View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/1995/wp9512.pdf

Working Paper 95 12

THE ROLE OF WARRANTS IN
CORPORATE REORGANIZATIONS
by Stanley D. Longhofer

Stanley D. Longhofer is an economist at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland. The author is grateful to
Charles Calomiris, Charles Kahn, and Anne Villamil
for helpful comments.
Working papers of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion
and critical comment. The views expressed herein are
those of the author and not necessarily those of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System.

November 1995

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK D
C-

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/1995/wp9512.pdf

I~~rn~~i~~~
9b0035

Abstract
That a firm's initial equityholders often emerge from Chapter 11 bankruptcy proceedings
with more value than the absolute priority rule would suggest is now a generally accepted
fact. The form in which this value is distributed, however, is less well understood. In
particular, why do the original shareholders of some firms emerge from Chapter 11
bankruptcy with stock in the reorganized firm, while others receive warrants? This essay
proposes that informational asymmetries provide the answer to this question. By
proposing a reorganization plan in which they receive warrants, the original stockholders
of a firm with good future prospects can signal their superior information to the creditors
in a way that firms with poor prospects will not wish to mimic.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/1995/wp9512.pdf

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/1995/wp9512.pdf

1. Introduction
That a firm's initial equityholders often emerge from Chapter 11 bankruptcy proceedings
with more value than the absolute priority rule (APR) would suggest is now a generally accepted
fact.' The form in which this value is distributed, however, is less well understood. Betker
(1991) notes that securities issued to firms' original shareholders during reorganizations are
virtually always in the form of new equity or warrants2 In fact, Franks and Torous (1994) show
that warrants account for, on average, 30 percent of the total payments made during a Chapter

11 reorganization to the bankrupt firm's original preferred stockholder^.^ The purpose of this
essay is to answer the question posed by this fact: Why do the original shareholders of some
firms emerge from Chapter 11 bankruptcy with stock in the reorganized firm, while others
receive warrants?
Chapter 11 bankruptcy law exists to facilitate the reorganization of the firm as an ongoing
concern, as opposed to liquidating its assets in a piecemeal fashion4 Because the firm's future
value is uncertain, its equityholders would like to delay the reorganization as long, as possible;

if, in the intervening period, the firm's prospects improve, it will be able to pay off its debts and
the equityholders will retain the residual value of the firm. This is the well-known "option to

See, for example, Betker (1995), Eberhart, Moore, and Roenfeldt (1990), Franks and Torous (1991),
and LoPucki and Whitford (1990).
This paper was later revised in Betker (1994).
The breakdown of the payments to common stockholders is not presented.
This justification seems well ingrained in the folklore of the Bankruptcy Code; see, for example,
Jackson (1986) and White (1990). Whether it stands up to critical analysis, however, is a different
question.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/1995/wp9512.pdf

delay" inherent in Chapter 11

One reason APR violations occur is to compensate

the firm's equityholders for giving up this delay option so that they will allow the reorganization
to proceed.
The insiders of a firm are likely to have superior information about its future prospects,
compared to other participants in the bankruptcy process. If this information is favorable, the
firm's shareholders would like to credibly convey it to their creditors - the larger the future
revenues of the firm are likely to be, the more valuable their delay option. Conversely,
shareholders of a firm with poor prospects would like to hide this information. By proposing a
reorganization plan in which they receive warrants, the original stockholders of a firm with good
future prospects can signal their superior information to the creditors in a way that firms with
poor prospects will not wish to mimic.
Key to our analysis is the fact that the firm's initial stockholders use the reorganization
process to extract surplus from their creditors. Brown (1989) models the reorganization game
implicit in Chapter 11 and shows that APR violations are driven by the borrower's first-mover
advantage (the exclusivity period given to the debtor for proposing a plan of reorganization); by
being able to offer the first plan of reorganization (which is accepted), equity reaps all the gains
from avoiding further delay. Bebchuk and Chang (1992) carry this idea one step further by
allowing the firm to continue running during the reorganization process. Since there is a chance
that the f m ' s ongoing revenues might be sufficient to pay off its debt obligations, an extended
renegotiation process provides the above-mentioned option value to the initial stockholders. In
this model, APR violations occur not only because of the delay costs avoided in a quick

See, for example, Franks and Torous (1989, 1994) and Bebchuk and Chang (1992).

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/1995/wp9512.pdf

reorganization, but also because equity must be compensated for giving up this option value.
One by-product of our analysis is to show how the "clean slate" of bankruptcy can be
used to look at the firm's capital structure decision (in this case, the choice between equity and
warrants). It is well understood that tax rules, informational asymmetries, and agency conflicts
among stockholders, managers, and bondholders are all important factors in determining how a
firm chooses to finance its investments. But a firm cannot ordinarily fully adjust its capital
structure as these incentives change over time. In order to optimize in the present, a firm may
need to undo a decision made in the past (for instance, by buying back old debt or equity it has
issued). While this may be feasible in some cases, in others it can be quite costly, and as a
result, the firm may end up with a hodgepodge capital structure that does not accurately reflect
its incentives at the moment. Chapter 11 bankruptcy, however, allows the firm to wipe away all
its old debts and stock and issue wholly new securities. Alderson and Betker (1994) take
advantage of this idea and show that fmwith high liquidation costs choose post-reorganization
capital structures that are typically low in debt and that have less restrictive covenant terms.
In the next section, we outline our basic model. Following the analysis of Bebchuk and
Chang (1992), we derive the amount of the firm's value that Chapter 11negotiations will allocate
to its original shareholder (called the entrepreneur) and its creditors. In section 3, we discuss
how the specific securities chosen to distribute this value can affect the payoff to each class of
claimants. Section 4 concludes.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/1995/wp9512.pdf

2. A Model of Bankruptcy Resolution
Consider a two-period world in which an entrepreneur/manager is the sole stockholder of
a firm. This firm has cash valued at x, and debt outstanding with a face value of 6, owed to a
single lender. Assume that x, < 6 so that the firm is in financial distress. One can think of x,
as the realized period-one profits from an investment project the entrepreneur selected in period
zero, and 6 as the payment required to ensure that the lender earned zero expected profits on a
loan extended in period zero. Assume, furthermore, that the firm's investment project will
produce a random return i2in period two.
While the distribution of i2is assumed to be independent of x,, in period one the

In particular, the firm's
entrepreneur learns private information regarding the distribution of i2.
period-two return may have one of two distributions, G(x2) or B(x2), where G is fist-order
stochastic dominant over B so that G(y) I B(y) , Vy, with strict inequality for a set of values
of y with positive probability. In other words, for any constant y, it is always more likely that
the realized value of

% will be less than y under distribution B than it is under distribution G.6

One implication of this assumption is that the expected value of i2is larger under G than under
B. For ease of exposition, we will refer to the firm with distribution G as the "good firm" and
to the other as the "bad firm."7 Using standard notation, let g(x2) and b(x,) denote the
respective density functions of the two types of firms. Finally, let p be the proportion of firms
in the population that have distribution G; this proportion is known by the lender, so absent any

For an introduction to first-order stochastic dominance, see Milgrom (1981) and Laffont (1989).
Similarly, we will refer to the "good entrepreneur" and the "bad entrepreneur."
4

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/1995/wp9512.pdf

further information, it assumes the distribution of Z2 is its ex ante expected value, II(x,) =

p G(x2) + ( 1 -p)B(x2). It is easy to show that G is first-order stochastic dominant over Il,which
is first-order stochastic dominant over B.
Since the firm is in financial distress, it must renegotiate with its creditors. Our model
of the Chapter 1 1 renegotiation process is a simplification of that developed by Bebchuk and
Chang (1992), the general structure of which can be described as follows.

A plan of

reorganization specifies the proportion of the firm's existing cash and expected future revenues
to be distributed to each class of claimants; a plan is adopted only if every class of claimants
accepts it. It is common knowledge that the firm will be allowed to continue in reorganization
for n periods, after which, if no plan is accepted, it will be liquidated and the proceeds will be
distributed according to the APR. Default costs of c are incurred in each period, meaning a
quick reorganization is more efficient than one that is drawn out. In the first e periods, the
debtor is granted an exclusivity period in which to propose a plan of reorganization. For the
remaining n-e periods, each class of claimants has an equal chance of being allowed to propose
a plan, with only one plan being offered each period. During this process, the firm continues to
operate and receive revenues; none of these revenues, however, may be distributed to any of the
claimants until a final plan of reorganization is agreed upon.

The equilibrium is found

recursively by solving the model for the final period and working backward.

In our model, there are only two classes of claimants - equity and debt

- and

we

assume that n = 2 and e = 1. If no agreement is reached by the end of period two, the
bankruptcy c o w imposes the liquidation outcome. At this point, the firm will have x, + x2 in
cash, minus the 2c in default costs incurred during periods one and two. Let V: and V: denote

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/1995/wp9512.pdf

the payoffs to the entrepreneur and the lender, respectively, when no agreement is reached:

Clearly, each of these payoffs is simply a direct application of the APR.
Knowing this guaranteed minimum outcome, in period two neither the entrepreneur nor
the lender will accept any plan of reorganization promising less. Since costs are incurred and
no uncertainty is resolved between period two and the court-mandated liquidation, the only plan
of reorganization either class may propose that will be accepted gives V: to the entrepreneur and V:
to the lender.8 Although the entrepreneur and the lender are equally Likely to be allowed to
propose a plan in this period, our structure implies that the choice is irrelevant - both classes
will offer the same plan, which will be a~cepted.~
Moving back to period one, the entrepreneur's exclusivity period, the lender must decide
whether to accept or reject the entrepreneur's proposed plan of reorganization. His expected
return from rejecting the plan and continuing the process into period two is

where h = 6 + 2c

- xl ,and F is the distribution function of the random variable Z2, depending

on whether the lender knows the fmis good or bad (in which case F = G or F = B,

Note that this is the outcome that would occur if the firm were simply allowed to pay off its debts
at any point during the reorganization process in which it was able. Thus, there is no loss of generality
in assuming that the firm, once in reorganization, must stay in reorganization until it is liquidated or a plan
is confirmed.
In a model with more periods, the method in which plan proponents are selected will have an impact
on the outcome of the process. See Bebchuk and Chang (1992).

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/1995/wp9512.pdf

respectively) or does not know the firm's type (in which case F = II). The lender will accept
any reorganization plan that offers him an expected return at least this large. Therefore, the
entrepreneur will propose a plan that offers V,* to the lender, leaving the remaining expected
revenue for himself:

As in Bebchuk and Chang, the (unique) equilibrium of this model is for the entrepreneur to
propose a plan of reorganization that gives V,' to the lender and V,' to himself, and for the
lender to accept the plan. Although the structure of our model is somewhat different from theirs,
the entrepreneur's payoff (V,') is analogous to Bebchuk and Chang's expression (13). The first
term is the delay cost avoided by early resolution of the bankruptcy process, which accrues to
the entrepreneur because of his first-mover advantage. The second term is the option value he
receives because the firm is allowed to continue. This value derives from the fact that the f m ' s
future revenues might exceed its current debts.
Expression (3) makes it clear that the value the entrepreneur receives from the
reorganization process depends on the lender's beliefs about the firm's type, i.e., the distribution
of i2.Since the good entrepreneur's option is more likely to end up "in the money," he is in
a stronger bargaining position than he would be if his firm were bad. To take advantage of this
position, however, he must credibly convince the lender that his firm is, in fact, good. In other
words, the good entrepreneur would like to separate. Unfortunately, the entrepreneur with the

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/1995/wp9512.pdf

bad firm would like to pool with the good firm, keeping the lender from differentiating the two.
These ideas are formalized in the following proposition.

PROPOSITION
1.1: The entrepreneur of the good firm can negotiate a higher expected return
when his firm separates than he can when it pools with the bad firm. In contrast, the
entrepreneur of the bad firm receives a lower expected return when separation occurs.

Proof: We will show that the difference between the good entrepreneur's expected return from
pooling and his expected return from separating is negative:

where this final step follows from the fact that G is first-order stochastic dominant over

n.

An

identical argument shows that the entrepreneur of the bad firm receives a lower expected payoff
from pooling. 4

The next logical question, then, is how the good entrepreneur might convince the lender
of his true type. This issue is addressed in the next section.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/1995/wp9512.pdf

3. The Form of Payoffs
The reorganization payoffs to the entrepreneur and the lender, as defined in (2) and (3)
above, merely specify the expected value each class of claimants will receive from any
equilibrium plan of reorganization. They do not, however, specify the form in which these
payments.are distributed. As will be seen below, the good entrepreneur can use the form of these
payments to signal his firm's type, allowing him to receive a different expected return than the
entrepreneur of the bad firm.
One common structure for reorganization payments is for the firm to cancel its existing
debt and stock and issue new equity to the claimants. We will call this kind of reorganization
a stock reorganization. The entrepreneur's expected return from a stock reorganization is

while the lender's expected return is

where o is the share of the reorganized firm controlled by the entrepreneur, and F is again the
appropriate distribution function of i2given the lender's beliefs about the firm's type (which in
equilibrium must equal the true distribution of i2). By the discussion in the previous section,
we know that these payoffs must equal the expected returns defined in (3) and (2), respectively.
We can use this fact to determine the fraction of the new stock given to the entrepreneur in an
equilibrium plan of reorganization:

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/1995/wp9512.pdf

It is a straightforward exercise to show that this o also ensures that the lender receives his
minimum expected return, as defined in (2).
The share of the reorganized firm's equity to be given to the entrepreneur clearly depends
on the lender's beliefs about the firm's type. If the firm were good and the entrepreneur could
convince the lender of this fact, he could bargain for more of the reorganized firm's stock and,
hence, earn a higher expected return. Nevertheless, a separating equilibrium does not exist in
which the good firm offers stock to its creditors.

PROPOS~~ION
1.2: The unique equilibrium of the reorganization game using only stock
distributions is a pooling equilibrium; a separating equilibrium does not exist.

Proof: Suppose the good firm were to separate and distribute stock to its creditors; let o, be the
proportion of the firm's new stock going to the entrepreneur when the firm is known to be good.
By definition, this value ensures that the entrepreneur receives an expected return of
c

+

f (x2-h) dG(x2), as long as the lender believes the fm is good.

But the entrepreneur of

the bad firm will receive a higher expected return by mimicking this offer than by separating (by
Proposition 1.1). As a result, the creditor will demand at least (1-0,) of the firm's stock, where on
is the share of the firm going to the entrepreneur when pooling is known to occur. 4

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/1995/wp9512.pdf

The intuition here is straightforward. Since the bad entrepreneur can mimic any offer
made by the good one and receives a higher expected return from doing so, pooling will always
occur. The lender anticipates this, and the good entrepreneur is unable to reap any of the benefits
of his superior return distribution.
How then might the good entrepreneur signal his firm's true nature? One alternative is
to offer his creditor a different bundle of securities that, while still giving the same expected
return to both the lender and the entrepreneur, provides for some state dependence. Warrants
have just these characteristics.
Suppose the firm's entrepreneur offered the lender all of the reorganized firm, but retained
for himself the right to buy, by paying P, a block of stock from the firm that would give him the
right to a fraction of the firm's revenues, o. More concisely stated, the entrepreneur gives
himself warrants with strike price P which, if exercised, would give him o of the firm. To
ensure that these warrants will be exercised when and only when the value of the firm exceeds
the debt due the creditor (i.e., x, +x2 - c 2 6), set P = 6 -.1W-w
The expected return to the entrepreneur is then

where cp = 6 + c - x,. To guarantee the entrepreneur the proper expected return, o must be
set to make this expression equal to (3):

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/1995/wp9512.pdf

The lender's expected return from this reorganization plan is

It is again straightforward to show that this expected return, along with the above definition for
o , guarantees the lender his minimum expected return, as defined by (2).
We now show that warrants allow for a separating equilibrium; moreover, when warrants
and stock are the only two securities available in reorganization, this separation is a unique
equilibrium:

PROPOS~~ION
1.3: The unique equilibrium of the reorganization game is for the good
entrepreneur to ofSer a plan that gives the entire jim to the lender while retaining for
himself warrants entitling him to buy oGof the firm for a price P = 6 o G / ( l-aG), and
for the bad entrepreneur to ofSer a stock reorganization in which he retains a fraction o,
of thefimz.

Proof:
-

First we will show existence.

Consider the action of the good firm's original

shareholders. By offering warrants, they expect to receive c
Proposition 1.2, they would receive c

+

+

6

(x2-A) dG(x2), whereas by

6

(x,-1) dll(x2) if they offered stock. By Proposition

1.1, the original shareholders receive a higher expected return from warrants.
Next, consider the action of the bad firm's shareholders by comparing their expected
return fiom issuing stock, c

+

"r

(x,-1) dB(x,) , with what they would expect to receive if they

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/1995/wp9512.pdf

mimicked the good firm and issued warrants, a,

Ly

(x2-cp) dB(x,); we will show that the

difference between the return from stock and the return from warrants is positive.

After

substituting for a,, this difference has the same sign as

Ly

( xh ) ( x )

+

c

f (x, -1) dG(x2) + c

This difference is minimized when G has no weight in the interval [cp, h ] , so we will impose this
restriction on G for the rest of the proof. Thus, (11) is equal to

Now, expression (12) has the same sign as

which (since h = cp

+

c ) is equal to

Some simple algebra shows this is equal to

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/1995/wp9512.pdf

Because G is first-order stochastic dominant over B,

This implies that expression (15) is weakly larger than

where this last step follows from the fact that h = cp+c. Since G(h) = G(cp) I B(cp), this
expression must be non-negative, implying that expression (11) is non-negative - i.e., the
entrepreneur of the bad firm will not wish to mimic the good f m ' s warrant offer.
Finally, consider the actions of the lender. Since full separation is occurring, it is an
equilibrium action for him to accept the offers of both the good firm and the bad h,
and to
believe that the good firm is offering warrants while the bad firm is offering stock.
The only other possible equilibrium is for the bad entrepreneur to separate by offering
warrants. But this cannot be an equilibrium, since the good entrepreneur would wish to mimic
this offer (this follows from the fact that a, > a,, i.e., that expression [Ill is positive). This

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/1995/wp9512.pdf

proves uniqueness. 4

Why does the entrepreneur of the bad firm mimic stock offers but not warrants? Since
the good firm is more likely to have high period-two profits, its entrepreneur needs a smaller
percentage of the firm to earn his minimum expected return than does the entrepreneur of the bad
firm. This also explains why the good entrepreneur would mimic a warrant offer made by the
bad firm: If he could get a larger fraction of the firm he would take it, even though he doesn't
need it to earn his minimum expected return.

4. Conclusions
In this paper, we have shown that firms with good future prospects will propose
reorganization plans in which any value given to the firm's original shareholders will be
distributed in the form of warrants. This is because the state-dependentnature of the payoff from
warrants allows these firms to credibly signal their true type.
In this model, separation of good and bad f m s occurs because the payoff fi-omwarrants
is state dependent. Given this, it is reasonable to wonder whether direct call options, with their
more simple structure, might provide a better signal of the firm's type. In particular, one might
imagine a plan of reorganization that allocates all of the firm's stock to its creditors, but gives
the original shareholders the option to buy this stock from the creditors at some future date (as
opposed to warrants, where the new stock is issued by the firm). This type of reorganization
plan would look much like the bankruptcy processes proposed by Bebchuk (1988) and Aghion,

Hart, and Moore (1992).

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/1995/wp9512.pdf

If, however, the firm's original creditors must exert effort to run the firm once they take
control, and if this effort affects the firm's future profitability, a pure stock option would give
them little incentive to increase the value of the fm. Working hard would increase the chance
that the firm's original stockholders could exercise their option. In contrast, warrants allow the
firm's original creditors to share in the upside gain during high-profitability states, no matter how
large it is.
Of course, there are several important caveats to this analysis. First, it assumes that the
managers of the firm are perfect representatives of its original shareholders. Betker (1995) argues
that the reorganization process can sometimes cause the firm's managers to have an incentive to
work in the interests of the firm's creditors (who will become its owners after the reorganization
is completed). Nevertheless, he does find that when a large portion of the CEO's compensation
is in the form of stock, his or her interests are, in fact, closely aligned with those of the
shareholders.
This paper also has nothing to say about the relative efficiency of the outcomes presented.
From an ex-ante standpoint (that is, when the firm initially incurs its debts and invests in a
project), the expected magnitude of any anticipated APR deviation in bankruptcy is unaffected
by the form this deviation might take.
The results developed here offer some easily testable empirical implications. Future work
will look at the stock prices of firms that have emerged from Chapter 11 reorganization. The
model in this paper suggests that the stock prices of firms whose reorganization plans issued
warrants to their original shareholders should be higher than those of f m s whose reorganization
plans used only stock or cash.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/1995/wp9512.pdf

Aghion, Philippe, Oliver Hart, and John Moore. "The Economics of Bankruptcy Reform."
Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 1992, 8(3), 523-546.
Alderson, Michael J. and.~rianL. Betker. "Liquidation Costs and Capital Structure." Journal
of Financial Economics, September 1995, 39(1), 45-70.
Bebchuk, Lucian A. "A New Approach to Corporate Reorganizations." Harvard Law Review,
February 1988, 101(4), 775-804.
Bebchuk, Lucian A. and Howard F. Chang. "Bargaining and the Division of Value in Corporate
Reorganization." Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 1992, 8(2), 253-279.
Betker, Brian L. "An Analysis of the Returns to Stockholders and Bondholders in a Chapter 11
Reorganization." University of California-Los Angeles, working paper, April 1991.
Betker, Brian L. "The Security Price Effects of Public Debt Defaults." Ohio State University,
working paper, August 1994.
Betker, Brian L. "Management's Incentives, Equity's Bargaining Power, and Deviations from
Absolute Priority in Chapter 11 Bankruptcies." Journal of Business, April 1995, 68(2),
161-183.
Brown, David T. "Clairnholder Incentive Conflicts in Reorganization: The Role of Bankruptcy
Law." Review of Financial Studies, 1989, 2, 109-123.
Eberhart, Allan C., W.T. Moore, and R.L. Roenfeldt. "Security Pricing and Deviations from the
Absolute Priority Rule in Bankruptcy Proceedings." Journal of Finance, December 1990,
45(5), 1457-1469.
Franks, Julian R. and Walter N. Torous. "An Empirical Investigation of U.S. Firms in
Reorganization." Journal of Finance, July 1989,44(3), 747-769.
Franks, Julian R. and Walter N. Torous. "How Firms Fare in Workouts and Chapter 11
Reorganizations." University of California-Los Angeles, Working Paper No. 1-91,
September 1991.
Franks, Julian R. and Walter N. Torous. "A Comparison of Financial Recontracting in Distressed
Exchanges and Chapter 11 Reorganization." Journal of Financial Economics, 1994, 35,
349-370.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/1995/wp9512.pdf

Jackson, Thomas H. The Logic and Limits of Bankruptcy Law. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard
University Press, 1986.
Laffont, Jean-Jaques. The Economics of Uncertainty and Information. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT
Press, 1989.
LoPucki, Lynn M. and William C. Whitford. "Bargaining over Equity's Share in the Bankruptcy
Reorganization of Large, Publicly Held Companies." University of Pennsylvania Law
Review, 1990, 139, 125-196.
Milgrom, Paul R. "Good News and Bad News: Representation Theorems and Applications."
Bell Journal of Economics, Autumn 1981, 12(2), 380-391.
White, Michelle J. "Bankruptcy Liquidation and Reorganization." in Dennis E. Logue, ed.,
Handbook of Modern Finance, 2d ed. Boston: Warren, Gorham & Larnont, Inc., 1990.