we use a longer sample. These changes alone
raise the U.S. correlation from 0.33 to 0.52. Third, our Table 14 reports
statistics on annual rather than quarterly data. For the United States, this
raises the correlation from 0.52 to 0.76. Fourth, we lack data on variations in
hours, so our labor series is employment. In the United States, using employment
rather than total hours raises the correlation from 0.76 to 0.87.
(At a
quarterly frequency, it raises the correlation from 0.52 to 0.79. ) So, based on
U.S. data, our use of employment rather than hours implies about a 10 percent
overstatement of the correlation. Hours variation appears to be much more
important relative to employment variation in the other countries in our sample;
see, e.g., Kennan (1987).
So, because the labor input appropriate to our
theoretical model is total hours, we would like the model to imply a correlation
that is no more than 10 percent smaller than the 0.76 correlation appearing in
Table 14, and ideally, smaller than that. Though the model in Case 1 matches
this 10 percent reduction, the other cases discussed below imply smaller
correlations that appear to be more consistent with the average experience in our
sample.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

25
In terms of international data, the model does a good job of matching the
correlation between aggregate output across countries. However, it overpredicts
the cross-country correlation of consumption by more than 50 percent. The model
slightly overstates the correlation between savings and investment,but is within
the two-standard-deviationband. It does quite well at matching the correlation
between

output

and

the

balance

of

trade, though

it

understates

the

countercyclical nature of the current account.30 The model's predictions for
the standard deviations of trade variables - - the terms of trade, trade balance
and current account

--

are much too low.

Overall, the model driven by Solow residuals has several problems. One of
these problems, the high cross-country correlation of consumption, was already
known to be present in one-sector models.

This observation motivated our

disaggregation into traded and nontraded sectors ; this disaggregation introduced
a number of new dimensions for testing the model. While the disaggregated model
provides more reasonable predictions for the correlation between consumptions
across countries, the countercyclical behavior of the trade balance and the
current account, and the correlations between quantities across sectors, the
model fails to predict the magnitude of the variability of consumption and the
co-movements between quantities and prices.

The next section shows that some,

though not all, of these problems vanish if the model is subject to taste shocks
as well as productivity shocks.

30~hemodel's ability to produce strongly countercyclical movements in the
trade balance and the current account is a direct consequence of the
incorporation of nontraded-goods production and the complementarity between
consumption of traded and nontraded goods. In one-sector models, the trade
balance is generally found to be procyclical.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

26
5.

The Effects of Taste Shocks
Table 14 shows simulation results in which the model is subjected to six

different kinds of taste shocks (labeled Cases 2 through 7), as well as to
technology shocks. The economy is identical to the model in Section 4, except
that the utility function is now

where

r (for i

=

1,2,3) is a positive random variable with mean zero

representing a taste shock.

There are three analogous taste shocks for the

representative foreign household. We assume that taste shocks are independent
across countries, that they are independent of technology shocks, and that the
vector r

=

( rl, r2,r3 ) follows a first-order autoregressive process.

Table 15

shows the matrix of autoregression coefficients and the covariance matrix of the
disturbances in each case.

The form of the taste shocks has a simple

interpretation: A unit increase in rl lowers marginal utility of good one by
the same amount as would a unit increase in cl.
In addition to technology shocks, Case 2 subjects the model to taste shocks
for the home-produced traded good. We assume that the variance of rl and the
corresponding taste shock in the foreign country (for their home-produced traded
good),

*

rl, are the same as the variances of the Solow residuals for traded-good

production.

In this sense, Case 2 considers taste shocks that are of the same

magnitude as the technology shocks. However, when the autocorrelation matrix of

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

27
taste shocks is set equal to that of technology shocks, the standard deviations
of consumption remain much too low in the model relative to the data. Therefore,
the

figures

reported

for

Case

2 correspond to

taste

shocks with

an

autocorrelation of 0.9 (per year).
Adding these taste shocks for home-produced traded goods raises the
standard deviation of consumption of traded goods to about its size in the data.
It also raises the standard deviation of labor in the traded sector.

These

shocks have little effect on the nontraded sector, despite the complementarity
between traded and nontraded goods in consumption. The taste shocks raise the
correlation between the relative price and the relative consumption of nontraded
goods from -1 to -0.45,which is much closer to the mean of the data. Adding the
taste shocks also raises slightly the correlation between the relative price and
the relative output of nontraded goods.

The taste shocks reduce the cross-

country correlation of consumption in half, from 0.78, which was above the twostandard-deviationband, to 0.39, which is within that band. This kind of taste
shock does not improve the model's performance for the standard deviation of the
terms of trade or trade balance. However, it does raise the standard deviation
of output to within the two-standard-deviation band of the data.

Not

surprisingly, the shock also results in a correlation between consumption of
traded and nontraded goods that is too small.
Case 3 shows the results of making the taste shocks much smaller but more
autocorrelated.

In this case, the variance of the taste shocks is one one-

hundredth the magnitude of the traded-sector Solow residuals.

The shocks are

nearly permanent, with an autocorrelation of 0.999. Interestingly, the results
of Case 3 are very similar to those of Case 2.
Case 4 considers taste shocks for the nontraded good (along with technology

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

28
shocks).

As in Case 2, we set the variance of the taste shocks for each good

equal to the variance of the Solow residuals in that sector.

We also set the

autocorrelation of the taste shocks equal to that of the Solow residuals.

In

this sense, the taste shocks and technology shocks are the same size.
The nontraded-good taste shocks in Case 4 affect standard deviations mainly
in the nontraded-good sector. The standard deviations of consumption and labor
in that sector are closer to the mean in the data. The correlation between the
relative price and relative consumption of. nontraded goods rises from -1 to
-0.54. The cross-country correlation of consumption falls, but still remains
above the mean in the data. The standard deviations of the trade variables are
too low, the correlations of consumption and output across sectors are too low,
and the standard deviation of consumption of traded goods is much too low.
Case 5 combines the taste shocks from Cases 2 and 4 by setting the taste
shocks for each good equal in size to the productivity shocks in the two sectors.
Case 5 assumes that these shocks are uncorrelated across sectors but are
positively autocorrelated.

