View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK - CLEVELAND

90005hLO
Working Paper 8610

ESTIMATING THE CONTRIBUTION OF URBAN PUBLIC
INFRASTRUCTURE TO REGIONAL GROWTH

By Randall W. Eberts

Randall W. Eberts is an assistant vice president
and economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland. The author gratefully acknowledges
the invaluable assistance of Douglas Dalenberg
and Chul Soo Park in constructing the public
capital stock series. The National Science
Foundation funded the estimation of the public
capital stock. Paul Bauer and Joe Stone offered
helpful comments and suggestions.
Working papers of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland are preliminary materials circulated to
stimulate discussion and critical comment. The
views stated herein are the author's and not
necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System.

December 1986

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

ESTIMATING THE CONTRIBUTION OF URBAN PUBLIC
INFRASTRUCTURE TO REGIONAL GROWTH

I.

Introduction

The question of whether or not public capital stock significantly
affects private sector output and productivity growth remains unanswered
and virtually untested.

Although this relationship is central to a num-

ber of issues of current interest, it has not been possible to estimate
directly the effect of public capital stock on economic activity.
The problem lies primarily with the lack of comprehensive estimates
of public infrastructure that are appropriate for performing time-series
and cross-sectional analysis.

To begin to fill this gap, we have esti-

mated components of public capital stock for 38 metropolitan areas from
1958 to 1981 using the perpetual inventory method.

This paper reports

the first attempt to use these series to estimate the effect of public
capital stock on regional manufacturing production.

Public capital stock

is entered as an input into a translog production function.

Estimates of

marginal productivities, elasticities, and returns to scale provide
information about the effect of public capital stock on output and about
the technical relationships between inputs.

11. Background

Current views of regional growth theory stress,the interdependent
nature of spatial investment decisions, spatial frictions on inter-

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

gional capital and labor flows, and the distinction between private
ctor capital and public sector capital.

Local public capital stock can

fect economic activity through various channels.

It can indirectly

fect economic activity by influencing the location decisions of
useholds and firms.

The addition of new firms and households into a

gion may, in turn, increase the region's agglomeration economies, which
ads to even greater growth potential.

It can directly influence output

d productivity by entering a firm's production process as an unpaid
ctor.
Most empirical studies of the effect of public infrastructure on ecomic development have estimated its indirect effects by relating various
asures of public capital to measures of regional economic development.

-

-.

frastructure on regional economic growth for the U.S.

He hypothesizes

at the growth of regional economic activity is determined primarily by
e growth of public infrastructure and technical progress in the
gion.

Interregional flows of labor and private capital respond to re-

onal differences in social capital and technical progress as well as
ice differentials. He examines the growth characteristics of the nine

S. census regions from 1947 to 1963 and concludes that more-developed
gions are growing because of the growth of public infrastructure, while
ss-developed regions are growing primarily because of the growth of
chnology.
Hansen (1965) focuses on the potential effectiveness of public infraructure across three broad categories of regions:
diate, and lagging.

-

.a-

7
-

ra (1975) provides the most comprehensive test of the effect of public

congested, inter-

Congested regions are characterized by a very high

ncentration of population, industrial and commercial activities, and

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

public infrastructure.

Any marginal social benefits that might accrue

from further investment would be outweighed by the marginal social costs
of pollution and congestion due to increased economic activity in the
area.

Intermediate regions are characterized by an environment

conducive to further activity--an abundance of well-trained labor, cheap
power, and raw materials.

In this area, increased economic activity

resulting from infrastructure investment would lead to marginal social
benefits exceeding marginal social costs.

Lagging regions are charac-

terized by a low standard of living due to small-scale agriculture or
stagnant or declining industry. The economic situation offers little
attraction to firms, and public infrastructure investment would have
little impact.

A direct test of Hansen's hypotheses is provided by Looney and
Frederiksen (1981).

Looking at economic development in Mexico, their

findings support Hansen's intuition:

economic overhead capital has a

significant effect on gross domestic product ( G D P ) for intermediate
regions, but not for lagging regions; social overhead capital exhibits
the opposite effect, as Hansen predicted.
One way in which local public capital stock affects regional growth
is through its effect on agglomeration economies.

