View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Working Paper 9119
ESTIMATING A FIRM'S AGE-PRODUCTIVITY PROFILE
USING THE PRESENT VALUE OF WORKERS' EARNINGS
by Laurence J. Kotlikoff and Jagadeesh Gokhale

Laurence J. Kotlikoff is a professor of
economics at Boston University and an associate
of the National Bureau of Economic Research.
Jagadeesh Gokhale is an economist at the
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. The authors
are grateful to the Hoover Institution and to
the National Institute of Aging, grant no.
lPOlAG05842-01, for research support. They
thank Jinyong Cai, Lawrence Katz, Kevin Lang,
Edward Lazear, Chris Ruhm, and Lawrence Summers
for helpful comments. Jinyong Cai provided
excellent research assistance.
Working papers of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland are preliminary materials circulated
to stimulate discussion and critical comment.
The views stated herein are those of the authors
and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System.

December 1991

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Abstract

In hiring new workers, risk-neutral employers equate the present expected
value of each worker's compensation to the present expected value of h i s h e r
productivity, Data detailing how present expected compensation varies with
the age of hire embed, therefore, information about how productivity varies
with age. This paper infers age-productivity profiles using data on the
present expected value of earnings of new hires of a Fortune 1000 firm. For
each of the five occupation/sex groups considered, productivity falls with
age, with productivity exceeding earnings for young workers and vice versa for
older workers.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Introduction
Understanding how productivity varies with workers* age is-important for
a variety of reasons. A decline in productivity with age implies that aging
societies must increasingly depend on the labor supply of the young and
middle-aged.

It also means that policies designed to keep the elderly in the

work force, while potentially good for the elderly, may decrease overall
productivity. A third implication is that, absent government intervention,
employers may not be willing to hire the elderly for the same compensation as
they provide to younger workers.
Labor economists are particularly interested in the relationship between
productivity and age because it can help them in testing alternative theories
of the labor market. The simplest of these is the spot market theory, in
which workers are paid, at least annually, their marginal product. Few, if
any, economists view the spot market theory as reasonable. Kotlikoff and Wise
(1985) present fairly strong evidence against it, demonstrating that many, if
not most, defined-benefit pension plans induce sharp discontinuities in vested
pension accrual at particular ages. Under the spot market theory, there
should be offsetting discontinuities in wage compensation at these ages, but
these are not evident in the data.
In contrast to the spot market theory, contract theories of labor markets
imply only a present-value relationship between compensation and productivity.
Consider, for example, the contracts that would be written by risk-neutral
employers. In these contracts, although earnings in any single year can
exceed or be less than that year's productivity, the present expected value of
the worker's output will equal the present expected value of his or her
compensation.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Different contract theories have different implications concerning the
relationship of productivity and wages as the worker ages. One such theory is
the specific human capital model of Mincer (1974) and Becker (1975).

It

suggests that if firms are free to fire older workers, the age-wage profile
will be structured such that earnings exceed productivity when workers are
young and vice versa when they are old. On the other hand, in Becker and
Stigler's (1974) and Lazear's (1979, 1981) agency models of worker shirking,
workers receive less than their marginal product when young, with the
difference paid out in the form of wages, accrued pension benefits, or
severance pay in excess of the marginal product when they are old. The
efficiency wage models of Harris and Todaro (1970), Stofft (1982). Yellen
(1984), Shapiro and Stiglitz (1984), and Bulow and Summers (1986) provide a
view of the labor market similar to that of Lazear. These models stress the
payment of above-market-clearing wages as a mechanism to induce greater worker
effort when such effort is not fully observable. As shown by Akerlof and Katz
(1985), these models yield identical predictions to the Lazear/Becker and
Stigler agency model concerning age-earnings profiles, with the difference in
the models involving the use of employment fees and performance bonds to clear
the market in agency models, but not in efficiency-wage models.
The evidence to date on the age-productivity relationship is limited and
mixed.

Medoff and Abraham (1981) find that older workers' pay increases

although indices of productivity decline, suggesting wages in excess of
marginal products toward the end of the work span. Lazear and Moore (1984)
report that the earnings profiles of the self-employed are flatter than those
of employees, also suggesting earnings in excess of productivity among older
employees. Kahn and Lang (1986), in contrast, examine responses to questions
concerning desired hours of work; they find that older workers, with earnings

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

in excess of their marginal products, are likely to be hours-constrained by
their employers and, therefore, desire to work more.

The opposite is true if

earnings of older workers are below their marginal products. Kahn and Lang's
empirical findings support the view that marginal productivity exceeds
earnings for older workers.
Knowledge of the difference between age-wage and age-productivity
profiles is potentially quite important to the financial valuation of firms.1
Suppose, for example, that wages are less than productivity for younger
workers and greater than productivity for older workers. Then, for each firm,
the excess of its present expected payment of wages to its existing workers
less the present expected productivity of these workers

-

its backloaded

compensation - represents an implicit liability. The word implicit refers to
the fact that firms do not carry such liabilities on their books.

Neverthe-

less, if the market is aware of these liabilities, the firm's market valuation
will be less by a corresponding amount. Hence, the shapes of the agecompensation and age-productivity profiles are important for determining the
ratio of a firm's market value to its replacement costs

-

its q.

Summers

(1981) points out the low q values for U.S. firms for much of the postwar
period.

These low q values are surprising given Salinger's (1984) findings of

high price-cost margins, which imply much more market power and higher profits
than are indicated by the observed values of q. Like Summers' tax adjustments
to q, backloaded compensation may go a long way toward reconciling the low
observed values of q.
This paper assumes risk-neutral employers and estimates the ageproductivity relationship for a single firm using the first-order condition
that the present expected value of total compensation equals the present
expected value of productivity; workers hired at different ages have different

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

present expected values of total compensation and, correspondingly, different
present expected values of productivity.

Hence, if one parameterizes the age-

productivity relationship, the parameters of this relationship can be identified from information on how total present expected compensation varies with
age.
The data in the study are earnings histories for more than 300,000
employees of a Fortune 1000 corporation covering the period 1969 to 1983.
Although its name cannot be disclosed, the firm is involved primarily in
sales.

These data are advantageous not only because one can control for the

firm, but also because one can determine precisely the accrued pension
compensation arising under the firm's defined-benefit pension plan.

At

particular ages and amounts of service, pension compensation in this firm is
an important component of total compensation.
The results indicate that productivity declines with age and that older
workers are paid more than they produce to offset having been paid less than
they produced when young.

For some occupation/sex groups, the difference

between productivity and compensation at young and old ages is sizable.

The

results support the bonding models of Becker and Stigler (1974) and Lazear
(1979, 1981), as well as the efficiency wage models.

The results seem less

compatible with the Becker-Mincer human capital model.
These results should be viewed cautiously, however, for a number of
reasons.

First, they apply only to the firm in question.

Similar analyses of

productivity and compensation profiles for other firms could reach quite
different conclusions.

Second, the analysis assumes that the form of

contracts remains constant over the sample period.

Third, the probability of

remaining employed is treated as exogenous and time invariant, rather than as
an endogenous choice of the employer.

Fourth, the analysis assumes the age-

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

productivity relationship has remained constant over a 16-year period.

Fifth,

the results may be subject to selectivity bias if (1) different workers within
an occupation group have contracts that differ in ways other than their
initial wage and (2) the composition of workers who join or leave the firm at
particular ages is correlated with the characteristics of the contract.
The paper continues as follows. The next section introduces the basic
methodology.
results.

Section I1 presents the data, and section I11 examines the

Section IV briefly considers the potential importance of the

findings for firms' values of q.

Finally, section V states conclusions and

suggests additional research.

I. Methodology
To understand our multiperiod model and its use in inferring the ageproductivity relationship, it may help first to consider a very simple onegood, two-period model with an interest rate of zero. Assume that some
workers work when they are both young and old and that other workers work only
when they are old, but that both types of workers are equally productive when
Further assume that to reduce shirking by young workers, to encourage

old.

human capital formation, or for other reasons, workers who are hired when
young are paid less (more) than their marginal product when young and more
(less) than their marginal product when old.
Let Z and Zo stand, respectively, for the present values of compensation
Y
of those hired when young and those hired when old.

Because workers who are

hired when old are paid their marginal product, Zo is also the productivity of
older workers, and because Z equals the sum of the marginal products of a
Y
worker when he is young and when he is old (recall the interest rate is zero),

Z -Z is the productivity of younger workers. Thus,if we know Z and Zo, we

Y

0

Y

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

can infer the age-productivity relationship. If Zy-Zo > Zo,productivity
falls with age; if Z -Z < Zo,productivity rises with age. Note that if
Y 0
workers are paid their productivity each period, this method will also
generate the correct age-productivity relationship.
We now consider a multiperiod model in which the interest rate is nonzero, in which workers may leave the firm, and in which productivity, in
addition to depending on age, may depend on service, on the date the worker is
hired, and on the worker's individual characteristics. The firm in our model
is assumed to have a constant-returns production function that depends on
capital and labor. Labor input is assumed to differ across workers only in
terms of effective units; that is, the labor input of one worker is a perfect
substitute for that of any other, but the number of effective labor units is
different for each worker. The firm is assumed to have full knowledge of the
worker's productivity at the time he or she is hired. Let Yt, Lt, and Kt
stand for output, labor, and capital, respectively, in year t. The concave
production function is

where

Equation (2) sums the labor input of workers hired this year and in past
years. Specifically, we assume that ages 18 and 75 are the minimum and
maximum ages of workers. Hence, the firm at time s has no workers hired
before year s-57, which is the first year included in the summation. The term
Nj,, stands for the number of workers hired in year j at initial hiring age a.

Of course, not all of the workers hired in the past stay with the firm. The

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

term q(a+s-j,a,s) denotes the fraction of those workers who are currently age
a+s-j, who joined the firm at age a, and who have remained with the firm
through year s .

Finally, h(a+s-j ,a,s) denotes the productivity in year s of

workers age a+s-j who joined the firm at age a.
The expected present value of real profits of the firm at time t, nt, is
given by

(3)

Rt

=

Et

x

[PsYs

-

Is,t

]R
'-~

s-t

-

s-t a-18

p-t
Ns,aes,a

-X
s-t-57 a-18

Ns,aDs,a,

where Et is the expectation operator at time t, Ps is the real price of output
in year s, R is one divided by one plus the real interest rate, Is is investment in year s (Is=Ks+l-Ks), es,a is the present (discounted to year s)
expected value of compensation payments to workers hired in year s at age a,
and Ds,, is the present expected value of remaining compensation payments to
workers hired in year s<t at age a.

Equation (3) states that the present

expected value of profits equals the present expected value of output, less
the present expected value of compensation paid to current and future hires,
less the present expected value of remaining compensation paid to past hires.
At time t, the future values of Ps are uncertain; as a consequence the future
values of Ys are also uncertain.
In maximizing the present expected value of profits, firms are
constrained to structure compensation payments to provide workers with competitive levels of expected utility.

In addition, they may face anti-shirking

constraints, requiring that they structure the time path of compensation to
reduce or eliminate worker malfeasance. Regardless of these side constraints,
the first-order condition for hiring workers age a in year t is that the

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

present expected value of marginal output equals the present expected value of
compensation; that is,

(4)

Et

t+75-a
X
~,~~,~(a+s-t,
a,t)h(a+s-t
s-t

-

,a,S)R~-~ et,a,

where FlS is the marginal product of labor in year s. The summation in (4)
runs from year t to the year in which.the worker, who is now age a, reaches
age 75, which is 75-a years from year t. The product PSFls gives the marginal
revenue product of one unit of effective labor in year s. Multiplying this
product by h(a+s-t,a,s) gives the marginal revenue product in year s of the
worker hired at age a and who is, in year s, a+s-t years of age. The term
q(

...)

adjusts for the probability that the worker hired at age a in year t is

still with the firm in year s (when he is age a+s-t).
The present expected value of compensation of a worker hired in year t at
age a, et,a, can be expressed in terms of the time path of future annual
compensation. Let w(i,a,s) stand for the total annual compensation paid to
workers who are age i in year s and who joined the firm at age a; Then

--a

According to (5), the present expected value of total compensation of the
) equals the present-value
worker who is hired in year t when he is age a (e
t,a

sum of the products of annual compensation, given by the w( ...)s, times the
probabilities, given by the q( . . . )s, that the worker will remain with the firm
until the year in question to collect the compensation.
While the length of employment is uncertain, the assumption of riskneutral employers and risk-averse workers, whose productive characteristics
are fully known by the firm, implies that the actual annual compensation

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

payments

- the

w( . . . )s in (5)

- are

specified with certainty at the time the

worker joins the firm.
Assuming the structure of the compensation contract is constant through
time, the ratio of compensation at age i+l to compensation at age i is independent of time; that is,

If the age-productivity relationship and the probabilities of departure are
also assumed to be time invariant, the third arguments in the functions h(..,)
and q(

...)

can be dropped.

Letting Bs stand for the marginal revenue product in year s of an effective unit of labor (PSFls), equations ( 4 ) , (5), and (6) imply that

(7)

t+75-a
w(a, a,t) C p (a+s-t ,a) (a+s-t ,a)~'-~
s-t
t+75-a
C ~,B,~(a+s-t, a)h(a+s-t ,a)Rset.
s-t

-

In equation (7), the left side expresses the present expected value of
compensation payments for a worker hired at age a in year t in terms of the
worker's first-year compensation, w(a,a,t), and his expected on-the-job wage
growth, which is given by the p(
remaining with the firm, the q(

...)s multiplied by

...)s, and

the probability of

then discounted.

The assumption of myopic expectations permits writing EtBs

- Bt,

and (7)

can be expressed as
t+75-a
(8)

C(a, t)

=

~
Bt X q(a+s-t ,a)h(a+s-t , a ) ~ ~=-BtH(a),
s-t

where C(a,t) stands for the left side of equation (7): the present expected
compensation of a worker hired at age a in year t. Equation (8) indicates

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

that, based on the stated assumption, the present expected value of the
productivity of a worker hired at age a can be written as the product of a
term involving the firm's expected, as of year t, overall productivity per
unit of effective labor input (Bt)

and a term indicating the present expected

number of units of effective labor input of a worker hired at age a, H(a).
To gain some intuition about the relationship between the present
expected value of compensation, C(..), and the productivity relationship,
h(..),

which is a function of age and age of hire, consider the simple case in

which there is a constant probability p of staying with the firm each year.
Here, q(i,a)

=

pi-a; h . . depends only on age, that is, h(i,a)

equals unity (it is time-invariant).

=

v

) and Bt

In this case, the present expected value

of compensation paid to a worker hired at age a can be expressed as a time-

*

invariant function C (a), where C(a,t)

- c*(a).

Manipulation of equation (8)

leads to

Equation (9) expresses the worker's productivity at age a in terms of the
difference in the present value of compensation paid to workers hired at age a
and workers hired at age a+l. This equation is the analogue to the difference
Z -Z in the very simple model discussed above.
Y 0
The first difference of equation (9) gives the growth in productivity
with age : that is,

From equation (9), if the product of the survival rate and the interest rate,
pR, equaled unity, productivity at age a, v(a), would just equal the
difference in the present expected value of compensation of workers hired at

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

age a and at age a+l.

In this case, the present expected value of compensa-

tion of younger hires would always exceed that of older hires (assuming
positive values of v(a) at all ages).

If, on the other hand, the annual prob-

ability of departing the firm is high, pR will be much less than unity, and a
value of c*(a+l)

in excess of c*(a)

is consistent with positive values of

v(a>
The formula for changes in productivity with age is given in equation
In some cases, one can read the age-productivity relationship from the

(10).

slope of the profile of present expected compensation by age, ~"(a) , and the
knowledge that pR<1.

For example, productivity is constant with age in the

range of ages over which the c*(a) profile is flat. One can also tell that
productivity rises with age over the ranges in which ~"(a) is rising, but at a
decreasing rate; the intuition here is that a positive but flattening slope of
~"(a) means that the immediate positive slope of ~"(a) (the difference in
c*(a+l)

and ~*(a))

is due to productivity at age a+l, v(a+l),

productivity at age a, v(a),
exceeding v(a).

exceeding

rather than due to later marginal products

If ~"(a) is rising, but at an increasing rate, one cannot say

whether productivity at age a+l exceeds or falls short of productivity at age
a.

Similarly, one can tell that productivity declines with age over ranges of

ages in which ~"(a) declines with age at a decreasing rate; however, if cX(a)
declines with age at an increasing rate, one cannot tell whether productivity
is decreasing or increasing with age.
Returning to the general case, equation (8) can be transformed into an
econometric relation by appending a multiplicative error term, eeast,j,where
the subscript j references the individual worker. The error term can be
viewed as a worker-specific productivity factor. Its inclusion in the model
means that workers hired at the same age in the same occupation/sex category

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

may have different initial salaries.

Hence, the model permits worker

heterogeneity as well as selectivity based on the r

a,t,j

's. While workers

hired at particular ages, or in certain years, may be more or less productive
than workers hired at other ages or in other years without biasing the
results, the model does require the same wage-growth contract and the
same departure rates for all workers within an occupation/sex group.

Taking

logarithms of the resulting expression yields

Here , ca ,t ,j is the logarithm of C(a,t) for worker j who is age a in year t.
While h(..) can, in principle, be parameterized as a function of service as
well as age, in practice the resulting cumulative age and cumulative service
variables are too colinear to estimate separate age and service coefficients.
Hence, we parameterize the productivity function h(..) as simply a cubic
function of age, and acknowledge that the age-productivity results reported
below confound service-productivity effects.2 Letting h(k,a)

- alk + a2k2 +

a3k3, H(a) can be written as
t+75-a

(12)

H(a)

- a1s-tP q(a+s-t, a) (a+s-t)RS-t
+

t+75-a
a2 P
q(a+s-t ,a) (a+s-t) 2~s-t
s-t
t+75-a

+ a3

P

q(a+s-t) ( ~ + s - ~ ) ~ R s - ~ .

s-t
One cannot separately identify all four of the parameters in equations
(11) and (12), Bt, al, a2, and a3.

TO see this, substitute from equation (12)

into equation (11) and divide both sides of the resulting expression by al;
observe that the resulting constant term will equal loget

+

logal.

Since this

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

poses no problem for estimating the age-productivity relationship, the parameter al is normalized to unity. With this normalization and using equation
(12), equation (11) can now be expressed as
(11'

ca,t,j

- loget

+ log[Xl(a)

+ a2X2(a) + a3X3(a)

I +

ea, t,J ,

where Xl(a), X2(a), and X3(a) are the respective sums on the right side of
equation (12).

Equation (11') can be estimated nonlinearly. Because time

enters only through the intercept term loget, data for workers hired in
different years can be pooled by simply entering year dummies. Given the
estimated value of the a2 and ag and the normalization al-1, we can determine
the shape of the h(k,a)-olk

+

a2k2

+

a3k3 function.

11. The Data and Empirical Imvlementation
The large firm's data used in this study are earnings histories covering
the period 1969 through 1983 of workers employed in the firm at some time
during the period 1980 through 1983. The workers are classified into three
rather broad occupation/sex groups: male office workers, female office
workers, salesmen, saleswomen, and male managers. There are too few female
managers to warrant their analysis. Unfortunately, no additional demographic
variables are available for inclusion in the analysis. Appendix table I
presents the distribution of the observations by age of hire and occupation/sex groups.
The firm has a defined-benefit plan with a fairly complex set of age- and
service-related benefits. A percent-of-earnings formula computes the basic
retirement annuity, which equals a percentage rate times the number of years
of service for workers with fewer than 26 years of service. For those with
more service, the formula equals 25 times the former percentage rate, plus the

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

additional service beyond 25 times a lower percentage rate.

The basic benefit

is offset by the amount of Social Security benefits the firm predicts the
worker will receive.

The predicted Social Security benefit is derived from

another age- and service-related formula unique to the firm.
The normal retirement age under the pension plan is 65, and the early
retirement age is 55.

For workers who retire after the early retirement age,

but before the normal retirement age, there is a special early retirement
benefit reduction table based on the the worker's age and service.

Those who

terminate employment before age 55 are not eligible for the generous earlyretirement reduction rates and instead face actuarially reduced benefits.
Another important penalty for workers who terminate before the early retirement age is that their Social Security offset is not deferred until they reach
age 65. The postponement of this offset until age 65 if the worker stays with
the firm until the early retirement age produces a substantial vested pension
accrual at age 55 as compared to the rather modest accrual prior to age 55.
After age 55, the accrual is much smaller and, indeed, can become negative.
The survival probabilities, the q(

,

)'s, used in constructing ca,t,j and

the variables in equations (10') and (13) were calculated separately for each
of the five age-occupation/sex groups in the following manner.

First, we

calculated the fraction of workers at a given age and initial age of hire who
remain in the firm from one year to the next.

Next, we smoothed these annual

survival hazards using a second-order polynomial in age, age squared, years of
service, years of service squared, and age times years of service.

Finally,

we computed the cumulative survival probabilities, the q( , )Is, based on the
smoothed annual survival probabilities.
The data used in the regressions of annual survival hazards encompass the
years 1980 through 1984.

For these years, we have complete employment

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

duration data on all workers in our five categories who were employed with the
firm. Unfortunately, while we have the complete employment/earnings histories
going back to 1969 for those workers hired prior to 1980 who were still
employed with the firm from 1980 though 1984, we do not have any information
on those workers hired prior to 1980 who did not remain with the firm through
1980. Hence, in forming the empirical hazards, we can use data only from 1980
through 1984. The R2's in these regressions are 0.23 for male office workers,
0.29 for female office workers, 0.12 for salesmen, 0.01 for saleswomen, and
0.21 for male managers. The respective number of observations in these
regressions are 1,344, 1,387, 1,274, 630, and 963. The smaller number of
observations for saleswomen reflects the fact that we lack data in certain age
and age-of-hire cells on the fraction of saleswomen remaining with the firm
between one year and the next. The missing data typically involve saleswomen
hired at older ages and, for a given age of hire, saleswomen who are older.
The explanation is that most saleswomen in the firm are hired at young ages
and have high probabilities of leaving the firm within a few years.
Table I presents the smoothed survival function q( , ) for the different
occupation/sex groups at selected ages and ages of hire. Table I indicates
substantial differences in job survival rates across the five groups; 34.3
percent of male managers who hire on at age 30 are predicted to remain with
the firm 25 years later. For male and female office workers, the comparable
percentages are 21.5 and 14.2, respectively. For salesmen and saleswomen, the
respective percentages are 5.4 and 2.3. The table also demonstrates that
workers hired at older ages, at least through age 50, have larger probabilities of remaining with the firm for a given period of time than do workers
hired at younger ages.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

The p( , )'s in the above discussion have stood for the growth in total
compensation, including pension compensation; but in order to determine the
course of pension compensation, one first needs to know the course of nonpension compensation. Hence, we first estimated the function p*(

, ) , which

gives the growth in nonpension compensation, by regressing observed growth
rates in earnings, excluding pension compensation, against a second-order
polynomial in age, age squared, service, service squared, age times service,
age squared times service, service squared times age, and age squared times
service squared. In these regressions we used data on workers' earnings
histories going back to 1969. We eliminated the first and last year (for
those workers who departed) of earnings because we were not sure those
earnings represented a full year's nonpension compensation. Hence, a worker
needs to remain with the firm for at least four years to have his wage growth
data included in the regression; for example, a worker who remains with the
firm for only three years will have only one year - his second year
usable earnings data

- an

- of

insufficient amount with which to calculate a value

for wage growth.
We have a large number of observations in these regressions, since each
worker who remains with the firm for several years supplies more than one
observation on the growth in nonpension compensation. The number of observations in these regressions total 71,903 for male office workers, 132,543 for
female office workers, 201,467 for salesmen, 6,482 for saleswomen, and 33,285
for male managers. The smaller number of observations for saleswomen shows
that, compared to other types of workers, a much smaller fraction of saleswomen remain with the firm for the four years needed to enter our regression
sample. Given the large number of observations and the small number (eight)
of regressors, it may not be surprising that the R ~ ' Sare small: 0.04 for male

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

o f f i c e workers, 0.04 f o r female o f f i c e workers, 0.01 f o r salesmen, 0.01 f o r
saleswomen, and 0.03 f o r male managers.
Obviously, much of the v a r i a t i o n i n nonpension compensation a s well a s i n
the survival hazards i s not dependent on age and\or age of h i r e .

This does

not appear t o present a problem f o r our analysis because we a r e i n t e r e s t e d i n
determining the expected (ex ante) present value of compensation, not the
r e a l i z e d (ex post) present value of compensation.

Although random f a c t o r s may

r a i s e or lower a worker's survival p r o b a b i l i t i e s o r wage growth above o r below
t h a t which would be forecast ex a n t e , it i s only the ex ante f o r e c a s t t h a t we
need t o assess.

W
e should a l s o note, i n t h i s context, t h a t despite the low

R 2 's i n the survival and wage growth regressions, the predicted survival r a t e s

and wage growth r a t e s d i f f e r considerably across workers who a r e i n d i f f e r e n t
occupation/sex groups, but who were hired a t the same age, and across workers

It is

i n the same occupation/sex group, but who were h i r e d a t d i f f e r e n t ages.

these differences t h a t provide the i d e n t i f i c a t i o n needed f o r t h i s analysis.
The i n i t i a l wage, together with the smoothed function f o r growth i n

*

nonpension compensation (p (

,

) function), provides a path of nonpension

compensation t h a t can be used t o calculate the path of pension accrual.

The

p a t h of nonpension plus pension compensation i s then used t o form the present
expected value of t o t a l compensation, the ca , t , j '"'
Table I1 presents the smoothed nonpension compensation growth r a t e
function p*(
ages of h i r e .

,

) f o r the d i f f e r e n t occupation/sex groups a t s e l e c t e d ages and

Table I1 indicates t h a t the age of h i r e i s a l s o an important

f a c t o r i n r e a l wage growth.

According t o the regression, workers hired a t

l a t e r ages often experience g r e a t e r r e a l wage growth than those h i r e d a t
younger ages.

I n addition, wage growth f o r female o f f i c e workers and sales-

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

women at particular combinations of age and age of hire often exceeds that of
their male occupational counterparts.
A reduced-form regression can help to illustrate the shape of the age
profile of the present expected value of compensation. This regression
relates the logarithm of the present expected value of compensation (calculated using the initial wage, the q( ,

)

survival function, and the

p(

,

)

compensation growth function) to a set of year dummies and a polynomial in
age. The exponent of the coefficients of this polynomial in age multiplied by
their respective variables indicates the shape of the profile of age/present
expected value of compensation. Figure I presents this profile for each of
the five occupation/sex groups normalized by the age 40 level of this profile.
Notice that each of the normalized profiles of present expected compensation
rises at early ages at a decreasing rate, suggesting, as indicated above, that
productivity rises with age at these ages. In addition, each of the profiles,
except that of saleswomen, declines at a decreasing rate in old age,
suggesting that productivity declines with age at these ages for at least the
other occupation/sex groups.

111. Estimates of the Aee-Productivitv Profile
Table I11 presents the regression results from estimating equation (11')
assuming a 6 percent interest rate. Recall that this regression relates the
logarithm of the present expected value of compensation to year dummies and
the logarithm of the sum of three nonlinear functions of age multiplied by
three coefficients, one of which is normalized to unity.

In this regression,

only observations on workers hired during the years 1970 through 1983 are
included, since pension accrual for workers hired prior to 1970 could not be
determined. All of the age-squared and age-cubed coefficients reported in the

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

table are highly significant. Many of the year dummies are also significant,
suggesting that the modeling of expectations of future 4's may be important.
The regression coefficients are little affected by the choice of interest
rate; the regressions were repeated assuming interest rates of both 3 percent
and 9 percent, and the coefficients are very similar to those reported in
table 111.
Figures I1 through VI are based on the 6 percent interest rate regressions of table 111. They present the age-productivity profiles (dashed lines)
predicted by the regressions for the five occupation/sex groups for workers
hired initially at age 35. They also present the age-total compensation
profile implied by the smoothed compensation growth function

p(

, )s and the

pattern of pension accrual. The age 35 initial level of productivity (Bt in
equation (8)) and compensation (w(a,a,t) in equation (7)) are chosen to ensure
that both the present expected value of compensation and the present expected
value of marginal product equal $500,000.
While productivity initially rises with age in each figure, it eventually
starts declining with age. For male office workers, productivity peaks at age
45 and declines thereafter. Age 65 productivity is less than one-third of
peak productivity for this group. The female office workers' productivity
profile is quite similar to that of the male office workers. Productivity
profiles for both the salesmen and saleswomen peak a few years later than
those of office workers, but their rate of decline with age is quite similar.
Productivity for male managers peaks at age 43; by age 60 productivity is less
than one-third of peak productivity, and productivity actually becomes
negative after age 62.
In four of the figures, productivity exceeds total compensation while the
worker is young and then falls below total compensation; in the remaining

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

case, that of salesmen, the relationship of compensation and productivity is
quite similar to the other four groups, except after age 61, when productivity
again exceeds compensation. Except for the kinks in the age-compensation
profiles associated with pension accrual, the age-compensation profiles and
age-productivity profiles for salesmen and saleswomen are very close to one
another at each age. This is predictable, because salesworkers in this firm
are paid, in large part, on a commission basis.
In contrast to the results for salesworkers, one might expect the weakest
connection between annual earnings and annual productivity among male
managers. Figure IV indicates this is indeed the case. At age 35, productivity for male managers exceeds total compensation by greater than a factor
of two, while compensation is more than twice as high as productivity by age
57. The discrepancies between total compensation and productivity at these
ages are somewhat smaller for office workers, but still significant. For
example, age 35 total compensation for female office workers is $22,616, while
age 35 productivity is $33,604. In contrast, age 57 total compensation is
$42,526, although productivity is only $28,117.
The results depicted in figures I1 through VI are not sensitive to the
inclusion of pension accrual in total compensation; if one ignores pension
accrual in the estimation, the age-earnings and age-productivity profiles have
the same relative shapes as those presented. Of course, the age-earnings
profile does not exhibit the kinks of the age-total compensation profile,
since these kinks arise from pension accrual. Ignoring pension accrual, one
can then use the data on workers hired prior to 1970. While the initial wage
of those hired prior to 1969 is not reported, it can be inferred based on the
wage observed in 1969 and the compensation growth function p ( ) ; that is, one
can impute backwards the wage at the initial age of hire. The results based

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

on this larger data set are very similar to those presented in figures I1
through VI.

The general shapes of the age-total compensation profiles and

age-productivity profiles are also insensitive to the choice of interest rate.
Another concern about the results is the extent to which the profiles
described here as age-productivity profiles confound service-productivity
effects. Unfortunately, the colinearity between cumulated service and age
variables precludes modeling the h(..)

function as a continuous function of

both age and age of hire. An alternative way to explore this issue is to
model h(..) as depending only on age, but to estimate the model separately for
workers hired at different ages. If one estimates the model separately for
those hired prior to age 35 and for those hired after age 35, the resulting
general shapes of the productivity profiles are quite similar to those based
on the entire sample. The post-35 profiles are indeed very similar, while the
pre-35 profiles exhibit a steeper decline in productivity with age, with
negative predicted productivity after roughly age 55. This prediction of
negative productivity late in the work span may simply represent a poor fit in
the tail of the estimated polynomial.

IV. Can Differences in Age-Productivitv and Age-Com~ensationProfiles Ex~lain
Low Value of Firms' a's?
In paying workers less than their productivity when young, a firm incurs
implicit obligations to pay its workers more than their productivity when they
are old. Although this implicit financial obligation does not show up on a
firm's books (given standard accounting practices), it will be reflected in
the firm's market value, making the ratio of the market value of a firm to the
replacement cost of its capital (q) less than unity.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

To see why deferred labor obligations reduce q, consider equation (3'),
the expression for the firm's market value (present value of expected profits)
in year t, nt, and equation (4), the firm's rule for hiring new workers.

- Ets-tX [PsYs - I,]R~-~
m

nt

(3')

' '

75

t
75
p-t -s-t a918Ns,aes,a
Ns,aDs,a.
s-t-57 a-18

' '

Recall that Et is the expectation operator at time t, Ps is the real price of
output Y, in year s, R is one divided by one plus the real interest rate, Is
is investment in year s (Is-Ks+l-Ks), e

s,a

is the present (discounted to year

s) expected value of compensation payments to workers hired in year s at age
a, NS,, is the number of workers hired at age a in year s, and Ds,a is the
present expected value of remaining compensation payments to workers hired at
age a in year s<t.

In equation (3'), output in year s, Ys, may be written as

the marginal product of labor in year s, FlS, times the supply of labor, Ls,
plus the marginal product of capital in year s, Fks, times the supply of
capital, Ks.

Dividing equation (3') by Kt and applying the first-order condi-

tion (4) leads to expression (13) for qt-nt/Kt.
m

(13)

qt

- Ets-tX [PsFksKs - I ~ ~ R ~ - ~ / K ~
t+5 6
s
X PSFls
X
t s-t
j-s-57

+ E

75

x

Nj ,,q(a+s-j

,a,s>h(a+s-j ,a,s)/Kt

a-18

Equation (13) indicates that qt, the ratio of the firm's market value to
its replacement cost, equals (a) the present value of expected total returns

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

from current and future capital less the present-value costs of current and
future investment

- all divided by

Kt, plus (b) the present value of expected

productivity of labor hired prior to year t, less (c) the present value of
compensation still owed to labor hired prior to year t. If the labor market
were a spot market, then the present expected value of workers' future productivity would equal the present expected value of workers' compensation, since
each year's compensation would equal each year's productivity. In this case,
the last two terms in equation (13) would cancel, and q would simply equal the
expected present discounted value of returns to capital less the cost of
investment. With the condition that the marginal revenue product of capital
in year s equals the interest rate, it is easy to show that the firm's market
value at time t, xt, simply equals Kt, the replacement value of its capital;
that is, in the case of a spot labor market (and ignoring capital adjustment
costs and inframarginal capital income taxes), the firm's q
its market value to its replacement cost

-

the ratio of

- equals unity.

While the firm's q is unity assuming a spot labor market, it is less than
unity if the firm pays its workers less than their productivity when the
workers are young and more than their productivity when the workers are old.
To see this, note that the difference between the last two terms in equation
(13) equals the present-value difference between the productivity and
compensation of all existing workers at time t divided by Kt. Because each of
these workers was hired subject to the first-order condition that productivity
equals compensation in present value over the work span, and because each of
these workers was underpaid at some point in the past, the difference for each
worker between the present value of his future productivity and his compensation will be negative. (This ignores unexpected changes in the firm's price of
output and production technology and assumes that productivity and compensa-

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

tion profiles cross only once.)

Hence, q in this case will be less than

unity.
In determining the amount of backloaded compensation (the present-value
difference between expected future compensation and productivity), we consider
each of the workers in our data in 1980 with at least one year of service.
For all of these workers, we first determine their past (back to their age of
hire) and future wage earnings using their 1980 reported earnings and our
calculated wage compensation growth profile.

To this absolute wage compensa-

tion profile we add the appropriate yearly pension accrual. We then calculate
the present value of each worker's total expected compensation as of his date
of hire.

Next we adjust the level of the worker's age-productivity profile

such that the present expected value of the absolute level of productivity as
of the worker's age of hire equals the present expected value of the worker's
total compensation as of his age of hire.

Benchmarking the productivity

profile against the compensation profile in this manner provides us with the
worker's level of productivity in 1980 and in all future years.

We use the

1980 and subsequent productivity and compensation levels to compute the
present-value difference between expected future compensation and productivity .
To get a rough idea of the potential impact on q of backloaded compensation, denote the difference between the last two terms in equation (13) multiplied by Kt as Bt, the present value of backloaded compensation, and denote Zt
as total year t compensation payments to the firm's workers.

We can now write

In evaluating equation (14), we assume that Zt/rKt, the ratio of current
earnings to capital income, equals 4, the national average. We also assume a

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

value of the interest rate r equal to 0.1. Then qt equals unity minus 0.4
times the ratio of the year t present value of backloaded compensation to
total compensation payments in year t.

If this ratio equals 1 (0.5), it means

that backloaded compensation can explain a value of q that differs from unity
by 0.4 (0.2).

For all of the workers included in our data in 1980 (which do

not include all of the firm's employees), the ratio of Bt to Zt equals 1.16.
It equals 2.29 for male office workers, 1.38 for female office workers, 4.88
for male managers, -0.30 for salesmen, and 0.76 for saleswomen. While additional data that are not available would be needed to assess fully the impact
of backloaded compensation on the firm's value of q, the values of Bt/Zt for
the five occupation/sex groups are sufficiently large to suggest an important
role for backloaded compensation in the firm's value of q.

V. Conclusion
The finding that productivity decreases with age must be viewed
cautiously. Contrary to what has been assumed, it may be the case that some
workers within an occupation/sex category receive different contracts than do
others. Suppose that within an occupation/sex category there are type A and B
workers and that type A workers receive contracts with steeper compensation
profiles as compared to contracts for type B workers. Also assume that type A
workers have smaller probabilities of remaining with the firm than type B
workers.

If the composition of workers remaining with the firm changes, the

estimated compensation growth function and the estimated job survival function
would differ from those for either A or B separately, or from those that would
arise if the separate job survival and compensation growth functions for A and

B were averaged using constant weights.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

As a consequence, the age-productivity profile derived using the method
presented here could differ substantially from either the profile for type A
workers or the profile for type B workers.

Similar biases may arise if the

composition of type A and type B workers among new hires changes as the age of
hire increases. These potential biases need to be explored more formally, as
does the possible bias arising from assuming static expectations of overall
worker productivity.
These concerns notwithstanding, the results are fairly striking. Productivity falls with age, compensation at first lies below and then exceeds
productivity, and the discrepancy between compensation and productivity can be
substantial. Interestingly, there is a much closer correspondence of productivity to compensation for salesworkers, who are compensated more on a spot
market basis, than for other types of workers. Also, the relationship of
productivity to compensation is weakest for male managers, who, one would
expect, are most likely to be hired on a contract rather than a spot market
basis.

In addition to confirming contract theory, the results lend support to

the bonding wage models of Becker and Stigler (1974) and Lazear (1979, 1981).
Finally, the results may help to explain low ratios of firms' market
values to the replacement costs (q's) of their capital. When future compensation exceeds future productivity for a firm's workers, as is the case for the
firm considered here, it represents a liability that presumably willbe
reflected in a lower market value of the firm and a lower value of q.

While

the results reported here must be viewed cautiously, if for no other reason
than they apply only to a single firm, they raise the possibility that backloaded compensation is an important determinant of firms' q's.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Footnotes
1. We thank Lawrence Summers for pointing this out.
2. To see why the estimation might confound age and service effects if service
as well as age influences productivity, consider the case that productivity at
a point in time is a linear function of age and service; that is, let h(k,a) =
@k+ A(k-a) (recall that k stands for age and k-a for service). Consider
first the case that the probability of leaving employment with the firm prior
to a given age, D, is zero, but it is unity after age D. In this case, the
function H(a) is given by
H(a)

D
X[pk
k-a

=

+

A(k-a)]

=

pa

+ A(D-a+l)(D-a)/2

=

cp +

(B

- A/2 - AD)a

+ Aa2/2

and the estimation of equation (8) would yield two coefficients, one for a
(age of hire) and one for a2 (age of hire squared). The coefficient on a
would combine both p and A (age and service effects), while the coefficient on
a2 would indicate the effect of service.
Next consider the case of a constant probability p of remaining with the
firm regardless of one's age and of R equaling unity. The term H(a) in
equation (8) would be given by

In this case, the present expected contribution of service to productivity is
identical for all hires (and is captured by the constant 4), and the estimation of equation (8) would recover only the coefficient p.
More generally, when we allow for more complicated departure processes as
well as productivity functions that are nonlinear in age and service, the H(a)
function will be a highly nonlinear function of age and service parameters.
Unfortunately, colinearity precludes estimating separate age and service
parameters, and it proved necessary to make the identifying assumption of zero
service effects. The literature is mixed with respect to the effects of
service on wages. Depending on one's model of labor contracts, the findings
of Altonji and Shakotko (1987) (but not of Lang [I9881 or Tope1 [1988]), that
wages do not rise with service, may imply that productivity also does not rise
with service.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

References
Abraham, Katharine, and Henry S. Farber, "Job Duration, Seniority, and
Earnings,"
, w IXX (1987), 278-97.
Akerlof, George, and Larry Katz, "Do Deferred Wages Dominate Involuntary Unemployment as a Worker Disciplinary Device?" NBER Working Paper No. 1616,
May 1985.
Altonji, Joseph, and Robert Shakotko, "Do Wages Rise with Job Seniority?"
Review of Economic Studies, LIV (1987), 437-60.
Becker, Gary S. Human Ca~ital,2nd ed. (New York: Columbia University Press,
1975).

, and George Stigler, "Law Enforcement, Malfeasance, and the
Compensation of Enforcers," Journal of Leeal Studies (1974), 1-18.
Bulow, Jeremy, and Lawrence H. Summers, "A Theory of Dual Labor Markets with
Application to Industrial Policy, Discrimination, and Keynesian Unemployment," Journal of Labor Economics, IV (1986), 376-414.
Harris, John, and Michael P. Todaro, "Migration, Unemployment, and Development: A Two Sector Analysis," m,
Review, (1970), 12643.
Kahn, Shulamit, and Kevin Lang, "Constraints on the Choice of Work Hours,"
Boston University, mimeo, 1986.
Kotlikoff, Laurence J., and David A. Wise, "Labor Compensation and the Structure of Private Pension Plans: Evidence for Contractual versus Spot Labor
Markets," in David A. Wise, ed., Pensions. Labor. and Individual Choice,
(Chicago: Chicago University Press, NBER volume, 1985).

, "The Incentive Effects of Private Pension Plans," NBER
Working Paper No. 1510, 1984.
Lang, Kevin, "Reinterpreting the Returns to Seniority," Boston University,
mimeo, 1988.
Lazear, Edward, "Agency, Earnings Profiles, Productivity, and Hours Restrictions," American Economic Review, IXXI (1981), 606-20.

, "Why Is There Mandatory Retirement?" Journal of Political
Economv, W U N I I (1979), 1261-84.
Lazear, Edward, and Robert Moore, "Incentives, Productivity, and Labor
Contracts," Ouarterlv Journal of Economics, XCIX (1984). 275-96.
Medoff, James L., and Katharine G. Abraham, "Experience, Performance, and
Earnings," Ouarterlv Journal of Economics, XLV (1980), 703-36.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

, and
, "Are Those Paid More Really More
Productive? The Case of Experience," Journal of Human Resources, XVI
(1981), 186-216.
Mincer, Jacob, school in^, Exverience. and Earninns (New York: Columbia University Press, 1974).
Salinger, Michael A., "Tobin's q, Unionization, and the Concentration-Profits
Relationship," Rand Journal of Economics, XV (Summer 1984), 159-70.
Shapiro, Carl, and Joseph Stiglitz, "Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker
Discipline Device," American Economic Review, LXXIV (1984), 433-44.
Stofft, Steve, "Cheat-Threat Theory," University of California, Berkeley,
Ph.D. thesis, 1982.
Summers, Lawrence H., "Taxation and Corporate Investment: A q-Theory
Approach," Brookings Pavers on Economic Activity, I (1981), 67-127.
Topel, Robert, "Wages Rise with Seniority," University of Chicago, mimeo,
1988.
Yellen, Janet, "Efficiency Wage Models of Unemployment," American Economic
Review, LXXIV (1984), 200-08.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table I
Predicted Probabilities of Remaining with the Firm from
Age of Hire to Specified Age by Occupation/Sex Group

Aae of Hire

25

Male Office Workers
20
0.461
30
40
50
60
Female Office Workers
20
0.472
30
40
50
60
Salesmen
20
30
40
50
60
Saleswomen
20
30
40
50
60
Male Managers
20
30
40
50
60

0.286

0.301

0.622

Source: Authors' calculations.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table I1
Predicted Annual Wage Compensation Growth Rates for
Specific Ages and Ages of Hire by Occupation/Sex Group
(percentage growth rate)

Age
25

Aee of Hire
Male Office Workers
20
30
40
50
60

0.071

Female Office Workers
20
30
40
50
60

0.047

Salesmen
20
30
40
50
60

0.016

Saleswomen
20
30
40
50
60

0.042

Male Managers
20
30
40
50
60

0.090

Source: Authors' calculations.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table I11
Age-Productivity ~ e ~ r e s s i o n s ~

Males
Variable

Office Workers

Salesmen Manapers

Females
Office Workers Saleswomen

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table I11 (continued)

Males
Variable

Office Workers

Number
of Obser.

7,083

Females

Salesmen Manaeers

19,696

Office Workers Saleswomen

2,116

a. Regressions of logarithm of the present value of compensation (assuming a 6
percent interest rate) against year dummies and the logarithm of the sum of
three nonlinear functions of age. D71 - D83 are the year dummies. The coefficients a and a3 multiply two of the three nonlinear functions of age (see
equation [ 1'1).
Source: Authors' calculations.

1

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Appendix Table
Distribution of Workers
by Age of Hire and Occupation/Sex Group
(percent of workers hired in given age range)

<20

20-24

25-29

30-34

0

31.0

33.9

Salesmen

0

18.4

Saleswomen

0

Maleoffice
Workers
Female Office
Workers

Male
Managers

55+

35-39

40-44

45-49

19.1

9.2

4.6

1.6

.5

.1

28.1

22.5

14.6

9.1

4.6

1.9

.6

12.1

19.7

20.3

21.1

15.2

8.0

3.1

.5

0

45.3

29.0

11.8

5.3

3.2

2.3

1.9

1.0

0

44.9

17.3

11.4

9.7

7.5

5.0

2.9

1.2

50-54

a. Rows may not add to 100 percent due to rounding. This table is based on
3,860 male managers, 25,858 salesmen, 2,054 saleswomen, 9,220 male office
workers, and 22,361 female office workers.
Source: Authors1 calculations.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Figure I
Relative Profile of Present Expected Compensation
RI
2.0.

RGE

A
B
C
D
E

= Male Managers

= Saleswomen
= Salesmen
= Female Office Workers
= Male Office Workers

Source: Authors' calculations.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Figure II
Total Compensation and Productivity Profiles (1980 dollars)
Present Value = 500,000, R = 6%, Male Office Workers

cow

o.-------------------------------------------------

- loo00 -20000 \
35

I

~

"

40

'

I

'

45

~

"

l

'

50

RGE
* = Total Compensation
0 = Productivity

Source: Authors' calculations.

"

'

I

"

"

55

I

'

"

"

60

'

l

65

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Figure Ill
Total Compensation and Productivity Profiles (1980 dollars)
Present Value = 500,000, R = 6%, Male Salesworkers
cone

1

'

"

.

1

35

"

~

'

40

1

"

"

1

45

"

"

I

"

"

50
RGE

+

= Total Compensation

0

= Productivity

Source: Authors' calculations.

55

1

.

60

'

.

'

1

65

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

F i g ~ ~ IV
re
Total Conipe~isationand Prodl~ctivityProfiles (1980 dollars)
Present Value = 500,000, R = 6%, Male Managers
COHP

35

40

45

50
AGE

* =
0=

Total Compensation
Productivity

Source: Authors' calculations.

55

60

65

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Figure V
Total Compensation and Productivity Profiles (1980 dollars)
Present Value = 500,000, R = 6%, Female Office Workers
cow

-10000

35

40

45

50
AGE

* =
=

0

Total Compensation
Productivity

Source: Authors' calculations.

55

60

65

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Figure VI
Total Compensation and Productivity Profiles (1980 dollars)
Present Value = 500,000, R = 6%, Feniale Salesworkers
COHP
1 10000
100000
90000
80000
70000
60000
50000
40000
30000
20000
loo00 3

o:-------------------------------------------------10000 1
-20000 1
1

35

'

"

40

'

1

'

4S

.

"

I

.

SO
AGE

* = Total Compensation

0 = Productivity
Source: Authors' calculations.

"

'

I

"

'

SS

~

I

~

~

60

7
65