View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Working Paper 9102

INFLATION, PERSONAL TAXES, AND
REAL OUTPUT: A DYNAMIC ANALYSIS
by David Altig and Charles T. Carlstrom

David Altig and Charles T. Carlstrom are
economists at the Federal Reserve Bank
of Cleveland. This paper is a revised
version of one prepared for the Conference
on Price Stability held at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland, November 8-10,
1990. The authors would like to express
their deep gratitude to their discussants,
Alan Auerbach and Finn Kydland, who of
course bear no responsibility for any
remaining errors and deficiencies. They
would also like to thank, without implicating,
Rao Aiygari, Steve Davis, Mike Dotsey, Ed
Gamber, Dick Jefferis, Charles Steindel, Alan
Stockman, Ellis Tallman, David Wildasin, their
colleagues at the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland, and seminar participants at
Indiana University, the 1990 Western Economic
Association annual meeting, and the 1990
Federal Reserve System's Business Analysis
Group meeting for many helpful comments on
earlier versions of this work. Kent Smetters
and Josh Rosenberg provided outstanding
programming and research assistance.
Working papers of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Cleveland are preliminary materials
circulated to stimulate discussion and
critical comment. The views stated herein
are those of the authors and not necessarily
those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System.
February 1991

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

I. Introduction
In the not-too-distantpast, examining the policy implications of
specific fiscal-monetary policy mixes meant entering a game with fairly well
established ground rules. These rules stressed the relative effectiveness of
fiscal versus monetary policy instruments in the context of an IS-LM paradigm
in which the causal relationship between high-frequency real economic activity
and "demand-management"policies was taken for granted.

The foundation of

empirical policy analysis in this tradition was the reduced-form econometric
model.

The models were sometimes quite small (the "St. Louis" model, for

example) and sometimes quite large (the DRI model, for example), but the
general notion of specifying reduced-form aggregate demand and supply curves
remained at the core of most empirical strategies.
Arguing within this tradition, Martin Feldstein (1982) pointed to a
specific problem with the common prescription of tight fiscal policy (low
deficits) and easy money - - the failure to recognize the potentially important
consequences of interactions between inflation and the type of nominally based
tax system that has existed in the United States for most of the postwar
period.

Feldstein argued that

the traditional policy mix reflects not only its optimistic view about
the feasibility of government surpluses, but also its overly narrow conception
of fiscal policy. In the current macroeconomic tradition, fiscal policy has
been almost synonymous with variations in the net government surplus or
deficit and has generally ignored the potentially powerful effects of taxes
that influence marginal prices.
Implicit in this reasoning is the assertion that the traditional policy
mix also conceived of monetary policy in an overly narrow way, ignoring the
potentially important effects on long- and short-run economic activity that
can arise through the interaction of inflation and nominal tax schemes.
As several of the papers presented at this conference verify, an
alternative approach to policy analysis has emerged that differs in

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

significant ways from the approach implicit in Feldstein's remarks. In place
of the "traditional approach," we find policy analysis conducted in the
context of general-equilibrium models in which preferences and technologies
are explicitly characterized and equilibria are obtained by aggregating the
decisions of individual firms and households operating in competitive markets.
"Empirical" policy analysis in this new approach typically involves analyzing

-

the simulated responses of artificial economies to particular policy choices,
sometimes in conjunction with formal econometric analysis, sometimes not.
Feldstein's remarks, however, are as salient as ever.

Even when

monetary phenomena are explicitly modeled, as in Huh (1990), Kydland (1989),
and Cooley and Hansen (1989), general-equilibrium simulation models fail to
find a significant explanatory role for monetary policy in the genesis of
business cycle fluctuations. But these models typically ignore the "Feldstein
channel" - - monetary effects that occur through the interaction of inflation
and distortionary nominal tax systems.
This paper addresses the issue implied by Feldstein's argument in a
framework that is consistent with the new generation of policy analysis
models.

In particular, we ask the following question: What consequences do

interactions between inflation and the nominal taxation of capital income have
for the cyclical behavior of the macroeconomy?
Our analysis utilizes the well-known overlapping-generations simulation
framework exemplified by Auerbach and Kotlikoff (1987), henceforth AK.l

We

have chosen this approach because our general orientation is towards examining
the value of extending the AK type of fiscal policy analysis to stochastic
environments. With respect to the specific question at issue here, our model

An extension of the AK framework to the study of business cycle phenomena
has also been developed independently by Rios-Rull (1990).

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

provides a natural framework for fully endogenizing marginal tax rates in a
world with a progressive tax s t r ~ c t u r e . ~
We do not explicitly model a monetary sector (inflation is introduced as
exogenous changes in an arbitrary unit of account), nor do we consider nonzero
levels of government expenditure. We assume that lump-sum adjustments in
taxes and transfers maintain balance in the government's budget constraint and
guarantee the absence of wealth effects on individual households. Also, we
focus solely on the personal tax code and generally ignore distortions
associated with corporate taxation of capital. These choices are obviously
not made because we think these elements are unimportant, but because we wish
to isolate the effects arising purely from distortions of "marginal prices"
created by the interaction of inflation and the personal tax code.
Two empirical observations that become important in our analysis are
demonstrated in figures 1 and 2:

Over the 1955-1988 period, the per capita

capital stock tended to be above its growth-adjusted mean and aggregate per
capita hours tended to be below its mean in periods when inflation tended to
be above its sample average.3 Our numerical model generally mimics this
pattern, a surprising result given that we allow inflation to distort capital
income tax liabilities and we fully index wage income.

McGrattan (1989) considers the cyclical consequences of stochastic
"average" marginal tax rates in a variant of the model developed by Kydland and
Prescott (1982). In her analysis, marginal tax rates are partially endogenous
in that the stochastic process for the average marginal tax rate depends on
realizations of lagged aggregate variables. They are not determined, however,
as the outcome of individual decisions made under a structural tax regime.
The capital stock measure is private fixed nonresidential capital,
measured at the end of the year (net of depreciation) and detrended by the
deterministic growth rate of per capita consumption expenditures on nondurable
goods and services. Total hours is calculated by annual average hours worked in
nonagricultural establishments multiplied by the total civilian population. The
consequences of choosing these particular measures will be dealt with briefly in
our concluding remarks.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

4
In a mechanical sense, our simulations yield these counterintuitive
results for the following reasons.

The level of the capital stock is

dominated by shocks to the model's "technology variable": Given the behavior
of technology shocks, inflation-induced variations in taxes on capital income
have only a small effect on the cyclical behavior of the capital stock. But
because the preference specification we use in our simulations implies that
technology growth exerts offsetting substitution and income effects on the
household leisure choice in the long-run, aggregate hours tend to exhibit
greater sensitivity to inflation shocks than does the capital stock.
The effect on hours occurs for two reasons. The first is that
individuals are taxed on nominal asset income. Because inflation is
persistent, an inflation shock decreases the after-tax rate of return on
savings, causing individuals to substitute intertemporally toward current
consumption and current leisure. That is, higher inflation causes hours
worked to decrease and current consumption to increase. This drives the
model's relationship between inflation and aggregate hours.
The second is due to a kind of "bracket creep":

Even though we assume

wage payments are indexed when determining taxable income, the effect of
overstating real capital income in an inflationary environment causes
inflation-induced increases in marginal tax rates. With flat taxes, the
variability of hours is not affected by the introduction of variable
inflation. With progressive taxes, however, the variability of hours
increases substantially and the covariance between hours worked and output
falls substantially with the introduction of variable inflation. Introducing
inflation/tax interactions also appears to have some effect on the
outputfiours correlation.
The conclusions of our investigations are considerably different from

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

5

what we had conjectured a priori. Despite the fact that the model predicts
"significant" steady-state effects of inflation/nominal-tax interactions, we
find that although variable inflation does appear to increase the variability
of consumption and decrease the variability of investment somewhat, there is
little indication in our model that these types of interactions are necessary
to explain the broad statistical characteristics of the postwar U.S. economy.
Furthermore, to the extent that inflationary biases from capital-income
mismeasurement affect cyclical behavior, the effects appear to affect labor
more than capital.

11. A Brief Look at Inflation and the U.S. Economy
Table 1 presents selected sample moments for several key macroeconomic
variables over the 1955-1988 period. Most of the variables, all of which are
described in the table, are expressed in logarithms and as deviations from a
common deterministic trend. The exceptions are aggregate hours, the average
marginal tax rate, and inflation. In accordance with our simulation
framework, aggregate hours and inflation (which is expressed in levels) are
treated as trendless stationary variables. A separate trend was estimated for
the average marginal tax rate.
Most of the information in table 1 is recognizable from almost any real
business cycle study. However, our detrending procedure differs from the more
common approach of filtering the data using the method first suggested by
Hodrick and Prescott (1980).4

Relative to the population moments obtained

As Kydland and Prescott (1990) note, the Hodrick-Prescott filter can be
thought of as an approximation to stochastic variation in trend. Although we
have chosen to use a log-linear deterministic trend as a first pass at the data,
we plan to examine the consequences of alternative filtering techniques at a
later time. Even though the exact nature of "stylized facts" may be filter
dependent (see, for instance, Nelson and Kang [I9811 and Cogley [I9901) , the

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

6
using the Hodrick-Prescott filter, the deterministic log-linear filter
reverses the relative size of the standard deviations of hours and
productivity and substantially increases the relative standard deviation of
the capital stock.
For purposes of this investigation, we focus on the behavior of tax
variables and the correlations of aggregate variables with inflation. We can
see from table 1 that, for the chosen sample period, -personaltax revenues are
roughly two and one-half times as variable as GNP, while average marginal tax
rates are roughly half as variable as GNP.

Inflation has a much stronger

contemporaneous correlation with tax revenues than with average marginal tax
rates. The contemporaneous correlation of personal tax revenues with output
is positive, although small, while the correlation between output and average
marginal tax rates is strongly negative.
The correlations of inflation and investment and inflation and the
capital stock are .6 and .67, respectively. The correlations of inflation
with output and consumption are both positive (.l and .26, respectively), but
much lower than the investment/inflation correlation. The correlation of
hours and inflation, on the other hand, is negative and equal to - . 3 6 .
Attempting to understand these patterns in the context of inflation/tax
interactions is the primary goal of our dynamic simulations in section VII.

111. The Simulation Framework

A. Households and Preferences
Our model is an overlapping-generations framework with a basic structure

ability of the simulation model to mimic population moments should be independent
of the filtering technique if the model is indeed a useful characterization of
the real economy.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

7
similar to that of AK.

In the basic AK framework, the economy is populated by

a sequence of distinct cohorts that are, with the exception of size, identical
in every respect. Each generation is l+n times larger than its predecessor,
and like AK, we assume that individuals live for 55 periods with perfect
certainty.
In our version of the AK model, individuals alive in calendar time s
choose expected consumption and leisure paths to maximize the expected value
of a time-separable utility function given by

where t indicates cohort age at time s and cj,,+j-,(lj,,+j-,) is the consumption
(leisure) of an age j individual at time s+j-t. The preference parameters p ,
a,, UL, and a represent, respectively, the individual's subjective timediscount factor, the inverse of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution
in consumption (c), the inverse of the intertemporal elasticity of
substitution in leisure (I), and the utility weight of leisure.
The operator E, is a mathematical expectation conditional on the

n,

information set n,. We assume throughout that
all stochastic variables up through time s.

includes the realizations of

Since all of our simulation

experiments assume fixed statutory tax codes,

n,

also includes knowledge of

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

8
the nominal tax structure for all s . ~
The time s budget equation for individuals aged t is given by

where a,,, refers to nonhuman asset acquisitions and Tt,,refers to personal
tax payments.
variable

tt

The pre-tax market wage at time s is given by w,, and the

is an exogenous productivity endowment of an individual in the tth

period of life.
Nonhuman assets represent claims to physical capital that earn a nominal
one-period rate of return R,.

We assume the existence of a single homogeneous

asset class, thus eliminating the potential consequences of tax-induced
portfolio adjustments that would occur in a model with heterogeneous assets.
Personal tax payments in the model arise from a progressive income tax
supplemented by a system of lump-sum transfers. Total tax payments are thus
given by

where y is the tax base, g(.) is a function relating the tax base to marginal
tax rates, and

r t r Sis

a lump-sum tax (or transfer).

We assume throughout

Rate structures and personal exemption levels in the personal tax code
were relatively stable until the late 1970s. Similarly, changes in the treatment
of income from capital gains and personal deduction provisions were relatively
infrequent until the early to middle 1970s. Since that time, however, the
frequency of structural changes in the personal tax code has increased
dramatically. The assumption that individuals take the tax structure as fixed is
therefore a better approximation for the first 20-25 years of the post-World War
I1 era than for the period since the mid-1970s (in the United States, at least) .
Bizer and Judd (1989) discuss some of the consequences of stochastic tax
structures in the context of a tax structure with exogenous marginal tax rates.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

that lump-sum taxes and transfers are used to offset all revenues raised
through the income tax.

In so doing, we concentrate our attentions on the

pure distortionary effects of the tax system.
We define the tax base y* as

where D,,, represents adjustments to gross income such as allowable deductions
and personal exemptions. By defining taxable income in this way, we are
implicitly adjusting tax brackets for inflation in a manner that is roughly
consistent with the indexing provisions in the current tax code (see Tatom
[I9851 and Altig and Carlstrom [1991] for a discussion of those provisions).
Our definition of the tax base means that, for any s , real capital
income is overstated by an amount equal to .Ir,a,-l/(l+.Ir,).6

This overstatement

causes inflation to have real effects that can arise through two separate
channels. The first is a pure capital-income mismeasurement effect that
lowers the after-tax real return to capital when nominal interest rates rise.
The second is a type of bracket creep effect that occurs under a progressive
tax system when overstatement of real capital income pushes individual
taxpayers into higher marginal tax brackets. We will see that both of these
effects can affect the behavior of aggregate hours, a result alluded to in the
introduction.
In addition to equation ( 2 ) , we impose the initial condition ao,,=O for
all s , and the terminal condition that the present value of lifetime resources
not exceed the present value of lifetime consumption plus tax payments.

In

Real capital income is given by (R, -T,)a,-l/(l+.lr,) . Deflating nominal
income by l + ~ ,thus overstates real income by .Irsas-l/(l+.Ir,).

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

10
the absence of a bequest motive and lifetime uncertainty, the wealth
constraint implies that a55,
,=0.
Equations (1)-(4)

yield the first-order conditions

and

or, in more familiar terms,

and

where py, is the marginal tax rate of an individual with taxable income y*.

B. Firms and Technologv
Output in the model is produced by competitive firms that combine
capital (K) and labor (L) using a neoclassical production technology. The
aggregate production technology is Cobb-Douglas, defined over aggregate
capital and labor supplies as

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

The parameter 8 is capital's share in production, A is an arbitrary scale
factor, p is the deterministic growth rate of effective labor units, and z, is
the realization of a stochastic labor-augmenting "technology ~ariable."~In
what follows, we normalize A to one.
We follow Prescott (1986) and assume that z, is generated by the process
2, =

where

<,

tlZ,-l

+

£,I

(10)

is the realization of an independent and identically distributed

(iid) normal random variable with mean zero. We further assume that the
absolute value of

is strictly less than one.

Aggregate capital and labor supplies are defined from individual
supplies as

55

K,

=

(l+n)'-'E
t=l

at, s-1
( l + n )t - 5 5

and

Note that equations (11) and (12) are just the capital- and labor-market

The debate over the exact nature of this "technology variable," which
empirically is just the part of GNP that cannot be explained by measured labor
and capital inputs under the maintained aggregate production technology, is well
known and need not be rehashed here. We refer interested readers to the
discussions in Prescott (1986), Summers (1986), McCallum (1989), and Eichenbaum
(1990).

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

12
adjusted aggregate labor supply given in equation (12) and the technology
parameter z,.

Dividing both sides of equation (9) by exp(ps+z,)L,

yields a

stationary relationship in terms of the effective capital-labor ratio, given
by

Under the standard assumption of competitive markets, the.pre-tax real wage
and nominal interest rates are given by

and

R,

=

( 0 k ; - l - 6 ) ( l + x , ) + x 9'

(15)

where 6 is a constant real rate of depreciation on physical capital. We
assume throughout that, for tax purposes, capital income is calculated
exclusive of real depreciation costs.'
Finally, we complete our description of the model by including the
goods-market clearing condition given by

The effect of inflation on investment decisions under historical cost
depreciation rules is of course central to any complete discussion of
inflation/tax-system interactions. The literature that specifically examines
this issue is quite large. A few examples that concentrate on quantitative
aspects of the issue are Feldstein and Summers (1979), Auerbach (1983), and King
and Fullerton (1984).

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

where

Note again that we do not explicitly model a monetary sector.

Inflation

is introduced into our framework by the addition of an arbitrary unit of
account. We thus ignore the effects of seigniorage and any distortions that
arise through monetary channels per se.

IV. Solving the Model
The steady state of the model is solved by setting the values of the
stochastic variables z, and

n,

equal to their unconditional means and applying

the iterative procedure described in AK (chapter 4).

This section briefly

describes the procedure we use for simulating what we loosely refer to as the
stochastic path of the economy.
The steady-state calculations provide us with endpoints for the
stochastic transition path simulations. The behavior of the economy along the
stochastic path is derived by calculating a sequence of transitions to
deterministic steady states arising from a sequence of inflation and
technology "shocks." The stochastic path of the economy is given by the
envelope of the first-period observations obtained from each of these
transition paths.

Specifically, we proceed as follows:

(i) Starting from the initial steady state, we set the realization of z1
and n1 equal to the actual values calculated for the U.S. economy in 1951.
Given assumed stochastic processes for inflation and the technology variable
(described in the next section), these realizations imply conditional

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

expectations for the time paths of z, and

R,

for s

=

l . . . ~ . The implied

expected values of inflation and the technology variables are then substituted
into individual first-order conditions and wealth constraints to obtain
certainty equivalent transition paths to the deterministic steady state.g
Assuming no further shocks to the inflation or technology process, these
transition paths correspond exactly to the perfect foresight transition paths
calculated in the typical AK simulation exercise. The initial element of the
transition path calculated in this way gives us our observations of the
economy for s=l .
(ii) The asset levels obtained for the s=l calculations are used as
inputs for the second stochastic path observation, s=2. For example, the
assets accumulated by the age t cohort at s=l would be those brought into the
period by the cohort that is age t+l at time s=2. From equation (ll),
aggregate asset accumulation at s=l provides the capital stock for the
calculations at time s=2.
(iii) Given the initial conditions implied by the s=l calculations, the
1952 values of inflation and the technology variable are used to repeat the
procedure described in step (i).

Specifically, the new values of z and n

imply a revision in the expected path of inflation and the technology
variable.

Based on the revisions of this expected path and the period's

initial conditions, a new transition to the deterministic steady state is
calculated, the initial observation of which describes the economy at s=2.
(iv) The entire sequence of stochastic path observations is obtained by
repeating steps (i)-(iii)

using observations of the calculations at s-1 as

Because we assume stationary processes for both inflation and the
technology parameter, the steady state is invariant to specific realizations of
these processes. In the actual simulations, we allow the model 110 periods to
converge to the steady state.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

15
initial conditions for time s and the realized values of inflation and the
technology variable for the U.S. economy from 1951 through 1988. This
procedure is represented schematically in figure 3.1°

V. Parameterizing the Model
Once values are chosen for the model's parameters, solutions are
obtained using the numerical methods just described. Our benchmark values for
most of the preference and technology parameters are reported in table 2.
These values are generally consistent with those found in other simulation
studies (see, for example, AK and Prescott [1986]) and are motivated by
independent empirical studies.''
The sensitivity of our simulations to selected parameter assumptions is
partially addressed in the next section. The main focus of the balance of
this section is the motivation for three elements not described in table 2:
the personal tax code, the stochastic processes for the technology variable,
and the rate of inflation. We base each of these parameterizations on simple
regression analysis.
A. The Personal Tax Code
We model marginal tax rates as a linear function of taxable income.
Thus, g(y) in equation (3) is given by

lo It is not possible in general to guarantee that the model will converge
to a unique equilibrium. The best that can typically be done is to hope for
convergence and examine the sensitivity of the model's solutions to starting
values. See, for example, the discussions in Rios-Rull (1990) and Laitner
(1990).
l1 An exception is the preference parameter a, which measures the utility
weight of leisure. Our choice of a=.5 implies that the average individual
allocates approximately 24 percent of his or her total time to labor-market
activity in the steady state. This amounts to an average workweek of just over
40 hours.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

S(Y)

=

where y is defined as in equation (4).

go

+

g,Yr

(18)

As a benchmark case, we obtained the

parameters go and gl by regressing marginal tax rates for married persons
filing jointly on the taxable income levels mandated by the 1965 tax code (in
1988 dollars).

This procedure yields the values go=.146 and gl=.0000023.

The 1965 personal tax rate structure was chosen for three reasons.
First, the 1965 rate structure, which was designated in the Revenue Act of
1964, was in effect longer than any other postwar rate structure. Second, a
linear function seems to fit the 1965 rate structure reasonably we11.12
Third, linear approximations of the 1965 rate structure yield values of gl
that are smaller than those obtained by performing analogous regressions with
other postwar rate structures. Since the benchmark tax structure turns out to
be too progressive in some important ways, our results would not be improved
by imposing tax structures that are more progressive (in the sense of yielding
larger values of gl).
In addition to choosing the tax parameters go and gl, it is necessary to
convert the gross income figures determined by the model into taxable income
values to be used in determining marginal tax rates. We proceed in two steps,
first scaling the absolute levels of gross income and then adjusting gross
income to arrive at taxable income values (by specifying levels for deductions

l2 By "reasonably well" we mean that a linear function is a good choice
among the class of continuous, differentiable functions. It is unclear how our
results would be biased by approximating the discrete tax code with a continuous
(and differentiable) function. On one hand, the discreteness of the true rate
structure means that many people face constant tax rates at the margin, a feature
that is obviously not captured by the linear rate structure we impose. On the
other hand, changes in marginal tax rates in the true personal tax code are much
larger for affected individuals than changes implied by our hypothetical tax
code. We are currently working on extensions of the model that we hope will shed
light on this issue.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

17
and personal exemptions).

The details of our calculations are described in an

appendix.

B. The Inflation and Technology Processes
As noted in section 111, our stochastic path simulations use realized
values of inflation and the technology variable for the U.S. economy over the
period 1951-1988. The inflation variable is simply the growth rate in the
CPI-U. The technology variable z is calculated from the relationship

z~ = ln(Y,) - [ l n ( A )

+

ps +

(1-6)ln(L,)

+

6ln(~,)],

(19)

which comes directly from equation (9).
Equation (19) is made empirically operational by letting Y equal annual
GNP, K equal the fixed nonresidential capital stock, and L equal total hours
calculated from data on hours and total employment (see table 1 for exact
definitions and data sources).

We set 8 = . 3 6 in constructing the series

described by equation (19).
Note that we eliminate the deterministic trend when calculating the
value of the technology variable. This allows us to solve the simulation
model assuming zero growth per capita.

In particular, this approach avoids

problems presented by the growth in the real wage indicated by equation
(14) . l3
Parameterizing expectations requires choosing specific processes for
inflation and the technology variable. The latter is provided by taking the
series calculated according to equation (17) and estimating the model given in

l3 This clarification was prompted by the remarks of Alan Auerbach. See
Hansen (1989) for a detailed discussion of the technical issues associated with
growth in real business cycle models.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

18
equation (9) over the sample period 1952-1988.14 This procedure yields the
estimated value $=. 80.l5

A second-order autoregressive process is estimated for the inflation
rate over the period 1953-1989. We assume the absence of trend in the
inflation rate and find that a second-order process is sufficient to eliminate
serial correlation in the residuals.16 The estimated inflation model is

Note that the intercept implies a steady-state annual inflation rate of just
over 4 percent.

VI. Steady-State Experiments
The steady-state output effects of distortions arising from
inflation/tax-system interactions (specifically, from capital-income
mismeasurement) are reported in table 3. The experiments reported therein use
the benchmark parameterization described in table 2.

In addition to the

linear tax scheme described in the previous section (which we designate the
Progressive I case), we consider a less progressive case and a flat-tax-rate

l4 Because A and p are not directly observable, we first construct the
-Bln(K,). Estimations of rl and the residual series
variable 91, = ln(Y,)-(1-B)ln(L,)
Es are then obtained by regressing the 91 on a constant, a time trend, and its own
values lagged once.
l5 This is the value we would expect to find at an annual frequency if the
autoregressive parameter found from a regression on quarterly data was roughly
.95. Having said this, we note that the properties we assume for the E, process
are not appropriate if the true process is iid at a quarterly frequency. In fact,
the residual series that we estimate exhibits some serial correlation, which
indicates the possibility of time aggregation bias in the annual data.
l6

model.

Trend terms are statistically insignificant when added to the regression

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

case. The parameterizations of each of the separate regimes are chosen to
yield steady-state average marginal tax rates of about 23 percent.l7
In each of the cases reported in table 3 , the steady-state output losses
due to capital-income mismeasurement are relatively large: Even in the flattax case, a 4 percent steady-state rate of inflation results in steady-state
output levels that are only about 95 percent of the levels that would be
realized in a zero-inflation steady state.
The lower panel of table 3 reports the value of output losses per dollar
of revenue raised through the income tax system. The losses range from 4.7
percent (in the flat-tax case) to 5.2 percent (in the Progressive I case) when
the steady-state annual inflation rate is 4 percent. Although not reported in
table 3, almost all of the reduction in output results from a reduction in the
capital stock, not from a large reduction in hours worked.
We emphasize that comparisons across the experiments reported in table 3
are inappropriate, since no attempt has been made to standardize tax revenues
under the different tax codes.

In addition, the figures reported in table 3

provide no information about welfare impacts or the relative efficiency of
raising revenue through inflation/tax interactions relative to statutory tax
changes in a zero-inflation environment.l8

The figures in table 3 are useful

l7 The 23 percent figure is obtained from the calibration exercise
described in the appendix, which uses the Progressive I tax scheme. Although the
Progressive I tax structure was not a priori chosen to yield this value, it is
gratifyingly close to the average value of 25 percent reported by Sahasakul
(1986) for effective marginal tax rates on personal income over the period 19511982.
l8
Naturally, the relative efficiency of raising revenue through
inflation/tax interactions depends on the nature of the alternative being
contemplated. The life-cycle nature of our model implies that individual saving
is high when income is high. Tax schemes with lesser degrees of progressivity
therefore tend to result in lesser degrees of "crowding-out" of steady-state
capital and output for a given revenue requirement.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

20

only as a means of demonstrating that the long-run consequences of the
inflation/tax interactions we are modeling are significant.
Table 4 reports the results obtained by repeating the steady-state
experiments after changing selected values of the benchmark parameters
reported in table 2. The picture that emerges from table 4 is that greater
steady-state output losses are associated with an increased willingness of
individuals to shift resources intertemporally (that is, smaller values of a,,
al, and p ) , smaller rates of depreciation and population growth, and stronger
preferences for leisure. In general, these are elements that tend to increase
per capita saving rates.
The numbers reported in tables 3 and 4 assume the absence of tax
arbitrage opportunities that would allow individuals to partially escape the
distortionary effects of inflation on capital income by changing the way in
which claims to capital are structured. We think particularly of shifts
between debt and equity in a tax environment where nominal interest payments
on debt are fully deductible but equity is tax preferred. The last row of
table 4 gives results derived from the case where debt and equity instruments
with these tax characteristics are introduced. This extension of the model,
which essentially follows Miller (1977), is otherwise identical to the basic
model used in the main body of this paper.
In the reported simulation, corporate tax rates are set to 16.5
percent, and 65 percent of equity income is tax sheltered. Although
introducing tax arbitrage opportunities does substantially reduce steady-state
output losses from capital-income mismeasurement, simply stating the
assumptions of this experiment suggests a problem with implementing this
particular extension of the model:

The corporate tax rate necessary to

generate an equilibrium with both debt and equity is extremely small

--

much

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

21
smaller than most estimates of the effective corporate tax rate.
We could, of course, attempt to justify the low corporate tax rate by
appealing to bankruptcy risk or losses of nondebt tax shields. Also, higher
corporate tax rates could be introduced into the model by increasing the
fraction of equity income that can be excluded from the calculation of taxable
income. However, neither of these strategies seems likely to overcome the
essential problem we face with our current model choice; that is, the
particular life-cycle structure of our model does not provide enough
heterogeneity to generate equilibria with realistic tax arbitrage behavior, a
weakness that is manifested in a very small parameter space over which both
debt and equity are held in the steady-state equilibrium.lg
To counter this problem, we are currently working on extensions of the
model with intracohort heterogeneity. We note for present purposes that one
of the implications we derive from the dynamic simulations reported in the
next section is the relatively small effect that inflation/tax interactions
seem to have on, say, the variability of output in our model.

In this sense,

excluding tax arbitrage opportunities strengthens our result.

VII. llStochastic Path" Simulations
The results of simulating the model using the method described in

l9 This weakness is manifested in two related ways. First, the debt-equity
ratio is extremely sensitive to the rate of inflation. For the parameterization
reported here, the steady-state debt-equity ratio falls from .734 to .225 as the
steady-state rate of inflation increases from 0 to 4 percent. (Note also that the
negative relationship between the debt-equity ratio and inflation is
counterfactual.) Second, small changes in the corporate tax rate push all
individuals to corners with respect to their desired holding of particular
assets. Holding all else constant, decreasing the corporate tax rate by 1
percent results in steady-state equilibria in which only equity is held.
Increasing the corporate tax rate by 1 percent results in equilibria in which
only debt is held.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

22
section IV are reported in tables 5-7. Each of the simulation exercises
assumes the benchmark parameterization given in table 2 and either the flattax scheme (table 5), the Progressive I scheme (table 6), or the intermediate
Progressive 11 scheme (table 7).

The simulations are conducted for the sample

period 1951-1988 with actual technology shocks ( E , ) as inputs. In addition,
for the variable inflation case, we include actual CPI-U inflation rates as
inputs.

In order to minimize the effect of the initial conditions, we

calculate simulated sample moments for the observations obtained for the
period 1955-1988.
Looking first at the constant inflation cases, we find that the standard
deviations of output, consumption, and investment are largely invariant to the
tax regime. The standard deviation of output is very close to the standard
deviation found in the data, with increases in the progressivity of the tax
code inducing slightly less volatility in output.

The relative standard

deviation of consumption is also very close to that found in the data (e.g.,
.73 for the Progressive I1 case versus .71 for the U.S. data).

Investment,

however, is somewhat smoother (relative to variation in output) than suggested
by the data (2.06 for the Progressive I1 case versus 2.23 for the actual
data).

The model also exhibits variation in the capital stock that is smaller

than that in the U.S. economy (as measured by nonresidential fixed capital).
The relative standard deviation in the Progressive I1 case is .95, versus 1.15
for the U.S. economy. Productivity has slightly too much variability (.91 for
the Progressive I1 case versus .85 found in the data).

Again, the relative

standard deviation is not substantially affected by the tax regime when
inflation is constant.
The correlations of output with consumption, investment, and capital are
all positive, but tend to be higher than the correlations found in the actual

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

23
data. This is not particularly surprising given the highly specific nature of
the model and the probable magnitude of noise in the actual data. Also, the
standard deviation of hours given by the model is much lower relative to the
standard deviation of output than is true for the aggregate hours/output
relationship in the data.

This result is familiar from real business cycle

studies with the simple type of labor- and goods-market structures we have
assumed.20
The ability of the model to mimic the behavior of the U.S. economy is
also demonstrated in figures 4 and 5, which plot the actual and simulated
paths of hours and capital from 1955-1988.21
Although the general trend in aggregate hours is replicated by our
model, figure 4 clearly demonstrates the overly smooth behavior of simulated
hours relative to actual hours.
The simulated path of capital matches the data quite well until the late
1970s, at which point it begins a decline toward below-mean values that
persists through 1988. The capital stock calculated from the data appears to
stay above its mean throughout the 1980s, however. As we note in the

20
We do not view our version of the AK framework as a competitor to
standard real business cycle models and certainly do not mean to engage in a
"horse race" of matching moments. However, given differences in structure and
solution approach, we would be concerned if we were not generally able to claim
that our approach yields results that are in the ballpark of alternative
simulation frameworks. In fact, we believe that they are. Consider, as a basis
of comparison, the "basic model" reported in McCallum (1989). The relative
standard deviations of consumption, investment, capital, andhours calculated for
quarterly data after application of the Hodrick-Prescott filter are .31, 3.14,
.26, and .52 in the model versus .73, 3.0, .36, and .94 in the data,
respectively. We feel that our results compare favorably to these. (Note,
however, the somewhat different patterns that emerge relative to table 3 under
the different filtering method.)

The simulated series in figures 4 and 5 assume the Progressive I1 tax
regime and are calculated with variability in both inflation and technology.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

24
conclusion, this divergence seems to be an artifact of the way we have
detrended the capital stock data.
Without inflation, the model generates too little variability in
personal tax revenues and generally too little variability in average marginal
tax rates. The variability of both tax measures does increase as the
progressiveness of the structural tax code increases, however.

The model also

generates a high positive contemporaneous correlation between output and our
tax measures, a result that is clearly at odds with the pattern found in the
data.
The bottom panels of tables 5-7 display results obtained when inflation
is introduced into the model.

Inflation increases the variability of

consumption and decreases the variability of investment, but has a minimal
impact on the standard deviation of output and capital. The introduction of
inflation also has little influence on the correlation of these variables with
output.
Hours are quite another story. The relative standard deviation of hours
almost doubles in the Progressive I tax structure (from .10 to .la) when
actual inflation values are used as inputs. Depending on the tax structure,
inflation also affects the correlation between output and hours.

In the

Progressive I case, the contemporaneous correlation of output and hours falls
by more than 50 percent, from .52 to .21. In the flat-tax case, however, the
relationship between output and hours changes considerably less, from .69 to
.57.
The Progressive I1 case yields a relative standard deviation of the
average marginal tax rate and personal tax payments much like the one found in
the data (.31 and 2.50, respectively, versus .40 and 2.60 for the actual
data).

However, with variable inflation, the Progressive I1 case delivers an

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

25
hours/inflation correlation that is more negatively correlated than that found
in the U.S. economy (-.75 versus -.356 in the data).

The lack of a corporate

income tax, and hence the lack of tax arbitrage, is one reason inflation has a
larger impact on this correlation than seems warranted in the data.

In a

model with corporate taxes, nominal interest rates will partially reflect a
tax-adjusted Fisher effect, which would minimize inflation-induced changes in
a consumer's after-tax rate of return.
The model also does a fairly good job of mimicking the positive
correlation between output and inflation, consumption and inflation, and
productivity and inflation. The correlations of productivity and consumption
with inflation are mimicked reasonably well in both the constant and variable
inflation models.

The output/inflation correlation is closer to the data in

the variable inflation case. Only with respect to investment are the results
of the model clearly at odds with the data.
Overall, our model seems to be consistent with the phenomena indicated
in figures 1 and 2 - - a positive correlation between the level of inflation
and capital and a negative correlation between the level of inflation and the
level of aggregate hours. This seems surprising at first, because the nature
of the tax structure we have imposed on the model is such that inflationinduced tax distortions occur only through capital-income mismeasurement.
Figures 6 and 7, which depict the perfect foresight paths of hours and
capital in response to various combinations of one-time unanticipated shocks
to the inflation and technology variables, shed light on why the model
generates these correlations. Each path is generated by a one-standarddeviation increase or decrease to one or both of the relevant variables. The
experiments assume the Progressive I tax regime because it amplifies the tax
structure found in the Progressive I1 tax regime. "Good shocks" are a

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

26

positive shock to the technology variable and a negative shock to inflation,
and "bad shocks" are a negative shock to the technology variable and a
positive shock to inflation.
The interesting cases in figures 6 and 7 are those with one good shock
and one bad shock.

Consider the combination of a positive technology shock

and a positive inflation shock. This combination is associated with capital
rising above its mean but hours that are below average.

Just the opposite is

true for the combination of a negative technology shock and a negative
inflation shock

--

capital moves below average while hours move above average.

The message here is that, with respect to the evolution of the capital
stock, changes in the level of the technology variable dominate distortions
associated with tax distortions arising from inflation/tax interactions in the
personal tax code. We infer that the positive correlation between capital and
inflation does not reflect a positive causal relationship from inflation to
capital, but rather coincidental correlations between the technology variable
and capital and the technology variable and inflation.

Indeed, although the

contemporaneous relationship between the technology variable and inflation is
small, the relationship is stronger - - and positive - - with inflation led one
period.
How does the negative correlation between aggregate hours and inflation
arise in a model in which the tax liability of labor income per se is
protected from inflation by the indexing scheme we have assumed in our
calculations? This pattern arises through two channels by which the
overstatement of capital income spills over into individual leisure decisions.
The first channel is a direct result of the fact that inflation-induced
changes in nominal asset income increase an individual's real tax on capital
income.

In particular, inflation decreases an individual's after-tax rate of

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

27

return on savings, causing individuals to substitute toward current leisure.
The second channel occurs because, with a progressive income tax,
marginal tax rates increase with nominal capital income, which in turn affects
both the return to saving and the future after-tax real wage.

The fact that

the model's outputfiours correlation and the standard deviation of hours
change substantially when progressivity is introduced into the tax system
suggests the importance of this type of phenomenon.

VIII. Concluding Remarks
We originally set out to uncover possible business cycle effects that
might arise from inflation/personal-tax interactions working through capitalincome mismeasurement in inflationary environments. We suspected that we
would find substantial variation in capital accumulation arising from this
channel. We did not.
Instead, we found effects in an unexpected place - - the behavior of
aggregate hours. We fully believe that understanding the cyclical behavior of
labor will involve enriching models in ways not considered here (as in
Christian0 and Eichenbaum [1990], for instance).

Based on our experiments, we

suggest another element that may be useful in developing an understanding of
the dynamic behavior of aggregate hours - - labor supply distortions that arise
specifically through distortions associated with both the direct effects of
capital-income mismeasurement and the more indirect effects of bracket creep.
Our extension of the AK framework, which easily incorporates structural tax
schemes, seems well suited to this task.
Another surprising finding is that the positive correlation between
capital and inflation does not reflect any causal relationship, i.e., it seems
to arise from the correlation between inflation and the Solow residual found

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

28

in the data. Our model did a good job of matching the correlation between the
model's capital series and the actual inflation rates for the U.S. economy
even when we assumed a constant inflation rate.
Further investigation of the mechanisms that yield the results reported
here is clearly in order. As noted by the discussants, the "stylized facts"
of the inflationfiours and inflation/capital relationships considered here are
somewhat puzzling and may not hold up to further scrutiny. Our preliminary
investigations, for instance, suggest that the negative inflationfiours
correlation may be sensitive to the data used in the construction of the
aggregate hours variable, which is based on establishment survey data rather
than on the broader household survey data.

It is unclear whether the model

would match the pattern of hours measured by the household data, since a
different measure of aggregate hours would imply a different series for the
Solow residuals.
The behavior of the capital stock series does appear to be sensitive to
our detrending method.

In fact, while the positive inflation/capital

correlation remains when capital is detrended by its own deterministic time
trend, the time path of the capital stock series behaves much like the
simulated series depicted in figure 5.
Despite these caveats, it seems clear that inflation/nominal-tax
interactions can have quite unanticipated effects on the macroeconomy, and
that the type of simulation framework developed here can aid in understanding
what these effects might be.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

References
Altig, .David and Charles Carlstrom, "Bracket Creep in the Age of Indexing:
Have We Solved the Problem?" Contemvorarv Policv Issues, 1991,
forthcoming.
Auerbach, Alan, "Corporate Taxation in the United States," Brookings Pavers on
Economic Activitv, 1983, 451-513.
Auerbach, Alan and Laurence Kotlikoff, Dvnamic Fiscal Policv, Cambridge
University Press, London, 1987.
Bizer, David and Kenneth Judd, "Taxes and Uncertainty," American Economic
Review. Pavers and Proceedings, 79, 1989, 331-336.
Christiano, Lawrence and Martin Eichenbaum, "Current Real Business Cycle
Theories and Aggregate Labor Market Fluctuations," Discussion Paper 24,
Institute for Empirical Macroeconomics, Federal Reserve Bank of
Minneapolis, January 1990.
Cogley, Timothy, "Spurious Business Cycle Phenomena in HP Filtered Time
Series," Discussion Paper 90-21,University of Washington, Seattle,
July 1990.
Cooley, Thomas and Gary Hansen, "The Inflation Tax in a Real Business Cycle
Model," American Economic Review, 79, September 1989, 733-748.
Eichenbaum, Martin, "Real Business Cycle Theory : Wisdom or Whimsy? " Working
Paper, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, July 1990.
Feldstein, Martin, "Inflation, Capital Taxation, and Monetary Policy," in R.E.
Hall, ed., Inflation: Cause and Effect, University of Chicago Press,
Chicago, IL, 1982.
Feldstein, Martin and Lawrence Summers, "Inflation and the Taxation of Capital
Income in the Corporate Sector," National Tax Journal, 32, December 1979,
445-470.
Hansen, Gary, "Technical Progress and Aggregate Fluctuations," Working Paper
546, University of California, Los Angeles, February 1989.
Hodrick, Robert J. and Edward C. Prescott, "Post-WarU.S. Business Cycles:
An Empirical Investigation," Working Paper, Carnegie-Mellon University,
Pittsburgh, PA, 1980.
Huh, Chan G. , "Output, Money, and Price Correlations in a Real Business
Cycle Model," unpublished manuscript, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco,
February 1990.
King, Mervyn and Don Fullerton, The Taxation of Income From Capital,
University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL, 1984.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Kydland, Finn, "The Role of Money in a Business Cycle Model," Discussion paper
23, Institute for Empirical Macroeconomics, Federal Reserve Bank of
Minneapolis, 1989.
Kydland, Finn and Edward Prescott, "Time to Build and Aggregate Fluctuations,"
Econometrica, 50, November 1982, 1345-1370.
Kydland, Finn and Edward Prescott, "Business Cycles: Real Facts and a Monetary
Myth," Quarterlv Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Spring
1990.
Laitner, John, "Tax Changes and Phase Diagrams for an Overlapping Generations
Model," Journal of Political Economv, 98, February 1990, 193-220.
McCallum, Bennett, "Real Business Cycle Models," in R. Barro, ed., Modern
Business Cvcle Theorv, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA, 1989.
McGrattan, Ellen, "The Macroeconomic Effects of Distortionary Factor
Taxation," manuscript, Duke University, Raleigh, NC, 1989.
Miller, Merton, "Debt and Taxes," Journal of Finance, 32, May 1977, 261-275.
Nelson, Charles and Heejoon Kang, "Spurious Periodicity in Inappropriately
Detrended Time Series," Econometrica, 49, May 1981, 741-751.
Prescott, Edward, "Theory Ahead of Business Cycle Measurement," CarnegieRochester Conference Series, Autumn 1986, 11-44.
Rios-Rull, Jose-Victor, "Life-Cycle Economies and Aggregate Fluctuations,"
manuscript, Carnegie-Mellon University, Pittsburgh, PA, 1990.
Sahasakul, Chaipat, "The U.S. Evidence on Optimal Taxation Over Time," Journal
of Monetarv Economics, 18, 1986, 251-276.
Summers, Lawrence, "Some Skeptical Observations on Real Business Theory,"
Quarterly Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, 1986.
Tatom, John, "Federal Income Tax Reform in 1985: Indexation," Review, Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis, February 1985.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Figure 1: Inflation and Capital
0.1

Sources: Department of Commerce and
Bureau of Labor Statistics.

I ------ Inflation -Capital I

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Year
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

------ Inflation - Hours

NOTE: The dashed lines represent certainty equivalent output paths conditional on the state of the economy and the realized
technology shock at time t. The solid line connects the initial observation of each of these transition paths and represents the
cyclical behavior of the economy conditional on the sequence of realized technology shocks.
SOURCE: Authors' calculations.

Figure 3: Schematic Representation of Solution Algorithm

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Figure 4: Hours,1955-1988
Actual and Simulated Hours Series
-- - - --- -

Hours

I Model Hours I

-0.08 1
1955

I

I

1965

I

I

1975

Year
Sources: Authors' calculations and Bureau of Labor Statistics.

I

I

1985

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Figure 5: Capital,1955-1988
Actual and Simulated Capital Series

......

..,.....s

Ca'pital
--------

1

-0.08 I
1955

i

1

1965

1

I

1975

I

I

1985

Year
Source: Authors' calculations. See previous figures for sources of actual data.

Model Capital

1

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Figure 6: Aggregate Hours
Implied Responses to Selected Shocks
V.V I J

-m-

F-......-...

:

.
*
a
-

0.01 -

Pos. Solow Only

........

+

x...-...

Pos. Inflation Only

.'...

*

----......

+Solow, -1nf lation

-€+
-Solow, +Inflation
4-

+Solow, +Inflation
.....&..-Solow, -Inflation

-0.01 5

0

I

1

I

I

1

2

3

4

5

Period
Each line represents the perfect foresight path given a one-standarddeviation shock to the indicated
exogenous variable at time 1.
Source: Authors' calculations.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Figure 7: Capital Stock
Implied Responses to Selected Shocks
-C-

Pos. Solow Only

0.03-

+

Pos. Inflation Only
..-.m -....
+Solow, -Inflation
-E3-

-Solow, +Inflation
Jt-

+Solow, +Inflation

........
..A
-Solow, -Inflation

A---.------A ....-.-..- --... .&----.---dL

-0.03
-0.041
0

1

1

1

1

2

3

1

4

1

5 6
Period

I

1

7

1

1

8

9

1

I

0

Each line represents the perfect foresight path given a one-standarctdeviation shock to the indicated
exogenous variable at time 1.
Source: Authors' calculations.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 1: Sample Moments, U.S. Data 1955-1988,
Common rend*

Variable

Standard
~eviation*"

Contemporaneous Correlation
With Output
With .~r

Kev :
Y: Gross National Product. Source: 1990 Economic Report of the President
(EROP) .
C: Personal Consumption Expenditures, Nondurable Goods and Services.
Source: EROP.
I: Gross Private Domestic Fixed Investment, Source: EROP.
H: Total Annual Hours: E*AvgH*52, where E = Total Civilian Employment
and AvgH = Total Private Nonagricultural Establishments Average
Weekly Hours. Sources: EROP and Bureau of Labor Statistics.
K: Fixed Private Nonresidential Capital, Net of Depreciation. Source:
Survev of Current Business, October 1989.
T: Personal Tax and Nontax Payments. Source: EROP.
T': Average Marginal Personal Tax Rate. Source: Sahasakul (1986).
.~r: Percent Change in the Consumer Price Index for All Urban Wage
Earners. Source: EROP.

* All variables except T'

and H refer to the logarithm of real per capita
values (in 1982 dollars) relative to a common linear time trend. Hours
are not detrended. The average marginal tax rate is not expressed in per
capita terms, but rather as a deviation from its own trend.

**
t

+

The standard deviation for output refers to the absolute percentage
deviation of the detrended series. All other standard deviations are
expressed relative to the standard deviation of Y.
In an earlier draft of this paper, we mistakenly reported the capital stock
correlations using the one-year-aheadstock values. Because reported
capital stock figures are end-of-year,the contemporaneous values are the
appropriate ones. We are grateful to Finn Kydland for drawing our
attention to this point.

The moments for average marginal tax rates are calculated for the sample
period 1951-1982.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 2: Benchmark Parameters

Value

Description

Parameter

Elasticity of
Substitution in
Consumption

l/a,

Elasticity of
Substitution in
Leisure
Subjective TimeDiscount Factor
Utility Weight of
Leisure
Population Growth
Rate
Capital Share in
Production
Depreciation Rate
of Capital
Productivity
Endowment of an
Age t Individual

*

Given by the formula r t

Sources: See text.

=

4.47

+

0.033t

-

0.00067t2.

1.0

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 3: Steady-State Output Losses

Tax ~odel*
Absolute Lossu
Flat
Progressive I
Progressive I1
Output
Loss Per Dollar
Revenue ~ainedFlat

3.46

3.88

Progressive I

4.06

4.67

Progressive I1

3.64

4.13

*

Marginal tax rates for an individual with taxable income y are calculated as
follows: Flat - - g(y) = .23
Progressive I - - g(y) = .I46 + .0000023*y
Progressive I1 - - g(y) = .20 + .000000789*y

**

Absolute losses are given by the percentage reduction in steady-state
output relative to the zero-inflation steady state.

*** Losses per

dollar of revenue gained are given by -(Y,-Yo)/(Rev,-Revo),
where Revo (Yo) is total revenue raised by distortionary taxation (total
output) in the zero-inflation steady state and Rev, (Y,) is total revenue
raised from distortionary taxation (total output) in the steady state with
the indicated inflation rate.

Source: Authors' calculations.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 4: Steady-State Output Losses: Alternative
~arameterizations*

Parameter Change

Equity Modelt

Absolute Loss

1.3%

Loss Per Dollar
Revenue Gained

2.74

** All

figures are calculated assuming the Progressive I tax regime and a 4
percent annual inflation rate. See the notes to tables 1 and 2 for further
explanation.

t

See text for basic description. A more detailed explanation is available
from the authors upon request.

Source: Authors' calculations.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 5 : Model Moments, Flat-Tax case*
CONSTANT INFLATION
Variable

Standard
Deviation**

Contemporaneous Correlation
With Output
With r t

VARIABLE INFLATION
Variable

*
**

t

Standard
Deviation**

Contemporaneous Correlation
With Output
With r

Simulated path based on actual realizations of technology variable and
inflation rates from 1955-1988. Definitions of the variables correspond
roughly. to the real data counterparts defined in table 1.
The standard deviation for output refers to the absolute percentage
deviation of the model series relative to the standard deviation of
detrended GNP reported in table 1. All other standard deviations are
expressed relative to the simulated standard deviation of Y.
Figures represent the contemporaneous correlations with the indicated
variables and actual inflation rates.

Source: Authors' calculations.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 6: Model Moments, Progressive I Tax case*

CONSTANT INFLATION

Variable

Standard
Deviation

Contemporaneous Correlation
With Output
With A

VARIABLE INFLATION

Variable

*

Standard
Deviation

Contemporaneous Correlation
With Output
With A

Assumes T' = .I46 + .0000023*y, where y is individual taxable income. For
other definitions, see the notes to table 5.

Source: Authors' calculations.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 7: Model Moments, Progressive I1 Tax casef
CONSTANT INFLATION

Variable

Standard
Deviation

Contemporaneous Correlation
With Output
With .~r

VARIABLE INFLATION

Variable

*

Standard
Deviation

Contemporaneous Correlation
With Output
With .~r

Assumes T' = .20 + .000000789*y, where y is individual taxable income. For
other definitions, see the notes to table 4.

Source: Authors' calculations.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

APPENDIX: CALIBRATION OF THE TAX CODE

Because our simulation model is geared toward capturing the average
effects of life-cycle behavior, we calibrate gross income levels so that the
highest level of cohort income in the model roughly coincides with the highest
cohort-average income in the data. Taking 1988 as the reference year, the
highest level of age-cohort median income is obtained for households with
heads age 45-54. The median income for this group is $38,213 in 1988
dollars.'

We convert this number to an average by scaling according to the

ratio of average-to-median income for all households in 1988. Doing so yields
an average income for the 45-54 year-old cohort of $47,776.
We chose the 1965 tax code as the basis for our benchmark tax code.
Because high income in our model is about $50,000 (by design), we estimate the
relationship between marginal tax rates and taxable income for income values
through $52,212 (in 1988 dollars).

The resulting regression yields the values

for go and gl given in the text.
The scale of our output measure is chosen so that the highest gross
income generated by the model in a steady state with the chosen tax schedule
and inflation set to 1.8 percent (the actual inflation rate measured by the
CPI-U in 1965) equals $47,766 in 1988 dollars.
Taxable income levels are obtained by adjusting gross income for
deductions and personal exemptions. In the benchmark case, we assume that all

1
The data used in constructing high cohort income were obtained from the
Current Po~ulationReports (Series P-60, No. 166), published by the Bureau of
the Census.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

taxpayers take a standard deduction equal to $1479 in 1988

dollar^.^

The

personal exemption level in 1965 was $600, or $2254 in 1988 dollars.
Multiplying by 3.31, the average household size in 1965, yields total personal
exemptions of $7460 in 1988 dollars. Taxable income, and hence the tax base,
is thus arrived at by subtracting these deduction and exemption levels from
gross income levels.

2
The 1965 personal tax code provided for a standard deduction equal to the
lower of 10 percent of adjusted gross income or $1000. Using the 1965
Statistics of Income for Individual Taxpayers, we calculated that the average
standard deduction was $394. The $1479 figure was arrived at by converting
the $394 to 1988 dollars using the CPI-U,