View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Working Paper 9305

GENERATIONAL ACCOUNTING IN NORWAY:
IS THE NATION OVERCONSUMING ITS PETROLEUM WEALTH?
by Alan J. Auerbach, Jagadeesh Gokhale,
Laurence J. Kotlikoff, and Erling Steigum, Jr.

Alan J. Auerbach is a professor of economics at
the University of Pennsylvania and an associate of
the National Bureau of Economic Research; Jagadeesh
Gokhale is an economist at the Federal Reserve Bank
of Cleveland; Laurence J. Kotlikoff is a professor of
economics at Boston University; and Erling Steigum, Jr.
is a professor of economics at the Norwegian School
of Economics and Business Administration, Bergen.
The authors would like to thank Carl E. Gjersem for
excellent research assistance and Olav Ljones and Dennis
Fredriksen of the Central Bureau of Statistics in Oslo
for providing estimates from the microsimulation model
MOSART. This research was financed by the Norwegian
Research Council for Applied Social Science.
Working papers of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion
and critical comment. The views stated herein are those
of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System.

October 1993

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Abstract
This paper uses generational accounting to assess Norway's fiscal position. Generational
accounting measures the remaining lifetime net tax burdens facing different living
generations. It can also be used to compute the percentage difference between the
average net tax burden facing future generations and that facing current newborns under
existing fiscal policies. Although the Norwegian government imposes sizable burdens on
current generations, it also consumes a large share of total national output. Our
calculations indicate that despite the government's positive net wealth, current policies
imply net tax burdens on future Norwegians that are about twice as large as those facing
current young generations.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

I. Introduction
This paper uses a new method, called generational accounting, to assess
Norway's long-term fiscal position.'

Generational accounting determines

whether a country's current fiscal policies can be sustained without requiring
future generations to pay higher net taxes (taxes paid net of transfers
received) over their lifetimes than current generations pay.
Understanding the sustainability of the current level of net taxation,
though important for any country, is particularly interesting in the case of
Norway. Unlike most countries, Norway has a large, positive stock of government wealth due mainly to its considerable petroleum resources. Based on
conventional macroeconomic analysis, which emphasizes the amount of government
debt, the fact that the Norwegian government has a net surplus would suggest
that its fiscal house is fully in order. But this does not mean that it will
have positive net wealth forever. Indeed, Norway's budget deficit, as conventionally measured, is expected to reach 6 percent of GDP in 1993. Even if the
budget deficit were zero, projected demographic changes as well as projected
increases in the scale of Social Security benefits raise the question of
fiscal sustainability.2 So too does the government's high and growing level
of purchases of goods gnd services.
In short, then, this paper considers whether Norway is consuming its oil
and other wealth too rapidly, with the consequence that future generations of
Norwegians will not benefit from that wealth to the same extent that current
generations have.

Our main findings suggest that this concern is real, that

current Norwegian fiscal policy is not sustainable, and that the continued
failure to adjust government policy will leave future Norwegians facing
1
See Auerbach, Gokhale, and Kotlikoff (1991, 1992a, 1992b, 1993, 1994)
and Kotlikoff (1992).
2 See Kotlikoff (1992) for a detailed critique of the deficit as a measure
of an economy's fiscal position.
3 For an early study of this issue, see Steigum and Thogersen (1992).

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

lifetime net tax burdens that could well be twice as large as those
confronting today's children based on current law. While the precise size of
this generational imbalance depends on the assumed rate of return the government earns on its assets, the disparity is large even under quite high
interest-rate assumptions.
The next section describes the Norwegian economy and provides an overview
of its fiscal policies.

Section I11 explains the method of generational

accounting. Section IV summarizes the data used to construct the accounts,
leaving a more detailed description for the appendix. Section V presents the
accounts, discusses their implications and sensitivity to assumptions, and
provides comparisons with generational accounts for the United States.
Section VI summarizes our findings and draws conclusions.

11.

he

Norwegian Economy and Fiscal Policy

-A

Brief Description

Norway is a small country with 4.3 million inhabitants and a highly open
economy. Exports accounted for 43 percent of GDP in 1992, almost one-third of
which were petroleum products, primarily oil and natural gas.

Living stan-

dards are quite high compared with those of most other OECD countries. In
1992, per capita GDP totaled $24,600. As indicated in table 1, the nation's
huge petroleum resources
$34,640 per capita

- estimated to

- are

equal about 41 percent of GDP, or

a prime source of this wealth.

About 86 percent of Norway's petroleum assets are directly or indirectly
(through taxation) owned by the government. In addition, the government has a
substantial stock of wealth resulting from its generation of hydroelectric
power.

It also has considerable financial reserves, with total government

wealth exceeding Norwegian GDP by a factor of more than 2.5.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Norway's proven oil reserves amount to 17 years of production at the
current rate.

Starting from zero in 1971, production increased to 132 million

tons oil equivalents (mtoe) in 1992, making the nation a larger producer than
the United Kingdom. According to the government's recent Long Term Program
1994-1997, this trend will continue throughout the rest of the 1990s, with
production expected to peak at 165 mtoe in 2000 and then to head downward to
137 mtoe in 2010 and 87 mtoe in 2030. Norway is also rich in natural gas
xeserves, which would last for 111 years at the current rate of production.
Extraction, however, is expected to increase substantially over the next 10 to
15 years.
Like almost all OECD countries, Norway's population is getting older.
Table 2 shows how this aging process will play out through the next century.
The projections, which are taken from the Long Term Program 1994-1997 and
Gjersem (1993), assume that the current fertility rate of 1.89 percent will
prevail in future years and that life expectancy will continue to increase.
The share of the population that is of working age (19 through 64) is
projected to rise over the next 20 years and then to reverse course. The
percentage of Norwegians over age 65 is now 0.163, but by 2050 that figure
should hit 0.203. The dependency ratio of 0.702 (the ratio of those age 18
and below plus those age 65 and above to those age 19 to 64), already quite
high, is expected to fall to 0.650 by 2015 and to begin increasing thereafter,
reaching 0.731 by the year 2050.
By international standards, Norway has a massive public sector. Table 3
compares key fiscal ratios for Norway, the United States, Italy, Japan,
Germany, and France in 1992. Of the six countries, Norway's 0.551 ratio of
total government outlays to GDP is the largest. The U.S. ratio of 0.354 is
the smallest.

While Norway's transfer payments to GDP ratio of 0.226 is

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

somewhat below that of France, its 0.260 ratio of direct government consumption plus investment spending is the highest of the six. Not surprisingly,
Norway also ranks first in the ratio of taxes to GDP.

In fact, the only

category in which Norway's fiscal policy compares favorably with those of the
other five countries is the ratio of net debt to GDP. The government's net
financial assets are a positive 17.2 percent of GDP. By way of comparison,
Italy's net financial assets are a negative 105.3 percent.
Table 4 presents the principal components of the Norwegian government's
expenditures and receipts in 1992.~ Transfers total 29 percent of GDP, of
which 6.41 percent represents subsidies, primarily agricultural. The current
universal Norwegian Social Security system was established in 1967, though
old-age pensions will not be fully phased in until the middle of the next
century. The system is fairly generous and is basically financed on a pay-asyou-go basis.

In 1992, public expenditure on o.ld-age pensions amounted to 6.8

percent of GDP, while disability pensions, sickness allowance, and unemployment benefits totaled 7.5 percent. Another important transfer is family
allowance, which amounted to 2.4 percent of GDP in 1992. Old-age pensions are
expected to grow rapidly in the years ahead, due both to demographics and to
the phase-in of the new pension system.
Public consumption spending represented 22.43 percent of GDP in 1992,
much of which was traceable to government workers' wages. About 30 percent of
total employment is in the public sector. The second largest component of
public consumption spending represents expenditures on health and education
As table 4 shows, the government runs a considerable deficit (3.62
percent of GDP) despite its huge wealth. In part, this stems from the recent

4 Note that some of the figures in this table differ from those in
table 3 due to differences in classifications.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

recession, which triggered a shift to an expansionary fiscal policy stance in
the beginning of the 1990s. It also reflects investment in the petroleum
sector, which in 1992 accounted for 32 percent of the budget shortfall
reported in table 4. Current projections show the deficit rising to 6 percent
of GDP in 1993, of which 43 percent represents direct investment in the
petroleum sector.
Table 4 also indicates the important role of indirect taxes and Social
Security contributions to Norway's public finance. In addition to a large
value-added tax (VAT), there are substantial consumption taxes (excise taxes)
on cars, gasoline, alcohol, and tobacco. Excluding petroleum taxes, most
direct taxes are on labor income. Capital taxes are low in Norway. Private

.

households are heavily indebted due to the deductibility of nominal borrowing
costs. In fact, aggregate capital taxes from private households are negative,
i.e., the government is, on average, subsidizing capital income. Property
taxes are also a minor item.
In 1992, the statutory tax rate for capital income was reduced to 28
percent and the maximum marginal tax rate on labor income was cut to about 50
percent. Overall, the effect of this reform has been to increase corporate
income taxation and to reduce personal capital income taxation.

111. ~ e t h o d o l o ~ ~ ~

Generational accounting is based on the government's intertemporal budget
constraint. This constraint, written as equation (I), requires that the
future net tax payments of current and future generations be sufficient, in
present value, to 1) cover the present value of future government consumption
5 This section provides a brief description of the method of generational
accounting. For a more detailed explanation, see Auerbach, Gokhale, and
Kotlikoff (1991).

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

and 2) pay off the government's initial net indebtedness,.
D

cQ

I: N t ,t-s

(1)

s=o

+

cQ

=

Nt,t+S
s=l

=

I: G~ (I+,) t-s s=t

WE

The first summation on the left-hand side of (1) adds together the generational accounts (the present value of the remaining lifetime net payments) of
existing generations. The term NtJk stands for the account of the generation
born in year k. The index s in this summation runs from age 0 to age D , the
maximum length of life.6
The second summation on the left-hand side of (1) adds together the
present value of remaining net payments of future generations. The first term
on the right-hand side expresses the present value of government consumption.
In this summation, the values of government consumption in year s , given by
Gs, are discounted by the pre-tax real interest rate, r.

The remaining term

6

on the left-hand side, Wt, denotes the government's net wealth in year t.
Equation (1) indicates the zero-sum nature of intergenerational fiscal
policy.

Holding the present value of government consumption fixed, a reduc-

tion in the present value of net taxes extracted from current generations (a
decline in the first summation on the left side of [I]) necessitates an
increase in the present value of future generations' net tax payments.
The term N

tJk

is defined by

6 Hence, the first element of this summation is NtSt,which is the present
value of net payments of the generation born in year t; the last term is
N f , t-D the present value of remaining net payments of the oldest generation
a lve in year t, namely, those born in year t-D.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Here, T
stands for the projected average net tax payment to the government
s ,k
made in year s by a member of the generation born in year k. The term Ps,k
stands for the number of surviving members of the cohort in year s who were
born in year k. For generations born prior to year t, the summation begins in
year t.

For generations born in year k , where k > t, the summation begins in

year k. Regardless of the generation's year of birth, the discounting is
always back to year t.

A set of generational accounts is simply a set of values of Nt,k, one for
each existing and future generation, with the property that the combined
present value adds up to the right-hand side of equation (1).

Though we

distinguish male and female cohorts in the results presented below, we
suppress sex subscripts in (1) and (2) to ease notation.
Note that generational accounts reflect only taxes paid less transfers
received. With the exception of government expenditures on education, which
are treated as transfer payments, the accounts do not impute to particular
generations the value of the government's purchases of goods and services.
Therefore, the accounts do not show the full net benefit or burden that any
generation receives from government policy as a whole, although they can show
a generation's net benefitburden from a particular policy change that affects
only taxes and transfers. Thus, generational accounting tells us which generations will pay for government spending, not which will benefit from that
spending.

Assessing the Fiscal Burden Facinp Future Generations
Given the right-hand side and the first term on the left-hand side of
equation (I), we determine, as a residual, the value of the second term on the
right-hand side, which is the collective payment (measured as a time-t present

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

value) required of future generations. Based on this amount, we determine the
average-present-value lifetime net tax payment of each member of each future
generation under the assumption that the average lifetime tax payment of
successive generations rises at the economy's rate of productivity growth.
Without this growth adjustment, the lifetime net tax payments of future generations are directly comparable to those of current newborns, since the generational accounts of both newborns and future generations take into account net
tax payments over these generations' entire lifetimes.
Note that our assumption that the generational accounts of all future
generations are equal, except for a growth adjustment, is just one of many
possible conjectures about the distribution across future generations of their
collective net payment to the government. We could, for example, assume a
phase-in of the additional fiscal burden (positive or negative) to be imposed
on new young generations. Clearly, this would mean that generations born
after the phase-in period has elapsed would face larger lifetime burdens (the
Nt,k's) than those calculated here.

IV. Constructing Generational Accounts
To form generational accounts for current and future generations, we need
1) proj'ections of the population by age and sex, 2) projections of average net
taxes for each generation in each year in which at least some of its members
will be alive, 3) a discount rate to convert flows of net taxes into present
values, 4) an estimate of the initial stock of government net wealth, and

5) projections of future government consumption. We describe the data sources
and procedures for obtaining this information in general terms here, and
provide a detailed description in the appendix.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Po~ulationProiections
The projection of population by age and sex from 1992 through 2050 is
taken from The Long Term Program 1994-1997, a fiscal planning document issued
by the Norwegian government. We have extended these projections through 2200
by assuming that fertility and mortality rates after 2050 equal those
projected for that year.

Proiection of Taxes and Transfers
Our projections of average future taxes and transfers by age and sex
begin with the 1992 official totals for all levels of government (central and
local).

All taxes and transfers are considered in this analysis. Taxes are

categorized as VATS, auto'excise and gasoline taxes, alcohol and tobacco
excise taxes, Social Security contributions, income taxes, and personal wealth
taxes. Transfer payments are categorized as old-age support, health, education, old-age pensions, disability pensions, sickness allowance, family
allowance, unemployment benefits, and other Social Security.
We distribute the 1992 totals of each of these taxes and transfers by age
and sex based on corresponding distributions in cross-section survey data.
The primary sources for these distributions are the 1990 Income and Wealth
Survey and the 1990 Survey of Consumer Expenditure. The Income and Wealth
Survey sample contains 8,287 households with 22,349 members. The Survey of
Consumer Expenditure contains 1,201 households with 3,216 members. The
appendix provides further details concerning the construction of the crosssection tax and transfer distributions.
The result of distributing the various aggregate taxes and transfers by
age and sex is a 1992 distribution of benchmarked average payments by age and
sex for each type of tax and transfer. We assume that, except for produc-

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

tivity growth, all distributions hold for future years. Thus, if we assume a
0.75 percent rate of productivity growth, the projected distribution of taxes
and transfers by age and sex for, say, 2020 equals the 1992 distribution
multiplied by 1.0075 raised to the twenty-eighth power.
The sole exception to this procedure arises in the case of old-age
pensions. The Norwegian Social Security system is relatively young, and
higher old-age pension benefits are to be phased in over time. To accommodate
this fact, we used the MOSART model (a microsimulation model constructed by
the Norwegian Central Bureau of Statistics) to project future distributions of
old-age pensions by age and sex.

Discount Rates
The appropriate discount rate for calculating the present value of future
amounts depends on whether or not they are known with certainty. Future
government receipts and expenditures are risky, which suggests that they be
discounted by a rate higher than the real rate of interest on government
securities. On the other hand, government receipts and expenditures appear to
be less volatile than the real return on capital, suggesting that they be
discounted by a rate lower than that. Our baseline calculations assume a 4
percent real discount rate, which appears to be close to the current average
real rate earned by the Norwegian government on its net financial wealth.

Government Consum~tion
The present value of government spending on goods and services is
estimated based on the assumption that spending grows over time (from its 1992
level) to keep pace with population plus productivity growth. This amounts to
assuming that spending per capita rises at the productivity growth rate.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Given the projected absolute stream of spending, forming its present value is
a simple matter of discounting.
Our estimate of spending includes infrastructure investment rather than
the imputed rent on the existing stock of infrastructure. Our failure to
impute rent on Norwegian government infrastructure (other than the
electricity-generating sector and the public telephone company) does not,
however, appear to bias our calculations. The reason is that, to a first
approximation, the present value of the future imputed rent on new infrastructure investment should equal the amount of the investment.
In the case of existing infrastructure, such as the Norwegian fjords, we
ignore both the value of the stock (in calculating the government's net
wealth) and the future imputed rent (in calculating the present value of
government spending).

To a first approximation, these adjustments would

cancel from the right-hand side of equation (1) and therefore would leave
unaltered our calculation of the net tax burden facing future generations.

Government Net Wealth
Our measure of government net wealth is the sum of five components: net
financial assets, the market value of publicly owned stock, the present value
of income from the sale of petroleum, the present value of the net cash flow
from hydroelectric power plants, and revenue from the public telephone
company. The appendix describes the data sources and calculation of each of
these items.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

V . Findings

Basic Results
Tables 5 and 6 present the basic generational accounts for Norwegian
males and females for the base year of 1992. For cohorts ranging in age from
0 to 95 in 1992, each table includes nine sets of calculations, corresponding
to three real, before-tax interest rates (2, 4, and 7 percent) and three rates
of multifactor productivity growth (0.25, 0.75, and 1.25 percent).

The center

column corresponds to our base-case assumptions of a 4 percent rate of
interest and a 0.75 percent rate of productivity growth.
For males in the base case (table I), the generational account is
$129,900 for newborns, rising to a peak of $295,200 for those who turned 25
in 1992. Thereafter the account falls, becoming negative at age 60 as individuals approach retirement and, with it, a reduced level of income taxes and
public pension benefits.

In interpreting this pattern, it is important to

remember that a generation's account equals the present value of its remaining
lifetime net tax payments. Thus, one cannot directly compare the accounts of
different current generations to determine their relative lifetime burdens.
For women (table 6), the lifetime pattern is similar for the base case,
but the accounts at each age are generally much lower. Newborns in 1992, for
example, face a net lifetime fiscal burden of just $5,600. This difference
can be understood by looking at more detailed information presented in tables
7 through 10.
Tables 7 and 8 repeat the generational accounts for males and females for
the base case, decomposing the results into the components of household
payments and receipts. Comparing these two tables, we see that taxes on
income and labor earnings explain most of the gender-related differences. As
a result of their lower rate of labor force participation and their lower

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

earnings when employed, females born in 1992 will pay $86,200 less in income
and payroll taxes.

In addition, women receive higher lifetime benefits.

Their higher public pensions result from greater longevity, although a large
share of general social welfare payments and most family benefits go to women.
Tables 7 and 8 also permit a number of other interesting observations
regarding the Norwegian fiscal system. One is the importance of indirect
taxes.

For males, roughly one-third of all lifetime taxes are indirect (VATS

plus specific excise taxes); for females, the share is one-half. On the
receipts side, the largest program for both men and women is education. While
pension benefits are larger in absolute terms, they are received much later in
life and hence have a smaller present value than education benefits.
This difference in timing is exhibited in tables 9 and 10, which present
the annual-flow components of the base-case accounts for a single generation

- 1992 newborns - over

10-year intervals. Each row in the table gives the

actual payments and receipts that a representative member of the cohort will
receive as he or she ages. The present values of these flows are presented in
the rows of tables 7 and 8. As one would expect, the tables indicate a
smoother lifetime pattern of consumption taxes than of income taxes. Because
income taxes include taxes on capital income, they occur, on average, later in
life than payroll taxes. On the receipts side, again as expected, education
benefits occur very early in life and pension benefits quite late. This
explains why the lower annual flows for education result in much larger age-0
present values. As a comparison of the tables for males and females shows,
men's pension benefits are actually greater than women's in each year. Thus,
the higher present value for women is entirely attributable to their greater
longevity.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

The Fiscal Burden on Future Norwe~ians
Having considered the accounts for existing generations in some detail,
what can we say about future generations?

Let us return to tables 5 and 6,

which present at the bottom the fiscal burdens that must be borne by future
generations in order to satisfy the government's intertemporal budget
constraint. For the base case, we estimate that future generations face net
payment burdens that, adjusted for growth, are 133 percent higher than those
faced by 1992 newborns. This indicates a severe imbalance in generational
policy. However, it is important to consider how dependent this finding is on
a variety of assumptions.
As discussed above, there are wide ranges of interest rates and economic
growth rates that could plausibly be used in calculating generational
accounts. How much do our conclusions hinge on the particular base-case
combination used thus far? Tables 5 and 6 provide the answer, giving current
and future generational accounts for nine different interest-rate/growth-rate
combinations. The results indicate that the finding of a severe generational
imbalance does indeed depend on our parameter assumptions.
The net-payment burden of a given generation is the sum of the present
values of different streams of taxes and transfers, some of which occur
earlier and others later during the generation's remaining lifespan. Hence,
the relationship between the net-payment burden and the rate of interest may
not be monotonic. Tables 5 and 6 show that the percentage difference between
the accounts of newborn and future generati0ns.i~smaller the higher is r.7
This difference is quite sensitive to the values of r and g used in the

7
Note that the percentage difference is adjusted for growth and is
- 1) x 100, where Nf is the net-payment
calculated as ([Nf/((l+g)*Nn)]
burden on future generations and Nn is that on current newborns.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

calculations, and it is large and positive for a range of plausible values of
these parameters.
For a given value of r, a higher value of g implies larger payments and
receipts the further in the future that these occur. Again, however, because
the timing of taxes and transfers is generally different over the lifespan,
values of g and of the net payment need not be related in a monotonic way for
particular generations. Table 5 shows that higher values of g produce larger
present-value net-payment burdens for future as compared to current generations and result in a larger percentage difference between the accounts of
future and newborn generations.

The Imvact of Petroleum Wealth
As mentioned above, one of the distinctive features of the Norwegian
economy is its considerable government wealth, due primarily to its energy
resources. Because of its prominence, petroleum wealth is often used as a
benchmark for questions about Norway's fiscal status. For example, we might
relate the size of Norway's current generational imbalance to its stock of
petroleum wealth, or ask how changes in the value of the nation's energy
resources affect its fiscal position.
One way of addressing the first question is to ask to what extent government spending out of its petroleum wealth would have to be reduced to restore
generational balance.

For the base case, in which there is initially a gener-

ational imbalance of 133 percent, we find that a permanent reduction in
spending of 22.0 percent would be required. In 1992, this would mean a reduction of $1,329 per person in government spending, which equals about twothirds of Norway's estimated 1992 income from its petroleum wealth.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Of course, the nation's actual petroleum wealth might change over time.
Because the value of energy resources is highly sensitive to the volatile
prices of oil and natural gas, significant unexpected increases or decreases
are quite plausible.

Our calculations indicate that a decline in petroleum

wealth could have a severe impact on the well-being of future generations.
For the base-case assumptions about interest and growth rates, halving the
value of petroleum wealth raises the generational accounts of the unborn by
62.6 percent - an absolute amount of $82,000 for males and $3,500 for
females. Thus, declines in petroleum wealth due to world oil price changes
could have an important impact on Norway's generational balance.

Comparing Norwegian and U.S. Generational Accounts
How do our findings for Norway compare to those for the United States?
Table 11 presents comparative generational accounts for the two countries
according to our base-case interest- and growth-rate assumptions. The
accounts for the United States correspond to those presented in earlier work
(see Auerbach, Gokhale, and Kotlikoff [1993]), except that an interest rate of
6 percent was used previously. The Norwegian accounts are those given above
for the base case in tables 1 and 2, except that educational spending is
included in other government spending rather than treated as a transfer
payment. We treat educational spending in this manner for the sake of
comparison, because this significant component of government purchases has not
been allocated by age and sex for the United States. As can be seen by
comparing the accounts for Norway in table 11 to those in the center columns
of tables 1 and 2, including educational spending with other government
purchases of goods and services raises the accounts for future generations and

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

for those current generations young enough to have benefited from such
spending.
In addition to the overall accounts for each generation, table 11
presents breakdowns of payments and receipts similar to those given for Norway
in tables 7 and 8; but aggregated somewhat to permit a standard categorization
for the two countries. As table 11 indicates, Norway has significantly higher
levels of generational accounts for almost all current male generations.

Some

young female generations, however, bear slightly lower net-payment burdens
compared to current younger female generations in the United States. For a
given level of government purchases per capita, this may translate, via the
government budget constraint, into a much lower burden on future generations
in Norway. However, while the percentage increase in the burden on future
generations is somewhat lower in Norway, the absolute burden on future
Norwegians still exceeds that faced by future Americans. The reason for this
is that Norway not only is raising more revenue from its current citizens, but
is also spending more on government consumption. While the two countries have
similar values of GDP per capita, government purchases represent 26 percent of
Norway's GDP, compared to 19 percent for the United States (see table 3).

Achieving Generational Balance

- Three

Illustrative Policies

What changes in taxes and transfers would be required to restore the
generational accounts of newborn and future Norwegians to fiscal balance?

