View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paper 8707

IDENTIFYING PRODUCTIVITY AND AMENITY EFFECTS
IN INTERURBAN WAGE DIFFERENTIALS

by Patricia E. Beeson and Randall W. Eberts

Patricia E. Beeson is a visiting economist at the
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland and an assistant
professor of economics at the University of
Pittsburgh. Randall W. Eberts is an assistant vice
president and economist at the Federal Reserve Bank
of Cleveland. Comments and suggestions by Joe A.
Stone and Tim Gronberg and computer assistance by
Ralph Day are gratefully acknowledged.
Working Papers of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland are preliminary materials circulated to
stimulate discussion and critical comment. The
views stated herein are those of the authors and
not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System.

August 1987

Abstract

This study focuses on the relative importance of amenity and
productivity differences in determining wage differentials across urban
areas.

The approach developed takes advantage of the connection between

land and labor market clearing conditions required for locational
equilibrium of households and firms.

Data on recent movers are used to

estimate equilibrium wages and rents for a sample of metropolitan areas.
This information is then used to identify amenity and productivity
components of wages for each city in the sample.

Using national estimates

of the relative share of land in consumption and production, differences
in productivity and amenities are found to be roughly equal sources of
wage variation across the sample.

-1I.

Introduction
The persistence of interarea nominal wage differentials in the

presence of a high degree of factor mobility suggests that wage
differentials should be viewed as an equilibrium phenomenon related to
differences in site characteristics across urban areas. 1

Recent work by

Roback (1982) stresses the interdependence between the decisions of firms
(as demanders of labor) and households (as suppliers of labor) in
determining interregional wage differentials.

In her model, site

characteristics are valued by both households and firms.

Thus, one can

think of nominal wage differentials as being composed of two components:
a supply-shift portion and a demand-shift portion.
However, empirical studies relating site characteristics to wage
differentials typically concentrate on either demand or supply, but not
both.

Demand-side studies, such as Kelly (1977) and Segal (19791, focus

on the relationship between site characteristics and the productivity of
firms.
area.

Consequently, low wages reflect the low productivity value of an
Supply-side studies, such as Gerking and Weirick (1983), Rosen

(1979), and Sahling and Smith (1983), view wage differences as
compensation to households for differences in amenities across areas,
which in turn affect the supply of labor to each area.

According to this

view, low wages are an indication of the high value households place on
amenities in the area.
Describing both supply and demand as functions of site
characteristics complicates the issue of explaining wage differentials.
For instance, suppose that a site characteristic is beneficial to both
households and firms.

In this case, households are willing to accept

-2-

lower wages, and firms are able to pay higher wages.

These two effects

may offset one another to the extent that little or no total wage
differential is observed between two regions.

The same offsetting effects

could occur when a site characteristic is detrimental to both households
and firms.

In both cases, the site characteristic appears to have no

effect on wages when, in fact, it affected the decisions of both
households and firms.
The purpose of this paper is to examine the relative importance of
labor supply and demand in explaining nominal wage differentials.

We

develop a nonparametric method of identifying the contribution of a shift
of each curve to the total interarea wage differential, which expands on
Roback's (1982) approach of using rent and wage differentials to value
amenities. This method is then used to estimate the relative contribution
of demand and supply (firms and households) to the total wage differential
for a sample of metropolitan areas.
two related questions:

This decomposition helps to answer

what are the causes of regional wage

differentials, and which variables (related to supply or demand) are more
appropriate to explain them?
The paper is organized in the following way.

The theoretical model

relating interarea differences in amenities and productivity to interarea
wage differentials is reviewed in section 11.

The method used to identify

empirically the amenity and productivity components of wage differentials
is developed in section 111.

The estimation technique and data sources

are discussed in section IV, and the empirical results are presented in
section V.

Section VI contains concluding remarks.

-311.

A Model of Household and Firm Equilibrium
We adopt Roback's (1982) general equilibrium model of household and

firm location.

In this model, cities are assumed to have different site

characteristics that enter into a household's utility function and a
firm's production function.

The objective of the model is to identify the

price mechanisms that compensate households and firms for interarea
differences in site characteristics.

Workers are assumed to be identical

in tastes and skills and completely mobile across cities.

Similarly,

capital is assumed to be completely mobile, and production technologies
are assumed to be identical across firms.

Equilibrium is then

characterized by equal utility across workers and equal unit costs across
firms.

However, wages and land rents may vary in equilibrium due to

interarea differences in site characteristics.
Residents with identical tastes and skills consume and produce a
composite consumption good X.

The price of X is determined by

international markets and for convenience is normalized to one.

Each

worker supplies a single unit of labor independently of the wage rate.
Intercity commuting is not considered, and differences in leisure
resulting from differences in intracity commuting are treated as a site
characteristic. 2
The problem for the worker is to maximize utility subject to an
income constraint.

Utility depends upon consumption of the composite

commodity (X), residential land (L')
characteristics (s).

and the bundle of site

Equivalently, the problem can be stated in terms of

an indirect utility function, V, which is a function of wages (w), rents
(r), and site characteristics(s).

Equilibrium for workers requires that

utility is the same at all locations, or

If the bundle of site characteristics in a city has a net positive effect
on utility (that is, it is a net amenity), then V,>O.

The migration of

workers in response to interarea differences in utility will insure that
wages and rents adjust to compensate workers for differences in amenities
across areas.
Firms are assumed to employ local residents and land to produce a
composite commodity (X), according to a constant-returns-to-scale
production technology.

Under these assumptions, equilibrium for firms

requires that unit costs are equal in all locations and equal to the price
of X, assumed to be 1,

The unit cost function C(.)

is increasing in factor costs, C, = NIX > 0

and Cr = LP/x > 0, where N is the total number of workers in the city
and LP is land used in production.
If a city's site characteristics provide a net productivity advantage
to firms, then C,<O and some combination of higher wages and rents will
be required to make firms indifferent between locations.

The movement of

firms between cities will insure that wages and rents adjust to compensate
firms for differences in site characteristics.
Equilibrium wages and rents are determined by the interaction of the
equilibrium conditions for suppliers (workers) and demanders (firms) of
labor.

Wage and rent differentials between cities with different site

characteristics can be determined by totally differentiating these

-5-

equilibrium conditions (equations 1 and 2), and solving for dwlds and
dr/ds.

(3)

This procedure yields:

dw/ds = (l/D)(-Vs~r

where D=V,Cr-VrC,>O.

+

VrCs)

and

As shown in equations 3 and 4, differences

in wages and rents across cities are dependent on both the marginal
valuation of workers (V,) and the marginal valuation of firms (C,) of
the bundle of site characteristics in each city.

111.

Identifying Amenity and Productivity Components
The equilibrium described above is illustrated in figure 1 (p.25).

The

workers' equilibrium condition is reflected in the upward sloping
'iso-utility' curves.
equal utility, given s.

These curves are combinations of w and r that yield
Individuals will move to cities with a net

amenity advantage until some combination of higher land rents and/or lower
wages makes the individual indifferent between locations.

Assuming S I

represents the average city, S z then would represent a high-amenity city.
Equilibrium combinations of w and r for firms given s are represented
by the downward sloping curves in figure 1.

Firms will locate in cities

with a net productivity advantage until some combination of higher wages
and rents equalizes unit costs across all locations.

Again assuming that

S I represents the average city, S g would represent a city in which

site characteristics have a net negative effect on productivity (C,>O).

-6Each city can be characterized by a specific bundle of site
characteristics and therefore by a pair of isocost and iso-utility curves,
as shown in figure 1.

Equilibrium wages and rents in each city are then

determined by the intersection of the appropriate pair of isocost and
iso-utility curves.

In equilibrium, wages and rents in the city

represented by S2 will be wz and rz, and wage and rent differentials
relative to the average city (S1) will be (WL-wl)and (rz-rl).
As shown in figure 1, the magnitude of the differential depends on
the size and direction of the shifts of each curve and the slopes of the
curves.

By definition, the net wage differential (wz-wl) is made up

of two components:

) related to the
the productivity component ( [dwlds]'

shift in the iso-cost curve; and the amenity component ([dw/dsIv)
related to the shift in the iso-utility curve.

Assuming linear isocost

and iso-utility curves about the neighborhood of inquiry, we have:

The right-hand side of equation 5 is the slope of the iso-utility curve
(-Vw/Vr), and the right-hand side of equation 6 is the slope of the
isocost curve (-Cw/C,).
Solving these equations for the productivity and amenity components
of the wage differential and summing up the components of dwlds yields:

Since ( d r ~ d s )=~ dr/ds - (dr~ds)~,

(8)

dw/ds = L'

(drlds) - (L'+L'/N)

(dr/d~)~,

or in logs

where k , is the share of land in households' budgets and Ri is the
cost share of the ith factor.
Substituting the resulting value into the log form of equation 5
yields the amenity component of the wage differential:

where L is total land used in housing and production and kl
r,/R, = Lr/Nw. 3

+

Substracting equation 10 from the total wage

differential (dlogw/ds) yields the productivity component of the wage
differential:

Calculating the ratio of the amenity component to the total wage
differential illustrates the dependence of the relative size of the wage
components on the estimates of land shares:

-8-

where A is land's share of total income (LrINw).

The ratio of the amenity

component to the total wage differential is roughly proportional to the
firm's share of total land value, (A-kl)/A.

This relationship follows

because estimates of the share of a household's income spent on land
(k,) tend to be very small and the ratio of the rent and wage
differentials is typically around one.

IV.

Estimation
The nominal wages and rents required to carry out the wage

decomposition must be adjusted for quality differences of workers and
houses across metropolitan labor and land

market^.^

To do this, we

estimate standard hedonic equations for wages and rents and then subtract
the predicted wage and predicted rent from their respective actual
values.

The quality-adjusted wage, in essence, indicates the wage a

worker with typical characteristics could receive in each labor market
examined;

the quality-adjusted rent records the value of a typical house

in each labor market.

In both cases, it is assumed that the differences

across cities of these quality-adjusted values reflect differences due to
site characteristics.

In particular, the difference in rent is due

primarily to differences in land prices (assuming construction costs do
not vary significantly across cities), which reflect the capitalization of
the effects of site characteristics on firms and households.

Data
The wage and rent equations are estimated using data drawn from the
combined A and B files of the 1 in 1000 samples of the Public Use
Microdata Sample (PUMS) of the 1980 Census of Population.

Only

-9individuals who lived and worked in the same Standard Metropolitan
Statistical Area (SMSA) in 1980 and who changed addresses between 1975 and
1980 are included in the analysis.

This subsample of movers was chosen

because we felt that these individuals represent more closely the marginal
decision maker and, thus, the prices they face more accurately reflect
current market conditions.
The rent equation includes both owner occupied and rental units for
which positive values of unit or gross rent are reported.

The dependent

variable in the rent equation is gross monthly housing expenditures.

For

homeowners, the monthly housing expenditure is based on the value of the
dwelling using 7.85 percent as the discount rate. 5

The monthly housing

expenditure is the sum of this imputed rent and monthly utility charges.
For renters, the monthly expenditure is gross rent (contract rent plus
utilities).
Individuals included in the wage sample had to meet the following
criteria.

Individuals had to be between the ages of 25 and 55; work more

than 25 hours per week; not be self-employed; and have positive wage and
salary income.

The dependent variable in the wage equation is average

weekly earnings, which is calculated by dividing annual wage and salary
income by the number of weeks worked.

Wage Equation
The first step in constructing the wage indexes is to specify
estimable equations that reflect appropriate individual characteristics of
workers that could affect wages.

Our approach follows the human capital

specification of individual wages set forth by Hanoch (1967) and Mincer
(1974).

Thus, we specify individual wages (expressed in logarithms) as a

-10function of education level (entered as a quadratic), potential experience
(age, minus years of education, minus six, also entered as a quadratic), a
binary variable indicating part-time employment status (less than 35 hours
per week), and 42 binary occupation variables (with one omitted as a
constant).

Binary variables are also entered to account for gender, race,

marital status, union affiliation, and military s e r ~ i c e . ~In addition,
the gender variable is interacted with other characteristics in order to
control for malelfemale differences in the rate of return to these
attributes.
The estimated coefficients of the wage equation are presented in
table 1, except for the occupation variables, which are omitted for
brevity.

The estimated coefficients are as expected.

Education and

experience are valued positively in the labor market, while part-time,
female, and nonwhite workers receive lower wages than their otherwise
identical counterparts.

We also find that individuals who are married,

head of households, and in highly unionized industries earn more than
their counterparts.

Females receive less return on experience than

males.
The predicted wage level for each worker in the sample is obtained by
multiplying the estimated coefficients by each worker's characteristics.
The predicted wage can be interpreted as the compensation a worker could
expect to receive, given his or her characteristics, regardless of
geographic location.

Subtracting the predicted wage from the actual wage

nets out the portion of the actual wage that is related to the individual
worker's characteristics.

The skill-adjusted metropolitan wage

differentials are then obtained by averaging the wage residuals (actual,
minus predicted, wage) for all workers in a particular metropolitan area.

-11Average wage differentials are calculated for each of 35 cities.

The 35

metropolitan areas are chosen by including only those SMSAs for which 100
or more individuals in the sample were recorded as movers between 1975 and
1980.

The quality-adjusted wage differentials are displayed in table 3.

Rent Equation
The method used to calculate quality-adjusted rent differentials is
similar to the one used to calculate quality-adjusted wage differentials.
The log of the reported house value is regressed against housing
attributes.

These characteristics include the number of rooms, number of

bedrooms, number of bathrooms, and separate binary variables indicating
location of the dwelling in the central city, and whether or not the
dwelling is a single structure, has central air conditioning and/or
heating, is connected to a city sewer system, and has well water.
year the dwelling was built is entered to proxy the vintage.

The

Dwelling

characteristics are interacted with rental status in order to account for
differences in the valuation of these attributes between rented and
owner-occupied dwellings.
Coefficient estimates are reported in table 2.
expected.

The results are as

Larger, newer dwellings with central air and heating and

located outside the central city have higher market value than otherwise
identical homes.

In general, attributes of rentals are valued less than

otherwise identical owner-occupied dwellings.

The predicted rent is

calculated by multiplying the estimated coefficients by the housing
characteristics of each household.

The quality-adjusted rent

differentials presented in table 3 are the differences between the actual
and predicted house values.

-1 2By including a number of housing characteristics in the rent
equation, the difference between actual and predicted house values can be
interpreted to reflect primarily land values in specific geographical
locations.

Thus, quality-adjusted rent differentials relative to the

national average reflect differences in city land values, which are due
primarily to the capitalized effects of differences in site
characteristics.

V.

Amenity and Productivity Components
The relative size of the amenity and productivity components of the

total wage differential is derived from equations 10 and 11.

Use of these

equations requires estimates of land income and derived estimates of
land's share of household budgets.

Unfortunately, accurate data

concerning land use and income in alternative uses are difficult to
obtain.

We follow Roback's approach of using national estimates, even

though we recognize that these shares may vary across areas.

The budget

share of land is calculated by multiplying the fraction of income spent on
housing (27.0

percent in our sample) by the ratio of land value to the

total value of the house (estimated to be 19.6 percent).

7

From these

estimates, land's share of household income (kl) is 5.3 percent.

The

ratio R,/R, is calculated by subtracting our estimate of kl from
the ratio of the total income to land (6.4

percent of national income)

relative to total labor income (73 percent of national in~ome).~ The
ratio of these income shares is 8.8 and the estimate of R,/Rw is

3.5.
Estimates of the wage decomposition are displayed in table 4.
Several features of these estimates should be noted.

For our sample, the

-13amenity component averages 40 percent of the total wage differential,
while the productivity component averages 60 percent.

9

The relative

contributions of productivity and amenity effects vary considerably across
cities.

However, the productivity effect is the primary source of the

wage differential for all but two cities:

Atlanta and San Diego.

In both

cases, the productivity component accounts for 38 percent of the total
wage differential.

For the other cities, the contribution of the

productivity component ranges from 51 percent for Indianapolis and St.
Louis to over 70 percent for Los Angeles.
Some of the variation across SMSAs could be due to differences in the
land shares.

As mentioned earlier, estimates of land shares are not

available for individual metropolitan areas.

To get some idea of the

sensitivity of the relative magnitudes of the wage components to estimates
of land shares, we computed values of k l associated with selected
magnitudes of these wage components.

As shown in table 5, the values of

each component range from contributing nothing to the total wage
differential to accounting for all of it.

Using as a benchmark our

estimates of 60 percent for the productivity component and 40 percent for
the amenity component, the simulation shows that the magnitude of the two
wage components would converge to be equal if k l decreases 11 percent,
from 5.3 percent to 4.6 percent.

Furthermore, if

kl

falls from 6.0

percent to 3.4 percent, a 43 percent decrease, the amenity component
changes from 33 percent of the total wage differential to 67 percent.
However, in order for amenity differences to account for the entire wage
differential, firms would not employ land in production.

Similarly, in

order for productivity differences to explain the entire wage
differential, households would not own land.

Of course, both of these

-14situations are implausible.

Thus, it appears that, in general, interarea

wage differentials reflect both the compensation to households for
differences in amenities, and to firms for differences in productivity.
Finally, it appears that with few exceptions the estimated
productivity and amenity effects are reinforcing.
coefficient of the two components is 0.98.

The correlation

Thus, high productivity cities

are also low amenity cities, and vice versa.

This result follows Rosen's

(1979) point that what benefits households may cost firms.

This high

correlation between the amenity and productivity components indicates the
difficulties one would encounter when using parametric estimation to
identify the amenity and productivity components of wages.

.

VI

Conclusion
We have attempted to assess the relative importance of supply

(amenity) and demand (productivity) factors in determining
intermetropolitan nominal wage differentials.

Our estimates of the

productivity and amenity components of the wage differential for
individual SMSAs indicate that, on average, the productivity component of
interarea wage differentials accounts for a larger share of the total
differential than the amenity component.

However, the relative importance

of these factors varies from one city to the next.

In some cities,

relatively low wages are found to be primarily the result of high
amenities, which increase the supply of labor to the city.

In other

cities, low wages are found to be primarily the result of the low
productivity-enhancing site characteristics, which decreases the demand
for labor.

-15These findings underscore the caveat that one should be careful not
to interpret interarea wage differentials as reflecting only amenities or
productivity differences.

Both factors appear to play comparable roles in

determining interarea nominal wage differentials.

Footnotes
1.

Bellante (1979), Johnson (1983), and Scully (1969) are examples of
numerous studies that have examined interregional nominal wage
differentials.

2.

Roback's model ignores intracity commuting. Hoehn, et. al. (1986)
have pointed out that this leads to incorrect estimates of the value
of other site characteristics. Since we are not interested in
deriving values for specific characteristics but simply valuing the
net impact of these characteristics, our model is not subject to this
criticism. We simply assume that intracity commuting is another site
characteristic that reduces leisure time and therefore is a
disamenity for workers.

3.

Note that k l = rlc/w = NrlC/Nw and Rr/Rw = rlP/Nw.
Therefore,

where L is the total land used in housing and production, and rL/wN
is simply the ratio of the total income to land relative to the
total income to labor.
4.

Recent studies by Farber and Newman (1987) and Jackson (1985) show
that regional nominal wage differentials also arise from differences
in returns to these characteristics. However, we concentrate on
differences in characteristics across regions, since we are
primarily concerned with the relative value placed on different
bundles of site characteristics.

5.

The discount rate is from a study of the user cost of capital by
Peiser and Smith (1985).

6.

The measure of unionization in the wage equation is the industry
unionization rate taken from Kokkelenberg and Sockell(1985).

7.

The ratio of land value to total house value was estimated by Roback
(1982) using FHA housing data. Unfortunately, the census data used
in this study cannot be used to make a new estimate.

8.

The estimate of labor compensation is taken from the national income
account data reported in Table B-23 of the Economic Report of the
President (1987).
Unfortunately, the national income accounts do
not include land income as a separate category of income. Our
estimate of land's share of income is taken from Mills and Hamilton
(1984).

9.

When the sample was expanded to include SMSAs that received 50 or
more movers, the results were identical.

References
Bellante, Don. "The North-South Differential and the Migration of
Heterogeneous Labor," American Economic Review, vol. 69, no. 1
(March 1979), pp. 166-75.
Farber, Stephen C., and Robert J. Newman. "Accounting for South/Non-South
Real Wage Differentials and for Changes in Those Differentials Over
Time." The Review of Economics and Statistics 69(2) (May 1987),
pp. 215-223.
Gerking, Shelby D. and William N. Weirick. "Compensating Differences and
Interregional Wage Differentials," Review of Economics and
Statistics, 65 (August 1983), pp. 483-87.
Hanoch, Giora. "An Economic Analysis of Earnings and Schooling," Journal
of Human Resources, 2(3) (Summer 1967), pp. 310-29.
Hoehn, John P., Mark C. Berger, and Glenn C. Bloomquist. "A Hedonic Model
of Interregional Wages, Rents and Amenity Values," University of
Kentucky Working Paper No. E-91-86, (1986).
Jackson, Lorie D. "The Changing Nature of Regional Wage Differentials
from 1975 to 1983." Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland, (First Quarter, 1986), pp. 12-23.
Johnson, George E. "Intermetropolitan Wage Differentials in the United
States," in Jack E. Triplett, ed., The Measurement of Labor Cost,
Chicago: University of Chicago Press, (19831, pp. 309-30.
Kelly, Kevin. "Urban Disamenities and the Measure of Economic Welfare,"
Journal of Urban Economics 4(October 19771, pp. 379-88
Kokkelenberg, Edward C. and Donna R. Sockell. "Union Membership in
the United States: 1973-1981." Industrial and Labor Relations
Review 38(4) (July 19851, pp. 497-543.
Mills, Edwin S., and Bruce W. Hamilton. Urban Economics.
Scott Foresman and Company, 3rd ed. (1984).

Glenview, Ill.:

Mincer, Jacob. Schooling, Experience, and Learning. New York: National
Bureau of Economic Research, Distributed by Columbia University
Press, 1974.
Piesner, Richard B. and Lawrence B. Smith. "Homeownership Returns, Tenure
Choice and Inflation," American Real Estate and Urban Economics
Journal 13 (Winter 19851, pp. 343-360.
Roback, Jennifer. "Wages, Rents and Quality of Life," Journal of
Political Economy 90(6) (December 1982), pp. 1257-78.
Rosen, Sherwin. "Hedonic Prices and Implicit Markets: Product
Differentiation in Pure Competition." Journal of Political Economy
82(1) (1974), pp. 34-55.

Rosen, Sherwin. "Wage-based Indices of Urban Quality of Life." in Current
Issues in Urban Economics, ed. P. Mieszkowski and M. Straszheim,
Baltimore, Maryland: Johns Hopkins University Press (1979), pp.
74-104.
Sahling, Leonard G., and Sharon P. Smith. "Regional Wage Differentials:
Has the South Risen Again?" Review of Economics and Statistics 65(1)
(February 1983), pp. 131-35.
Scully, Gerald W. "Interstate Wage Differentials: A Cross Sectional
Analysis," American Economic Review 59 (5) (November 1969), pp.
757-73.
Segal, David. "Are There Returns to Scale in City Size?" Review of
Economics and Statistics 53 (August 1976), pp. 339-50.

Table 1:

Estimates of Wage Equation

Variables

Mean

Coefficient

Intercept
Sex (Female=l)
Race (Black=l)
Education
Education squared
Experience
Experience squared
Part time
Usual hours worked per week
Head of household
Veteran
Sex x Race
Sex x (Marital status)
Sex x Experience
Sex x (Experience Squared)
Marital Status
Union member
(42 Occupation Dummies)
R-square
No. observations
Dependent Variable:
log(week1y earnings)
Note:
Source:

5.50

Estimates derived from Public Use Microdata Sample.
in parentheses.
Authors.

T-statistics

Table 2:

Estimates of Rent Equation

Variables
Intercept
Dwelling rented (=I)
Central City (=I)

x rental
Number of floors

x rental
Attached dwelling (=I)

x rental
Year dwelling built
x rental

Number of rooms

x rental
Number of bedrooms

x rental
Well water (=I)

x rental
Central air conditioning
x rental

Central heating (=I)
x rental

Mean

Coefficient

Table 2 (continued)
Dwelling other than condominium (=I) .96
Number of units at address

2.92

x rental
Number of bathrooms

2.72

x rental

City Sewer Connection (=I)

.87

x rental
Lot size less than one acre (=I)

.92

x rental
Elevator (=I)

.04

R-square
No. of observations
Dependent variable:
log(house value)
Note:

Source:

Estimates derived from Public Use Microdata Sample. T-statistics
in parentheses. The entry "x rental" indicates that the rental
dummy variable has been interacted with the variable listed
immediately above it.
Authors.

Table 3:

Quality-Adjusted Rent and Wage Differentials

Metropolitan Area

Quality-Adjusted
Rent
Wage

Anaheim, CA
Atlanta, GA
Baltimore, MD
Chicago, IL
Cincinnati, OH
Cleveland, OH
Columbus, OH
Denver, CO
Detroit, MI
Ft. Lauderdale, FL
Houston, TX
Indianapolis, IN
Kansas City, MO
Los Angeles, CA
Miami, FL
Minneapo 1is, MN
Nassau-Suffolk
New Orleans, LA
New York, NY
Newark, NJ
Philadelphia, PA
Phoenix, AZ
Pittsburgh, PA
Portland, OR
Riverside-San Bernardino, CA
Sacramento, CA
St. Louis, MO
Salt Lake City, UT
San Antonio, TX
San Diego, CA
San Francisco, CA
San Jose, CA
Seattle, WA
Tampa, FL
Washington, D.C.
Source: Authors. Quality-adjusted differentials are obtained by
subtracting the predicted estimate from the actual value. The reference
point for these estimates is the sample average.

Table 4: Decomposition of Interarea Wage Differentials into Amenity
and Productivity Components
Metropolitan Area
Sample Average
Anaheim, CA
Atlanta, GA
Baltimore, MD
Chicago, IL
Cincinnati, OH
Cleveland, OH
Columbus, OH
Denver, CO
Detroit, MI
Ft. Lauderdale, FL
Houston, TX
Indianapolis, IN
Kansas City, MO
Los Angeles, CA
Miami, FL
Minneapolis, MN
Nassau-Suffolk, NY
New Orleans, LA
New York, NY
Newark, NJ
Philadelphia, PA
Phoenix, AZ
Pittsburgh, PA
Portland, OR
Riverside-San Bernardino, CA
Sacramento, CA
St. Louis, MO
Salt Lake City, UT
San Antonio, TX
San Diego, CA
San Francisco, CA
San Jose, CA
Seattle, WA
Tampa, FL
Washington, D.C.
Source:

Authors.

Wage Components
Share of Total
Amenity
Productivity Amenity
Productivity

Table 5:

Sensitivity of the Size of the Wage Components to
Values of Household Budget Shares to Land ( k l )

Share of Wage Components
of Total Wage Differential:
Amenity
Productivity

k1

Note: K 1 is derived by solving equations 10 and 11
under various assumptions about the relative magnitudes of
the two wage components and assuming that A equals .088.
Values of k l are then derived for each SMSA using observed
values of total wage and rent differentials. The sample
average of the appropriate values of k l are reported in
the table.
Source:

Authors.

FIGURE 1: Determination of
Equilibrium Wages and Rents