The standard deviations of consumption

--

in the

aggregate and in each sector - - are now close to the mean in the data.

The

cross-country correlation of consumption is closer to its mean in the data, as
are the correlations of consumption, investment, the trade balance and current
account with output. The correlation of savings and investment also gets closer
to its mean in the data.

As in Cases 2 and 3, the standard deviation of the

current account is within the two-standard-deviationband in the data.
There are a number of problems with the combined shocks considered in Case
5.

Aggregate labor is too volatile relative to the data, investment in the

traded-good sector continues to be too volatile, the correlations of output and
consumption across sectors are too small, the standard deviations of the terms

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

29
of trade and trade balance are too small, and the correlation of the relative
price of nontradables with relative output continues to be too small.
Case 6 repeats the pattern of taste shocks for both goods considered in
Case

5, but makes

these

shocks more

correlated

across

sectors.

The

contemporaneous correlation is set at 0.5. The primary result is an increase in
the correlation of consumption across sectors.

Otherwise, the results are

similar to those of Case 5.
Case 7 reduces the variance of the taste shocks to one one-hundredth of
their size in Case 5 , and adds higher autocorrelation. The results are better
in some respects than in Cases 5 and 6, and not as good in other respects.

Impulse-Res~onseFunctions
The intuition for some of these results becomes clearer by studying the
impulse-response functions of macroeconomic variables following a one-time
disturbance to tastes and technology.

Figures 3 through 6 show the dynamic

responses of consumption, work effort and investment to a 1 percent (above steady
state) change in productivity and consumer preferences for traded and nontraded
goods. Both types of shocks are assumed to die out at a rate of 20 percent per
year (i.e. , p

=

0.8). The shocks occur only in the home country; the top graphs

show the resulting dynamics in the home country and the bottom graphs show the
response in the foreign country.
Figures 3a and 3b show the responses in the two countries to a disturbance
in the traded-good-producing sector in the home country.

At the time of the

productivity disturbance, work effort in the traded-goodsector rises in response
to the higher marginal product of labor and then gradually decreases as capital
investment in that sector rises. Consumers in both countries consume more of the

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

30
home country's traded good and substitute away from the foreign country's traded
good.

Nontraded-good consumption rises

in both

countries due

to

the

complementarity between traded and nontraded goods.
When the productivity shock occurs in the nontraded-good sector (Figures
4a and 4b), the response of consumption is quite different. Consumption of the
nontraded good rises in the home country, along with investment of the nontraded
capital good. Labor again shifts out of the high-productivity sector, resulting
in an increase in leisure and in greater effort in the traded-good sector. The
consequent increase in output of the home country's traded good leads to an
increase in consumption of that good in both countries.
Figures 5a and 5b reveal that the dynamics following a taste shock are
markedly different from the smooth, bell-shaped curves that follow a productivity
shock. The primary effects are on consumption and work effort; since the shock
in these experiments is "unanticipated" and rapidly diminishes, there is no
incentive for building up the capital stock to respond to the changes in demand.
Work effort rises in the sector where the demand shift occurs and falls in the
other sector. Interestingly, labor rises in the foreign country's traded-good
sector: Foreign consumers shift out of the now more expensive domestic traded
good, increasing demand for their own traded good.
Figures 6a and 6b show the response to an increase in home demand for the
domestic nontraded good. In this case, domestic consumers must increase domestic
output of the nontraded good in order to meet demand.

Work effort in the

nontraded-good sector rises dramatically and falls in the traded-good sector.
As a result, output of the domestically produced traded good falls and
consumption of the good decreases in both countries.

Foreign-country labor

shifts into the traded-good-producingsector as consumers substitute toward c2

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

31
and away from cl.
Overall, the results of these simulation experiments indicate that taste
shocks improve the fit of the model.

Of course, it is easy to improve the fit

when there are free parameters with which to play. However, the central issues
are whether certain types of exogenous shocks, like taste shocks, are required
to explain that data and, if so, what the nature of those shocks must be.

It

seems clear that some features of the data cannot be explained by the model with
productivity shocks alone.

Those shocks cannot explain the high standard

deviations of consumption, the fact that the correlation between the relative
price and the relative consumption of nontraded goods is so far from -1, or the
low correlation between consumptions across countries.
something like them, seem to be required.

Taste shocks, or

These shocks may result from

government policies rather than from changes in tastes, or they may result from
changes in household production technology. The disturbances must affect mainly
consumption, however, and not investment: Investment is already volatile enough
in the pure technology-shock model of Case 1.31
Although we have shown that taste shocks of a particular form can improve
the performance of the model along certain dimensions, there are three dimensions
along which the model fares poorly. First, our model does not explain the high
standard deviations of the terms of trade or balance of trade, though the model
performs better for explaining the standard deviation of the current account.
Second, we have not explained the positive correlation between the relative price
of nontraded goods and relative output (though the taste shocks help in this

3 1 ~ fwhat we have called taste shocks are really the results of fiscal or
monetary policies, it appears that those policies must have their main effects
on consumption rather than on investment!

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

32
dimension).

Third, the taste shocks we have added are inconsistent with the

o'bservedhigh cross-sectoral correlations of consumption and output.

6. Conclusion
We have constructed and simulated a neoclassical macroeconomic model of a
two-country world.

The model matches most of the key features of the data. In

particular, our model is consistent with the observations that the cross-country
correlation of consumption is smaller than that of output, and that the crosscountry correlation of output exceeds that of the Solow residuals. The model is
also broadly consistent with the standard deviations of main economic aggregates
and with those same variables in the traded- and nontraded-good sectors.
model

is consistent with

The

the correlations between aggregate output and

investment, consumption and the trade balance.

It is also consistent with the

correlation between the relative price and the relative consumption of nontraded
and traded goods.
To match the data, we required a model with shocks to t a s t e s as well as to
technologies.

The disturbances that we have interpreted as taste shocks may

actually result from shocks to technology i n the household or from fiscal or
monetary policies. But we require some form of disturbance that, like a taste
shock, acts mainly to shift intersectoral demand in order to explain certain
features of the data that cannot be explained by the technology-shock model.
There are, however, three main observations that our model does not
explain:

the intranational correlation between quantities in the traded and

nontraded sectors, the correlation between relative quantities and relative
prices in those sectors, and the standard deviations of the trade variables.. The
first two of these observations deal with issues suggested by our disaggregation

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

33
i n t o traded and nontraded s e c t o r s .

I t appears t h a t while some form of t a s t e

shock ( o r disturbance with s i m i l a r e f f e c t s ) i s required t o explain the d a t a , we
have not y e t i d e n t i f i e d the precise form t h a t those shocks must take.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

REFERENCES
Ahmed, Shagil, Barry Ickes, Ping Wang, and Sam Yoo, "International Business
Cycles," Working Paper 7-89-4,Pennsylvania State University, 1989.
Backus, David K., and Patrick J. Kehoe, "International Evidence on the
Historical Properties of Business Cycles," Working Paper 402, Federal
Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, 1988.

, and Finn Kydland, "International Borrowing and World
Business Cycles," Working Paper 426R, Federal Reserve Bank of
Minneapolis, 1989.
Baxter, Marianne, and Mario Crucini, "Explaining Savings-Investment
Correlations," Working Paper 224, Rochester Center for Economic
Research, 1990.
Baxter, Marianne, and Alan C. Stockman, "Business Cycles and the Exchange Rate
Regime: Some International Evidence," Journal of Monetary Economics,
vol. 23 (May 1989), pp. 377-400.
Benhabib, Jess, Richard Rogerson, and Randall Wright, "Homework in
Macroeconomics I: Basic Theory," Working Paper, New York University,
1990a.

, "Homework in Macroeconomics I: Aggregate Fluctuations," Working
Paper, New York University, 1990b.
Benzivinga, Valerie, "An Econometric Study of Hours and Output Variation with
Preference Shocks," Working Paper, University of Western Ontario,
1987.
Costello, Donna, "A Cross-Country, Cross-Industry Comparison of the Behavior
of Solow Residuals," chapter 1 of Productivity Growth. the Transfer of
Technology. and International Business Cpcles. Ph.D. dissertation,
University of Rochester, 1990.
Dellas, Harris, "A Real Model of the World Business Cycle,' Journal of
International Money and Finance, vol. 5 (September 1986), pp. 381-94.
Feldstein, Martin, and C. Horioka, "Domestic Saving and International Capital
Flows," Economic Journal, vol. 90 (1980), pp. 314-29.
Gerlach, Stefan, "World Business Cycles under Fixed and Flexible Exchange
Rates," Journal of Money. Credit and Banking, vol. 20 (November 1988),
pp. 621-32.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Greenwood, Jeremy, Zvi Hercowitz, and Gregory W. Huffman, "Investment,
Capacity Utilization, and the Real Business Cycle," American Economic
Review, vol. 78 (June 1988), pp. 402-17.
Heston, Alan, and Robert Summers, "What Have We Learned about Prices and
Quantities from International Comparisons: 1987?" AEA Papers and
Proceedings (May 1988), pp. 467ff.
Kennan, John, "Equilibrium Interpretations of Employment and Real Wage
Fluctuations," NBER Macro Annual (1987), pp. 157-205.
King, Robert G., Charles I. Plosser, and Sergio T. Rebelo, "Production,
Growth, and Business Cycles I: The Basic Neoclassical Model," Journal
of Monetarv Economics, vol. 21 (March/May 1988), pp. 195-232.
Kravis, Irving, Alan Heston, and Robert Summers, "Real GDP per Capita for More
Than One Hundred Countries," Economic Journal, vol. 88 (June 1978), pp.
215-42.

, "International Comparisons of Real Product and Its Composition:
1950-77,"Review of Income and Wealth, vol. 26 (March 1980), pp. 19-66.
, World Product and Income: International Comparisons and Real GDP.
Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press, 1982.
Kravis, Irving, and Robert E. Lipsey, "The Assessment of National Price
Level," in Sven W. Arndt and J. David Richardson, eds., Real-Financial
Linkages among Open Economies. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1987.

, "The International Comparison Program: Current Status and
Problems," manuscript, University of Pennsylvania, November 1989
Kydland, Finn E., and Edward C. Prescott, "Time-to-Buildand Aggregate
Fluctuations," Econometrica, vol. 50 (November 1982), pp. 1345-70.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr., "Interest Rates and Currency Prices in a Two-Country
World," Journal of Monetarv Economics, vol. 10 (November 1982),
pp. 335-60.
Meyer-zu-Schloctern,F.J.M., "An International Sectoral Data Base for Thirteen
OECD Countries," Working Paper 57, Organisation for Economic
Co-operation and Development, Department of Economics and Statistics,
November 1988.
Prescott, Edward, "Theory Ahead of Business-Cycle Measurement," in Real
Business Cvcles, Real Exchange Rates, and Actual Policies,
Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy. New York:
North-Holland, vol. 25 (1986), pp. 11-44.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Figure 2: U .S. Output of Nont r aded Goods

Year
Source:

Authors' calcul ations .

-

Hodrick-Prescott

Filter

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Figure 4a: Home-Country Response to Nontraded-Good Productivity Shock
(ANT)

Poriod

Figure 4b: Foreign-Country Response to Nont raded-Good Productivity Shock
(ANT)

Poriod

Source:

Authors' c a l c u l a t i o n s .

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Figure 3a: Home-Country Response to Traded--Good Productivity Shock
(AT)

Period

Figure 3b: Foreign-Country Response to Traded-Good Productivity Shock
(AT)

Period

Source:

Authors ' cal cul a t i o n s .

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Figure 6a: Home-Country Response to Nontraded-Gmd Taste Shock ( r 3 )

Figwe 6b: Foreign-Country Response to Nontraded-Good Tute Shock ( r 3 )

Source:

Authors' c a l c u l a t i o n s .

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Figure 5a: Home-Country Response to Traded-Good Taste Shock (rl)

Parlod

Figure 5b: Foreign-Country Response to Traded-Good Taste Shock ( r l )

Source:

Authors ' c a l c u l a t i o n s .

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 1: Cross-Country Correlations of Output and Productivity
A. Correlations of Output (1971-1988)
CANADA

USA
4%
T
NT

.679
.737
.318

JAPAN
.525
.379
.530

GERMANY
.858
.839
.713

ITALY
.571
.479
.623

CANADA
Agg
T
JAPAN

GERMANY
Agg
T
NT
B. Correlations of Solow Residuals (1971-1984)

CANADA

JAPAN

GERMANY

ITALY

USA
%
4
T
NT

.718
.770
.546

.441
.092
-.212

.570
.346
.299

.454
.I93
.704

CANADA

JAPAN
Agg
T
NT
GERMANY
Agg
T

Source:

Output and Solow residuals from OECD International Sectoral Data Base.
All data are detrended using the Hodrick-Prescott filter.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 2: Cross-Country Correlations in Consumption
A.

Correlations of Aggregate Consumption (1970-1988)
CANADA

USA

.442

FRANCE
.lo3

ITALY

U.K.

-.581

.533

CANADA
FRANCE
-.003

ITALY

B.

Correlations of Aggregate, Private Final Consumption and Consumption of
Traded and Nontraded Goods (1971-1987)
CANADA

FRANCE

JAPAN

U.K.

USA

CANADA

FRANCE

JAPAN

Source:

Part A is based on IFS annual data. Part B is based on data from the
OECD Ouarterlv Accounts, which are annualized by averaging. All data
are detrended using the Hodrick-Prescott filter.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 3:

Average Labor Shares

(Standard deviations in parentheses)
Period

&regate

CANADA

1970-1984

.650
(.018)

.633
(.023)

FRANCE

1977-1989

.570
(.006)

.646
(.011)

GERMANY

19704985

.593
(.014)

.641
(.022)

JAPAN

1970-1985

.530
(.038)

(.044)

UNITED KINGDOM

1970-1985

.645
(.025)

.680a
(.040)

UNITED STATES

1960-1985

.63 1
(.013)

.661
(.012)

Traded

ITALY

a.

Average for the period 1960-1985.
Source: OECD International Sectoral Data Base.

.544

Nontraded

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 4: Correlations between Savings, Investment, Trade Balance,
Current Account and Output

CANADA

ITALY
61-87

.472

-.444

-.787

-.3 79

-.510

.214

-.379

UNITED KINGDOM

UNITED STATES
60-88

a.
b.

.904

-.412

.589

Terms of trade data available through 1987.
Savings for France is measured as GDP less aggregate consumption, since
annual GNP data were not reported in the
Source: Columns 1, 2 and 3 are from IFS annual data. Terms of trade is
defined as the ratio of the import deflator to the export deflator.
Terms of trade data are taken from the OECD Main Economic Indicators.
All series are detrended using the Hodrick-Prescott filter.

m.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 5: Correlations of Output, Consumption and
the Trade Balance with the Real Exchange Rate, 1970-1987
A. O u t ~ u t

GDP

FRA

GBR

USA

CAN

FRA

GBR

USA
-

-

,551

.037

-.555

CAN

CAN

-

FRA

-.687

ITA
-

-.431

GBR

.528

USA

.256

B. Consumvtion
Cons
CAN
FRA
-

-.533

-

-.317

-.616

ITA

-.236

.I12

-.426

-.I16

GBR

.726

.671

-

USA

-357

.380

.076

-582

C. Trade Balance
TB

CAN

FRA

ITA

GBR

USA

.212

-487

CAN

-

FRA

-.030

-

.280

.078

-009

ITA

-.I46

.051

-

,062

-087

GBR

-.338

-.I86

-.I89

-

-.I23

-.236

-

USA

.061

Source:

IFS annual

-.551

-332

-.388

.I65

data, 1970-1988. Output, consumption and the real
exchange rate are Hodrick-Prescott filtered. The trade balance is
measured as exports less imports. where both series are
Hodrick-Prescott filtered. The real exchange rate is defined as the
ratio of the domestic Consumer Price Index to the exchange-rateadjusted foreign Consumer Price Index.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 6: Standard Deviations of International Variables

Countrv

Time
Period

TOT

CPI

TB

CA
-

CANADA
60-88
70-88

3.27
3.94

5.05
5.59

4.71
5.41

4.54
4.86

60-88
70-88

4.87
5.83

5.77
6.43

4.64
4.31

3.55
3.93

60-88
70-88

4.48
5.43

9.36
10.49

5.86
6.96

6.85
8.19

60-88
70-88

5.36
6.19

5.21
5.60

6.95
8.02

3.49
4.02

FRANCE

ITALY

UNITED KINGDOM

UNITED STATES

Source:

Column 1 is taken from the OECD Main Economic Indicators. Columns 2
through 4 are taken from
All data are detrended using the
Hodrick-Prescott filter.

m.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 7: Shares of GDP by Sector, 1984
CAN
-

FRA

GER

ITA

Ag-riculture

.03

.04

.02

.05

Manufacturing

.19

.25

.33

Mining

.06

n.a.

Transportationb

.07

Traded

U.K.

U.S.
-

.03

-02

.02

.27

.29

.23

.21

.01

n.a.

-0

.08

.03

.05

.06

.07

.06

-07

.50

.48

.53

.54

.53

.52

Electricity, Gas
and Water

.03

.05

.03

.05

.03

.03

Construction

.06

.06

.06

.08

.07

.06

Finance, Insurance
and Real Estate

-19

.19

.13

n.a.

.15

.19

Private servicesC

.05

.09

.13

-19

-13

.05

Gov't. Services

.16

.13

.12

-14

.08

.15

Nont raded

.50

.52

.47

.46

.47

.48

JAPAN

a. Includes wholesale and retail trade, restaurants and hotels.
b. Includes transport, storage and communication.
c. Includes community, social and personal services.
Source: OECD International Sectoral Data Base.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 8: Volatility of Macroeconomic Variables
A.

Standard D e v i a t i o n s of Annual Time S e r i e s (1970-1986)

Solow
Residualsa
CANADA

GERMANY

ITALY

JAPAN

U.S.
-

5-COUNTRY AVERAGE

C a ~tal
i

Labor

Investment

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 8: Volatility of Macroeconomic Variables (cont.)

B.

Ratio of Standard Deviations of Variables to the Standard Deviations of
Output

Solow
Residuals a

C a ~t a1
i

Labor

Invest men t

CANADA

GERMANY

ITALY

JAPAN

U.S.
-

a.

The Solow residuals are estimated from capital, labor and output data,
which are detrended using the Hodrick-Prescott filter.
Source: OECD International Sectoral Data Base. Data are detrended using the
Hodrick-Prescott filter. Standard deviations are calculated over the
period from 1970 to the last available observation.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 9: Shares of Nontraded Goods in Consnmption
A. Services as a Share of Private Final Consumption

CANADA
FRANCE
ITALY

JAPAN^
UNITED KINGDOM
UNITED STATES

UNITED

STATES^

B. Expenditure on Nontradablesd as a Share of Private Final Consumption
CANADA

n.a.

n.a.

n.a.

FRANCE

.22se

n.a.

.350

ITALY

n.a.

n.a.

.271

JAPAN

n.a.

.249

.280

UNITED KINGDOM

.I89

.223

.259

.363

.392

.443

UNITED
a.
b.
c.

STATES^

Private final consumption includes net direct purchases abroad and gifts.
Average for the period 1975:l-1979:4.
Data from Citibase; expenditure on services (private plus government) as a
share of total consumption.
d. Expenditure on "rent, fuel and power" and "transportation and
communication" used as proxies for expenditure on nontradables.
e. Average for the period 1966:l-1974:4.
f. Based on Citibase data. Calculated as the share of clothing and shoe
repair. personal care (barbershops, etc.). housing, household utilities,
medical care, personal business, auto repair. local and intercity public
transportation, and education expenditures in total personal consumption
expenditures.
Source: OECD Quarterly Accounts.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 10: Standard Deviations of Consumption
Time
Period

Country
CANADA

60-88
70-88

FRANCE

60-88
70-88

ITALY

60-87
81-87

JAPAN

61-88
71-87

GREAT BRITAIN

60-88
70-88

UNITED STATES

60-88
70-88

Source:

Private Final
Consum~tion

Traded

Nontraded

OECD guarterlv Accounts. U.S. data from Citibase. Data are
converted from quarterly to annual time series by taking annual
averages. The annual data are detrended using the Hodrick-Prescott
filter

.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 11: Long-run Shares of Investment, Consumption
and Trade in GDP

CANADA

ITALY

UNITED KINGDOM

UNITED STATES

Five-Count rv Avg,

Model

Source:

IFS annual data. Trade (column 3) is defined as the average of
nominal exports plus nominal imports.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 12: Correlations Between Prices and Quantities

a. Output data available through 1986.
b. Output data available through 1984.
c. Output data available through 1985.
Source: Columns 1 and 2 are from the OECD Ouarterlv Accounts. Columns 2 and
4 are from the OECD Intersectoral Data Base. All series are
detrended using the Hodrick-Prescott filter.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 13: Parameter Values
Technolonv

7 = 2.73

Rate of technical progress (percent per annum)

6 = .10

Depreciation rate

sT (=s NT ) = 0.5

Share of production of traded ( and nontraded ) goods in
total output

aT = 0.61

Labor share in traded-good industry

aNT= 0.56

Labor share in nontraded-good industry

vT = 0.521

Share of work effort allocated to traded-good production

vNT = 0.479

Share of work effort allocated to nontraded-good production

l / a = -3.173

Intertempord elasticity of substitution in leisure

Preferences
9 = 0.5

Home country's share of world wealth

p = 0.96

Rate of time preference

l / a = 0.5

Intertempord elasticity of substitution

1/1+p = 0.44

Elasticity of substitution between-traded and nontraded goods

8 = 0.5

Share of domestically produced goods in consumer's bundle of
traded goods

Source:

Authors.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

TABLE 14: SIMULATION RESULTS
Standard Deviations:
Data:
-

Variable
Aggregate:
Output:
Capital:
Labor:
Investment :
Consumption:
Traded-Good Sector:
Output:
Capital:
Labor:
Investment:
Consumption:

3.45
2.50
2.17
7.02
3.32

Nontrade&Good Sector:
Output:
Capital:
Labor:
Investment:
Consumption:

1

2.02
6.51
2.78

2.38,
1.85,
1.34,
5.26,
2.29,

4.52
3.15
3.00
8.78
4.35

1.48,
3.28,
0.82,
5.20,
2.04,

2.56
4.00
1.90
7.82
3.52

Case 1
Model:

Case 2
Model:

2.86
2.97
6.13
1.86

2.89
3.03
1.20
6.19
1.89

0.92
0.95
0.83
0.45
0.69
0.85

0.89
0.92
0.38
0.38
0.54
0.77

Domestic Correlations:

y Correlations:

-0.42*
0.28

(-71 -.I21
(.07, .49

2:::

-0.45
-0.52

International Variables:
Correlations:

0.49, 0.78
0.25, 0.75

Standard Deviations:
s.d. TOT)
s.d.[TB1
s.d. CA

5.66
6.63
6.07

1

1

4.56, 6.76
4.88, 8.38
3.55, 8.59

2.05
0.45
2.61

2.56
0.57
3.88

Case 3
Model:

Case 4
Model:

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

TABLE 14: SIMULATION RESULTS (cont.)
Standard Deviations:
Variable

Case 1
Model:

Data:

Aggregate:
Output:
Capital:
Labor:
Investment:
Consumption:
Traded-Good Sector:
Output:
Capital:
Labor:
Investment:
Consumption:
Nontraded-Good Sector:
Output:
Capital:
Labor:
Investment :
Consumption:

3.45
7.02
3.32
2.02
6.51
2.78

2.38,
1.85,
1.34,
5.26,
2.29,

4.52
3.15
3.00
8.78
4.35

1.48,
3.28,
0.82,
5.20,
2.04,

2.56
4.00
1.90
7.82
3.52

Domestic Correlations:

Correlations:
4 . 4 2 * (-.711 -.I21
0.28
(.07, -49
International Variables:
Co~tions:

Standard Deviations:
s.d.. TOT)
s.d.[TBi
s.d. CA

1

5.66
4.56, 6.76
66.07
. 6 3 14.88, 8.38
3.55, 8.59

Source : Authors ' calculations .

Case 5
Model:

Case6
Model:

Case 7
Model:

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 15: Technology and Taste Shocks Used in Simulations

Case I: Solow Residuals only:
Variance-Covariance Matrix of Productivity Shocks:

Autocorrelation Matrix of Productivity Shocks:

Case 2 Taste Shocks for Home-Produced Traded Good:
Vaxiandovariance Matrix of Preference Shocks:

Autocorrelation Matrix of Preference Shocks:

Case 3 S m d Taste Shocks for Home-Produced Traded Good:
Vaxiance-Covariance Matrix of Preference Shocks:

Aut ocorrelation Matrix of Preference Shocks:

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 15:

Technology and Taste Shocks Used in Simulations (cont.)

Case 4: Taste Shocks for Nontraded Goods:
Variance-Covariance Matrix of Preference Shocks:

Autocorrelation Matrix of Preference Shocks:

Case 5 T a t e Shocks to Home-Produced Goods:
Variancecovariance Matrix of Preference Shocks:

Autocorrelation Matrix of Preference Shocks:

Case 6: Taste Shock to Home-Produced Goods, Correlated across Goods:
Variance-Covariance Matrix of Preference Shocks:

Autocorrelation Matrix of Preference Shocks:

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 15:

Technology and Taste Shocks Used in Simulations (cont.)

Case 7: SmaU Taste Shocks to Home-Produced Goods:
Variance-Covariance Matrix of Preference Shocks:

Autocorrelation Matrix of Preference Shocks:

Source:

Authors ' cal cul ations .

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

APPENDIX A:

Description of the Data Sources

The International Sectoral Data Base compiled by the OECD provides
time-series data on output, employment, investment, capital stocks and factor
payments by sectors for 13 OECD countries. The sector classification is based
on the ISIC. Gross capital stocks are estimated from investment data,
allowing for varying rates of depreciation across countries and across
sectors. For a detailed description of the estimation procedure, see
Meyer-zu-Schloctern(1988, pp. 2-6). We construct time series for
productivity growth in the traded- and nontraded-goods-producing sectors from
constant-price,domestic-currency series of output, capital, compensation of
employees and total number of employees.
We take consumption data from the OECD Ouarterlv Accounts.

We decompose

private final consumption of commodities by type (durables, semidurables,
nondurables and services) and by object (food, beverages and tobacco; clothing
and footwear; gross rent, fuel and power; transportation and communication;
furniture and household operations; and other goods and services).
proxies for consumption of nontradables:

We use two

services from the classification by

type; and gross rent, fuel and power plus transportation and communication
from the classification by object. U.S. data for these categories are taken
from the Citibase database. We construct the relative prices of nontradables
in each of the countries from the price deflators of the service and
nonservice components of consumption. Deseasonalized quarterly data from the
OECD are annualized by averaging.
We take data on aggregate output, investment, savings, net foreign
investment, exports and imports from the International Financial Statistics of
the IMF. We deflate production data using the GNP (GDP) deflator and

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

consumption data using the Consumer Price Index. In some cases, data for the
United States are taken from Citibase. The export and import price deflators
used to calculate the terms of trade are taken from the OECD Main Economic
Indicators.
Unless otherwise noted, empirical results cited in the body of the paper
are based on data detrended using the Hodrick-Prescott filter. Results based
on data detrended by taking first differences (growth rates) appear in
Appendix B.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

APPENDIX B
Table B1: Cross-Country Correlations of Output and Productivity
A.

Correlations of Output (1971-1988)
CANADA

JAPAN

GERMANY

ITALY

USA
At%
T
NT

.693
.746
-.027

.623
.557
.317

.821
.811
.601

.494
.422
.604

CANADA
Agg
T
NT
JAPAN

GERMANY

B. Correlations of Solow Residuals (1971-1 984)
CANADA

JAPAN

GERMANY

ITALY

USA
4%
T
NT

.659
.674
.I48

.486
.370
-.214

,575
.381
.I35

.I51

-. 070

.553

CANADA
At%
T
NT
JAPAN

GERMANY
At%
T
NT
Source:

Output and Solow residuals from OECD International Sectoral Data Base.
All data are logged and first-differenced.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table B2: Cross-Cotmt ry Correlations in Consumption
A. Correlations of Aggregate Consumption (1970-1988)
CANADA
USA

.278

CANADA

FRANCE

-205
.451

FRANCE

ITALY

U.K.

-.432

.321

.052
-.007

ITALY

.086
.I12
-032

B. Correlations of Aggregate, Private Final Consumption and Consumption of
Traded and Nontraded Goods (1971-1988)
CANADA

FRANCE

JAPAN

U.K.

USA

CANADA

FRANCE

JAPAN

Source:

Part A is based on IFS annual data. Part B is based o n data from the
OECD Ouarterlv Accounts, which are annualized by averaging. All data
are first-differenced.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table B3: Correlations between Savings, Investment, Trade Balance,
Cnnent Account and Output

corr(6.i)

c o r r ( T ~ . G ) c O ~ ( C A . Y ~ c o r r ( T 0 T a ~ ) CO~~(TOT%B)

CANADA

60-88

.846

-.339

-.I57

-.422

.001

70-88

.753

.06l

.008

-.359

-.546

ITALY

61-87

.644

-.261

-.664

.256

7212

70-87

.642

-.214

-.722

.293

-.258

-.301

-.I19

-.593

-.390

-.413

.084

UNITED KINGDOM

60-88

.733

-.376

.

UNITED STATES

60-88

a.
b.

.932

-.356

Terms of trade data available through 1987.
Savings for France is measured as GDP less aggregate consumption, since
annual GNP data were not reported in the

Source:

m.

Columns 1, 2 and 3 are from IFS annual data. Terms of trade is
defined as the ratio of the import deflator to the export deflator.
Terms of trade data are taken from the OECD Main Economic Indicators.
All series are first-differenced.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table B4: Correlations of Output, Consumption and
the Trade Balance with the Red Exchange Rate, 1970-1987

A. Output
CAN

FRA

CAN

-

.I11

-.lo3

-.079

-.234

FRA

-.386

-

-.200

-.338

-.476

-.I20

-.037

GDP

ITA

GBR

USA

ITA

.030

.051

-

GBR

.449

.560

.485

-

.419

USA

.053

.203

.I14

.057

-

CAN

FRA

IT A

GBR

USA

CAN

-

.I93

-.044

.083

-.334

FRA

-.254

-

-.400

-. 154

-.354

ITA

-.I87

.I10

-

-.359

-.I71

B.

Consum~tion

Cons

GBR

.687

.696

.661

-

.621

USA

.I70

.250

-217

.098

-

FRA

ITA

GBR

USA

.I46

.035

C. Trade Balance
TB

CAN

CAN

-

-.325

FRA

-.290

-

IT A
-

-.081

-.047

-

GBR

-.328

-.I80

-.I89

USA

-.I21

Source:

IFS annual

.418

-.266
.I42

.255

-.091

-.I91

.043

-.048

-

-. 198

-.312

-

data, 1970-1988. Output, consumption and the real
exchange rate are first-differenced. The trade balance is measured
as exports less imports, where both series are first-differenced.
The real exchange rate is defined as the ratio of the domestic
Consumer Price Index to the exchange-rate-adjusted foreign Consumer
Price Index.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table B5: Standard Deviations of International Variables

Countm

Time
Period

TOT

a3

TB

CA

CANADA
60-88
70-88

3.19
3.81

3.20
2.86

4.84
5.24

5.20
5.27

60-88
70-88

4.46
5.37

3.41
3.30

5.69
6.02

4.33
5.06

60-88
70-88

3.74
4.53

5.09
5.11

5.51
5.91

6.35
6.82

60-88
70-88

4.97
5.70

3.18
3.02

8.12
8.54

3.39
3.96

FRANCE

ITALY

UNITED KINGDOM

UNITED STATES

Source:

Column 1 is taken from the OECD Wain Economic Indicators. Columns 2
through 4 are taken from
All data are detrended by
first-differencing.

m.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table B6: Volatility of Macroeconomic Variables
A.

Standard D e v i a t i o n s of Annual T h e S e r i e s (1970-1986)

Out~ut
CANADA

GERMANY

ITALY

JAPAN

U.S.
-

5-COUNTRY AVERAGE

Solow
Residuals a

C a ~t al
i

Labor

Investment

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table B6:

B.

Volatility of Macroeconomic Variables (cont.)

Ratio of Standard Deviations of Variables to the Standard Deviations
of Output

Solow
Residuals a

C a ~t ial

Labor

Investment

CANADA

GERMANY

ITALY

JAPAN

U.S.
-

a.

The Solow residuals are estimated from first-differenced capital, labor
and output data.
Source: OECD International Sectoral Data Base. Data are detrended by taking
first differences. Standard deviations are calculated over the
period from 1970 to the last available observation.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table B7: Standard Deviations of Consumption
Time
Period

Agerepate

CANADA

61-88
70-88

1.64
1.81

2.08
2.34

2.85
3.37

1.79
1.42

FRANCE

61-88
70-88

1.67
1.35

1.78
1.55

n.a.
1.85

n.a.
1.37

UNITED KINGDOM 61-88
70-88

1.81
2.09

2.24
2.63

n.a.
2.96

n.a.
2.76

UNITED STATES

1.57
1.53

1.66
1.77

2.54
2.78

1.00
0.94

Countrv

Private Final
Consum~tion

Traded

Nontraded

ITALY
JAPAN

Source:

61-88
70-88

OECD Quarterlv Accounts. U.S. data are from Citibase. Data are
converted from quarterly to annual time series by taking annual
averages. The annual data are detrended by taking first differences.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table B8: Correlations between Prices and Quantities

a. Output data available through 1986.
b. Output data available through 1984.
c. Output data available through 1985.
Source: Columns 1 and 3 are from OECD Quarterly Accounts. Columns 2 and 4
are from the OECD Intersectoral Data Base. All series are detrended
using the Hodrick-Prescott filter.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table B9: Domestic Correlations
Hodrick-Prescott-Filtered Data

(C* Y)
CANADA

FRANCE

ITALY

60-87
70-87
GREAT BRITAIN

UNITED STATES

Source:

IFS annual data.

(
I
.
)

First-Differenced Data

(C* Y)

(
I
.
)

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

APPENDIX C:

The Social Planner's Problem

This appendix contains a full description of the social planner's problem
and the first-order conditions as they appear after linearization around the
steady-state equilibrium. The social planner maximizes:

over

in the home country, and over

in the foreign country, subject to 1) the market-clearing conditions for each of
the four goods:

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

2) the four equations describing the evolution of the capital stocks:

I?*

NT*

= YKt+1

-

(1-6)K y * ,

where future capital stocks are augmented by the rate of technical progress, and

3) the labor constraints in each country:

NT* + N f

Equations

* +

*

L~ = 1 .

(C.12)

through

(C.11)

(C.24)

are

the home

country's

first-order

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

conditions for this maximization problem in linearized form.

Maximizing with

respect to the consumption goods and leisure in the home country, we find:

T

~~~e~~

+

~ 1 3 ~ ~t 1 4 =
~ @t
t

~~~e~~

+

e22e2t

+

~233t

eqlelt+

e42e2t

+

~ 4 3 3 t+ ~ 4 4 i t= *tr

+

+

+

T*

~ 2 4 =
~ @t
t

(c.12)

(C. 13)

(C. 15)

where

The first-order conditions for work effort in the two industries are

BT

+

2
:

T -T
• qKNxt

T -T

+

~ ) N N N= ~*t

(C. 16)

(C.17)

where etaij is the elasticity of the marginal product of factor i with respect

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

to factor j .
Total differentiation of the labor constraint yields:

(1-N)
N

it +

VTfi;

+

VNTfi:

= 0,

(C.18)

where N is the (constant) fraction of time allocated to work effort and vi is the
(constant) fraction of time allocated to sector i.
The first-order conditions for choosing next period's capital stocks are

The investment equations and budget constraints in totally differentiated
form are

(C.21)

(C.23)

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

(C.24)

The share parameters, scland scl*,denote the shares of consumption of good 1 in
total output of the home-produced traded good, and :s
the home-traded good allocated to investment.

is the share of output of

Similarly, sd and s,NT are the

shares of the domestic consumption and investment of the nontraded good in total
output of the nontraded good. The parameters s~ and s~ are the capital and labor
shares in each industry.
foreign country.

Symmetric equations are similarly derived for the

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

APPENDIX D:

Simulation Results Based on Growth-Rate-Filtered Data

This appendix contains simulation results based on Solow residuals
calculated from growth-rate-detrended (first-differenced) data.

The estimated

autocorrelation matrix of the Solow residuals is

and the estimated variance-covariance matrix is

Table Dl shows the results of simulations based on these estimates of the
Solow residuals (Case 1) and the effects of adding taste shocks (Cases 2
through 7).

Table D2 provides a catalog of the various taste shocks used in

the simulations.
The results based on first-differenced data are somewhat different from
the Hodrick-Prescott-filtered results.

The standard deviation of aggregate

output is at the upper end of the two-standard-deviation band with
disturbances to productivity alone, while the standard deviation of
nontraded-good output is above the band.

Similarly, the standard deviation of

aggregate labor already exceeds the upper limit of the band.

The correlations

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

between relative prices and quantities are well below the data, and again, the
correlation between consumptions across countries is too large.
Cases 2 through 7 consider taste shocks of roughly the same types
discussed in the text.

The simulation results reveal that these types of

demand shocks introduce a trade-off:

Taste shocks improve the correlations

between prices and quantities, raise the standard deviation of consumption and
reduce the cross-country consumption correlation.

When the shocks are large

enough to produce these effects, however, the standard deviations of labor and
output exceed the two-standard-deviation band, and the correlation between
quantities across sectors is too low.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table Dl: Simulation Results
Standard Deviations:
Variable

Case 1
Model:

Data:

Aggregate:
Output:
Capital:
Labor:
Investment :
Consumption:
Traded-Good Sector:
Output:
Capital:
Labor:
Investment:
Consumption:
Nontraded-Good Sector:
Output:
Capital:
Labor:
Investment:
Consumption:
Domestic Correlations:

Domestic P r i T u a n t i t y Correlations:
-0.28*
1-.67,
PN/PT,CN CT .
PN/PT,YN/YT!
-0.07
-.27,

0.11)
0.14

International Variables:
Correlations:
0.64
0.40

0.51, 0.77
0.18, 0.62
0.67, 0.90

-0.25

Standard Deviations:
s.d. TOT)
8.d.[TBl
8.d. CA

6.02

4.19, 5.93
4.57, 10.87
4.08, 7.96

Case 2
Model:

Case 3
Model:

Case 4
Model:

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table Dl: Simulation Results (cont.)
Standard Deviations:
Variable

Case 1
Model:

Data:

Case 5
Model:

Aggregate:
Output:
Capital:
Labor:
Investment :
Consumption:

Trad*
Sector:
Output:
Capital:
Labor:
Investment:
Consumption:
Nontraded-Gmd Sector:
Output:
Capital:
Labor:
Investment:
Consumption:

3.79

4.24
3.51
2.46
12.69
2.44

7.13
2.81
1.87
3.17
1.26
6.13
1.68

1.38,
1.80,
0.77,
5.02,
0.99,

2.36
4.541
1.75
7.24
2.37

2.77
2.48
1.49
6.80
1.50

2.84
2.73
1.89
7.34
2.30

Domestic Coxrelations:

uantity Correlations:
-0.28'
[-.67,
-.27,
-0.07

International Variables:
Correlations:

Standard Deviations:
s.d. TOT)
s.d.[TB]
s.d. CA

:
6.02

Source: Authors ' calculations.

-1.00
-0.77

-0.46
-0.68

0.51

0.50
0.34
0.86
-0.49
-0.40

4.19, 5.93 1 0 . 2.05
6 2
4.57, 10.87
4.08, 7.96
3.69

2.51
0.64
3.90

0.11)
0.14

Case 6
Model:

Case 7
Model:

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table D2: Technology and Taste Sho& Used in Simnlations
(First-Differenced Data)

Case 1: Solow Residuals only :
Variance-covariance Matrix of Productivity Shocks:

Autocorrelation Matrix of Productivity Shocks:

Case E Taste Shocks for Home-Produced Traded Good:
Variance-Covariance Matrix of Preference Shocks:

Autocorrelation Matrix of Preference Shocks:

Case 3 SmaU Taste Shocks for Home-Produced Traded Good:
Variance-Covariance Matrix of Preference Shocks:

Autocorrelation Matrix of Preference Shocks:

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table D2:

Technology and Taste Shocks Used in Simulations (cont.)
(First-Differenced Data)

Case 4: Taste Shocks for Nontraded Goo&.
Variance-Covariance Matrix of Preference Shocks:

Autocorrelation Matrix of Preference Shocks:

Case 5: Taste Shocks to Home-Produced Goo&
Variandovariance Matrix of Preference Shocks:

Autocorrelation Matrix of Preference Shocks:

Case 6: Taste Shock to Home-Produced Goods, Correlated across Goods:
Variance-Covariance Matrix of Preference Shocks:

Autocorrelation Matrix of Preference Shocks:

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table D2:

Technology and Taste Shocks Used in Simulations (cont.)
(First-Differenced Data)

Case 7: Small T u t e Shocks to Home-Produced Goods:
Variance-Covariance Matrix of Preference Shocks:

Autocorrelation Matrix of Preference Shocks:

Source:

Authors' c a l c u l a t i o n s .