By

fiscal balance, we mean that the ratio of the net-payment burden on future
generations to that on newborns should be no higher than the rate of multifactor productivity growth. Table '12 shows the effects on the accounts of
current and future generations of three alternative ways of achieving fiscal
balance.

The first column shows that the average VAT rate would have to be

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

raised by 48 percent.

This would involve substantial increases in the burdens

on young and middle-aged generations: For example, 30-year-old males and
females would be required to pay more than $30,000 in additional VATS.

The

net-payment burden on future male generations would fall by about $144,000,
while for future female generations it would rise by $23,000.
As shown in column two of table 12, the effect of raising payroll (SST)
taxes by about 37 percent would be similar, except that current older generations would pay somewhat less, and middle-aged and younger male generations
somewhat more, than under the first policy. All current female generations
would, however, pay lower additional amounts under the second policy.

The net

gain to future male generations would be $143,000, while the loss to future
female generations would be about $9,000 - substantially lower than under the
first policy.
Alternatively, as column three in table 12 indicates, pension (PEN)
benefits could be reduced by about 52 percent to achieve fiscal balance.

In

this case, those under age 40 would lose less while older living generations
would lose significantly more in present value as compared to the first
policy. Under the third policy, the burdens on future male generations would
fall by $166,000, while those on future females would increase by about
$5,000.

VI. Summary and Conclusion
This paper uses generational accounting, a new tool for fiscal analysis
and planning, to study Norway's long-term fiscal position. The findings are
quite unsettling. Despite having one of the highest rates of taxation in the
OECD and a sizable amount of public wealth, Norway's fiscal policy appears to
be unsustainable. Unless adjustments are made and made soon, future genera-

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

tions of Norwegians are likely to face a much higher fiscal burden than that
now in place.
There are many different ways to restore generational balance to
Norwegian fiscal policy. One is to reduce government spending by roughly onefifth. Another is to set aside (not spend) about two-thirds of the country's
petroleum income.8 A third option is to limit any further growth in the
generosity of Norwegian old-age pensions. Finally, the government could raise
taxes. While Norway's leaders will ultimately have to decide how and when to
make the necessary adjustments, they can use generational accounting to ensure
that whatever increased fiscal burden they impose on current generations is
distributed fairly. They can also use it to check, on an ongoing basis, that
their largess to current Norwegians does not come at the price of higher
fiscal burdens on future citizens.

8

Steigum (1993) provides an analysis of such a policy.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

References
Auerbach, Alan J., Jagadeesh Gokhale, and Laurence J. Kotlikoff, "Generational
Accounts: A Meani~gfulAlternative to Deficit Accounting," in D. Bradford,
ed., Tax Policv and the Economv, vol. 5. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1991,
pp. 55-110.
,
, and
, "Generational Accounting: A New
Approach to Understanding the Effects of Fiscal Policy on Saving,"
Scandinavian Journal of Economics 94(2), June 1992a, pp. 303-18.
,
, and
, "Social Security and Medicaid Policy
from the Perspective of Generational Accounting," in J. Poterba, ed.,
Policv and the Economy, vol. 6. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, June-1992b, pp.
129-45.
,
, and
, "Generational Accounts and Lifetime
Tax Rates, 1900-1991," Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Review,
vol. 29, no. 1, 1993.

,
, and
, "Generational Accounting: A Meaningful
Way to Evaluate Fiscal Policy," Journal of Economic Persvectives,
forthcoming, 1994.
Franco, Daniele, Jagadeesh Gokhale, Luigi Guiso, Laurence J. Kotlikoff, and
Nicola Sartor, "Generational Accounting - The Case of Italy," Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Working Paper No. 9208, August 1992.
Gjersem, Carl E., "Aging Populations: Projections for Norway, 1990-2200,"
Working Paper 51/1993, Center for Research in Economics and Business Administration, Bergen, Norway, 1993.
Kotlikoff, Laurence J., Generational Accounting - Knowing Who Pays. and When,
for What We S~end.New York: The Free Press, 1992.

, "From Deficit Delusion to the Fiscal Balance Rule - Looking for an
Economically Meaningful Way to Assess Fiscal Policy," Journal of Economics,
Suppl. 7, 1993, pp. 17-41.
Long Term Program 1994-1997. St.meld. nr.4 (1992-93). Ministry of Finance,
February 1993.
Steigum, Erling, Jr., "Accounting for Long-run Effects of Fiscal Policy by
Means of Computable Overlapping Generations Models," in S. Honkapohja and M.
Ingberg, eds., Macroeconomic Modelling and Policg Imvlications. Amsterdam:
Elsevier, 1993.
Steigum, Erling, Jr., and Oystein Thogersen, "Petroleum Wealth, Debt Policy
and Intergenerational Welfare: The Case of Norway," Norwegian School of
Economics and Business Administration Discussion Paper 09/92, September
1992.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Table 1
Norway's

National Wealth Per Capita, 1992

Physical capital
Natural resources
Human capital
Net financial assets
National wealth
Assumptions: Exchange rate: 6.65 kroner per dollar
Real rate of return: 7 percent per year
Productivity growth: 1 percent per year
Source: Central Bureau of Statistics.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Table 2
Norwayrs Demographic Trans it ion

Population (millions)
Working age (percent)
Dependency ratio

4.25
58.8
.702

4.60
60.6
.650

4.66
57.8
.731

4.42
57.2
.749

Share of population
over age 65
over age 75

,163
.070

.I64
.068

.203
.lo6

.208
.lo3

Source: Gjersem (1993).

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Table 3
Comparative Fiscal Ratios in 1992
Japan Germany France

Norway

Italy

T~X~S/GDP~

46.9

40.7

30.6

43.7

43.6

Total Outlays/~~pb

55.1

51.3

25.7

45.7

48.5

Direct spending/~~pC 26.0

20.7

15.0

22.9

22.3

22.6

20.3

11.5

n.a.

Interest Payments/GDP

3.7

11.4

3.9

3.3

3.4

Deficit/GDP

2.8

9.5

-1; 8

2.8

3.9

-17.2

105.3

4.2

24.4

30.1

rans sf~ ~ S / G D P ~

Net Debt/GDP

24.8

a. Direct taxes, indirect taxes, and social insurance contributions.
b. Purchases on current account.
c. Government consumption plus investment.
d. Includes Social Security benefits, but excludes subsidies.
Source: OECD.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Table 4
Public Expenditures and Receipts, 1992

Receipts (percent of GDP)

t

Direct and indirect petroleum taxes
Other direct taxes
Social Security contributions
Other indirect taxes
Income from government wealth
Total receipts
Expenditures (percent of GDP)
Public consumption
Net investment in fixed capital
Transfers
- private households
- subsidies
- abroad
Interest
Increase in capital deposits in state
enterprises (net)
Total expenditures
Deficit
Source: Revised National Budget 1993 St.meld. nr.2 (1992-93), Ministry of
Finance (May 1993).

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Table 7
The Composition o f Male Generational Accounts (r=.04,

g=.0075)

Present Values of Receipts and Payments
(thousands o f do1 l a r s )
Receipts

Payments

Generation's
Net
Age i n 1992 Payment

VAT

62.4
65.8
69.0
71.8
71.1
69.1
64.0
58.7
53.7
47.8
41.8
35.0
28.6
22.2
16.8
12.3
9.1
6.8
5.0
3.7
Future
Generations

305.4

Percentage
Change

133.3

Source: Authors1 calculations.

EX1

EX2

SST

YTX

WTX

2.6
3.1
3.7
4.2
4.7
5-3
6.0
6.7
7.1
7.4
7.5
7.2
6.9
6.0
4.7
2.8
1.6
1.o
0.9
0.8

OLD

HOS

EDU

PEN

DIS

SIK

FAM

UNH

OTH

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Table 8
The Composition of Female Generational Accounts (r=.04, g=.0075)
Present Values of Receipts and Payments
(thousands of do1 lars)
Payments

Generationls
Net
Age i n 1992 Payment

VAT

62.9
66.4
69.4
72.5
72.0
71.0
66.6
61.9
57.5
52.1
46.3
39.8
33.4
26.6
20.7
15.2
10.9
7.8
5.3
3.4
Future
Generations

13.1

Source: Authors1 calculations.

Receipts

EX1

SST

YTX

WTX

15.7
16.7
17.6
18.7
18.7
17.8
15.9
14.6
14.0
13.1
11.5
9.4
7.5
5.5
3.3
1.9
1.1
0.8
0.6
0.3

43.7
52.3
61.1
70.6
76.8
78.6
74.1
68.3
61 -6
51.4
39.4
27.1
17.1
9.3
5.2
4.0
3.0
2.2
1.7
1.2

39.4
47.2
55.1
63.7
69.8
72.9
71 -4
69.0
65.1
57.0
46.8
35.5
25.8
17.6
11.5
8.0
5.9
4.2
2.7
1.6

1 .o
1.2
1.4
1.6
1.7
2.0
2.1
2.2
2.4
2.7
2.9
2.8
2.6
2.4
2.1
1.8
1.6
1.2
0.9
0.8

OLD

HOS

EDU

PEN

DIS

SIK

FAM

UNM

OTH

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Table 9
The Components of Male Generational Accounts (r=.06,

g=.015)

Average Annual Values of Receipts and Payments
Payments

Generations

Net

Age 0 i n 1992

Payment

Receipts

VAT

EX1

EX2

SST

YTX

UTX

OLD

HOS

EDU

PEN

DIS

SIK

FAM

UNM

OTH

VAT

EX1

EX2

SST

YTX

UTX

OLD

HOS

EDU

PEN

DIS

SIK

FAM

UNM

OTH

Year
1992
2002
2012
2022
2032
2042
2052
2062
2072
2082
Generations

Net

Age 10 i n 1992 Payment
Year
1992
2002
201 2
2022
2032
2042
2052
2062
2072

Table 9 (Continued)

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm
Generations
Age 20 i n 1992

Net
Payment

VAT

Generations

Net

VAT

Age 30 i n 1992

Payment

Age

Year

20

1992

30
40
50
60
70
80
90

2002
2012
2022
2032
2042
2052
2062

EX2

SST

YTX

UTX

OLD

HOS

EDU

PEN

DIS

SIK

FAM

UNM

SST

YTX

UTX

OLD

HOS

EDU

PEN

DIS

SIK

FAM

UNM

SST

YTX

UTX

OLD

HOS

EDU

PEN

DIS

SIK

FAM

UNM

OTH

Year

1992
2002
2012
2022
2032
2042
2052

12740.3
17496.1
20341.4
12929.9
-11056.6
-15662.8
-19604.9

2975.6
3033.3
3336.6
3137.1
2683.5
2261.5
2178.0

Generat ions

Net

VAT

Age 40 i n 1992

Payment

Age

Year

40
50
60
70
80
90

1992
2002
2012
2022
2032
2042

16236.4
18876.9
11968.8
-11459.5
-15734.1
-19392.4

2814.9
3096.3
2911.2
2490.3
2098.7
2021.2

OTH

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Table 9 (Continued)
Generations
Net
VAT
Age 50 i n 1992 Payment
Age
50
60
70
80
90

Year
1992
2002
2012
2022
2032

17517.8
11105.2
-10707.3
-14674.1
-18069.0

2873.4
2701.6
2311.0
1947.6
1875.6

Generations
Net
VAT
Age 60 i n 1992 Payment
Age
60
70
80
90

Year
1992
2002
2012
2022

10402.4
-8848.6
-12529.8
-15680.3

2507.1
2144.6
1807.4
1740.6

Generations
Net
VAT
Age 70 i n 1992 Payment
Age
70
80
90

Year
1992
2002
2012

-5662.1
-9078.3
-12002.0

1990.2
1677.2
1615.3

Generations
Net
VAT
Age 80 i n 1992 Payment
Age
80
90

Year
1992
2002

-7720.1
-10433.3

1556.5
1499.0

Generations
Net
VAT
Age 90 i n 1992 Payment
Age
90

Year
1992

-7368.5

1391.1

Source: Authorst calculations.

EX1

EX2

SST

821.2
699.3
573.0
269.5
203.5

481.5
624.4
436.1
418.3
839.7

EX1

EX2

SST

648.9
531.8
250.1
188.9

579.5
404.7
388.2
779.3

5870.3
1437.3
678.5
496.0

EX1

EX2

7756.7
6325.8
1548.8
731.2
534.4

SST

YTX

8874.6
7987.1
5382.3
3072.0
1425.0
YTX

7412.1
4994.8
2850.8
1322.4
YTX

WTX

332.8
501.8
713.2
480.2
337.0
WTX

465.7
661.9
445.6
312.7
WTX

OLD

HOS

-8.3
-188.2
-8.9 -340.8
-183.0 -615.8
-553.6 -919.5
-2116.4-1048.3
OLD

-8.3
-169.9
-513.8
-1964.0
OLD

HOS

EDU

PEN

DIS

SIK

FAM

UNM

OTH

EDU

PEN

DIS

SIK

FAM

UNM

OTH

EDU

PEN

DIS

SIK

FAM

UNM

OTH

-

-316.2
-571.4
-853.3
-972.8
HOS

I

W
CI
I

493.5
232.1
175.3

375.6
360.2
723.2

EX1

EX2

SST

YTX

WTX

215.4
162.6

334.3
671.1

584.3
427.1

2455.1
1138.8

EX1

EX2

SST

150.9

622.8

396.4

1333.8
629.7
460.2

4635.1
2645.5
1227.2

614.2
413.5
290.2

-157.6
-476.8
-1822.6

-530.3
-791.9
-902.8

OLD

HOS

383.8
269.3

-442.4
-1691.4

-734.9
-837.8

YTX

UTX

OLD

1056.8

249.9

-1569.6

HOS

-777.4

EDU

PEN

DIS

SIK

FAM

UNM

OTH

EDU

PEN

DIS

SIK

FAM

UNM

. OTH

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Table 10
The Components of Female Generational Accounts (r=.06,

g=.015)

Average Annual Values o f Receipts and Payments
Payments

Generat ions
Age 0 i n 1992

Net
Payment

Receipts

VAT

EX1

EX2

SST

YTX

WTX

OLD

HOS

EDU

PEN

DIS

SIK

FAM

UNM

OTH

Generations
Net
VAT
Age 10 i n 1992 Payment

EX1

EX2

SST

YTX

WTX

OLD

HOS

EDU

PEN

DIS

SIK

FAM

UNM

OTH

Year
1992
2002
2012
2022
2032
2042
2052
2062
2072
2082

Age
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90

Year
1992
2002
2012
2022
2032
2042
2052
2062
2072

-3673.5
-380.1
3931.4
6522.3
9580.0
2620.6
-17303.2
-19883.0
-21529.2

1397.1
2288.7
3455.2
3522.2
3874.4
3642 - 7
3116.0
2626.0
2529.0

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm
Table 10 (Continued)
Generations

Net

VAT

EX2

SST

YTX

WTX

OLD

HOS

EDU

PEN

DIS

SIK

FAM

UNM

OTH

SST

YTX

WTX

OLD

HOS

EDU

PEN

DIS

SIK

FAM

UNM

OTH

SST

YTX

WTX

OLD

HOS

EDU

PEN

DIS

SIK

FAM

UNM

OTH

Age 20 i n 1992 Payment
Year

1992
2002
2012
2022
2032
2042
2052
2062
Generations

Net

VAT

Age 30 i n 1992 Payment
Year

1992
2002
2012
2022
2032
2042
2052
Generat ions

3385.7
5616.9
8251.2
2284.5
-13788.4
-16010.0
-17427.7

2975.6
3033.3
3336.6
3137.1
2683.5
2261.5
2178.0

Net

VAT

Age 40 i n 1992 Payment
Age

Year

40
50
60
70
80
90

1992
2002
2012
2022
2032
2042

5212.5
7657.8
2140.5
-11973.7
-14035.4
-15351.1

2814.9
3096.3
2911.2
2490.3
2098.7
2021.2

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Generations
Net
VAT
Age 50 i n 1992 Payment
Age

EX2

SST

YTX

UTX

OLD

HOS

EDU

PEN

DIS

SIK

FAM

UNM

OTH

EX2

SST

YTX

UTX

OLD

HOS

EDU

PEN

DIS

SIK

FAM

UNM

OTH

EX2

SST

YTX

UTX

OLD

HOS

EDU

PEN

DIS

SIK

FAM

UNM

OTH

EX2

SST

YTX

UTX

OLD

HOS

EDU

PEN

DIS

SIK

FAM

UNM

OTH

EX2

SST

YTX

UTX

OLD

HOS

EDU

PEN

DIS

SIK

FAM

UNM

OTH

Year

50

1992

7110.0

2873.4

60
70
80
90

2002
2012
2022
2032

2028.0
-9437.6
-11350.9
-12571.8

2701.6
2311.0
1947.6
1875.6

Generations
Net
VAT
Age 60 i n 1992 Payment
Age Year
60
1992
70 2002
80 2012
90 2022

1937.6
-8200.6
-9976.2
-11109.2

2507.1
2144.6
1807.4
1740.6

Generations
Net
VAT
Age 70 i n 1992 Payment
Age
70
80
90

Table 10 (Continued)

Year
1992
2002
2012

-6052.3
-7700.0
-8751.4

1990.2
1677.2
1615.3

Generations
Net
VAT
Age 80 i n 1992 Payment
Age Year
80
1992
90 2002

-7917.8
-8893.5

1556.5
1499.0

Generat ions
Net
VAT
Age 90 i n 1992 Payment
Age Year
90
1992

-9293.2

1391.1
-

Source: Authors1 calculations.

-

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Table 11
The Composition o f Norwegian and U.S.

Generational Accounts (r=0.04, g=0.0075)

Present Values o f Receipts and Payments (thousands o f d o l l a r s )
U n i t e d States

Age
in

Net
Payment

Income
Taxes

1992

40
50
60
70
80
90
Future
Generations

40
50
60
70
80
90
Future
Generations
Percentage
Difference

Excise

59.2
76.0
91.1
73.6
31.2
-39.0
-117.9
-133.4
-92.3
-9.8
113.4

90.3

Source: Authorsr calculations.

Social

Health

Other

8 Other S e c u r i t y B e n e f i t s Welfare
Taxes

HALES
0
10
20
30

FEMALES
0
10
20
30

Payroll
Taxes

Norway

Benefits

Benefits

Net
Income
Payment Taxes

Payroll
Taxes

Excise

Social

Health

Other

8 Other S e c u r i t y Benefits Welfare
Taxes

Benefits

Benefits

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Table 12
The Changes i n Generational Accounts Required to
Equalize Burdens on Newborns and Future Generations
Present Values of Receipts and Payments (thousands of dollars)

Increasing VAT
by 48.0 percent

Increasing SST
by 36.8 percent

Reducing PEN
by 51.7 percent

Generation's
Age i n 1992
MALES:

Future
Generations

-144.3

-143.3

-165.6

23.0

8.8

4.6

FEMALES:

Future
Generations

Source: Authors1 calculations.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Appendix: Data Sources
Population
The projection of the Norwegian population through 2200 is taken from
Gjersem (1993). It is based on estimates to 2050 made by the Central Bureau
of Statistics and used in the Long Term Program 1994-1997. We assume a
constant fertility rate of 1.89 (observed in 1990) and a net inflow of
immigrants of 5,000 persons a year. Mortality rates are projected to decline
gradually through 2010, leading to an expected lifespan of 75 years for males
and 81.6 years for females.
Wealth
Our calculations of generational accounts are not based on the conventional definition of wealth in the national accounts, primarily because we
include natural resource wealth. Since Norway's petroleum reserves are not
marked to market, the petroleum wealth estimate is calculated as the present
value of expected net future cash flow, assuming a given time path of oil
prices and field-specific natural gas prices, investment outlays and production costs, as well as a projection of the future speed of resenre depletion.9
Given that future oil prices, production costs, reserves, and other factors
are highly uncertain, estimates of petroleum wealth are very sensitive to
assumptions. As illustrated in appendix table 1, they are also sensitive to
the interest rate used to discount future streams of government income from
oil and gas.
Existing data on public wealth are incomplete and generally are not based
on market values. Our estimates, reported in appendix table 2, must therefore
be viewed cautiously. Hydroelectric power wealth is the present value of the
government's net cash flow from its hydroelectric power plants. It is calculated as the sum of the replacement value of the fixed capital invested in
this sector and the present value of supernormal rents on that capital. The
Long Term Program 1994-1997 estimates the latter to be 90 billion kroner, or
$3,153 per capita, in 1992.
The estimated value of shares and equity capital has been provided by
the Ministry of Finance. The government owns about 20 percent of the total
stock of the Oslo Stock exchange. Another important asset is the public telephone company. Its value is estimated simply on the basis of a crude cash
flow projection. We have not attempted to estimate the values of other public
enterprises.
Transfers
Age and sex profiles for family allowance, disability pensions, old-age
pensions, and other Social Security benefits are constructed on the basis of
the 1990 Income and Wealth Survey, which contains information on 22,349 individuals (0.53 percent of the population), 17,676 of whom are over age 12.
Individual tax returns are linked to the data collected by the survey. The
various tax and transfer age-sex profiles were smoothed using a seven-period
moving average, with weights reflecting the number of observations in each age
group.
To account for the expected average growth in per capita old-age
pensions, we use estimates provided by the Central Bureau of Statistics'
9 The underlying cash flow data were provided by the Ministry of Finance
and are the same as those used in the Long Term Program 1994-1997.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

microsimulation model MOSART. Appendix figure 1 shows the projected value of
the average pensions of 70-year-old males and females relative to the minimum
pension G, The latter is the pension that each Norwegian receives starting in
the year he or she reaches age 67, assuming no past labor market participation. The Norwegian parliament chooses each year's value of G. While the
general intent is that G will rise over time to keep pace with inflation and
long-run productivity growth, during recent years the growth in G has fallen
short.
Age-sex profiles for sickness allowance are estimated on the basis of
individual 1989 data from the KIRUT data base. In 1992, sickness allowance
transfers totaled 2.15 percent of GDP. The estimate of the age profile of
unemployment benefits is based on recent cross-section unemployment data
(which were aggregated into age intervals of five years.) from the Labor Market
Directorate.
Education and Health Expenditures
In 1992, public expenditures on education and health amounted to 6.8 and
8.0 percent of GDP, respectively. For education, we have adopted coverage
rates and costs per student of various educational institutions based on
public education statistics. While the age and sex profiles for primary and
secondary education are very accurate, we had to resort to a subjective
estimate of the age and sex profiles for college education.
Due to incomplete and missing data, most public health expenditures are
not distributed by age and sex. Those expenditures that have been distributed
(partly on a subjective basis) are for old-age homes, old-age wards and dwellings, home nursing and assistance, and other home help. We also estimate an
age profile of expenditures on hospitals based on data from a single large
hospital in Bergen.
Indirect Taxes and Social Securitv Contributions
Our age-sex profile for VATS is estimated from the 1990 Survey of
Consumer Expenditures. This is a survey of 1,201 households containing 3,216
individuals. In distributing household consumption, we assumed that each
child under age 17 consumed 70 percent of what adults consume. The 1992 total
VAT receipts are adjusted upward to take into account the recent increase in
the VAT tax rate from 20 to 22 percent.
Various excise taxes and import duties on gasoline and cars are
aggregated into one single age profile based on the 1990 Survey of Consumer
Expenditures. Also, excises on tobacco, beer, and other alcoholic drinks are
combined into a single age profile based on the same survey.
Age and sex profiles for Social Security contributions are calculated
using the 1990 Income and Wealth Survey. Total 1992 Social Security contributions were reduced to take account of the reduction in the payroll tax rate,
which offset the 1993 increase in the VAT tax rate.
Income and Wealth Taxation
The 1990 Income and Wealth Survey permits a fairly good estimate of the
age-sex profiles of income and wealth taxes. The totals are, however, based
on preliminary data. Final tax data for 1992 will not be available until
September 1993. Another complication is that the 1992 tax reform makes it
difficult to extrapolate from 1991 tax data.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Appendix Table 1
Petroleum Wealth and Permanent Income
Based on Alternative Interest-Rate Assumptions
Interest rate (percent)

Petroleum
wealth ( $
per capita)
Permanent income ( $ per
capita)

26,813 30,199 34,367 39,890 46,171 54,680 65,808

1,877

1,811

1,718

1,584

1,385

1,094

658

Note: Calculations assume an exchange rate of 6.65 kroner per dollar.
Source: Ministry of Finance.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Appendix Table 2

Public wealth
Per c a p i t a

Percent of GDP

Petroleum wealth
Hydroelectric power wealth
Shares and e q u i t y c a p i t a l
Other f i n a n c i a l a s s e t s ( n e t )

$ 34,640
12,561
5,378
10,261

140.9
51.1
21.9
41.3

T o t a l p u b l i c wealth

$ 62,840

255.6

Note: The c a l c u l a t i o n s a r e based on a 4 percent discount r a t e and an exchange
r a t e of 6.65 kroner per d o l l a r .
Source: Ministry of Finance.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm