View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paper 8913

PORTFOLIO RISKS AND BANK ASSET CHOICE

by Katherine A. Sarnolyk

Katherine A. Samolyk is an economist
at the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
The author gratefully acknowledges helpful
comments from Mark Gertler, Donald Morgan,
William Osterberg, and James Thomson.

Working papers of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Cleveland are preliminary materials
circulated to stimulate discussion and
critical comment. The views stated herein
are those of the author and not necessarily
those of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System.

October 1989

ABSTRACT

This paper investigates the effects of both credit risk and interest-rate risk
on bank portfolio choices. It presents a model of banking that explains
portfolio risks with informational asymmetries; depositors cannot observe the
returns on bank loans and banks cannot observe depositors' liquidity needs.
Bank capital must cover possible losses due to loan default and high future
deposit costs given the maturity imbalance of bank portfolios. We show how
bank capital inadequacy may prevent a bank from investing in the optimal
portfolio and how the efficiency of the bank's intermediation technology
affects its choice of second-best portfolio.

I. INTRODUCTION
Depository institutions are unique in the degree of asset
transformation associated with their intermediaQion activities. These
institutions (hereafter referred to as banks) invest in a portfolio of claims,
many of which cannot be traded individually in direct credit markets, and are
often issued by borrowers who would find it prohibitively costly to obtain
external finance. Banks fund these investments largely by issuing highly

-2

**,
,.

liquid claims that serve as substitutes for legal tender in depositors'
portfolios. These activities allow banks to profit while creating a primary
market for certain borrowers and liquidity for bank depositors. The purpose of
this paper is to examine how the risks associated with asset transformation
affect bank portfolio choices.
Recent literature formalizing the allocative role of banks has
considered the implications of their maturity transformation, diversification,
and information production. Diamond and Dybvig (1983), Bhattacharya and Gale
(1987), and Bernanke and Gertler (1987) motivate the maturity transformation
services associated with demand-deposit contracts by assuming that depositors
face unobservable stochastic consumption preferences. Banks must manage the
liquidity risk of their deposit liabilities.
Another branch of the financial intermediation literature focuses on
the monitoring and diversification services that banks provide on the asset
side of their balance sheets (Diamond [1984], Williamson [1986], Boyd and
Prescott [1985], and Bernanke and Gertler [1987]). In these papers, banks
minimize the real resources used to monitor risky investments in a world where
information about investment returns is costly. l Also, by diversifying

across many borrowers, banks can promise a more certain return to

depositor^.^ Many of the results in this area hinge on the ability of
intermediaries to diversify perfectly. Bernanke and Gertler relax this
assumption by restricting the ability of banks to diversify away default risk.
The resulting variability of privately observed bank portfolio returns implies
that the quantity of bank capital will affect bank performance.
Previous researchers have usually examined risk on only one side of
the balance sheet, treating asset and liability management as separate

decision^.^ However, risks on each side of the balance sheet are jointly
considered in portfolio management.
This essay describes a model of a banking sector in which
intermediation exposes banks to portfolio risks on both sides of their balance
sheets. We consider banks that are "special" because they initiate risky
investments that would not be funded in direct credit markets due to
information costs (Fama [1985]). These banks transform both the maturity and
the default risk of the indirect securities they issue relative to the assets
in their portfolios. We then examine the effects of credit risk and short-term
in5erest-rate variability on bank portfolio management
portfolio risks arise because of informational asymmetries; depositors
cannot observe the returns on bank loans and banks cannot observe depositors'
liquidity needs. The deposit contract depends on banks' information about
depositors as well as depositors' information about banks. As a result,
deposit liabilities have a shor2er maturity than bank assets and .paya return
that is not contingent on unobservable bank portfolio risks.

The structure of deposit contracts introduces interest-rate risk into
bank portfolios. This risk translates into uncertainty about deposit costs.
t

Interest-rate swings can create fluctuations in the relative values of bank
assets and liabilities and in bank earnings; consequently, they impact the
capital accounts of banks. We abstract from the moral hazard problem of
monitoring the risk of bank investments to focus on the implications of
interest-rate risk for investment activity.

%

1

When banks cannot diversify away privately observed risks perfectly,
bank capital must cover possible portfolio losses due to either loan default
or high deposit costs. The greater the degree of possible interest-rate
volatility, the more banks must rely on their capital accounts to buffer
corresponding fluctuations in earnings.
When a banker's capital is insufficient to absorb possible losses on
the profit-maximizing level of bank projects, the bank is "capital-constrained."
This constraint requires that a second-best portfolio be chosen to ensure bank
solvency. An alternative "reserve" asset will be substituted for risky bank
projects in order to eliminate some of the portfolio risk. However, as the
expected return on an alternative asset is less than that of the risky
project, expected profits are lower for constrained banks. We formalize how
interest-rate risk increases the likelihood that a bank will become
capital-constrained.
We then consider how bank monitoring costs and the relative portfolio
risks affect the optimal choice of a reserve asset. A bank can use its
technology to fund long-term bank projects with less credit risk or to
fund short-term storage projects costlessly. The return on the former is

higher for banks with an efficient monitoring technology. However, as
long-term(albeit safer) bank projects do not eliminate interest-rate risk
from the bank portfolio, their effectiveness per project in reducing portfolio
risk is smaller. A capital-constrained bank faces a retum and risk-reduction
trade-off in choosing among alternative reserve assets. This further
illuminates the dual role of banks in transforming both the credit risk and
maturity of their specialized loan portfolio.
An

important conclusion of this analysis is that the efficiency of a

bank's specialized intermediation technology will affect its choice of
second-best portfolio. For relatively efficient but capital-constrained banks,
the retum from using their technology may be sufficient to cover losses from
maturity imbalances. We describe when long-term bank projects are the
preferred reserve assets because of the real return to utilizing bank
technology. We also show how the degree of relative risk on either side of the
bank's balance sheet affects the choice of the optimal reserve asset.
Section I1 outlines the model of the banking sector. Sections 111 and

IV describe the alternative equilibria for banks with differing degrees of
'#

ef£iciency in funding investments. Section V is the conclusion.

11. THE BASIC MODEL OF DEPOSITORS AND BANKS
This section presents the framework used to examine the effects of both
default risk and short-term interest-rate risk on the banking equilibrium.
i

Production Possibilities
Three production technologies are available in the economy.

Each

technology requires an initial investment of the economy's endowment in a
project that yields consumption goods in a future period. The investment
opportunities of the economy are described by thh following three projects:
1) Default-free long-term projects, I*, yield a certain gross rate of
return, R*, two periods after the projects are undertaken.

2) Risky long-term projects, 1 , have an expected gross rate of return, R, in
the second period after the projects are undertaken. The returns on these

.

,I
4.

projects are random and can be observed only by the originator of the
investments. The gross rate of return on this technology has a lower bound of

R ~ .The distribution of returns on risky projects is costlessly obsenred by
all individuals in the economy.
3) Default-risk free, short-term storage projects, s, yield a certain gross

rate of return, r, one period later. The gross yield from this technology can
be consumed or reinvested at a future short-term rate. However, the future
short-term storage rate, effective upon reinvestment, is random when the
projects are undertaken. In the initial investment period, the one-period
future storage rate has an expected gross rate of return, rl, and an upper
bound, rh, which is observed by all individuals in the economy.
Both long-term investments are funded through banks that possess the
technology to locate these projects and to monitor them, when necessary.
Monitoring and locating requires a fraction of the total resources invested in
the project, &(€I).

This monitoring cost differs across bankers; 6(ei)

is the marginal monitoring cost of a type

ei banker.

The distribution of

bankers will be ordered by the efficiency of their technology, where
(2.1)

6(ei)<6(ej),

r

as Bi < Bj and where Bi is the fraction of all individuals with
monitoring costs of 6(0,)

or less. The following relationships are assumed

to hold:
(2.2,

Rm
< (1+6R*(0)) <
(1+6 (0))

(1+6 (0))

< rrh.

All individuals in the economy can invest in short-term storage
projects.

Depositors and Bankers
The economy consists of a continuum of individuals measured along the
interval (0,l). These individuals live for three periods, indexed by (0,1,2).
In period 0 they receive an endowment w, which they invest to maximize
expected utility. An exogenous fraction, a , will be called depositors. The
remaining fraction,(1-a), will be called bankers.
As in Diamond and Dybvig (1983), depositors face privately
observed liquidity risks modeled as preference shocks. A fraction, t, will
desire to consume their wealth in period one. The remaining fraction will
desire to consume it in the following period. A depositor's ex-post
pqpferences are not observable. Depositors do not know their preference type
in period zero; thus, they desire to hold a portfolio that can be liquidated
completely in either period.
One investment option for depositors is short-term storage.
Alternatively, banks issue deposits to fund bank-specific projects. Banks
offer a deposit contract, described below, which can be liquidated or
reinvested in period one.

Formally, a representative depositor maximizes his expected utility
given his endowment, aw:
(2.3)

Max E(U(cl,c2))
(d,sd)

(2.4)

(2.5)
(2.6)

t ln(~c~,)+

(1-t) 1n?(l3cd2)

s.t.

E(c~,)

=

rdd

+

~(c~,)= rd2d
aw

=

=

d

+

+

rsd,
rrlsd,

s d,
%,

where d are deposits, sd is direct investment in storage assets, and cdl

< .

and cd2 are first-period and second-period consumption, respectively. The
expected one-period and two-period deposit rates are rd and rd2. The
first-order necessary conditions for d and sd imply that depositors will
hold bank liabilities only if they yield at least the expected return on the
storage technology.
Bankers' fraction of the population is (1-a).

They live for three

periods and maximize their expected consumption in period two. Bankers
possess the technology for locating and monitoring long-term investment
projects. In period zero, a given banker decides whether or not to operate a
bank. If he operates a bank, he invests his :endowment as bank capital and

I

issues deposit liabilities to fund bank-specific projects. The efficiency of
his intermediation technology determines whether he can operate profitably;
the expected return on bank-specific projects must be greater than that of the
storage technology. In choosing among bank-specific projects, a banker
maximizes investment in projects with the highest expected return. From (2.1)
and (2.2), a banker of type

ej will

operate a bank if

where rrl = R/ (1+6(6) ) defines

6 as

the type of the marginal

operating bank and the fraction of individuals who operate as bankers. A
banker with a more efficient technology has ahigher expected net return from
locating and monitoring long-term projects.
To ensure that some fraction of bankers will operate

(6 > 0),

it

is assumed that the gross expected rate of return on the storage technology is
below that of the long-term risky project. To ensure an interior solution for
the number of operating banks in the economy, it is assumed that the leastefficient banker does not find it profitable to operate:

where 6(1-a) is the monitoring cost of the least-efficient banker (type
Bj=(l-a))

in the population.
Nonoperating bankers lend to operating banks. Because they are

risk-neutral and maximize expected period-two consumption, they will be
willing to hold two-period "time deposits."
Operating bankers are located in a "market." The remaining
bankers and short-term depositors are distributed evenly across markets, and
cafinot costlessly move across markets. Thus, a bank knows the quantity of
depositors it will receive and the minimum rate of return it must pay to
attract depositors.
The following quantities will be used in characterizing the economy.
The total monitoring costs in the economy are
I

where 0 5

6

5 (1-0).

Normalizing the number of operating bankers at

unity, the average quantities of demand deposits, time deposits, and bank
't

capital are wd=aw, wt =(l-a-i))w, and W"

=

Gw, respectively.

The Portfolio Choice of an Operating Bank
In this section, the optimization problem of an operating banker is
described. The nature of the profit-maximizing deposit contract must satisfy ,'

?::

the banker's maximization problem and the utility maximization problem of
depositors. (The indexes identifying the technological type of banker have
been omitted for notational clarity.)
In period zero, an operating bank chooses an investment portfolio funded
by bank capital and deposit liabilities that satisfies the following portfolio
balance constraint:
(2.10)

(1+6)(1

+

l*)

+

s

- W" + d + dt,

where d and dt are the quantities of demand deposits and time deposits
issued by the bank. In period zero, expected period-two bank profits are
(2.11)

E(x)

=

R1

+

~*l+
* rlsl - rd2(l-t)d

-

rtdt,

where sl is the share of bank assets invested in the storage technology in
period one, rd2 is the gross expected yield on demand deposits held for
two periods, and rt is the gross time-deposit rate.
Technological and informational assumptions affect the contracts
issued by banks to attract deposits. One important friction is that a
project's return is observed only by the originating bank. A second important
assumption is that a bank funds a finite number of risky projects and thus
cannot perfectly diversify idiosyncratic risk on its most profitable

investments. Finally, we assume that depositors 1) can observe bank balance
sheets in their locality, 2) know the distribution of depositors in their
locality, 3) know the distribution of future short-term rates, and 4) know the
lower bound on bank-specific projects.

A bank must issue demand-deposit contracts that 1) promise a
default-free rate of return, 2) promise an expected yield that is competitive
with that of the storage technology, and 3) can be withdrawn after one or two
periods. A bank can fulfill these conditions by satisfying

(2.13)

Rml + ~ * l *
+ rJs, 2 rdZj(l-t)d

(2.14)

rd22rr,,

(2.15)

rd>r.

+

rtdtl (j=l,h),

Equations (2.12) and (2.13) state that the return on a bank's portfolio will
be able to compensate depositors as promised in any state of nature (where the
subscripts 1 and h refer to the states where the lower bound and upper bound
on the future storage rate are realized, respectively).

Equations (2.14) and

(2.15) require that the expected return on deposit contracts be at least equal
:-'

to the expected return on the short-term storage technology.

The Maximization Problem of the Marginal Operating Banker
The constrained-optimization problem of the marginal operating banker
determines the profit-maximiziy deposit contract. An operating banker desires
to maximize the share of: his portfolio invested in long-term, risky projects.

A demand-deposit contract, where storage is held solely to pay off early
consumers, minimizes a bank's holdings of short-term projects (and maximizes

expected bank profits) .= This contract promises to pay a deposit rate equal

I

!

to the current short-term rate.

Thus, a bank pqols the liquidity risks of

depositors(by issuing them demand deposits) while investing in long-term
assets.

I

The constrained-optimization problem of the marginal operating banker
I

also determines when this optimal portfolio is feasible. Other operating

I

i

bankers' portfolios will be related to the marginal banker's portfolio via t
l
&&%A

1

distribution of the monitoring technology. The marginal operating banker will

I

make zero expected economic profits as his net expected return on long-term

I

I

risky investmeats equals the two-period expected rate of return on short-term

>

I
I

1

investments. The marginal banker in the economy solves

i
I

(2.16)

1,
1

Max

I

E(X(~)),

(l*,l,~)
8

I

1

subject to (2.12)-(2.15)

I

I

rs - rdtd

(2.17)
1 1 1

I. i

where

I

-

and
s,,

n ( 6 ) is defined by (2.11). Substituting the constraint (2.17) for

s, and using the portfolio balance constraint (2.10) to eliminate d from the

1'11

problem, the first-order necessary conditions for 1, l*, and s are

1;:

I

(2.20)

I

I!, I
I

I' !

/ /j

i1
~

J

J

I:.:

11. :

r(rl+Blrh+P) > rdt(rl+plrh+p) + (1-t) (rd2+plrdZh)
,

respectively, where p is the multiplier for constraint (2.12) and
I

the multiplier for the solvency constraint(2.13).

p1 is

All banks pay depositors

the opportunity cost of their funds. The profit-maximizing deposit costs are

1 rt=rr1 2) r L r , and 3) rdZj=rri,where the future short-term

rate is bounded by (rl,rh).

The marginal operating bank has a monitoring

cost of

'

and makes zero expected profits.

3.11. THE UNCONSTRAINED BANKING ALLOCATIONS

This section describes the alternative equilibrium portfolios of an
operating bank and of the aggregate economy. The results presented are for
banks that can intermediate funds only in their particular location.
We assume that the marginal operating bank uses its technology; thus,

(2.9) and (2.21)
population,

determine the number of operating banks as a fraction of the

2 < (1-a) .

For all banks with monitoring costs below 6(6),

(3-1)

(1+6(e))

>rrl f o r e < g .

These banks maximize profits by maximizing their investments in the long-term,
risky technology and holding storage projects only to meet expected period-one
wikhdrawals; this describes the "optimal portfolio." A type 8 bank has the
following portfolio balance constraint for the optimal portfolio:
(3.2)

1(8)(1+6(8))

+

s

- wb + wt + wd.

The left-hand side of equation (3.2) shows that a 'bank's investments vary
inversely with its monitoring costs, since each bank has the same resources to
invest. Actual bank profits willtvary randomly with 1) the actual return on
risky projects and 2) the actual future interest costs on demand deposits. The

bounds of possible default losses and future &posit

costs are defined by

(2.2). The worst possible profit scenario occurs when a bank realizes the
I

maximum default losses and the highest deposit costs.

The Unconstrained Banking Allocation
The unconstrained allocation for a type B bank is feasible if

The optimal portfolio for an unconstrained bank is thus

I

(3.4)

(1+6(8))1*,

(3.5)

(1+6(8))1,

(3.6)

s,=twd,

=

=

0,

wb + wt + (1-t)wd,

where the subscript u denotes that a bank is unconstrained.
If the marginal operating bank's portfolio satisfies (3.3), all banks

I

A

of types

ei < 8

are also unconstrained. Summing over all operating

banks, expected bank profits for the economy are

since

s=t&.

We will compare alternative constrained allocations to the

unconstrained allocation.

IV. ALTERNATIVE CAPITAL-CONSTRAINED BANKING ALLOCATIONS
1

i

To invest in the optimal bank portfolio, a bank's capital

I

I

must be sufficient to cover possible losses on the share of risky bank assets,
funded by deposit liabilities. When this condition is not satisfied, a bank
is capital-constrained. This occurs when

The first term in (4.1) is the maximum possible portfolio losses on savings
deposits, due to both high future short-term rates and asset default. The
second term is the maximum losses on time deposits due to default losses on
investments made with these funds. The expression (4.1), to be called A, is
strictly positive when the solvency constraint is binding. We shall describe
the alternative equilibria that satisfy the bank solvency constraint in terms
of the optimal portfolio and the term A.
Since A is increasing in b ( 8 ) , the distribution of monitoring costs
will determine the marginal unconstrained bank. Letting 5(eU) solve A

=

0,

then 8" is the share of operating banks that attain the first-best
equilibrium.

A capital-constrained bank must choose an alternative investment, a
"reserve" asset to reduce the risk of the bank portfolio. It has two possible
asset-management options:
1) invest in more short-term storage projects, reinvesting the yield in period
one, as a substitute for a share of risky investments; and

2) invest in a larger share of default-free, long-term investments as a
s-qbstitutefor risky investments.
"9

These choices shall be referred to as options 1 and 2, respectively.
Because both of these assets have a lower expected return, capital-constrained
banks will have lower expected profits than if they could invest in the
unconstrained portfolio. Thus, when eU <

6,

the aggregate quantity of

long-term risky investments and aggregate expected profits will be less than
the unconstrained levels.

A second-best portfolio minimizes the decrease in expected profits
relative to the optimal portfolio while meeting the capital constraint. The
second-best portfolio is not identical for all bahks; the optimal reserve
asset depends o n the efficiency of a banker's technology. Bank technology
determines the relative rate of return on using option 1 versus option 2 to
meet the capital constraint; more efficient banks find that option 2 has a
higher (per-unit) rate of return. However, option 2 reduces only default risk
#. . ,

in a bank's portfolio; it provides a smaller per-unit degree of risk

, P'

reduction. The degree of default risk relative to interest-rate risk in asset
markets determines how much of the respective reserve assets must be held to
meet the capital constraint.

A bank will unambiguously use the storage asset as a reserve asset
when that return dominates the return on default-free bank projects. This will
be the case for operating banks of types 8, > 8*, where 6(8*) solves

If 8* >

eU,capital-constrained banks

of types

ei < 8*

may find it

optimal to use long-term projects as a reserve asset. For a bank with
sufficiently low monitoring costs, the higher rate of return on long-term
projects outweighs the opportunity cost of investing a larger share of the
portfolio in the reserve asset.
The alternative allocations are derived in the appendix. In the
following sections, options 1 and 2 will be described and compared to the
first-best allocation.

Alternative Constrained Allocations
Option 1 can be expressed in terms of A as

(4.4)

- l" - c,(1+6)
A
' where cl

lcl

=

(rrh-L).
( l+6 1

Option 2 can be expressed in terms of A as
(4.5)

I*,,

(4.6)

.
1 c2

=

=

A

(R*- Rm)
A
lU - -

C2 '

- -A

C2'

where c2 = (R*

.-

Rm).

Note that as cl(described as the risk reduction per unit of storage) is
greater than c2, lClis greater than lC2.
/'

Comparing Alternative Portfolio Strategies
In the unconstrained equilibrium, expected profits are
(4.7)

E(mu) =~l~-rr,((l-t)wd+w~).

Expected profits in the two alternative constrained equilibria are

(4.9)

E(r,,)

=

A + R*(~) - rrl((l-t)wd
R(lU- -)

+ wt).

Expected profits are higher for banks when investing in default-free,
long-term projects to reduce portfolio risk when

The expected profitability of option 2 is inversely related to monitoring
costs (and to A). Letting 6(eC2) solve (4.10) with equality, we find
that the marginal monitoring cost below which option 2 represents the
second-best equilibrium is

The value of 6 (gc2) represents a corner solution for banks.

Also, the number of banks choosing option 2 is positively related to
the degree of default risk relative to interest-rate risk. Determining the
parameter values such that no bank will find opti8n c2 to be more profitable
than option cl involves solving (4.11) for 6(eC2)

=

0. Rearranging the

resulting expression illustrates that 6(OC2) is positive and
increasing in the following expression:

This expression has a useful interpretation. The terms in the numerators of
the ratios reflect the expected opportunity cost (per unit) of options 1 and

2, respectively, independent of bank monitoring costs. The terms in the
denominators measure the degree of portfolio risk-reduction (per unit) of
options 1 and 2, respectively. Thus, the ratio measures the marginal cost
relative to the marginal benefit of the alternatives for all banks. As the
cost/benefit ratio of option 1 rises relative to that of option 2,
6 ( e C 2 )increases, and banks with less-efficient technologies find it

profitable to shift to using bank projects as a reserve asset.
When default losses have a large weight in the risk of bank portfolios,
default-free bank projects are a more efficient substitute for risky assets
than the storage technology. A mean-preserving spread on R unambiguously
increases the marginal monitoring cost below which option 2 is optimal. It
should be noted that the share of banks that are constrained increases as
well. Thus, the total holdings of these reserve assets increase.
When interest-rate variability plays a larger role in constraining bank
portfolio choices, the storage technology is a more efficient reserve asset.

A mean-preserving spread of the distribution of future short-term rates

increases the fraction of banks that use option 1 (eC2falls); this, in
turn, increases the share of banks that are constrained as well as the
aggregate quantity of storage projects. lo

V. CONCLUDING REMARKS
This paper has focused on analyzing the implications of bank asset
transformation for bank portfolio choice. Our model shows how a short-term
'M

substitute for bank liabilities and informational asymmetries force banks to
consider interest-rate variability as well as default risk.

A frequent result in the asymmetric information literature is that
information costs create a nonlinearity in the optimization problem of
risk-neutral agents, which makes them behave as if they are risk-averse. The
'ajspersion of imperfectly observed variables affects the expected information
costs associated with making a transaction.
In our framework, there are sufficiently high costs for 1)
risk-neutral depositors to observe bank project returns and 2) risk-neutral
banks to observe depositors' preference shocks. Hence, banks "self-insure"
that they can pay off deposit liabilities under all possible portfolio
outcomes. When a bank is capital-constrained, meeting the worst possible
outcome involves choosing a second-best portfolio, and a risk-neutral banker
is forced to sacrifice (expected) return for portfolio risk-reduction.
Although both depositors and bankers are risk-neutral, asymmetric information
forces a constrained bank to consider risk factors as well as (expected)
return.

Given that a bank is capital-constrained, the relative portfolio risks
affect a bank's choice of a reserve asset to reduce portfolio risk. The
expected relative return from using bank technology and the relative portfolio
risks affect the choice of the most efficient r e s h e asset. A bank will weigh
the expected return/risk-reduction trade-off of alternative bank investment
opportunities. In a sense, a bank has an efficient frontier of projects, and
the parameters of the binding capital-constraint determine its portfolio
choices.
Capital-constrained banks behave as if they are risk-averse to avoid

,

',;

the extreme costs of indifference toward risk, which is the inability to
conduct intermediation and profit from their technology.

FOOTNOTES

1. See Gertler (1988) for an expose on this literature.
2.

These models do not model deposit insurance in their analyses.

3. Bemanke and Gertler (1987) do have both risky assets and demand deposits,
but the latter are relatively inconsequential to their analysis.
This market structure results in a banker accruing all of the profits when
the (expected) marginal return on his portfolios is above the opportunity cost
of funds.
4.

This is the case because a mutual-fund-type "share" contract requires
banks to hold a reserve of storage assets to meet higher period-one deposit
costs when future storage rates are low.
5.

Because the expected return on risky projects is greater than the expected
two-period storage rate for all but the marginal operating banker, bankers
minimize their storage holdings and satisfy (3.12) and (3.15) by linking
one-period deposit returns to market rates.
6.

7. The multiplier #3
equality.

=

0,even when constraint (3.9)

is holding with

8. This separation of banking markets is necessary because bankers have
different monitoring costs, which are assumed to exhibit constant returns to
scale. Another way to avoid having a monopolistic banker would be to place an
upper bound on the quantity of projects a banker can evaluate.

9.

6 (ec2) is decreasing in r, r,, rh, and R, and .increasingin

R* and R ~ .
10. The effect on the quantity of long-term, default-free investments is
uncertain.

.

APPENDIX: ALTERNATIVE CAPITAL-CONSTRAINED ALLOCATIONS
Option 1 can be described by
(A.l)

l*cl=O,

(A.2)

(1+6)lC1

I

+

s,,

- twd

=

(1+6)lU,

(scl - 4) > 0 ,

(A.3)

where sclsolves

Using (A.l), (A.2), (A.3), and the appropriate substitutions, 'scland
lClcan be expressed in terms of A (in section IV) as:

h
l c 1 = l u -cl(I+&)
A
' where cl = rr

(4.4)

-R"
(1+6)

'

Option 2 involves substituting default-free long-term projects for risky,
long-term investments to satisfy the solvency constraint; thus,
wb

+

(A. 5)

(1+6)ltC2

(A. 6)

1,- <

(A.7)

s,,=s"=t~~.

The value for
(A.8)

(1-t)wd + wt

-

1,,(1+S),

lU,

will solve

Rm (wb + (1-t)wd
( 1+6

From(A.5)

(4.6)

=

+

wt- l*cz (I+&))

+~

* 1 =* rrh(l-t)wd
~ ~

+

rrlwt.

to (A.8), expressions for 1*c2and lC2 in terms of A are

1,. = F - ,A

where cz =(R* - R") .

Because cl(which is the risk-reduction per unit of storage) is greater than
Cz lcl

' lC2'

REFERENCES
Bernanke, B., 1983, "Non-Monetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the
Propagation of the Great Depression," American Economic Review,
73, 257-76.

, and M. Gertler, 1987, "Banking and Macroeconomic
Equilibrium," in New Approaches to Monetary Economics, Cambridge
University Press, New York, 89-111.
Bhattacharya, S., and D. Gale, 1987, "Preference Shocks, Liquidity, and
Central Bank Policy," in New Approaches to Monetary Economics,
Cambridge University Press, New York, 69-88.
Boyd, J., and E. Prescott, 1985, "Financial Intermediary Coalitions,"
Journal of Economic Theory, 38, 221-232.
Diamond, D., 1984, "Financial Intermediation and Delegated Monitoring,"
Review of Economic Studies, 51, 393-414.
, and P. Dybvig, 1983, "Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and
Liquidity," Journal of Political Economy, 91, 401-419.

Fama, E., 1980, "Banking in the Theory of Finance," Journal of Monetary
Economics, 6 , 39-57.

, 1985, "What's Different about Banks?" Journal of
Monetary Economics, 15, 29-40.
Gertler, M., 1988, "Financial Structure and Aggregate Economic Activity: An
Ovenriew," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 20, 559-588.
Smith, B., 1984, "Private Information, Deposit Insurance Rates, and the
'Stability' of the Banking System," Journal of Monetary
Economics, 14, 293-317.

, 1986, "Bank Panics, Suspension, and Geography: Some Notes on
the 'Contagion of Fear' in Banking," Working Paper, Carnegie-Mellon
University, Pittsburgh, PA.
Townsend, R., 1979, "Optimal Contracts and Competitive Markets with Costly
State Verification," Journal of Economic Theory, 21, 1979,
265-293.
Williamson, S., 1986, "Costly Monitoring, Financial Intermediation, and
Equilibrium Credit Rationing," Journal of Monetary Economics,
18, 159-179.