Public infrastructure

affects agglomeration primarily through the influence of the scale and
spatial arrangement of public investment on firm and household location
decisions.

While empirical evidence of the direct link between measures

of agglomeration and economic growth is weak, it provides some support
for this argument.
Empirical evidence of agglomeration effects takes two approaches.
One approach interprets estimates of returns-to-scale as evidence of

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

gglomeration economies (Shef er [I9731 and Carlino [19791 )

.

This view is

msistent with the Kaldor hypothesis that economies of scale in the
snufacturing sector is the source of cumulative growth of regions
Zaldor [1970]).

A second approach treats agglomeration economies as

?crating through the efficiency parameter of the production function
4berg [I9731 ; Sveikauskas [I9751; Segal [I9761 ; Moomaw [I9821 ).

These

rudies assume that agglomeration economies are independent of returns to
-ale. Under this approach, Segal indirectly considers the contribution
i the public capital stock of Standard Metropolitan Statistical Areas

SMSAs) to productivity differentials between SMSAs during the mid360s.

He attributes his estimate of an 8 percent productivity

ifferential in favor of the largest metropolitan areas to economies in
--.
:ansport and communication. Unfortunately, Segal combines ~rivateand
iblic capital together within a single measure of SMSA capital stock.
One critical step in the argument linking public infrastructure to
:glomeration economies is its effect on location decisions.
:udies have explored this relationship.

Only a few

For example, Helms (1985) shows

lat government expenditures on highways, local schools, and higher edultion positively and significantly affect state personal income growth.
I

the other hand, Herzog, Schlottmann, and Johnson (1986) find that

.gh-technology workers, presumably a highly mobile labor group, exhibit
.ttle sensitivity to public infrastructure-type amenities and services.
Eberts (1985) explores the relationship between public infrastructure
id firm location in a somewhat different way by considering the causal

tlationship between public and private investment.

His premise, follow-

tg the cumulative model of regional growth, is that the timing of
lvestment indicates the role of public investment in promoting local

--

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

economic development.

If public investment precedes private investment,

then it would appear that local areas actively use public outlays as an
instrument to direct local development.

On the other hand, if the

sequence of events occurs in the opposite direction, it would appear that
local officials merely respond to private investment decisions.

Using

public outlay and manufacturing investment data from 1904 to 1978 for 40
cities, Eberts finds a significant causal relationship between public
outlays and private investment in 33 of the 40 cases.
causation goes either way.

The direction of

Private investment is more likely to influ-

ence public outlays in cities located in the South and in cities that
have experienced above-average growth after 1950.

Public outlays are

more likely to influence private investment in cities that experienced
much of their growth before 1950.
Looney and Frederiksen, in their study of Mexico, support Eberts'
findings for older U.S. cities--that public investment appears to be the
initiating factor in the development process rather than the passive or
accommodating factor.
These results raise an interesting question:

Is the growth assoc-

iated with public infrastructure a result of an overall increase in
firm-level productivity or a result of an increase in the region's
C

attractiveness to labor and capital? Hulten and Schwab's (1984) research
on regional productivity differentials provides some insight into this
distinction. They test the hypothesis, that the economic decline of the
Snowbelt was due to differences in economic efficiency relative to the
Sunbelt, by calculating regional differences in total factor productivity.

They find little evidence to support this hypothesis-

Instead,

they find that these interregional differences are largely a result of

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

fferences in the growth of capital and labor input.

Thus, the implica-

on from these findings is that regional differences in the quality and
antity of public infrastructure may have a greater effect on the
gration decisions of factors than on the productivity differentials.
These studies raise a host of issues that can be addressed using the
blic capital stock estimates.

I propose to explore a simple question

at is basic to much of this discussion:

what happens when public

pital stock is entered as an input into the production function?

111. Public Capital Stock as a Production Input

Following Meade's (1952) classification of public inputs, public
--

-

pital stock is treated as a n unpaid factor of production that con-tribi
es independently to the firm's output.

Since firms, by definition, do

t pay directly for the public input, they initially earn profits or
nts according to the value of the marginal product of the public
put.

Thus, firms in metropolitan areas with above-average investments

public infrastructure may be more productive than firms in other
eas.

This advantage explains why firms in high-wage cities may be able

compete successfully with firms in low-wage cities.

Also, it explains

y capital may move from low-wage to high-wage areas.

The use of public capital as an input introduces at least three comications related to the efficiency conditions:

(1) there are no formal

rket prices for public inputs, (2) an individual firm has little con31 over the quantity of public capital that is in place, since public
pital is determined collectively, and (3) public capital stock is used
others who are not directly involved in manufacturing.

--

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

The consequences of these public capital stock characteristics for
estimating a production function are reduced somewhat by aggregating
firm-level data to the SMSA-level.

At this level, the allocation of

public infrastructure becomes more endogenous to the decision-making
process.

As proposed by Negishi (1973) and Pestieau (1976), local gov-

ernments may invest in public capital with the goal of maximizing the
profits of firms, since individual taxpayers may view the presence of
firms as beneficial to the community.

In addition, firms may pursue a

"Tiebout-like" process of seeking to locate within jurisdictions in which
the level of public investment best matches their preferences. Deno and
Eberts (1986) construct and estimate a model of the interaction between
private and public investment decisions, which takes into account voters'
perceptions of the effect of public investment on local economic activity
and thus their expected income levels.

Although such an interaction of

investment decisions underlies the approach taken in this present paper,

I emphasize the technical relationships instead of the resource allocation issues.
Another issue is how to apportion the use of public capital stock
between manufacturing production activity and other activities.

Various

sharing measures could be used such as the percentage of the metropolitan
population employed in manufacturing or the percentage of local personal
income in manufacturing.

These measures introduce their own problems,

however, so I prefer to enter the entire estimate of the metropolitan
public capital stock as an input into the production function.
Another approach is to treat public infrastructure as a quasi-fixed
input in a cost function.

In the short-run, firms are assumed to respond

to input prices of the variable inputs and the existing technology sub-

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

tct to a given level of output and the existing levels of fixed
ictors.

This method takes into account the possibility that public

lvestment is not allocated at the lsvel preferred by the firm.

An

iteresting extension of this approach is made by Dalenberg (1986), who
icorporates into the cost function an adjustment process for public
ivestment based on local public sector resource allocation.

IV.

Capital Stock Estimates

Two unique data sets make possible the estimation of the effect of
~bliccapital stock on SMSA manufacturing: one is a public capital:ock series for each metropolitan area; the other is a private manufac-

ring capital-stock series-for each SMSA. The perpetual inventory
xhnique is used to value both capital stocks.

This approach is used by

le Bureau of Economic Analysis for national-level estimates of both
-ivate and government assets and in many national and regional produc.vity studies.

The measure of capital under this method is the sum of

ie value of past capital purchases adjusted for depreciation and
.scard.
Two assumptions are made in using this scheme.

First, the purchase

-ice of a unit of capital, which is used to weight each unit of capital,

:fleets the discounted value of its present and future marginal prod:ts. The first assumption is met if perfectly competitive capital
lrkets exist.

One criticism of the perpetual inventory approach for

lblic capital stock is that government is not subject to competitive
lrket constraints and thus the price does not reflect the marginal
-0ductivityof public capital.

As discussed earlier, this may be less

--

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

of a problem for local governments, since they compete for households and
firms.

Second, a constant proportion of investment in each period is

used to replace old capital (depreciation).

Fulfillment of the second

assumption requires accurate estimates of the asset's average service
life, discard rate, and depreciation function.
To derive the stock measures, specific retirement and replacement or
depreciation functions are applied to the accumulated gross investment
series.

The investment series must extend back far enough in time in

order to account for all prior investment that has contributed to the
current capital stock.

Given the average life and retirement and depre-

ciation assumptions used to construct the series, public outlays going
back to 1904 were required for each city.

The data were obtained from

City Finances and from other census publications for the 38 cities.
Public outlays for the SMSAs associated with these cities were available
from 1964 to present.

Per capita estimates of public outlays within a

central city and outside the central city within an SMSA are used to
construct SMSA-level public outlay estimates for years prior to 1964.
SMSA-level estimates are constructed according to the 1977 boundary
definitions.
Public capital outlay is defined by the Census Bureau as direct
expenditure for either contract or force account construction of buildings, roads, and other improvements, and for purchases of land and
existing structures.

Included in total outlays are expenditures on: (a)

sanitary and storm sewers and sewage disposal facilities, (b) roadways,
sidewalks, and all structures and improvements necessary for their use,
such as toll highways, bridges, and tunnels, (c) public hospitals, and
(d) public service enterprises, which includes airports and ports.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

ublic-type services provided privately are not included.

Estimates of

verage asset lives, depreciation, and discard functions are obtained
rom the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) and other sources.

The series

s converted to constant 1967 dollars by using the Engineering
ews-Record indexes for construction.

Eberts, Dalenberg, and Park (1986)

escribe the construction of the public capital stock estimates in
reater detail.
Private manufacturing capital stock estimates are derived for the
ame set of SMSAs using investment data from the Census of Manufactures
nd the Annual Survey of Manufactures.

After adjusting the investment

eries by national-level depreciation rates and discard patterns for each
wo-digit industry, a capital-stock series is obtained for the period
-- - 958 to c978. Although the depreciation and discard rates do not ieflect
ocal rates within industries, the rates do vary across SMSAs due to
nterregional differences in industrial composition.

Capital stock is

djusted for capacity utilization using Federal Reserve Board national
stimates.

SMSA boundary definitions and price indexes are the same as

hose used for public capital stock estimates.
Estimates of the total amount of public and private capital stock for
le 38 SMSAs between 1958 and 1978 are shown in figure 1.

Total public

3pital stock grew by 33 percent between 1958 and 1978, while private
3pital stock increased 55 percent.

The ratio of public capital stock to

rivate stock averaged 1.52 but declined from 1.60 in the earlier years
3

1.36 in the later years.

Public capital stock is also broken down

to three major categories (not shown):

~pply,and water treatment.

roads and highways, water

Roads and highways comprised 9 percent of

~ t a lcapital stock on average, water accounted for 14 percent, and water

.- -

-

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

treatment another 11 percent.

These proportions remained relatively con-

stant between 1959 and 1978 with highways increasing slightly, especially
in the earlier years, primarily at the expense of water supply.

Highways

grew the fastest at 50 percent while water treatment grew at 40 percent
and water supply at 19 percent.
Public capital stock growth rates have diminished over time.

A con-

venient way to look at the variation in growth rates over time is to
divide the annual series into intervals that reflect as closely as possible the trough-to-trough periods of the national business cycle.
such periods occur between 1958 and 1978:
1975-78, as shown in table 1.

Four

1958-61, 1961-70, 1970-75, and

In the first two periods, the average

annual growth rate (calculated using arithmetic means) of total public
capital stock was around 1.8 percent.

In the two more recent periods,

the growth rate has steadily fallen to 1.44 percent and 1.03 percent.
This recent decline in the growth rate of public capital stock is in
sharp contrast to the recent increase in the growth rates of output and
private capital stock.

During the periods of 1970-75 and 1975-78, when

the growth rate of public capital stock fell, manufacturing output rose
by a dramatic 6.7 percent and private capital stock increased 7.5 percent.

The only major component of public capital stock that exhibited an

accelerated growth rate over this period was water treatment facilities.
Another interesting feature of the annual average growth rate series
of public capital stock is that, unlike private capital stock, it does
not follow the national business cycle.

For instance, as one might

expect, the annual average growth rate of private capital stock is at the
lowest point in its cycle during the year the business cycle trough
occurs.

Public capital stock, on the other hand, is at or close to its

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

ighest point during some of these years.

A casual look at the growth

ate series in figure 2 fails to suggest any obvious lagged relationships
hat may bring the private and public capital series in line.

The ob-

ious explanation is that public investment is determined by factors that
re not tied directly to business cycle activities.
Table 2 shows the level of public and private capital stock for each
MSA for 1978.
tock.

The SMSAs are ordered by the size of the public capital

Notice the difference in rankings of SMSAs by public capital

tock, private capital stock, population, and land area.

For example,

altimore is ranked eighth according to public capital stock, but is
anked thirteenth according to private capital stock and eleventh accordng to population. Houston, on the other hand, is ranked third according
- -- o private manu£acturing capital stock, but thirteenth according fo pubic capital stock and eighth according to population.

Per capita public

nd manufacturing capital stock estimates show an even larger disparity
n the rankings of SMSAs by these two stocks.

New York, for example,

anks first in public capital stock per capita, while it ranks thirtyifth in manufacturing capital stock per capita.
he exact opposite.

Houston's rankings are

Obviously, the public capital stock estimates are

ot simply proxies for the area's population size.
Although the age of public capital stock is not considered in the
stimation of the production function, it is interesting to examine the
ankings of the SMSAs by percentage of public capital stock put in place
ithin the last 10 years.
d:

The rankings of SMSAs are generally as expect-

the so-called Sunbelt areas such as Atlanta, Dallas, and Houston

ave the largest percentage of recently constructed public capital stock,
hile the older Snowbelt areas like Cleveland, Newark, and Jersey City

.=-

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

have the least amount of newly created public capital stock.
few surprises, however.

There are a

Two Sunbelt SMSAs, Los Angeles and San Fran-

cisco, are far down the list of metropolitan areas with newly created
public capital stock.

Two Snowbelt SMSAs, Grand Rapids and Minneapolis,

for example, rank near the top of SMSAs with public capital put in place
in the last 10 years.

V.

Production Function Estimation

To explore the effect of public capital stock on regional manufacturing output and the technical relationships between public capital and the
other inputs, a production function is specified and estimated using data
from the 38 SMSAs between 1958 and 1978.

Consider a production function

aggregated to the SMSA-level in which

where Q is the output of the manufacturing sector of each SMSA; Ky G and
H are private capital stock, labor, and public capital stock in the SMSA;
and T is technical change.

By employing Hicks' theorem of aggregation,

returns to scale for a city as a whole is the weighted average of the
returns of individual firms, corrected for the positive and negative
externalities they confer on one another (Tolley and Smith, 1979).

The

weights are the shares of total income generated by each firm, assuming
relative prices of goods produced in different SMSAs are constant across

.

SMSAs

The two variables not yet discussed are price-deflated value added

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

Q) and worker hours (H) in manufacturing. Value added deflated by the
roducer price index is used as a measure of manufacturing output.

How-

very value added reported in Census of Manufactures includes the value
f purchased services.

Since the capital and labor estimates do not

eflect the inputs used to produce these services, including services in
he output measure would lead to overestimation of the marginal physical
roducts of the three inputs.

Value added is thus adjusted to correct

or purchased services by using the ratio of GDP from NIPA to census
alue added for U.S. manufacturing as described in Beeson (1986).
Hours worked by production and nonproduction workers obtained from
he Census of Manufactures are used as a measure of labor.

A variant of the translog specification of a VES production function
-.

s chosen to estimate the

relationships.

Thus, equatioa (1)

s respecif ied as:

n

adopting equation ( 2 ) , it is assumed that technical change is Hicks

zutral and that the production technologies are similar across cities.
ne production function in equation (2) is estimated with and without

~ b l i ccapital stock as an input using the Park's method of correcting
3r

disturbances that are both serially and contemporaneously correlated

Qnenta [I9711).
Three separate models were estimated. The first model is a translog
lnction without public capital stock as an input.

The second model

z-

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

includes capital stock estimates for roads and highways and water treatment and supply as a way to control for differences in composition of
public capital stock across metropolitan areas.

The third model includes

a measure of the total public capital stock in the SMSA, as defined
earlier.

Estimates of the coefficients are displayed in table 3, and

estimates of marginal elasticities, marginal physical products, and economies of scale are reported in table 4.
Each input has a positive and statistically significant direct effect
on manufacturing output.

The estimates of the marginal elasticities of

labor and private capital are very similar across the three models.

When

public capital stock is entered as either measure, the marginal elasticity of labor falls slightly, while the marginal elasticity of private
capital remains the same.

The fall in the marginal elasticity of labor

is offset by an increase in the magnitude of the marginal elasticity of
public capital so that both models exhibit constant returns to scale.
Since each measure of public capital stock yields virtually identical
results, the remaining discussion makes no distinction between the two
models.
The magnitude of the marginal elasticity of public capital is quite
small compared with estimates of the marginal elasticities of the other
two inputs.

This low estimate may be related to the fact that public

capital stock is shared not only by manufacturing firms within an SMSA,
but also by firms in other sectors and by households.

One can see the

potential effect of this public good aspect on the marginal physical
product of public capital by conducting the following conceptual experiment.

Suppose that the per unit prices of public and private capital

stock are equal, presumably due to perfect capital markets.

In this

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

ase, one would expect the marginal physical product of the two capital
tocks to be equal.

Yet, the estimate of the marginal physical product

f private capital is 5 to 10 times greater than that of public capital,
epending upon the measure of public capital stock.

If one were to

ttribute this difference to the fact that we are observing the use of
ublic capital by manufacturers much further down the marginal product
chedule than is the actual case, then we would conclude that only oneeventh or 14 percent (taking the midpoint of the two estimates) of the
otal public capital stock is used on average by the manufacturing secor.

In fact, a crude sharing measure, the ratio of manufacturing

mployment to metropolitan population, comes very close to this percentge at 11 percent. Using the size of the labor force instead of popu- --ation would increase this percentage to something closer to 14 pgrcent.
Another way to interpret these results is to consider public capital
tock to be a pure public good.

Assuming that local governments compete

or households and firms and thus allocate resources efficiently, the
alue of the marginal product of public capital stock reveals the manuacturing sector's valuation of the total stock of public investment in
lace in the SMSA.

Since the production function exhibits constant

eturns to scale, the output elasticity of public capital equals the
hare of total revenue paid to the public sector for the use of public
spital.

It is not unreasonable for a typical firm to pay around four

srcent of its total income to state and local taxes, which is the estiate of the output elasticity of public capital.
Estimates of the marginal productivities of each of the three inputs
2pend upon the coefficients of the interaction terms in the production
mction and the input and output levels.

Consequently, as these levels

--

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

change over time, marginal products also change.

For example, the mar-

ginal product of labor continually increases over time as labor declines
relative to private and public output.

The marginal product of capital

increases throughout the 1960s and then remains relatively constant.

The

marginal product of public capital continually falls throughout the
20-year period as public and private capital increase.

This decline

results partly from the negative second partial derivative of public and
private capital. Thus, allowing output to vary but fixing labor, an
increase in public capital is associated with a decrease in private capital productivity. In this respect, the levels of public and private
capital could be considered to move in the same direction.
Technological relationships between inputs can also be described as
substitutes or complements.

The definition of complements and substi-

tutes is based upon the input demand relationship, which assumes that
costs vary but that output is held constant. A pair of inputs are
complements if the cross-price effect is negative and substitutes if the
cross-price effect is positive.

It can be shown that

where C j i is the co-factor of the element in row j and column i of the
bordered Hessian, which is derived from the cost niinimization problem.
is the determinant.

Therefore, the relationship between inputs can be

derived from technical relationships without estimating input prices.
Since the determinant is negative, inputs are complements if the cofactor is negative and substitutes if the co-factor is positive.

D

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

Calculation of the co-factors based on estimated coefficients indites that public and private capital are substitutes, labor and private
pital are substitutes, while public capital and labor are complements.
e finding that public capital and labor are complements is consistent
th Deno and Eberts' (1986) study, which estimated input demand
uations for labor and private investment.

One interpretation of this

lationship is that public capital stock provides a base for the future
pansion of manufacturing employment.

VI.

Conclusion

The production function estimates yield three basic results.

First,

-

blic caFital-stock makes

positive and significant contribution to

nufacturing output in the sample of 38 SMSAs.

Second, its contribu-

3n, unadjusted for the public good characteristics of public capital,
much less than that of private capital and labor.

Third, public

pital and labor are complementary inputs, whereas private capital and
slic capital, and private capital and labor, are substitutes.
As mentioned at the beginning of the paper, public capital stock is
?ortant to issues related to regional economic growth.

Public infra-

ructure is considered to be an important element of agglomeration
momies.

Following previous work using population as a proxy for

glomeration, one would expect public capital stock to yield increasing
turns to scale, which is not the case here.
?

However, the results here

not directly comparable to the results of other studies on agglomera-

In.

In this paper, public capital is entered as an input; in the other

?ers, Hicks-neutral technical change is regressed against population.

.-

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

Therefore, the results are merely suggestive of future research.
Previous work suggests that, in many respects, public capital stock
may be considered the foundation of regional economic development.

The

finding that public capital and manufacturing employment are complementary inputs into the regional production function indicates that public
capital stock is necessary for future expansion in the manufacturing
sector.

However, the overall effect of public capital investment on

manufacturing output is relatively small.

Previous research suggests

that specific types of public infrastructure may have more noticeable
effects on the output of specific sectors in regions with differing characteristics.

Future work should look at more disaggregated numbers for

manufacturing and for public capital stock and take into account regional
differences.
Finally, Hulten and Schwab suggest that regional growth differences
are due not to productivity growth differentials, but to input growth
differentials.

Although we do not address this question directly, our

results, by showing a positive and significant relationship between
public capital stock and manufacturing output, indicate that regional
growth differences are influenced by the growth rate of a third input,
public capital stock.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

References
,erg, Y. "Regional Productivity Differences in Swedish Manufacturing,"
Regional and Urban Economics, vol. 3, no. 2 (1973), pp. 131-56.
?eson, Patricia E. "Productivity Growth and the Decline of Manufacturing
in Large Metropolitan Areas: 1959-1978," Working Paper 8607,
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, July 1986.
irlino, Gerald A. "Increasing Returns to Scale in Metropolitan
Manufacturing," Journal of Regional Science vol. 19, no. 3
(August 1979), pp. 363-74.
ilenberg, Douglas. "A Dynamic Factor Demand Model for Public
Infrastructure," Dissertation Proposal, University of Oregon,
Department of Economics, 1986.
:no, Kevin, and Randall W. Eberts. "The Impact of Public Investment on
Net Private Investment and Labor Demand: A Dynamic Analysis,"
Mimeo, 1986.
Ierts, Randall W. "The Role of Public Investment in Regional Economic
Development," Presented at the Association for Public Policy
~nal~sis-ahd
~ana~ement,
Washington, D.C., October 15, 1985.Ierts, Randall W., Douglas Dalenberg, and Chul Soo Park. "Public
Infrastructure Data Development for NSF," Mimeo, University of
Oregon, 1986.
msen, Niles M. "Unbalanced Growth and Regional Development," Western
Economic Journal, vol. 4 (Fall 1965), pp. 3-14.
:lms, L. Jay. "The Effect of State and Local Taxes on Economic Growth:
A Time Series-Cross Section Approach," Review of Economics and
Statistics, vol. 67, no. 4 (November 1985), pp. 574-582.
?rzog, Henry W., Alan M. Schlottmann, and Donald L. Johnson.
"High-Technology Jobs and Worker Mobility," Journal of Regional
Science, vol. 26, no. 3 (August 1986), pp. 445-60.
~lten,Charles R., and Robert M. Schwab. "Regional Productivity Growth
in U.S. Manufacturing: 1951-78," American Economic Review, vol. 74,
no. 1 (March 1984), pp. 152-62.
~ldor,Nicholas. "The Case for Regional Policies," Scottish Journal of
Political Economy, vol. 17, no. 3 (November 19701, pp. 337-48.
lenta, Jan.

Elements of Econometrics. New York: Macmillan, 1971.

tven, Charles, John Legler, and Perry Shapiro. An Analytical Framework
for Regional Development Policy. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press, 1970.

-

i

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

Looney, Robert, and Peter Frederiksen. "The Regional Impact of
Infrastructure Investment in Mexico," Regional Studies , vol. 15, no.
4 (1981), pp. 285-96.
Meade, J. E. "External Economies and Diseconomies in a Competitive
Situation," Economic Journal, vol. 62 (March 19521, pp. 54-67.
Mera, Keoichi. Income Distribution and Regional Development.
Japan: University of Tokyo Press, 1975.

Tokyo,

Moomaw, Ronald. "Productive Efficiency and Region," Southern Economic
Journal, vol. 48, no. 2 (October 19811, pp. 344-57.
Negishi, Takashi. "The Excess of Public Expenditures on Industries,"
Journal of Public Economics, vol. 2, no. 3 (July 1973), pp. 231-40.
Pestieau, Pierre. "Public Intermediate Goods and Majority Voting," Public
Finance, vol. 31, no. 2 (1976), pp. 209-17.
Segal, David. "Are There Returns to Scale in City Size?" The Review of
Economics and Statistics, vol. 58, no. 3 (August 1976)- pp. 339-50.
Shefer, Daniel. "Localization Economies in SMSA1s: A Production Function
Analysis," Journal of Regional Science, vol. 13, no. 1 (April 19731,
pp. 55-64.
Sveikauskas, Leo A. "The Productivity of Cities," Quarterly Journal of
Economics, vol. 89, no. 3 (August 1975), pp. 393-413.
Tolley, George S., and B. Smith. "Scale Economies, Externalities, and
City Size," in Tolley, Graves, and Gardner, eds., Urban Growth Policy
in a Market Economy. New York: Academic Press, 1979, pp. 37-49.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

Table 1: Average Annual Growth Rates of Manufacturing Output
Labor, Private Capital, and Public Capital for the 39 SMSAs
sriable
utput

1958-61

1961-70

1970-75

1975-78

2.62

4.32

1.08

6.70

.64

1.62

-1.88

3.06

rivate Capital Stock

1.34

3.01

.77

7.35

3tal Public Capital
Stock

1.80

1.81

1.44

1.04

sbor

2ad and Highways
2ste Treatment
lter System

Ite:

Time periods correspond to the trough-to-trough intervals of the
national business cycle.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

Table 2: Rankings of SMSA's by Size of Public Capital Stock, Private
Capital Stock, Population, Area, and Age of Public Capital Stock
Ranking of SMSA by:
SMSA
New York
Los Angeles
Chicago
Detroit
San Francisco
Philadelphia
Pittsburgh
Baltimore
Minneapolis
Cleveland
Seattle
Dallas
Houston
Milwaukee
Atlanta
St. Louis
Newark
Buffa10
Cincinnati
Kansas City
San Diego
Memphis
Denver
New Orleans
Portland
Rochester
Indianapolis
Columbus
Louisville
Dayton
Birmingham
Akron
Jersey City
Richmond
Grand Rapids
Youngstown
Note:

Public
Capital
1

Private
Capital
5

Population
1

Area
32
9
11
10
19
13
17
22
22
28

7
1
2
29
65
3
34
27
23
15
8
21
4
25
12
18
16
20
31
26
14
35
36
24
30
33

Per Capita
Public Private Age
1
35
32
7
24
13
13
9
4
2
29
18
21
11
7
10
22
10
22
8
6
5
26
33
32
35
1
6
14
24
33
32
20
22
9
3
3
17
19
15
23
36
36
4
25
26
30
19
34
23
31
14
5
29
15
30
28
20
17
25
16
12
34
21
8
16
10
27
18
31
11
28
2

Erie, Canton, and Reading were not included in these rankings, although
they were included in the rest of the analysis. Age of the public
capital stock is measured as the percentage of public capital put in
place during the last 10 years. Definitions of the other variables are
described in the text.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

Table 3:

Production Function Estimates with and without
Public Capital Stock
Model A

Variable

Model B

Model C

tercept

(hours )

(hours )*
Ln(prvcap )

(prvcap )*
Ln( pubcap )

-.077
(5.31)
-- - -.

-.020
(2.82)

-.046
(11.58)

-.051
(3.01)
-.142
(14.89)

-

(hours )*
Ln ( pubcap )
(hours )

te:

Model A does not contain public capital stock; Model B
contains public capital stock measured as water treatment,
water supply, and highways and roads; Model C contains
public capital stock measured as total public capital stock
defined in the text. Park's method of correcting for autocorrelation and heteroskedasticity is used. T-statistics are
in parentheses. The Park's procedure in SAS does not report
an R-square.

=-

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

Table 4: Estimates of Marginal Elasticities, Marginal Physical Products,
and Returns to Scale
Characteristic

Model A

Model B

Model C

Values of:
Marginal Elasticity of:
Labor
Private Capital

.22

Public Capital

-32

.31

.03

-04

Returns to Scale

1-01

1.01

1.00

Marginal Physical Product of:
Labor

5.08

4.21

4.27

.23

.32

.30

-07

.03

+

+

-

-

Private Capital
Public Capital
Signs of:
Second Partial Derivative between:
Private and public capital
Private capital and labor

+

Private capital and
private capital
Public capital and labor
Public capital and
public capital
Labor and labor
Co-factor between:
Private and public capital
Private capital and labor
Public capital and labor
Note:

+

Elasticities and marginal products are calculated from
estimates displayed in table 3.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy