View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paper 9215
DO HOSTILE TAKEOVERS REDUCE
EXTRAMARGINAL WAGE PAYMENTS?
by Jagadeesh Gokhale, Erica L. Groshen,
and David Neumark

Jagadeesh Gokhale and Erica L. Groshen
are economists at the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland. David Neumark is an assistant
professor of economics at the University of
Pennsylvania and a faculty research fellow of
the National Bureau of Economic Research. The
authors are grateful to Steven Sharpe for
helpful discussions and to Colin Drozdowski and
Edward Bryden for research assistance.
Working papers of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland are preliminary materials circulated
to stimulate discussion and critical comment.
The views stated herein are those of the authors
and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System.
December 1992

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

ABSTRACT
Hostile takeovers may have significant implications for long-term
employment contracts if they facilitate the opportunistic expropriation of
extramarginal wage payments. We test the expropriation hypothesis by studying
the relationship between proxies for extramarginal wage payments and
subsequent hostile takeover activity. This paper improves on existing
research by using firm- and establishment-level data from a salary survey of
employers. In addition, we observe characteristics of wage and employment
structures both before and after the occurrence of a hostile takeover and
hence can see whether the data are consistent with reductions in extramarginal
wage payments following such takeovers. Results from this ex post experiment
provide evidence consistent with the hypothesis that hostile takeovers result
in reductions of extramarginal wage payments to more-tenured workers, mostly
through cutbacks in senior positions at firms with relatively steep wage
profiles.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

I, Introduction
Hostile takeovers may have significant implications for long-term
employment contracts. Shleifer and Summers (1988) argue that hostile
takeovers may facilitate opportunistic behavior at the expense of workers by
making possible the removal of "entrenched" managers who would otherwise
uphold implicit contracts with employees. Their argument is based not on the
presence of reputation effects, but rather on the hypothesis that because of
management loyalty--aningredient necessary to make implicit contracts in the
first place--along-time manager tends to avoid breaking implicit contracts
with employees even when doing so would benefit shareholders. Neumark and
Sharpe (1992) contend that hostile takeovers may facilitate such opportunistic
behavior even if there are reputation effects. The new management taking
command after an unfriendly takeover breaks the implicit contracts of the
previous managers and therefore may not suffer a damaged reputation. This is
especially likely if the takeover is engineered by an individual or company
that then resells the target firm.l
Neumark and Sharpe (1992) conduct an ex ante analysis of this question,
studying the relationship between proxies for extramarginal wage payments and
subsequent hostile takeover activity. They construct two types of proxies for
extramarginal wage payments: differences in wage levels unattributable to
measured human capital and other standard wage equation controls in the
industries in which firms conduct business, and differences both in the
steepness of age-earnings profiles and in the relative employment of older
l ~ h a ~ a tShleifer,
,
and Vishny (1990) argue that because corporate raiders
typically resell acquired assets to firms in similar industries, hostile
takeovers are largely an "industrial organization problem," resolving issues
similar to those that trigger friendly mergers, and were perhaps spurred by
lenient antitrust enforcement in the 1980s that released pent-up demand for
acquisitions in related industries. The argument in Neumark and Sharpe, which
emphasizes reputation effects, suggests another reason why other firms are
interested in acquiring hostile takeover targets from raiders.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

workers across the industries in which firms conduct business. They find some
evidence, albeit weak, consistent with the view that hostile takeovers are
used to expropriate extramarginal wages. Specifically, proxies for
extramarginal wage payments sometimes have predictive power for an eventual
hostile takeover attempt, although this power tends to diminish as controls
for firm financial characteristics are added. The results in that paper are
interpreted as a joint test of two hypotheses: 1) that the characteristics of
the wage structure captured in these proxies actually represent extramarginal
wage payments and 2) that hostile takeovers target firms with relatively high
extramarginal wage payments.
This paper improves on that empirical analysis in two important ways.
First, Neumark and Sharpe use industry-level characteristics of the wage
structure and then construct firm-levelproxies for extramarginal wage
payments by assigning industry-level data to firms in Compustat based on the
industry or industries in which these firms conduct business.

In contrast, in

this paper we use firm- and establishment-level data from a salary survey of
employers, similar to that used in Groshen (1991~). These data should yield
better proxies for extramarginal wages at the firm or establishment level,
given evidence of firm-specificwage differentials within industries (Groshen
[1991a, 1991bl).

Second, these data permit more than an ex ante experiment.

Because we can observe characteristics of the establishment's wage and
employment structures both before and after the occurrence of a hostile
takeover, we can see whether the data are consistent with firms in fact
expropriating extramarginal wages following hostile takeovers, by examining
changes in extramarginal wage payments. This analysis may reveal effects of
hostile takeovers that are obscured by heterogeneity bias in the ex ante
analysis. Furthermore, these data cover the same reporting unit (one or a
number of establishments) before and after the takeover, so there is no
2
clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

problem of attributing changes in wages or employment to the acquired entity,
rather than to the new parent company.
11. Extramareinal Wages
A considerable amount of research in labor economics documents evidence
that is consistent with extramarginal wages and attempts to provide related
theoretical models. One focus of this research has been industry- and firmspecific wage premia.

In wage regressions that control for variables that

economic theory suggests ought to determine wages, substantial industry wage
differentials persist (Krueger and Summers [1988]).

Some explanations that

have been considered and rejected are compensating differentials (Murphy and
Tope1 [1987]), unobserved ability (Gibbons and Katz [1992], Blackburn and
Neumark [1992]), demand or supply shifts (Helwege [1992]), and union threat
effects (Newark and Wachter [1992]).
This evidence of industry-level wage differentials has been supplemented
with evidence of persistent, unexplained wage differences at the firm and
establishment level (Groshen [1991a]).

Employer wage differentials within

industry are about the same size as differences between industries, are linked
to observable characteristics of the establishments (such as size, technology,
product, and unionization), and appear to be long-lived (Groshen [1991b]).
Some researchers, such as Dickens and Katz (1987a, 1987b), have
concluded that these industry-, firm-, and establishment-levelwage
differentials reflect rents. Such rents arise in the gift-exchange model of
Akerlof (1982), in which workers receive above-market-clearingwages (in some
firms) in return for exerting more-than-minimaleffort. They can also arise
if firms base wages partly on ability to pay, perhaps out of equity concerns
(see the review in Levine [1991]).
A second labor market model that leads to the payment of extramarginal
wages, although only to more-tenured workers, is the incentive contract model
3
clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

of Lazear (1979).

In this model, firms can only imperfectly monitor workers,

who therefore have some incentive to shirk on the job. To eliminate or reduce
shirking, firms pay workers less than their marginal product when their tenure
is low, and more than their marginal product when their tenure is high.

In

this deferred compensation scheme, employees essentially post a "bond" that is
forfeited if they are caught shirking. They are willing to accept the
deferred-compensation implicit contract ex ante because it results in greater
output, and hence a higher present value of earnings, relative to the spot
market outcome.
Empirical research on Lazear contracts seeks to distinguish the deferred
compensation explanation of rising wages from the general human capital
investment explanation. In particular, this research asks whether wages rise
faster than marginal product, consistent with Lazear's model, or rise in
concert with marginal product.

Numerous researchers have found evidence

consistent with wages rising faster than marginal product (Medoff and Abraham
[1981], Lazear and Moore [1984], Kotlikoff and Wise [1985], Kotlikoff and
Gokhale [1991]), although others have argued to the contrary (Brown [1989]).
Based on these two avenues of research, we construct two measures of
possible payments of extramarginal wages for our sample of firms. First, to
2 ~ alternative
n
hypothesis under which workers receive less than their
marginal product when young, and more when old, is that workers prefer rising
wage profiles as a forced-saving mechanism (Frank and Hutchens [1992],
Loewenstein and Sicherman [1991]). In this case, however, workers sacrifice
their present value of earnings in order to receive deferred compensation.
Nonetheless, older workers are still paid extramarginal wages. Neumark (1992)
provides some evidence consistent with the forced-saving hypothesis. Neumark
and Taubman (1992) exploit the different implications of alternative
explanations of wage growth for present values of earnings streams to
distinguish among the explanations.
There is also a version of the human capital model (Carmichael [1983])
with the same empirical implications. In this paper, we do not distinguish
between the Lazear model and these models; any evidence regarding the validity
of one bears equally on the others. Thus, our research sheds light on the
existence of extramarginal wage payments to older, more-tenured workers, but
does not address the source of these payments.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

study extramarginal wage payments captured in wage levels, we estimate the
unexplained fixed establishment component of wages.

Second, to examine

extramarginal payments to more-tenured workers, we construct estimates of the
steepness of the wage profile at the firm level, as well as the relative
employment of senior-level workers. The particular combination of steep
profiles plus high employment of more-tenured workers should be most consonant
with this latter type of extramarginal wage payment.
111. Existine Research on Hostile Takeovers

A number of recent papers look at the consequences of alternative types
of corporate restructurings for wages, pensions, and employment (for example,
Lichtenberg and Siege1 [1989], Brown and Medoff [1988]); a subset of these
focus on hostile takeovers. One obstacle to studying hostile takeovers
explicitly is that it is difficult to attribute changes that occur for the
acquiring firm to the acquired entity per se. Thus, studies of the
consequences of these takeovers have used unusual, specially constructed
samples. Bhagat, Shleifer, and Vishny (1990) and Bhide (1989) study a small
sample of firms that were hostile takeover targets, finding that substantial
layoffs are frequently reported at target firms following such events,
although they conclude that layoffs explain only a fraction (11 to 26 percent)
of the takeover premium for their firms. One problem with these studies is
that they consider only hostile takeover targets; they are constrained to do
this because they do not use standard data sources (such as Compustat) to
attribute changes to the acquired entity.3 Thus, there is no "control group"
of firms that fail to experience takeover bids. On the other hand, firms that
did not experience such bids may have taken actions similar to those that
3~hagat,Shleifer, and Vishny do present some partial evidence, based on
Wall Street Journal reports of industry and firm layoffs, that layoffs were
higher in hostile target firms than in similar nontarget firms and that the
higher layoffs followed the takeover (or attempt).

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

ensued at takeover targets to forestall the bids, in which case comparisons of
targets to nontargets would understate the effects of hostile takeovers.
In contrast, for a sample of union contracts matched to firms, Rosett
(1990) finds that hostile takeovers (identified as takeovers accompanied by
CEO changes) do not result in lower real wage growth than friendly takeovers
(in specifications excluding year and industry effects) and have no
discernible impact on real wage growth (in specifications including these
effects).

One problem with this sample, however, is that the union contracts

apply to only a fraction of the firms' work forces, so it is difficult to
generalize to real wage changes for all employees.
None of these papers, however, addresses explicitly the question of the
expropriation of extramarginal wages or, in the language of Shleifer and
Summers (1988), breaches of implicit contracts. That is, none attempts to
identify components of wage levels that are in any sense extramarginal, and
none focuses on the steepness of the wage profile or on the relative
employment of more-tenured workers. As outlined in section 11, however, it is
these characteristics of wages and employment that may indicate the existence
of implicit contracts.

Instead, the studies reviewed so far focus on wage or

employment cuts per se, which have nothing to do with reducing extramarginal
wage payments, and therefore may have nothing to do with the gains from
hostile

takeover^.^

These limitations of existing studies are imposed by the

data, since none of the standard data sources (such as Compustat or the Census
Bureau's Longitudinal Research Database) or the nonstandard sources used to
date (as in Bhagat, Shleifer, and Vishny [1990]) contains information on the
shape of the wage profile, on the relative employment of older workers, or on

4 ~ h i spoint is recognized explicitly in Bhagat, Schleifer, and Vishny
(1990), but the authors nonetheless estimate savings from layoffs as the wage
bill previously paid to laid-off workers.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

skill measures that could be used to estimate the portion of the firm's wage
level that is not attributable to worker productivity.
In contrast, the empirical analysis in Newark and Sharpe (1992), like
the analysis in this paper, attempts to construct measures of extramarginal
wage payments, or indicators of implicit contracts, and to study their
relationship to hostile takeover bids.

They consider a number of proxies for

extramarginal wages: the overall wage level, the steepness of the age-earnings
profile, the relative employment of older workers, and the steepness of the
profile interacted with the relative employment of older workers. The study
is also different from others in the literature because it is ex ante in
nature, studying whether these extramarginal wage proxies, measured at a point
in time, are associated with later hostile takeover bids.

Thus, the authors

can use standard data sources (such as Compustat) to compare hostile targets
and other firms, but still avoid the attribution problem referred to above.
Newark and Sharpe find that these proxies for extramarginal wage
payments are positively related to hostile takeover bids, in logit estimates
for the probability of hostile takeovers, although the effects are often
statistically insignificant once controls for financial and other
characteristics of firms are included; the results are strongest for the
interaction between the steepness of the age-earnings profile and the relative
employment of older workers. Given that they use industry-level proxies for
extramarginal wages, which are matched to firms based on the industry or
industries in which the firms conduct business, it is perhaps surprising that
much of a relationship is detected, even if the expropriation hypothesis is
correct. Also, they find that the effects of the extramarginal wage proxies
are generally strongest when comparing hostile takeover targets to other
corporate restructurings. They interpret this as providing stronger evidence
in favor of the expropriation or breach-of-contracthypothesis, since it is
7
clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

based only on those firms that underwent changes in control, and focuses on
the unique aspect of hostile takeovers--thechange in management.
An alternative avenue, which focuses more explicitly on expropriation of
extramarginal compensation or breaches of implicit contracts, investigates
defined-benefit pension plan terminations and reversions of excess assets from
overfunded plans.5 Employees can lose out from a termination because the
explicit sponsor's obligation to current jobholders upon termination is based
only on wages at that date rather than on wages at retirement. Firms may be
tempted to terminate and revert because of the overfunding that results from
the requirement that they fund plans based on projected salaries at
retirement.

This research finds some evidence (although not one-sided)

consistent with hostile takeovers leading to terminations and reversions as
breaches of implicit contracts (Pontiff, Shleifer, and Weisbach [1990],
Mittelstaedt [1991], Ippolito and James [1992]).
To summarize, most existing evidence on the effects of hostile takeovers
on wages and employment does not speak directly to whether such takeovers ar'e
a means of expropriating extramarginal wage payments or of breaching implicit
contracts.

Evidence on pension plan terminations and reversions is more

relevant to the expropriation hypothesis and provides some (although not onesided) support. This paper extends the approach taken in Neumark and Sharpe
(1992), of looking at the relationship between hostile takeovers and
characteristics of the wage structure and employment that may indicate
extramarginal wage payments or implicit contracts. This paper is unique

5~etersen(1992) provides empirical evidence supporting the notion that
reversions are breaches of implicit contracts of a Lazear nature.
%en
a pension plan is terminated, the firm has the option of buying
annuities with a value equal to the explicit pension obligations, based on
current salaries, or replacing the plan with one of at least that value. In
cases where the plan is overfunded, the firm can retain the assets left over.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

because it studies this relationship based on characteristics of the wage and
employment structures at the firm or establishment level and because the
nature of the data set used permits both an ex ante and ex post analysis.
IV. The Data

A. The Community Salary Survey
We use data from 1980 through 1991, constructed from the annual
Community Salary Survey (CSS) conducted by the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland (FRBC) personnel department. The survey, which covers employers in
Cleveland, Cincinnati, and Pittsburgh, assists in annual salary budgeting at
the Bank.7 In return for their participation, surveyed companies are issued
result books for their own use.

Salary surveys such as the CSS currently

offer the only source of longitudinal wage data accompanied by both detailed
occupation and information on employers.'
The FRBC chooses participants in each city to be representative of large
employers in area.g

Each one judges which establishments to include in the

7 ~ general,
n
Cleveland, Cincinnati, and Pittsburgh are more urban, have
more cyclically sensitive employment, and have undergone more industrial
restructuring than the nation as a whole. Prior to the 1980s, wages in these
three cities were higher than the national average. Now, they are
approximately average for the country.
'see Hotchkiss (1990) for a summary of data sets with information on
employers. For example, the microdata collected in Industry Wage Surveys and
Area Wage Surveys by the Bureau of Labor Statistics have occupational detail,
but lack any way to identify changes in ownership, are not easily linked over
time, and are not preserved for long periods. Unemployment Insurance ES-202
data, when available, report average employee earnings by employer, not
individual wages, and lack occupational detail. The Longitudinal Research
Database, maintained by the Center for Economic Studies, goes back to 1972,
but covers only manufacturers and provides only mean establishment earnings
for production and nonproduction workers, with no occupational detail.
9 ~ check
o
whether the wages paid by members of the CSS sample were
unrepresentative of the areas' rates, wages in the survey were compared to
Bureau of Labor Statistics' Area Wage Surveys (AWS) in the same cities for the
late 1970s and early 1980s. The AWS also oversamples large employers.
Movements of mean wages for similar occupations were found to be highly
correlated across the two surveys, and levels were usually within 5 percent of
each other.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

survey, according to their internal organization.

Some include all branches

in the metropolitan area, while others report wages for only a single
facility. We use the purposely vague term "employer" to mean the employing
firm, establishment, division, or collection of local establishments for which
the participant reports wages.lo
The industries included vary widely, although the emphasis is on
obtaining employers with many "matches," or employees in the occupations
surveyed. The number of companies participating on an ongoing basis in these
years averages about 93. Overall, 133 employers participated in the survey at
one time or another over these 12 years and had enough data for use in the
analysis.l1
The CSS covers 75 occupations each year; each employer reports wages for
an average of 28 of these. The surveyed occupations are almost exclusively
nonproduction jobs, since these positions are found in all industries.
Included are office, maintenance, technical, supervisory, and professional
personnel.
Many jobs are further divided into a number of grade levels, depending
on required responsibilities and experience. Job descriptions for each are at
/

least two paragraphs long. In consGltation with the FRBC personnel
department, we grouped 50 (two-thirds) of the surveyed occupations into 17 job
"families." Each family comprises at least two, and up to as many as five,
levels. Appendix A presents a list of the job families and levels (with their
associated job titles) used in the analysis.
1°since'a participant's choice of the entities to include presumably
reflects those for which wage and personnel policies are actually administered
jointly, the ambiguity here is not particularly troublesome.
"~welve companies had no employees in any of the job families used to
estimate extramarginal wages. Thus, they had to be excluded from the
, analysis, although they were used to estimate overall establishment
differentials.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Each observation in the original data set gives the salary of an
individual employed in a surveyed occupation by a surveyed employer.

Cash

bonuses are included as salary, but fringe benefits are not.

B. Identification of Takeovers
Takeovers, whether hostile or not, were identified by a combination of
four methods.

In 1989 and 1990, participants were asked if they had had a

change of ownership during the past five years and, if so, by whom they had
been acquired. We also looked up the CUSIP number of all publicly held firms
and took any change in number as an indication of a possible takeover. Then
Moodv's, the Harris Industrial Directory, and Mergers and Acauisitions
magazine were consulted in order to characterize the takeover. In a few
cases, the company contact for the CSS was also consulted to make a final
determination.
C. Ex Ante Observations vs. Ex Post Observations

We organize the data into ex ante and ex post observations.

Ex ante

observations are taken for the first year the employer enters the sample and
are described in table 1A. In most cases, the year of entry is 1980, but 55
employers join the sample at some later date. In the first column, we see that
employers represent all industry groups, but are most heavily concentrated in
durable goods manufacturing and in finance, insurance, and real estate (FIRE).
The other columns divide the sample into four categories: 34 employers that
were not candidates for takeover (governmental agencies, public utilities, or
nonprofit organizations), 67 potential candidates that had no change of
ownership, 25 entities that were acquired in a (nonhostile) merger or
acquisition, and 7 employers that underwent hostile takeovers.12
Table 1B reports sample characteristics for the 97 observations with
12For reasons of confidentiality, we cannot divulge the names of the
companies from which the data were collected.
11
clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

complete data on unionization and employer size. Most of the observations
lost are unmerged candidates or employers that underwent friendly mergers.
Noncandidates have strikingly higher rates of unionization (UNION, defined as
at least 25 percent unionized) and average size (SIZE) than do candidates.
Among candidates, employers that did not undergo friendly mergers or hostile
takeovers are larger but less unionized than those that did.
Ex post observations are defined from the first year observed (usually
1980) until the last year observed (usually 1991).
characteristics for this sample.

Table 2 reports sample

It is smaller (121 observations) than the ex

ante data set because employers that participated only once in the CSS (mostly
in Pittsburgh), or for which an observation after a merger or takeover
occurred was unavailable, are excluded.l3 The industrial distribution
remains about the same. We divide the sample into three subgroups: 101
employers that were not merged (noncandidates plus intact candidates), 14
mergers and acquisitions, and 6 hostile takeovers. On average, our
observations on the wage and employment structure occur 3.7 years after
hostile takeovers, and 2.5 years after mergers and acquisitions.
The ex post analysis looks at changes in the variables describing the
wage and employment structures. Using the data in difference form controls
for all static differences among these employers. The more direct forms of
controlling for differences among employers, such as merging in data from
other sources (Compustat, for example), cannot be used for the ex post
analysis (the unique contribution of the paper) because financial data for
units within firms are not available.

here were two observations with mergers/acquisitions for which the
date of the merger occurred immediately before the first year the company was
observed. These are included in the ex ante data set as nonmergers, but are
excluded from the ex post data set because some effects of the earlier mergers
may take a number of years to occur.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Finally, we note that firms are free to refuse to participate in the
survey.

If this generates any selection bias, it seems to us most plausible

that hostile takeover targets that experience particularly severe changes
related to expropriation of extramarginal wages (such as large-scale firing of
older workers) may be most likely to discontinue participation. This would
bias the results against finding evidence consistent with the expropriation
hypothesis.

D. Measures of Extramarginal Wages
We use three conceptually distinct, employer-specific measures of the
presence of extramarginal wages: overall wage differentials, wage profile
slope differentials, and employment concentration in senior levels. We also
interact the slope and concentration measures as a proxy for the size of the
.seniority-relatedextramarginal wage bill.
Employer wage differentials (such as unexplained deviations from mean
wages in a city) are estimated independently for each city and year, from an
OLS regression of log median wages for each occupation in each employer,
controlling for detailed occupation (following Groshen [1991aJ). Estimated
coefficients on employer dummies (after standardizing the mean to zero for
each city-year) are denoted LEVMED, and represent the average log wage
differential across occupations paid by that employer in that year.l4
Similarly, employer slope differentials capture the extent to which the
slope of an employer's wage profile deviates from its annual city mean.

We

base our estimates on the 17 job families that were found in the occupations
surveyed in the CSS (see appendix A).

Employer-specific steepness of

age-earnings profiles is estimated in the same nonparametric way as employer
wage differentials.

In every case where two occupations in a family are

14~og-point
wage differentials can be interpreted as approximate
percentage-point differences from the mean.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

observed at a single employer, the difference in the mean of log wages between
the steps is used as a dependent variable for the regression of wage gaps on a
set of fully interacted family-step dummies and a set of employer dummies.
The estimated employer coefficients are labeled WGDIF and measure the average
seniority-wage slope difference (relative to the mean in the city and year)
paid by the employer in a particular year. A positive number for a company
reflects above-average wage differences between steps in these 17 job-family
ladders among their employees.
Finally, to measure the relative seniority of the work force, we
estimate what we call the "employment concentration" for each CSS participant.
The log employment difference between steps in a job-family ladder is
regressed on the same set of dummy variables (for all possible family-step
combinations and for employers) used in the slope estimates. The estimated
employer coefficients are retained; a positive coefficient, labeled EMPDIF,
reflects an above-average concentration (within their city in that year) of
senior employees in these job ladders.
V. Results

A. Ex Ante Tests: The Effects of Wage and Employment Structures on the
Probability of Hostile Takeovers
Descriptive statistics for the wage and employment structure variables
for the ex ante analysis are reported in the last rows of tables 1A and 1B.
As a group, the seven companies that underwent hostile takeovers had the
lowest average wages (LEVMED), relatively flat seniority profiles (WGDIF), and
the highest concentration of workers in senior job classifications (EMPDIF).
However, these differences between groups are small relative to the variation

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

within groups.l5
We now turn to a more formal investigation of whether establishmentlevel employment distributions and wage structures are related to the
probability of a hostile takeover. For each firm, the estimates of the
employer-specific log median wage differential (LEVMED), log inter-job-level
wage difference (WGDIF), and log inter-job-levelemployment difference
(EMPDIF) are used to predict the occurrence of a hostile takeover. For firms
that underwent a hostile takeover, we ensure that these estimates are for a
year prior to the year of the takeover.
To reiterate, WGDIF serves as a proxy for extramarginal wage premia paid
to more-tenured workers, and EMPDIF is an index of employment concentration in
upper-level jobs. But wage or employment differences alone need not reflect
high overall rent payouts to employees. Firms with high employment
concentration in upper-level jobs but with small wage differences across job
levels or, conversely, those with high wage slopes but with relatively low
employment in upper-level jobs, may not be attractive hostile-takeover targets
because both of these cases are unlikely to be associated with substantial
extramarginal wage payments to more-tenured workers. However, the joint
incidence of relatively high employment in senior job levels and high interjob-level wage slopes may represent high overall extramarginal payments that
could be susceptible to expropriation. Thus, the interaction variable WGXEM,
computed as the product of WGDIF and EMPDIF, provides the strongest test of
the expropriation hypothesis with respect to extramarginal wages paid to moretenured workers. LEVMED is used to explore whether overall wage-level
differences across firms affect the probability of hostile takeovers.

15The means for the whole sample are different from zero because the
observations come from different years; only within a year is the average
firm-specific differential equal to zero.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 3 reports these probit estimates for various specifications. The
sample is restricted to firms that were candidates for a hostile takeover.
The first nine columns show the regressions on a subsample with nonmissing
data on union status, UN, and the log of firm size, LNSIZE. This subsample
contains 7 firms that experienced a hostile takeover during the period spanned
by the data, and 64 that did not. Table 4 reports results when the
noncandidates are included. The signs of the estimated coefficients of LEVMED
and WGDIF are negative, reflecting the differentials in tables 1A and 1B. The
estimated coefficients of WGXEM and EMPDIF are almost always positive. These
signs are robust to the inclusion of UN and LNSIZE in the regressions (columns
5 through 9), to the inclusion in the sample of firms with missing data on UN

and LNSIZE (columns 10 through 13), and to the inclusion of nontakeover
candidates in the regressions (table 4).
Results for all of these samples suggest that a more-senior work force
(EMPDIF) is positively related to probability of hostile takeovers, except in
regressions that control for LEVMED, WGDIF, and WGXEM (column 9 in tables 3
and 4). The probability of a hostile takeover based on a one-standarddeviation increase in each independent variable (holding the others at their
means) is shown in brackets below each coefficient estimate; these can be
compared to the probability at the means, in the last row of the table.l6
For example, in column 7 of table 3, increasing the interaction between
seniority and profile steepness (WGXEM) by one standard deviation raises the
probability of a hostile takeover from 0.10 to 0.12.
While none of the estimated coefficients of the wage and employment
structure variables is statistically significant, the signs of the estimated
coefficients point to several conclusions. First, higher wage levels per se
l6J?or the probit model, in contrast to the logit model, the estimated
probability at the means need not exactly equal the unconditional probability.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

are not positively associated with hostile takeover probabilities.

Second,

high wage differentials between job levels do not attract predators.

Third,

the positive signs on the interaction variable, WGXEM, suggest that firms with
higher wage payouts to senior workers in conjunction with high employment
concentrations in senior-level jobs are more likely to experience a hostile
takeover.

These results are consistent with Neumark and Sharpe's (1992)

findings in favor of the expropriation hypothesis that extramarginal wage
premia induce hostile takeovers, but, as in that paper, the evidence is not
statistically strong. In addition, presumably the inclusion of financial
controls would, as found by Neumark and Sharpe, further weaken these results.
Fourth, support is weak at best for the hypothesis that a higher employment
concentration in upper-level jobs, by itself, leads to a higher probability of
a hostile takeover.

B. Ex Post Tests: The Effects of Hostile Takeovers on Wage and Employment
Structures

As shown in the last rows of table 2, in the ex post observations,
employer-specific wage differentials rose most rapidly for employers that
experienced a hostile takeover (ALEVMED).

However, the concentration of

employees in senior positions drops dramatically following hostile takeovers
(AEMPDIF), while it rises after a merger. Wage profiles seem to be relatively
unaffected (AWGDIF).
The effects of hostile takeovers on firm wage and employment structures
are analyzed using data on the last year available for each firm. For firms
that underwent a hostile takeover, we ensure that this year is later than the
year of takeover. OLS regressions are estimated for differences in LEVMED,
WGDIF, WGXEM, and EMPDIF (denoted with A's) between the last and first years
of data availability, ensuring that for firms that were taken over, the change
occurred in an intervening year. The differences are regressed on a dummy
17
clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

explanatory variable, H , that indicates the occurrence of a takeover.
Table 5 reports results from two sets of regressions, the second set
containing an additional regressor, YRAFTH, indicating the span between the
year of takeover and the year to which the changes are computed. The
coefficients on H are negative in the AWGXEM and AEMPDIF regressions, but only
the coefficient on AWGXEM is significant (at the 10 percent level). The AWGDIF
regression produces a positive estimated coefficient that is not significant,
suggesting that inter-job wage differences remain substantially unchanged
after hostile takeovers.
The inclusion of YRAFTH in the regression preserves the negative signs
on both AWGXEM and AEMPDIF and renders the coefficient for AWGXEM more
strongly significant. These coefficient estimates indicate that hostile
takeovers are followed by relatively large reductions in employment
concentration in senior positions and in employment-weighted wage slopes. The
positive coefficients on YRAFTH in the AWGXEM and AEMPDIF regressions suggest
that the initial reductions in these variables after a hostile takeover are
partially reversed over time.
This apparent reversal could stem from at least two sources.

In line

with the hypothesis advanced here, suppose hostile predators extract
extramarginal rents from more-senior workers at the time of takeover, but do
not change the Lazear-type bonding offered to continuing or new employees. If
Lazear contracts are efficient and the new parent's offer is credible (because
the company has been resold or the predator is expected to honor its own
implicit contracts), then wage profiles would be unchanged after the takeover,
and, for example, the drop in the seniority concentration of workers would
dissipate over time. The second possibility is related to the fact that the
changes in the wage and employment structures for the earliest takeovers in
the sample were observed over the longest period; it is possible that the
18
clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

nature of the hostile takeovers differed between the early and late 1980s.
Under this interpretation, the positive coefficients on YRAFTH in the AWGXEM
and AEMPDIF regressions, and the stronger effects of hostile takeovers on
these variables once YRAFTH is included, suggest that the reductions in
extramarginal wage payments were larger in the later takeovers. This is
consistent with evidence in Kaplan and Stein (1991), showing that goingprivate transactions had higher prices relative to cash flow in the latter
half of the 1980s, which

suggests that in order to service the debt incurred

in these later transactions, reductions in the claims of other stakeholders
(such as more-tenured workers) were more likely.
In the case of ALEVMED, the coefficient on H is positive and
significant. The sign and significance are preserved when YRAFTH is included
in the regression. This positive effect on the post-hostile-takeover wage
levels may reflect "house cleaning" by the new owners/managers as some of the
less-efficientworkers are fired. Or, it may reflect an attempt to retain the
more-efficient workers in response to perceived increases in their jobseparation probabilities in light of the abrogation of implicit wage contracts
with senior workers. However, if hostile takeovers do reduce extramarginal
wage payments, then this result may imply that overall employer wage
differentials do not reflect extramarginal wages.17
Table 6 shows the same set of regressions with additional controls for
nonhostile mergers and akquisitions, M and YRAFTM. The addition of these
variables does not substantially change the signs and standard errors on any
of the coefficients on H and YRAFTH. More interesting is the fact that none

17~lternatively,it is possible that these extramarginal wage payments
are not reduced following hostile takeovers, while those paid to more-tenured
workers are decreased. Since the two types of extramarginal wage payments may
have different sources, it is conceivable that only the expropriation of the
latter type is profitable from the perspective of an acquiring firm.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

of the estimated coefficients of the dummy variable for nonhostile mergers is
significant and, in most cases, the signs are opposite those on H.

Thus, the

reductions in employment concentrations in senior positions and in employmentweighted inter-job wage differences, and the increases in median wage levels
following hostile takeovers, stand in contrast to the movements in these
variables following mergers and acquisitions.
The preservation of the negative and significant coefficient on H in the
AWGXEM regression is consistent with the hypothesis that post-hostile-takeover
restructuring results in an expropriation of extramarginal payments to the
more-tenured workers of firms. The results for AEMPDIF and AWGDIF suggest
that most of the reduction in extramarginal payments occurs not through
reductions in inter-job wage differentials, but through reductions in
employment concentrations in upper-level jobs.
VI.

Discussion of Interviews
After obtaining a complete set of results, we contacted each hostile

takeover target in our sample, in order to add qualitative evidence to our
findings. We were able to speak with current personnel officers at five of
the seven targets.
After confirming the history of the takeover, we asked open-ended
questions about the adjustment process and ensuing changes in personnel
policy.

In all cases, the respondents reported substantial employment

restructuring, continuing for as long as three years after the takeover. In
each case, most of the effort was directed at thinning out middle management.
Often, employees were encouraged to leave through early retirement plans or
"voluntary separation agreements" (including severance payments based on
seniority).

In three cases, a substantial number of workers were laid off or

fired, after an evaluation of each person and hisher position.
Consistent with our quantitative results, wage levels and differentials
20
clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

were not usually redesigned by the new parent company. However, some benefit
packages and incentive programs underwent substantial change to bring them in
line with parent company policies. A number of respondents reported that
pension plans proved hardest to redesign or replace, so the plans were usually
left intact. Finally, we note that four of the seven respondents have had
another change of ownership since the hostile takeover.
VII. Conclusion
The ex ante results do not provide evidence that extramarginal wages
paid to all workers in a firm, or to more-tenured workers, are associated with
subsequent hostile takeovers. However, the ex post results do provide
evidence consistent with the hypothesis that hostile takeovers result in
reduced extramarginal wage payments to more-tenured workers, mostly through
cutbacks in employment in senior positions.

Furthermore, the signs of the

estimated coefficients from the ex ante analysis are consistent with the
targeting of such payments in hostile takeovers; the term for the interaction
between inter-job-levelemployment difference and the slope of the wage
profile is positively associated, ex ante, with hostile takeovers, even if the
results are not statistically significant. The evidence from the ex post
analysis is consistent with findings suggesting that pension plan terminations
and reversions of excess assets, entailing breaches of implicit Lazear-type
contracts, are more likely to follow hostile takeovers.
One implication of these findings is that an active market for corporate
control may weaken Lazear-type bonding solutions to the effort-extraction
problem in the labor market.

If the prices at which hostile takeovers are

transacted reflect the costs and benefits of this bonding, then these findings
do not necessarily imply any inefficiency generated by the market for
corporate control. But if hostile takeover premia indicate short-term gains
from expropriating extramarginal wages, but not longer-term costs of the

21
clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

reduction of this bonding activity, then hostile takeovers may ultimately
prove destructive. Because employees in some companies may come to discount
the value of their long-term implicit contracts as other companies abrogate
theirs, the social costs of hostile takeovers may not be reflected in the
prices at which firms trade.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

References
Akerlof, George A. 1982. "Labor Contracts as Partial Gift Exchange." Quarterly
Journ.al of Economics 91(4): 543-69.
Bhagat, Sanjai, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny. 1990. "Hostile
Takeovers in the 1980s: The Return to Corporate Specialization." Brookings
Papers: Microeconomics 1990, 1-72.
Bhide, Amar V. 1989. "The Causes and Consequences of Hostile Takeovers." The
Continental Bank Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 2(2): 36-59.
Blackburn, McKinley and David Neumark. 1992. "Unobserved Ability, Efficiency
Wages, and Interindustry Wage Differentials." Forthcoming in Quarterly Journal
of Economics.

Brown, Charles and James L. Medoff. 1988. "The Impact of Firm Acquisitions on
Labor." In A. Auerbach, Ed., Cor~orateTakeovers: Causes and Conseauences
(Chicago: University of Chicago Press), 9-25.
Brown, James N. 1989. "Why Do Wages Increase with Tenure?" American Economic
971-92.

Review 79(5):

Carmichael, Lorne. 1983. "Firm-Specific Human Capital and Promotion Ladders."
251-8.

Bell Journal of Economics 14(1):

Dickens, William T. and Lawrence F. Katz. 1987a. "Inter-Industry Wage
Differences and Industry Characteristics." In K. Lang and J.S. Leonard, Eds.
Unemplovment and the Structure of Labor Markets (New York: Basil Blackwell),
48-89.

. 1987b. "Inter-Industry Wage Differences and Theories of Wage
Determination." NBER Working Paper No. 2271.
Frank, Robert H. and Robert M. Hutchens. 1992. "Wages, Seniority, and the
Demand for Rising Consumption Profiles." Mimeograph.
Gibbons, Robert and Lawrence Katz. 1992. "Does Unmeasured Ability Explain
Inter-Industry Wage Differentials?" Review of Economic Studies 59: 515-35.
Groshen, Erica L. 1991a. "Sources of Intra-Industry Wage Dispersion: How
Much Do Employers Matter?" Quarterly Journal of Economics 106(3): 869-84.

.

1991b. "Five Reasons Why Wages Vary among Employers." Industrial
350-81.

Relations 30(3):

. 1991c. "Rising Inequality in a Salary Survey: Another Piece of the
Puzzle." Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Working Paper 9121.
Helwege, Jean. 1992. "Sectoral Shocks and Interindustry Wage Differentials."
55-84.

Journal of Labor Economics lO(1):

Hotchkiss, Julie. 1990. "Compensation Policy and Firm Performance: An
Annotated Bibliography of Machine Readable Data Files." Industrial and Labor
Relations Review 43(3): 274-89
Ippolito, Richard A. and William H. James. 1992. "LBOs, Reversions and

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Implicit Contracts." Journal of Finance 47 (1): 139-67.
Kaplan, Steven N. and Jeremy C. Stein. 1991. "The Evolution of Buyout Pricing
and Financial Structure in the 1980s." Mimeograph.
Kotlikoff, Laurence J. and Jagadeesh Gokhale. "Estimating a Firm's AgeProductivity Profile Using the Present Value of Workers' Earnings." Quarterly
Journal of Economics 431(4): 1215-42.
Kotlikoff, Laurence J. and David Wise. 1985. "Labor Compensation and the
Structure of Private Pension Plans: Evidence for Contractual versus Spot Labor
Markets." In D. Wise, Ed. Pensions. Labor, and Individual Choice (Chicago:
University of Chicago Press), 55-85.
Krueger, Alan B. and Lawrence H. Summers. 1988. "Efficiency Wages and the
Inter-IndustryWage Structure." Econometrica 56(2): 259-94.
Lazear, Edward P. 1979. "Why Is There Mandatory Retirement?" Journal of
1261-84.

Political Economy 87(6):

Lazear, Edward P. and Robert L. Moore. 1984. "Incentives, Productivity, and
Labor Contracts." Quarterly Journal of Economics 99(2): 275-95.
Levine, David I. 1991. "Fairness, Markets, and Ability to Pay: Evidence from
Compensation Executives." University of California at Berkeley, Center for
Research in Management, Organizational Behavior and Industrial Relations
Working Paper No. 55.
Lichtenberg, Frank R. and Donald Siegel. 1989. "The Effect of Takeovers on the
Employment and Wages of Central-Office and Other Personnel." NBER Working
Paper No. 2895.
Loewenstein, George and Nachum Sicherman. 1991. "Do Workers Prefer Increasing
Wage Profiles?" Journal of Labor Economics 9(1): 67-84.
Medoff, James L. and Katharine G. Abraham. 1981. "Are Those Paid More Really
More Productive? The Case of Experience." Journal of Human Resources 16(2):
186-216.
Mittelstaedt, H. Fred. 1991. "Takeovers, Asset Reversions, and Wealth
Transfers." Mimeograph.
Murphy, Kevin M. and Robert H. Topel. 1987. "Unemployment, Risk, and Earnings:
Testing for Equalizing Wage Differentials in the Labor Market." In K. Lang and
J.S. Leonard, Eds., Unemplovment and the Structure of Labor Markets (New York:
Basil Blackwell), 103-40.
Newark, David. 1992. "Are Rising Wage Profiles a Forced-Saving Mechanism?"
Mimeograph.
Neumark, David and Steven A. Sharpe. 1992. "Hostile Takeovers and
Expropriation of Extramarginal Wages: A Test." Mimeograph.
Newark, David and Paul Taubman. 1992. "Why Do Wages Rise with Experience:
Tests of the Lazear, Human Capital, and Forced-Saving Hypotheses." Mimeograph.
Neumark, David and Michael L. Wachter. 1992. "Union Threat Effects and
clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Nonunion Industry Wage Differentials." NBER Working Paper No. 4046.
Petersen, Mitchell A. 1992. "Pension Reversions and Worker-Stockholder Wealth
Transfers." Quarterly Journal of Economics CVII (2): 1033-56.
Pontiff, Jeffrey, Andrei Shleifer, and Michael S. Weisbach. 1990. "Reversions
of Excess Pension Assets after Takeovers." Rand Journal of Economics 21(4):
600-13.
Rosett, Joshua. 1990. "Do Union Wealth Concessions Explain Takeover Premiums?
The Evidence on Contract Wages." Journal of Financial Economics 27(1): 263-82.
Shleifer, Andrei and Lawrence H. Summers. 1988. "Breach of Trust in Hostile
Takeovers." In A. Auerbach, Ed., Corporate Takeovers: Causes and Consequences
(Chicago: University of Chicago Press), 33-68.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Appendix A:

Occupation Families in the CSS

Familv
Economists
Administrators
Secretaries

Security
EDP Audit
Audit Analysts
Programmer/
Analysts

Computer
Operators
Programmers
Mechanics
Building
Engineers
Payroll Clerks
Statistical Clerks
Check Processors
Accounting
Benefits
Data Processing

Leve1
Economist 1
Economic Advisor
Admin. Assistant 1
Admin. Assistant 2
Admin. Assistant 3
Stenographer
Secretary 1
Secretary 2
Secretary 3
Executive Secretary
Security Guard 1
Guard Supervisor
Protection Manager
EDP Audit Analyst 1
EDP Audit Analyst 2
Internal Audit Manager
Audit Analyst 1
Audit Analyst 2
Audit Analyst 3
Programmer/Analyst 1
Programmer/Analyst 2
Programmer/Analyst 3
Systems Analyst 1
Consulting Analyst
Computer Operator 1
Computer Operator 2
Lead Operator
Programmer 1
Programmer 2
Maintenance Mechanic 1
Maintenance Mechanic 2
Chief Maintenance Mechanic
Building Engineer 1
Building Engineer 2
Chief Building Engineer
Payroll Clerk 1
Payroll Clerk 2
Payroll Supervisor
Statistical Clerk 1
Statistical Clerk 2
Check Processing Clerk 1
Check Processing Clerk 2
Check Processing Clerk 3
Accounting Supervisor
Accounting Manager
Employee Benefits Counselor
Benefits Administrator
Data Processing Supervisor
Data Processing Manager

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 1A: Ex Ante Observations. Complete Sample
Whole Sample
Number of
observations

133

Noncandidates
34

Unmerged
Candidates
71

Merners/Acsuisitions

Hostile Takeovers

21

7

City
Cleveland
Cincinnati
Pittsburgh
Year entered
survey
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
One-digit industry
Mining and construction
Nondurable manufacturing
Durable manufacturing
Transportation, comrmnication,
and utilities
Trade
Finance, insurance, and
real estate
Miscellaneous services
Professional services
Government
Employer wage and
employment differentials
LEVMF.D (wage level)

-0.026
(0.167)

0.009
(0.142)

-0.027
(0.173)

-0.067
(0.192)

-0.065
(0.116)

WGDIF (wage profile
steepness)

0.009
(0.104)

-0.022
(0.086)

0.018
(0.113)

0.037
(0.089)

-0.020
(0.113)

-IF

-0.041
(0.596)

-0.087
(0.601)

-0.027
(0.620)

-0.042
(0.591)

0.035
(0.374)

(employment
seniority)

Cell counts are reported, except for employer wage and employment differentials, where means are reported, with atandarc
deviations in parentheses.
Source:

Authors' calculations.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 1B: Ex Ante Observations, Semple with Unionization and Employer Size Data

Whole Sample
Number of
observations

97

Noncandidates
26

Unmerged
Candidates
56

Merners/Acauisitions
8

Hostile Takeovers
7

City
Cleveland
Cincinnati
Pittsburgh
Year entered
Survey
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
One-digit industry
Mining and construction
Nondurable manufacturing
Durable manufacturing
Transportation, comrmnication,
and utilities
Trade
Finance, insurance, and
real estate
Miscellaneous services
Professional services
Government
Employer wage and
employment differentials

LEVMED (wage level)

-0.038
(0.151)

0.000
(0.145)

-0.043
(0.161)

-0.107
(0.101)

-0.065
(0.116)

EMPDIF (employment
seniority)

-0.054
(0.588)

-0.112
(0.670

-0.052
(0.607)

0.042
(0.314)

0.035
(0.374)

UNION (unionized)

0.37

0.73

0.23

0.25

2758
(8826)

5900
(16363)

1797
(2744)

1009
(1158)

KiDIF (wage profile
steepness)

SIZE (firm size)

0.29

Cell counts are reported, except for employer wage and employment differentials, where means are reported, with standard
deviations in parentheses.

Source:

~uthors'calculations.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 2: Ex Post Observations
Whole Sample
Number of
observations

121

Nomergers Merners/Accruisitions
101

14

Hostile Takeovers
6

City
Cleveland
Cincinnati
Pittsburgh
Year of takeover or
merger/acquisition
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
One-digit industry
Mining and construction
Nondurable manufacturing
Durable manufacturing
Transportation, comrmnication,
and utilities
Trade
Finance, insurance, and
real estate
Miscellaneous services
Professional aervices
Government
Changes in employer wage and
employment differentials
ALEVMED (wage level)

0.033
(0.097)

AWGDIP (wage profile
steepness)

-0.022
(0.117)

m D I F (employment
seniority )

0.004
(0.743)

YRAFTH (mean no. of years
observed after hoatile
takeover)

-

YRAFTM (mean no. of years
obaerved after merger/
acquisition)

-

Cell count8 are reported, except for changes in employer wage and employment differentials, where meana are reported,
with standard deviations in parentheses.
Source: Authora' calculations.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 3: Probit Estimates of the Effects of Ex Ante Wage and Employment Structure on Hostile Takeovers

Excludes Noncandidates and Firms With Missing Observations
On Union Status and Firm Size

WGDIF

-

EMPDIF

LNSIZE

-2.19
(1.94)
10.061

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

Log likelihood -22.83
Prob. at
means

0.10

-

0.14
(0.40)
[0.111

-

-

-2.21
(1.98)
[0.061

-

-

-

-

-0.14
(0.22)
10.071

-0.16
(0.22)
10.071

-0.12
(0.23)
[0.071

-

Excludes Noncandidates Only

-2.08
(2.06)
[0.061

0.16
(0.41)
[0.111

-0.08
(0.78)
[0.081

-0.13
(0.22)
10.071

-0.14
(0.23)
[0.071

-

-1.83
(1.85)
[O.051

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

0.10
(0.35)
10. 081

-

-22.19

-22.59

-22.80

-22.55

-21.95

-22.36

-22.54

-21.72

-25.19

-24.78

-25.06

-25.25

0.10

0.10

0.10

0.09

0.09

0.10

0.10

0.09

0.07

0.07

0.07

0.07

LEVMED = employer-specific level of median wage; WGDIF = employer-specific inter-Job-level wage difference; WGXEM =
interaction between WGDIF and PIDIF ; EMPDIF = employer-specific inter-job-level employment difference; UN = union status
(=I if 25% unionized); LNSIZE = log of firm size. Standard errors are reported in parentheses. The intercepts are not
reported. In columns (1)-(91, there are 7 hostile takeovers and 64 other observations. In columns (10)-(13); there
are 7 hostile takeovers and 92 other observations. The last row reports the estimated probability of a hostile takeover
at the sample means; the numbers in square brackets report the estimated probability following a one-standard-deviation
increase in the variable in each row, holding the other variables at the sample means.
Source:

Authors' calculations.
clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

nn

C5

m m u
o m 0

...

I

N d O
I w u

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 5: Effects of Hostile Takeovers on Firm Wage and Employment Structure
Dependent
Variable:
INTERCEPT

YRAFTH

ALEVMED AWGDIF
0.025 - 0 . 0 2 1
(0.009) (0.011)

-

-

AWGXEM

AEMPDIF

0.013
(0.022)

0.015
(0.069)

-

-

ALEVMED AWGDIF

AWGXEM

AEMPDIF

0.013
(0.022)

0.015
(0.069)

0.038
-0.006
-0.013
(0.012) (0.015) (0.030)

0.038
(0.095)

0.025 -0.021
(0.009) (0.011)

H = dummy variable indicating hostile takeover; YRAFTH = years elapsed after hostile takeover
(PO for other firms).
See footnotes to table 3 for other variable definitions. Standard
errors are reported in parentheses. There are 123 observations.

Source: Authors' calculations.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 6: Differential Effects of Hostile Takeovers and Mergers and Acquisitions
On Firm Wage and Employment Structure
Dependent
Variable:

ALEVMED

INTERCEPT

AWGDIF

AWGXEM

AEMPDIF

0.030 -0.020
0.017
0.030
(0.009) (0.012) (0.023) (0.074)

ALEVMED AWGDIF

AWGXEM

AEMPDIF

0.030 -0.020
0.017
0.030
(0.009) (0.012) (0.023) (0.074)

YRAFTH

-

-

-

-

-0.006 -0.013
0.038
0.038
(0.012) (0.015) (0.030) (0.096)

YRAFTM

-

-

-

-

0.015 -0.013
0.009 -0.019
(0.009) (0.011) (0.023) (0.072)

M = Durmny variable indicating nonhostile merger and acquisition; YRAFTM = Years elapsed after
merger. See footnotes to tables 3 and 5 for other variable definitions. Standard errors are
reported in parentheses. There are 121 observations.
Source:

Authors8 calculations.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm