View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm
Best available copy

Workins P a ~ e r8903

PREDICTING DE NOVO BRANCH ENTRY
INTO RURAL MARKETS
by Gary Whalen

Gary Whalen is an economic advisor
at the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland.
Working papers of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland are preliminary materials
circulated to stimulate discussion and
critical comment. The views stated herein
are those of the author and not necessarily
those of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System.

March 1989

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm
Best available copy

Predicting De Novo Branch Entry
Into Rural Markets

I. Introduction

Currently, there is a great deal of debate among industrialorganization economists about whether potential competition can be
relied upon to be an effective disciplinary force in real-world
markets. Contestable-market theorists argue that, in general, the
answer is yes.'

However, others have questioned the assumptions

and/or predictions of contestable-market theory on a variety of
grounds.2 One of the primary reasons for the lack of consensus is
the dearth of empirical studies on this issue, which is largely due
to the difficulties involved in developing measures of potential
competition for use in empirical work.3
Additional insight into potential competition would be of
considerable value to bank regulators, who are charged with
preventing bank mergers and acquisitions that
lessenw competition.

"substantially

A large number of states have lowered long-

standing geographic barriers to bank expansion in recent years.
These developments, in turn, have stimulated a great deal of
merger/acquisition
transactions

imply

activity.
substantial

More

frequently,

increases

in

local

proposed
market

concentration. To reliably determine the competitive impact of the
concentration increases in individual cases, regulators must be
able to evaluate the intensity of potential competition in the
markets affected. The aim of the current study is to provide such
information.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm
Best available copy

2

We estimate a logit model designed to explain the probability
of de novo branch entry into rural banking markets in Ohio and
~ennsylvaniafrom 1980 to 1984 .4

The key assumption underlying

this approach is that the intensity of potential competition in any
local banking market is highly correlated with the threat or
probability of d e novo market entry.
The focus is on rural or non-MSA counties for several reasons.
The

number

of

actual

competitors

is

generally

concentration is high relative to urban counties.

small

and

Further, the

number of potential entrants, both bank and nonbank, is generally
lower and de novo entry is less common.

Thus, knowledge about the

likelihood of entry and about potential competition in rural
markets is particularly useful.
The findings presented in this study are noteworthy for
several reasons.

Unlike most previous studies, de novo branch

entry is investigated.

This appears to be the most appropriate

entry measure if one is attempting to gain insight on potential
competition.

Further, entry is defined in two alternative ways:

by commercial banks only, and by both banks and savings and loan
associations

(S&Ls).

Consideration of

S & L entry

seems appropriate

given the expansion of S&L asset and liability powers in 1980 and
1982.

Finally, explicit measures of the number of potential

entrants are included as explanatory variables in the estimated
model.

This should provide valuable insight concerning the

relationship between the number of potential entrants and the
likelihood of entry.6

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm
Best available copy

g
The existing body of previous empirical work on entry in
banking has been summarized and reviewed recently in Amel (1988).
His analysis demonstrates that surprisingly little work has been
done in this area.

However, he does find that most researchers

have used the same basic set of variables to explain entry.

The

most common measures are market growth, market size, concentration,
density of customers per bank office, profitability, and legal
restrictions on branching.

Other, less frequently used variables

are measures of bank holding company presence in a market, previous
entry, and the number of potential entrants.
Several conclusions can be drawn after reading Amel's review.
First, many of the previous studies are now dated, and many have
at least several important flaws.
investigate de novo entry.

In particular, very few

Those that do typically examine the

determinants or impacts of establishing de novo banks, rather than
branches.

De novo branch entry is much more common, particularly

now that intrastate branching restrictions have been reduced in
many states.

Most studies, including the two most recent ones

(Arne1 [I9881 and Lawrence and Watkins [1986]) examine entry only
by acquisition. While there are drawbacks associated with the use
of both types of entry measure, the use of a de novo entry measure
appears to be preferable on theoretical grounds.

Potential

competition should be more closely related to the threat of de novo
entry, which implies an additional competitor, than to a change in

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm
Best available copy

4

the identity of an existing one because of a merger.
S&Ls are generally ignored in these studies.

They are not

considered in the construction of the entry measures employed,
presumably because they are not viewed as competitive equals of
commercial banks.
market-presence

Most studies do not include any type of S&L

variable

as

a

commercial bank entry decision.

possible

determinant

of

the

Many do not even consider S&L

market deposits in the calculation of the measures of market growth
and size that are typically used as explanatory variables in the
entry equations estimated.

Neglect of S&Ls may not have been

important in studies done prior to 1980, but it seems inappropriate
now given the substantial expansion of S&L powers that has occurred
recently.
Finally, most studies do not include a measure of the number
of potential entrants as an explanatory variable.

The likelihood

of market entry should depend in some fashion on the number of
potential

entrants,

and

insight

into

the

nature

of

this

relationship should be of value to bank regulators.

111. Model S~ecification

A logit model is the statistical technique employed in this

study.

This type of model is used because the primary aim of this

research is to develop a reduced-form model that will produce
relatively accurate estimates of the probability of future entry
into local financial markets.

A

particularly well-suited to this task.

logit model of entry is

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm
Best available copy

5

The dependent variable used in the equations estimated is a
binary dummy measure, defined to equal one if a rural county
experienced de novo branch entry over the two-year period from June
1980 to June 1982.

Otherwise, the variable is set equal to zero.

The choice of this particular time period was not completely
arbitrary.

D e novo branching laws were roughly the same in Ohio

and Pennsylvania over this interval, so markets in both states
could be used in the study. Furthermore, the substantial expansion
of

S&L

powers

authorized

in

the

Depository

Institutions

Deregulation and Monetary Control Act (DIDMCA) took effect at the
beginning of 1980.

The use of the two-year period also reflects

uncertainty about the length of the lag between a decision to
branch and the actual establishment of an office.

Finally, since

a relatively small number of markets are examined and since de novo
entry is relatively rare in non-MSA markets, a period of this
length was necessary to provide enough instances of entry to
estimate the model.
In general, the explanatory variables used are the same set
identified in Amel (1988) as the most useful predictors of market
entry.

Specifically, measures of market growth, market size,

market income, concentration, market profitability, and customer
density are used.

Market growth (MGROWTH) is defined to be the

percentage change in market deposits over the three years ending
in June 1980. Market size (MSIZE) is total market deposits at the
end of June 1980.

Market income (MINC) is per capita personal

income as of year-end 1979.

Concentration (CR3) is the share of

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm
Best available copy

market deposits controlled by the three largest institutions in
June 1980.~ Customer density (POPTO) is population in the market
at year-end 1979, divided by total offices in the market in June
1980. All of these variables are defined to include S&Ls operating
in the market. The profitability of each market (MPROF) is proxied
by the mean annual return on assets of all single-market commercial
banks in the market, averaged over the 1977-1979 period.9
A potential entrant variable is also calculated for each
market.

This is relatively straightforward for banks because in

both Ohio and Pennsylvania over the 1980-1982 time period, banks
were permitted to branch de novo only within their home office
1
i

I

county and into contiguous counties.
The bank potential
competition variable for any market (BPE) is simply the total
number of banking organizations operating in counties contiguous
to (but not in) themarket that are legally able to branch de novo
into it.
The S&L potential entrant variable is more difficult to define
because S&Ls had more freedom to branch de novo over this interval.
Consequently, we consider any S&L organization operating an office
in a county contiguous to (but not in) a particular market to be
a potential entrant into that market. An analysis of S&L branching
patterns indicated that this approach is reasonable.

The total

number of potential entrants variable for each market (BSLPE) is
I

the sum of these two measures.

These potential entrant measures

were calculated as of June 1980.
One additional explanatory variable is included in some

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm
Best available copy

7

versions of the equations estimated: a dummy variable with a value
set equal to one for markets that had experienced de novo entry
over the previous two-year period (PREVENT).

This variable is

included because of the realistic possibility that entry in the
recent past could impact the probability of entry in the current
period.
An important consideration is that entry over the June 1980
to June 1982 interval is presumed to depend solely on variables
known prior to this time period.

This is desirable for two

reasons. First, this specification realistically reflects the lag
between the decision,tobranch and the actual establishment of an
office.

Second, using the estimated model to predict the

probability of future market entry does not require forecasts of
any of the explanatory variables in it.
Markets

that

are

larger,

more

rapidly

growing,

more

profitable, with wealthier residents, or with more population per
existing office are expected to be more attractive, ceteris
paribus. This implies that the coefficients on the market growth,
market size, market profitability, per capita personal income, and
population per office variables should be positive.
The expected sign of the concentration variable is unclear.
If concentrated markets are more profitable and/or less risky than
less-concentrated ones, and if entrants can expect to share in
these benefits, then the level of

concentration should

positively associated with the probability of market entry.

be
If,

on the other hand, market concentration signals that the large

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm
Best available copy

8

players in a market possess some type of competitive advantage over
smaller prospective entrants, a negative coefficient might be
observed.

Thus, the expected sign of the concentration variable

is ambiguous.
There is also some uncertainty about the sign of the potential
entrant variable.

The conventional view is that the overall

likelihood of market entry will be positively related to the number
of potential entrants.

Some writers, however, have demonstrated

that mutual awareness among potential entrants could cause the
relationship between the number of potential entrants and the
overall likelihood of: entry to be non-monotonic, perhaps even
negative.

Given this uncertainty, the sign of the coefficient on

the number of potential competitors term is also viewed as
indeterminate.
The sign of the previous entry variable is also unclear.
Previous de novo entry could be a signal that expected market
profitability is high and thus could be positively related to the
probability of entry in the current period.

On the other hand,

previous de novo entry could imply downward profitability pressure
on current and any future competitors in the market and could be
negatively related to the probability of entry in the current
period.

IV. Em~iricalResults

Various versions of the logit model described above were
estimated using the complete or pooled sample of markets.

These

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm
Best available copy

9

models were then used used to predict the probability of entry into
rural markets in Ohio and Pennsylvania over the ensuing two-year
period (1982-1984).
Before proceeding, several circumstances that could affect the
forecasting accuracy of equations estimated usingthe pooled sample
should

be

noted.

Over

the

1980-1982

period,

geographic

restrictions on bank expansion were similar but not identical in
both states.

The major difference was that multibank holding

v

companies and statewide branching through merger were permitted in
Ohio but not in Pennsylvania.

The availability of these options

could influence the relationship between de novo branch entry and
its hypothesized determinants in each of the two states, and could
therefore reduce the out-of-sample predictive accuracy of models
estimated using the pooled sample.

In addition, Pennsylvania

enacted major changes in its bank expansion law, effective in 1982.
Multibank holding companies were permitted for the first time and
were allowed to acquire banks thoughout the state.

Further, banks

were allowed to branch de novo on a bicontiguous county basis.
These changes could make it more difficult to forecast entry in
Pennsylvania over the 1982-1984 period using the pooled model.
The

models

that

performed

best

in

terms

of

in-sample

classification accuracy are presented in tables 1 and 2.

The

former contains results for models in which the dependent variable
measures entry by commercial banks only.

The latter contains

equations in which the dependent variable measures entry by a bank
or S&L.

In general, the definition of entry does not have a major

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm
Best available copy

10

impact on the sign and statistical significance of the estimated
coefficients or on the overall explanatory power of the equations.
Examination of the results reveals that the signs of the
estimated coefficients on several of the variables are contrary to
expectations and/or are insignificant. This is not surprising for
several reasons.

Similar results were obtained in many other

previous studies, including Amel (1988), with much larger samples.
The samples used to estimate the models in this study are quite
small, and several of the explanatory variables are highly
collinear.

In any event, the model is viewed as a reduced-form

model which we hope will produce accurate forecasts of market entry
out-of-sample. Thus, the sign and statistical significance of the
individual estimated coefficients are not a primary concern, and
the discussion of these coefficients below is cursory.
Four variables were found to be statistically significant in
the estimated models:

market income, market concentration, the

potential competition term, and the ratio of population to the
number of financial offices in the market-

The signs of these

coefficients are reasonable. The probability of de novo entry is
positively related to market income.

De nova market entry is less

likely in markets that are highly concentrated, Presumably because
it is difficult to take market share away

large, established

competitors. The probability of market entry is higher, the larger
the number of potential entrants. The likelihood of entry is also
greater, the higher the ratio of population to the number of bank
and S&L offices in the market.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm
Best available copy

11
Tables 1 and 2 also present the in-sample classication results
obtained

using

each

model

and

a

probability

cutoff

value

approximately equal to the proportion of markets that experienced
entry. The overall classification accuracy of the estimated models
is generally in excess of 80 percent.

More important, the Type I

(incorrectly classifying a market that experienced entry) and Type
I1 (incorrectly classifying a market that did not experience entry)

error rates are roughly the same.

This finding is encouraging

because it implies that the estimated models allow both entered and
nonentered markets to be identified with a reasonable degree of
accuracy, at least in-sample.
To be useful for antitrust policy, however, the estimated
models

must

produce

relatively

accurate

estimates

of

the

probability of market entry in the near future, that is, they must
do a relatively good job of forecasting out-of-sample. Preliminary
analysis indicated that the simplest models estimated (model 1 in
each table) did the best job of identifying markets entered over
the 1982-1984 period, so only the results obtained using these
models are discussed.
The out-of-sample predictions of market entry by commercial
banks obtained using model 1 and a prediction cutoff value of .10
(equal to the proportion of markets entered over the 1980-1982
interval) appear in table 3.

The results are presented for the

entire sample and also for Ohio and Pennsylvania separately.
The entry predictions generated by this relatively simple
model are reasonably accurate, given the small sample size.

For

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm
Best available copy

12
the whole sample, roughly two-thirds of the markets are classified
correctly.
occurred

More important, seven of the nine markets where entry
were

correctly

identified.

The

results

for

each

individual state reveal that the overall classification accuracy
of the model does not differ greatly for each of the two subsamples. However, the two type I errors were both in Pennsylvania,
where bank branching laws changed in 1982, rather than in Ohio,
where they did not.
These results may actually understate the predictive accuracy
of the estimated models somewhat. Further analysis disclosed that
bank entry occurred dver the following two-year period (1984-1986)
in six markets that the model predicted would be entered over the
1982-1984 period.

Five of these were located in Ohio, and one was

located in Pennsylvania.
The out-of-sample predictions of market entry by either a bank
or an S&L generated by using equation 1 from table 2 also appear
in table 3.

Once again, a prediction cut-off value approximately

equal to the sample proportion of markets entered over the 19801982 period is employed.

This value is 0.2.

The results are similar to those obtained when only bank entry
was considered.

However, the model for bank/S&L entry produces

somewhat less-accurate predictions than the bank-only model. This
may be due to the unsustained surge in S&L branching activity,
particularly in Ohio, that occurred during 1980-1982, the interval
over which the forecasting equation was estimated. This branching
activity was probably largely due to nonrecurring events (such as

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm
Best available copy

13

expanded powers authorized by the DIDMCA of 1980 and the Garn-St
Germain Act of 1982) rather than to traditional economic factors.
Thus, the model typically generates higher entry probabilities over
the 1982-1984 period and so tends to have a Type I1 error rate and
an overall error rate slightly above the bank entry model.
Roughly 60 percent of the complete sample of markets were
correctly classified by the bank/S&L model. The overall error rate
was slightly higher for the Ohio subsample, due to a higher Type
I1 error rate.

Eight of the eleven markets entered were correctly

identified for the complete sample.

As in the previous model, all

of the Type I errors were concentrated in the Pennsylvania
subsample.
Market entry in the 1984-1986 period should be considered in
evaluating the predictive accuracy of this model, as well.

As was

the case for the bank entry model, six of the markets for which
entry was incorrectly predicted over the 1982-1984 interval were
subsequently entered during the next two-year period.

Five of

these were located in Ohio.

V. Summary and Conclusions

The results of the study suggest that it is possible to
produce relatively accurate estimates of the probability of future
de novo branch entry into rural markets using relatively simple

models.

The forecasting performance of the estimated models is

viewed as surprisingly good given the relatively small sample size
and the change in branching laws that occurred in Pennsylvania

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm
Best available copy

14

immediately prior to the forecast period.

If the key assumption made in this study is correct

--

that

the intensity of potential competition in any local market is
directly related to the threat of Be novo entry
indicate that good

--

the results

estimates of potential competition can be

generated at relatively low cost.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm
Best available copy

Footnotes
1. See, for example, Baumol, Panzar and Willig (1982).
2. For an opposing view, see Schwartz (1986).

3. Only two empirical examinations of the impact of potential
competition in banking are known to the author: Hannan (1979) and
Whalen (1988). Very few empirical studies of potential competition
have been done for other industries.
4 . Thus, local banking markets are assumed to be approximated by
rural counties.

5. These powers were authorized in the Depository Institutions
Deregulation and Monetary Control Act in 1980 and the Garn-St
Germain Act in 1982.
6. Some researchers have suggested that the relationship between
the number of potential entrants and the overall likelihood of
market entry might not be a positive, linear one.
See, for
example, the discussion in Hannan (1981).
7 . The main reason cited by Amel for choosing to analyze entry by
acquisition rather than de novo entry is simply that it is easier
to assemble data on the former.

8. A Herfindahl index of concentration was also employed. Use of
this measure did not materially impact the reported results. Since
the three-firm concentration ratio is much easier to compute, it
was the concentration measure of choice in this study.

9. Single-market banks are those with all offices located within

their home office county. Presumably the profitability of such
banks reflects local market opportunities.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm
Best available copy

TABLE 1
LOGIT REGRESSION
DEPENDENT VARIABLE:

Variables

Coef

Model 1
T- Stat

Bank E n t r y

Model 2
Coef
T- Stat

Model 3
Coef
T- Stat

Constant - 10.80810

- 1.56

- 8.83336

- 1.25

- 10.09931

- 1.46

MGROWTH

- 0.15558

- 1.12

- 0.13608

- 0.97

- 0.14293

- 0.98

MSIZE

- 0.00425

- 1.16

- 0.00450

- 1.20

- 0.00393

- 1.09

0.00117

1.81

0.00125

1.91

0.00113

1.77

CR3

- 0.10504

- 2.17

- 0.12307

- 2.09

- 0.10887

- 2.18

BPE

0.13020

2.03

0.12902

2.02

0.12115

1.89

POPTO

2.10460

2.48

2.29404

2.33

2.08918

2.49

-------------

-------

- 1.78405

- 0.91

-------

----

-------

----

MINC

MPROF
PREVENT

- 0.69627

- 0.52

A D J R SQ =
.382
CHI
SQUARED = 1 9 . 9 3

-

In- Sample C l a s s i f i c a t i o n R e s u l t s
Pred

Pred

Act

NE

E

Act

NE

E

12

NE

61

14

NE

61

14

6

E

2

6

E

2

6

Act

NE

E

NE

63

E

2

NE: M a r k e t s n o t e n t e r e d .
E:
Markets entered.

Source:

Author.

Pred

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm
Best available copy

TABLE 2
LOGIT REGRESSION
DEPENDENT VARIABLE:

Model 1
Variables

Coef

Bank/S&L E n t r y

Model 2
Coef
T- Stat

T- Stat

Constant

-7.76417

-1.67

-6.01392

MGROWTH

-0.06269

-0.70

MSIZE

-0.00353

MINC

Model 3
Coef
T- Stat

-1.27

-8.33036

-1.76

-0.03938

-0.39

-0.03599

-0.37

-1.32

-0.00435

-1.43

-0.00349

-1.37

0.00084

1.89

0.00097

2.05

0.00089

1.97

BSLPE

0.04950

2.20

0.04866

2.24

0.05065

2.32

POPTO

1.27440

2.46

1.53052

2.41

1.27148

2.45

-------------

-------

-2.34456

-1.67

-------

----

----

-1.01016

MPROF
PREVENT

.

-------

-1.09

ADJ R SQ =
.219
CHI - SQUARED = 20.39

In-Sample C l a s s i f i c a t i o n R e s u l t s
Pred

Act

NE

E

Act

NE

E

16

NE

52

16

NE

55

13

11

E

4

11

E

4

11

Act

NE

E

NE

52

E

4

NE: Markets n o t entered.
E:
Markets entered.

Source:

Author.

Pred

Pred

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm
Best available copy

TABLE 3
OUT-OF-SAMPLE BANK ENTRY PREDICTIONS
1984
1982

-

Entire Sample
Pred
Act
-

E

NE

E

48

26

NE

2

7

Ohio Subsample
Pred

Act

E

NE

E

27

18

NE

0

3

Pennsylvania Subsample
Pred
-

NE: Markets not entered.
E: Markets entered.

Source:

Author.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm
Best available copy

TABLE 4
-OUT-OF-SAMPLE BANK/S&L ENTRY PREDICTIONS
1982

-

1984

Entire Sample
Pred

Act
E
NE

E

NE

43

29

3

8

Ohio Subsample
Pred

Pennsylvania Subsample
Pred

Act

E

NE

E

20

9

NE

3

5

NE: Markets not entered.
E: Markets entered.

Source:

Author.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm
Best available copy

REFERENCES

Amel, Dean F.,
"An Empirical Investigation of Potential
Competition: Evidence From the Banking Industry,~~
Working Paper
No. 88-1, Financial Structure Section, Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, April, 1988.
Baumol, William, John C. Panzar and Robert D. Willig, Contestable
Markets and the Theory of Industry Structure. New York: Harcourt,
Brace and Jovanovich, 1982.
Gilbert, Gary C., "Predicting De Novo Expansion in Bank Merger
CasesrtlJournal of Finance, XXIX, No. I.,March, 1974.
Gilbert, R. A., "Measures of Potential for De Novo Entry in Bank
Acquisition Cases: An Evaluati~n,~~
Proceedinss From a Conference
on Bank Structure and Com~etition,Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
1974.
Hannan, Timothy H., 91Prices,Capacity and the Entry Decision: A
Conditional Logit A n a l y ~ i s ,Southern
~~
Economic Journal, Vol. 50,
No. 2, October, 1983.

, I1Mutual Awareness Among Potential Entrants:
An Empirical Examination," Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 47, No.
, "Limit Pricing and the Banking Industryttl
Journal of Money, credit and ~ankinq,XI, No. 4, November, 1979.
Hanweck, Gerald, "Bank Entry into Local Markets:
An Empirical
Assessment of the Degree of Potential Competition Via New Bank
Formationrtt
Proceedinss From a Conference on Bank Structure and
Com~etition,Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 1971.
Lawrence, David B. and Thomas G. Watkins, "Rural Banking Markets
and Holding Company Entry,I1Journal of Economics and Business, Vol.
38, No. 2, May, 1986.
Lister, Roger C., "The Expansion of Banking in the Metropolitan
Areas of the So~thwest,~~
Voice, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas,
September, 1974.

, "Entry Into Local Banking Markets: California
1884 -1908,It Proceedinss From a Conference on Bank Structure and
Com~etition,Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 1980.
Rose, John T., "~uyinga Country Bank: De Novo Entry and Market
Attractivenesst1IBankins Law Journal, Vol. 96, No. 3, March, 1979.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm
Best available copy

, "The Attractiveness of Banking Markets for De Novo
Entry: The Evidence From Texas, Journal of Bank Research, Vol.
7, No. 4, winter, 1977.
Rose, Peter S., "Entry into U.S. Banking Markets: Dimensions and
Implications of the Charter ProcesstUAntitrust Bulletin, Vol. 25,
No. 1, Spring, 1980.
Schwartz, Marius, "The Nature and Scope of Contestability Theory,"
Oxford Economics PaDers, Vol. 38, Supplement, November, 1986.
Whalen, Gary W., ItActual Competition, Potential Competition and
Bank Profitability in Rural Markets,It Economic Review, Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Vol. 24, No. 3, Quarter I11 1988.