View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Working P a ~ e 931
r 1
THE EQUITY OF SOCIAL SERVICES
PROVIDED TO CHILDREN AND SENIOR CITIZENS
by Laurence J. Kotlikoff and Jagadeesh Gokhale

Laurence J. Kotlikoff is a professor of economics
at Boston University and an associate of the
National Bureau of Economic Research, and Jagadeesh
Gokhale is an economist at the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland.
Working papers of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland are preliminary materials circulated to
stimulate discussion and critical comment. The
views stated herein are those of the authors and
not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System.
December 1993

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Abstract
This paper marshals a variety of evidence in considering the degree of equity in the
U.S. government's treatment of children vis-a-vis adults, particularly the elderly. We begin
by showing that poverty rates among American children have increased dramatically over
the past two decades, while those of the elderly have fallen. Next, we show that during
the same period, consumption and income levels among the elderly have risen relative to
those of other Americans, including children.
The paper then turns to the role of govemment policy in influencing these trends.
First, we document the high level of transfer payments going to the elderly relative to
children, even if educational expenditures on children are included. We then argue that
such point-in-time comparisons are invalid because they fail to consider that at any given
time, children and the elderly are at different stages of their life cycles. Controlling for this
fact requires an examination of the government's fiscal treatment of different generations
over their entire lifetimes. Thus, we present/project lifetime net tax rates for generations
born since 1900 as well as for future generations. The results indicate that, given current
policy, today's and tomorrow's children could wind up paying as much as 70 percent of
their lifetime income to the government, while the current elderly will pay only about 25
percent on average. Although the paper cautions that generational equity is in the eye of
the beholder, the disparity reported here does considerable violence to the norms of
generational fairness.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

I. Introduction
This paper examines the U.S. government's current and prospective fiscal
treatment of American children from the perspective of transfer payments now being
received and government services now being purchased on their behalf. It also considers
the benefits and services today's children will receive as well as the taxes they will pay in
their adult years.
In examining the transfer payments and services that the current generation of

children will receive and the taxes they will pay over their lifetimes, we seek to answer the
question, "Are today's children being treated equitably compared with other generations,
particularly the current elderly?" Our answer relies in part on a new method of comparing
the lifetime net tax burdens (taxes paid less transfers received) of different generations.
This method, called generational accounting, overcomes the Wiculty encountered with
point-in-time comparisons between any two generations, namely, that each is at a different
stage of the life cycle.
To understand this problem, consider a country with a long-standing policy of
financing transfer payments to children through taxes on the elderly. While a point-intime, say time-t, comparison of the treatment of children versus their elders would suggest
that children are being treated relatively favorably, it ignores the fact that the time-t elderly
received the same amount of transfers when they were children, and that the time-t
children will pay the same amount of taxes as the time-t elderly when they are old. Thus,
from a lifetime perspective, the time-t children in this example are being treated neither
better nor worse than the time-t elderly. In contrast to current-flow accounting,
generational accounting, when applied in this hypothetical setting, documents the equal
lifetime treatment of the time-t children and elderly. It thus provides a useful tool for
comparing the fiscal treatment of different generations despite their being at various stages
of the life cycle.
-

l ~ e Kotlikoff
e
(1992) and Auerbach, Gokhale, and Kotlikoff (199 1).

1

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Section I1 begins by pointing out that poverty rates among American children have
increased steadily over the past two decades, while those of the elderly have fallen. The
paper then documents the concomitant rise in the income and consumption levels of older
generations relative to younger generations, including children. Finally, we look at the
government's role in altering the living standards of children vis-h-vis the elderly. Our
results show that much of the current plight of America's youngest citizens is traceable not
to a lack of government financial support, but to the breakup of the family unit, which has

left almost one-quarter of the nation's children dependent on just one parent.
While section II's discussion of demographics provides some perspective on the

limits of government policy in determining the living standards of children, the question
remains as to whether the government has offset or exacerbated the relative economic
situation of today's children. The rest of the paper considers this question from both a
point-in-time and a lifetime perspective. Section III examines the current flows of transfer
payments and services being provided to children and compares them with those going to
senior citizens. Section IV presents the generational accounting approach to examining
the lifetime net tax treatment of different generations. In particular, we compare the
lifetime net tax rates of each generation of males and females who were born or who will
be bornh this century. A generation's lifetime net tax rate is defined as the ratio of its

lifetime net tax payment to its lifetime labor earnings. Lifetime tax rates for different'
generations are calculated based on a continuation of current fiscal policy as well as under
alternative policies. Section V summarizes the main findings of the paper and presents our
conclusions.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

11. The Relative Economic Condition of America's Children
A. Poverty Rates among Children and the Elderly
~
35
Nearly 13 million American children are currently living in p ~ v e r t y .About
percent of these children are black and at least 20 percent are Hispanic. This translates
into a child poverty rate of nearly one in five overall, two in five for black households, and
more than one in three for Hispanic households.
The 20 percent aggregate child-poverty rate, however, tells us only about the
fraction of children who are poor at a particular point in time. It does not indicate the
percentage of those who were poor in the past or who will be poor in the future. Since
there is considerable mobility of children into and out of states of poverty, one can surmise
that more than 20 percent of American children will experience one or more such spells
before reaching their eighteenth birthday. Indeed, calculations by Ellwood (1988), based
on panel data, indicate that more than one-third of the children born around 1970
experienced some years of poverty before reaching age 10.
As figure 1 shows, childhood poverty has been increasing steadily over the last two
decades. In 1970, only 15 percent of American children were classified as impoverished.
By 1990, that figure had risen to 20 percent. Over the same period, poverty rates
declined among the elderly. In 1970, almost one-quarter of all Americans age 65 h d
older were officially poor. By 1990, that figure had fallen to 12 percent.

2~overty-ratefigures are taken from U.S.Bureau of the Census, Current Population Reports, Series P-60,
No. 168 and earlier reports.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

B. Demoma~hicsand Child Poverty
The difference in poverty trends between the young and old raises the question of

equity in the government's treatment of children vis-A-vis the elderly. However, other
factors clearly seem to be at play, at least as regards higher child poverty rates. One of the
most important of these is the increase in the fraction of American children living with
only one parent. In 1989,73.1 percent of all U.S. children, including 67.0 percent of
Hispanic children and 38.0 percent of black children, lived with both parents. The
respective figures for 1970 were considerably higher at 85.2 percent, 77.7 percent, and

5 8.5 p e r ~ e n t .Not
~ surprisingly, child poverty rates are much greater among single-parent
households than in two-parent households. Currently, almost 50 percent of children living
with one parent are poor, compared to only 10 percent of those living in intact homes. All
told, about two in every three poor children come from single-parent families.
The increase in the fraction of children living with only one parent can be traced to
two factors: the rising divorce rate and the increasing share of children born out of
wedlock. Today, close to 13 percent of Americans age 35 to 44 are divorced, up from 2.9
percent in 1960.4 As a consequence, two children in five now grow up in broken homes.5
Concern about children living in single-parent homes would be mitigated if the absent
partner were a frequent visitor, but quite often this turns out not to be the case.
According to a recent survey, almost one-quarter of divorced fathers had no contact with
their children in the previous five years and another 20 percent had not seen their children
during the preceding year.6
Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1991, table 70, p. 53.
4~usinessWeek,May 20, 1991, p. 76.
5 ~ e Jane
e E. Brody, "Childrenof Divorce: Steps to Help Can Hurt,"The New York Times, July 23,1991.
The 1989 Statistical Abstract of the United States (table 132, p. 87) indicates that in 1985,1.73 percent of
all children age 18 or younger had parents who divorced that year. The comparable percentage for 1970
was 1.25 percent.
6The survey, by Dr. Frank F. Furstenberg, Jr., and his colleagues at the University of Pennsylvania, is
cited in Brody (1991). See footnote 5.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

The increase in the fraction of children born to unmanied women since 1970 is
even more dramatic than the increase in the divorce rate. In 1970,just over 10 percent of
children were born to unwed mothers. By 1990, that figure had topped 25 percent -- an
explosion that transcends race. In the case of whites, the 1970 share of births to unwed
mothers was 6 percent. By 1988, that figure had tripled to 18 percent. For blacks, the
respective figures were 38 and 64 percent.

C. Recent Chan-

the Relative Cowuption J ~ v e lof
s Different Ape G r o w

The increase in childhood poverty relative to that of adults is suggestive of a
general deterioration in the living standards of children vis-a-vis their elders. However,
the evidence is inconclusive for the simple reason that impoverished children are only a
segment of the entire population of children. One way to assess the overall change in the
living standards of children relative to adults is to look at changes over time. To do that,
we look at age-consumption profiles, or the ratio of one agelsex group's average
consumption to that of a reference group. The reference group used here is 40-year-old
males.
The data sources employed in our analysis are the 1972-73 and 1987-90 Survey of
Consumer Expenditures, issued by the Bureau of Labor Statistics. The procedures used
to form average consumption by age and sex for each of the survey periods are described

in detail in Kotlikoff and Sabelhaus (1993). Briefly, expenditures reported in the surveys
were first benchmarked against the National Income and Product Accounts (NIPA) totals
to adjust for under- or overreporting. Next, each household's adjusted expenditures were
distributed to individual household members, producing a data set consisting of individuals
with particular consumption expenditures and particular characteristics. The third step
involved averaging these consumption expenditures across all individuals of a particular
age and sex to obtain the average consumption values for each age/sex category. The last
step entailed adding to these values the age- and sex-specific average amounts of

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

consumption expenditures included in the NlPAs but excluded from the consumer
expenditure surveys. An example is health care expenditures by third-party.insurers,
including the government.
Figures 2 and 3 present the calculated age-consumptionprofiles for 1972-73 and
1987-90 for males and females, respectively. Note that both figures show that in the late
1980s, consumption by the elderly grew relative to that of other age groups, including
children. Young adults -- those between the ages of 20 and 40 -- experienced a
particularly marked decline in their relative levels of consumption.
To obtain a quantitative sense of the amount by which children's consumption has
fallen since the early 1970s relative to that of the elderly, consider the average
consumption among all 10-year-oldsversus that of all 70-year-olds. In 1972-73,
consumption among 10-year-olds averaged 37 percent of the average for 70-year-olds.
By 1987-90, the corresponding level was only 31 percent, a 16 percent drop.
D. Recent Chan~esin the Relative Incomes of Different Age Groups

What explains the recent increase in the elderly's relative consumption? The
answer is that over the past 20 years or so, this group's income has grown much more
rapidly than that of any other age group. Figure 4, reproduced from Boskin, Kotlikoff,
and Knetter (1985), shows the age-income profiles for different age groups over the
1968-84period. Specifically, it plots the ratio of the average income of households
whose heads are in particular age groups divided by the average income of households
whose heads are age 35-44.
Note the sustained increase in the relative income of households age 65 and older
over the period charted. In 1968, income per elderly household averaged 43 percent of
income per household age 35-44. In 1984, this figure was 52 percent, a 21 percent rise
over 16 years. This increase represents an even larger percentage -- 45 percent -- relative

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

to households age 25-34, since, as figure 4 shows, the latter experienced a drop in their
income relative to the 35-44 age group.
If anything, figure 4 is likely to understate the recent growth in the relative income
of the elderly. The reason is that income as defined in the Bodsin study includes only
labor earnings, property income, private pension income, welfare benefits, annuities,
unemployment benefits, and Social Security. It does not include the imputed value of
government-provided health care benefits, such as Medicare and Medicaid.
Figure 5, also from the Boskin study, examines the source of older Americans'
relative income growth. First, it plots the shares of particular types of income received by
the elderly between 1968 and 1984. Second, it plots the ratio of particular types of
income that elderly households received, on average, to the corresponding average for
households age 35-44. Note the rapid growth in the relative Social Security and property
income of the elderly as well as the decline in their relative labor earnings. The latter can

be traced to the elderly's shrinking labor force participation over this period.
111. The Government's Treatment of Children Relative to Other Age Groups
A Point-in-Time Perspective

--

A. Flows of Transfers and Taxes by Age and Sex
The last section documented the decline over the last 20 years in the economic
well-being of children relative to the elderly. This section asks whether the government
(federal, state, and local) has offset or worsened that trend. One way to approach this
question is to consider the taxes paid and the direct transfers received by different age
groups.
To that end, tables 1 and 2 present these values for various age-sex groups for the
years 1970 and 1990. The tables are constructed using cross-section profiles of relative
transfer receipts and tax payments by age and sex in order to distribute aggregate transfers
and taxes according to those two demographic characteristics. As described in Auerbach,

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Gokhale, and Kotlikoff (1991), the cross-section profiles are obtained from various
microdata sets, the most important of which is the Census Bureau's Survey of Income and
Plan Participation. Values for both aggregate transfer receipts and tax payments are
obtained from the NIPAs and include all federal, state, and local government taxes and
transfers. Hence, tables 1 and 2 provide a comprehensive picture of the gross payment
flows that the government made to, and took from, different age-sex groups in 1970 and
1990.
Each of the tables reports, for selected age-sex groups, the group's averpge net
payment, defined as its average tax payment minus its average transfer receipt. The tables
also decompose average tax payments into average labor income tax payments, average
capital income tax payments, average payroll tax payments, and average exciselsales tax
payments. Average transfer receipts are decomposed into average non-Medicare Social
Security benefits (OASDI), average government-provided health care benefits (primarily
Medicare and Medicaid), and average welfare benefits (primarily Aid to Families with
Dependent Children, food stamps, unemployment insurance, and general relief). All
figures are reported in 1991 dollars.7

If one focuses solely on the transfer payments recorded in tables 1 and 2, one sees
that older Americans have benefited much more than have children. For example, in 1970
the average transfer payment made to 70-year-old women was $5,120, while the average
payment to 10-year-old girls was $350. In 1990, the comparable figures were $10,467
and $410. In 1970, the ratio of the average transfer payment to 70-year-old women to
that of 10-year-old girls was 14.6. By 1990, that figure had grown to 25.5.
The elderly do, however, pay out much more in taxes than do children, even if one
imputes sales and excise tax payments to children. For instance, in 1990 the average tax

70ne aspect of the tables that may seem anomalous is the excise tax payments imputed to children. These
taxes represent the payment of sales and excise taxes on goods and services purchased for children by
their parents. Admittedly, a case could be made for imputing these payments to the parents.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

payment was $7,412 for 70-year-old women, but only $799 for 10-year-old girls. If one
subtracts these transfers from the taxes paid, the resulting net payment figures still show
an enormous difference in the flow of income from the government to the elderly versus
children.
B. Flows of Age-Related Government Services
The flows of transfers and taxes just considered do not provide a complete picture
of the annual flow of economic resources between the government and the private sector.
The main omission is the flow of services provided directly by the government as a
consequence of its purchases of goods and services. These services are wide-ranging and
include items such as the protection afforded by national defense spending, reduction of
travel time and transportation costs arising fiom federal, state, and local road systems,
provision of public education, and the general knowledge that has filtered down from the
space program. Unfortunately, with the exception of educational expenditures (which in
the main benefit children), government purchases consist of public goods, whose
advantages cannot be ascribed to particular generations or groups within generations.
Be that as it may, educational expenditures are still worth considering because they
are so large. In 1990, combined education purchases for elementary education by federal,
state, and local governments totaled $220 billion in 1991dollars -- nearly equaling the

amount spent on that year's total Social Security retirement and survivor benefits. If we
divide that $220 billion by the 72.3 million children alive in 1990, we arrive at a per child
educational expenditure level of $3,042, which swamps the average level of transfer
payments children received that year. The comparable calculation for 1970 leads to an
average educational expenditure of $1,785 per child (again measured in 1991 dollars).
These figures indicate several things. First, they show that educational
expenditures far outweigh direct transfer payments as a means of providing assistance to
children. Second, they reveal that since 1970, there has been a dramatic increase (70

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

percent) in real spending per elementary school-age child. Third, they indicate that even if
one adds to current per-child transfer payments today's historically high real spending per
child on education, the government's total payment flow to children is still considerably
smaller than the per capita transfers received by the elderly. This is true whether the
calculations are net or gross of tax payments by the elderly.

In sum, if one ignores the fact that children and the elderly are at different stages of
their life cycles -- and thus can be expected to receive different treatment by the
government -- one can make a strong case that children are getting the short end of the
stick.

IV. The Government's Treatment of Children Relative to Other Age Groups
A Lifetime Perspective

--

While the flow figures are striking, ignoring the fact that children and the elderly

are at different stages of their life cycles seems clearly inappropriate. Does it make sense,
for example, to claim that the current elderly are being treated better than current children
because they generally receive large Social Security benefits? Such an assertion ignores,
among other things, the fact that the current elderly did not receive much in the way of
Social Security benefits when they were children, and that today's children will receive
larger Social Security benefits when they are old.
By controlling for the life cycle, generational accounts can help us to assess the
true degree of generational equity underlying government policy. Generational accounts
indicate, in present value, the average net taxes that members of a generation can expect
to pay over their remaining lives. The generational account at birth of a given cohort is
particularly interesting, as it indicates the average present value of the net taxes the
generation's members will pay to the government over their entire life spans. Such lifetime
accounts can be used to compare the government's treatment of different generations,

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

since all taxes and transfers taken from or paid to a generation over each stage of its life
cycle are included.

In discounting taxes and transfers back to the year a generation is born, lifetime
generational accounts place a smaller weight on taxes paid and transfers received at later
stages of the life cycle. This makes sense because a dollar of taxes paid in the future is
less painful (in economic terms) than a dollar paid in the present, and a dollar of transfers
received in the future is less valuable than a dollar received in the present. In discounting
each generation's life cycle of tax payments and transfer receipts back to age zero, lifetime
generational accounts in effect produce a single lifetime net tax bill that each generation
faces upon birth.
B. What Constitutes Generationally Equitable Fiscal Policv?
In considering which cross-generation pattern of lifetime generational accounts

constitutes equitable lifetime treatment of different generations, it may help to start by
taking the simple case of an economy in which all members of a given generation are
identical, productivity and population growth rates are zero, and the government
purchases no goods or services. In such a world, taxes and transfers would be used only

to redistribute wealth across generations. What would an equitable lifetime treatment of
different generations entail in such an economy? If we interpret equity to mean treating
each generation identically, then an equitable policy would require setting the lifetime
generational accounts of each generation to zero.
To understand this requirement, suppose, to the contrary, that the government
decides to make the lifetime generational account of a particular generation negative, i.e.,
it wants to provide net transfers to a particular generation. Since this largess would have
to be paid for by some other generations, the government's decision would necessitate
making their lifetime generational accounts positive. Consequently, only zero lifetime

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

generational accounts are consistent with equal treatment of all generations given the
circumstances we have assumed.
This notion of equity -- that each cohort's lifetime generational account should
equal zero -- carries over to the case in which both government purchases and
productivity growth are zero, but there is positive population growth. In this scenario,
future generations are obviously more numerous, but setting each one's lifetime account to
zero ensures that members of each generation will bear the same fiscal burden -- namely,
zero.
Now let's add government purchases to our hypothetical economy, but assume that
these are of no value to any generation. In this case, equitable treatment would mandate
setting each generation's lifetime account to the same positive value, where this amount is
determined such that the present value of all lifetime generational accounts of all current
and future generations pays for the present value of government purchases.
Next take the case where government purchases do provide services of positive
value to some earlier generations, but where all such purchases occurred in the past.
Further, suppose that the generations who received these benefits were not required to pay
for them. This means that existing and future generations would have to pick up the tab.g
Equity in this context again mandates setting each current and future generation's lifetime
account equal to the same positive value -- once again the amount needed to pay off, in
present value, the bill these generations inherit collectively. The same situation would
arise if the bill bequeathed to current and future generations were not for past government
services enjoyed by older generations, but rather for past net transfers made to them.9
gThkbill might, for example, be presented to current and future generations in the form of official
government debt.
gThe initiation of an unfunded "pay-as-you-go" Social Security system is one example of a situation in
which current and future generations are forced to pay for tmufers to a previous generation, namely, the
one that is old when the system is initiated. This start-up generation receives Social Security benefits
without ever having paid Social Security taxes. As a consequence, later generations are forced, when
young, to make contributions to a system that provides them with less old-age income than they would
have earned had they been free to invest that money privately. The lower-than-market rate of retum that

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Finally, suppose government purchases do provide services of value to current as
well as future generations. Here, equitable government policy would involve 1) providing
each generation with the same level of services, and 2) making each generation pay the
same amount for these services (i.e., setting the lifetime accounts of all generations at the
same positive amount needed to cover, in present value, the government's spending).
Thus far, we have argued that generationally equitable fiscal policy entails equal
lifetime accounts for all generations. But this prescription becomes less clear once we
alter our assumptions to include positive productivity growth. In this case, generations
born in the future will have higher lifetime incomes than those currently alive. If
government policy is intended to equalize the welfare of all generations, it must find a
means to redistribute, on an ongoing basis, from as-yet unborn generations toward those
currently alive. As suggested above, the available mechanism is to set the lifetime
accounts of earlier generations at lower values (not necessarily positive values) than those
of later generations. As can easily be shown, such a policy requires the government to set
successive generations' lifetime accounts equal to a larger and larger fraction of their
lifetime incomes. In other words, the lifetime tax rate, or the ratio of a generation's
lifetime account to the present value of the income it earns over its entire life span, must
approach 100 percent asymptotically. lo
While positive productivity growth coupled with the goal of equalizing each
generation's after-tax lifetime income means that today's children should face higher
lifetime tax rates than today's adults, including the current elderly, the goal of perfect
equality of welfare across generations is not sacrosanct. Society may view different
intergenerational distributions of after-tax income as equitable, even though these do not
-

-

Social Security pays on contributions is the means by which current and future generations are forced to
pay for the free benefits received by the start-up generation of elderly.
losuppose that each generation's income grows at rate g. Then the tax rate required to equalize the aftertax lifetime incomes of each generation is 1 - [r/(r-g)] / ( I + ~ )where
~ , r is the rate of interest and t indexes
the year the generation is born. This formula assumes that a generation'sincome is independent of the tax
rate it faces.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

entail perfect equality of after-tax lifetime income. For example, society may consider the
higher levels of productivity that future generations will enjoy as their natural inheritance.
Under this view, equitable fiscal treatment of different generations requires each to pay the
same share of its lifetime income to finance expenditures on public goods and services as
well as past transfers to now-deceased generations. Such equal proportional s d i c e
means, of course, that each generation should face the same lifetime tax rate.

C. Lifetime Tax Rates of Americans Born since 1900
Ultimately, the cross-generational distribution of lifetime accounts that constitutes

an equitable distribution is a value judgment that cannot be resolved by economists or any
other social scientists. What economists can do is to help society think through its
decision and to show what generational lifetime net tax policy is actually in place.
Hopefully, the above discussion has contributed to accomplishing the first task. The
second task -- understanding actual U.S. generational policy -- is addressed in table 3,
which shows the lifetime net tax rates of generations of American males and females born
since 1900.
Lifetime net tax rates are defined here as a generation's lifetime generational
account (the age-zero present value of the average net taxes its members pay in each year
of their remaining life) divided by the present value of the generation's lifetime labor
income. As described in appendix I, section F of Budget Baselines, Historical Data, and

Alternatives for the Future (Office and Management and Budget [January 1993]), lifetime
net tax rates are based on estimates of actual taxes paid and transfers received between
1900 and 1991 as well as on projections of future taxes and transfers.ll Lifetime income
is defined as the present value of pre-tax lifetime labor income. Ideally, one would include

l l ~ h i part
s of the current paper draws heavily on that work, which was written by Alan J. Auerbach,
Jagadeesh Gokhale, Laurence J. Kotlikoff, and several OMB staff members. The principal OMB author
was Robert Kilpatrick.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

the present value of anticipated inheritances in forming lifetime income, but unfortunately,
that information is not available.
The lifetime net tax rate for males begins at 17.8 percent for those born in 1900
and rises to 33.9 percent for those born in 1991. The corresponding figures for females
exhibit a quite different pattern. For them, the rate starts at 35.3 percent, declines on
average for about 50 years, then rises slightly, leaving a 1991 value of 32.8 percent. The
high initial rate for females can be traced to two factors. First, the present value of labor
earnings for women born in the early part of the century is low. Second, in allocating
taxes between the sexes, we attribute certain types equally to husbands and wives (excise
taxes, for example). Hence, women born in the early 1900s have low lifetime incomes,
but are imputed with relatively high tax payments. For females born in the postwar
period, the absolute size of their lifetime net tax bills is higher, but due to the increase in
female labor force participation, so too is their lifetime labor income. This explains why
lifetime tax rates for females born in the postwar period are below those of women born
around the turn of the century.
Since the allocation of taxes between husbands and wives within marriages is,
admittedly, somewhat arbitrary, table 3 also reports lifetime net tax rates for males and
females together, calculated as a weighted average of the net tax rate for each sex. Note
that in this case the average net tax rate rises significantly over time, from 21.5 percent for
the generation born in 1900 to 33.5 percent for the generation born in 1991.
Table 3 also reports gross tax and transfer rates. To calculate these, the present
value of a generation's lifetime taxes (or transfers) is divided by the present value of its
labor income. This breakdown reveals the growth of government transfer payments
during this century. The lifetime transfer rate for males and females taken together nearly
quadrupled between 1900 and 1991, rising from 3.3 percent to 12.2 percent. The increase
was more rapid, in both relative and absolute terms, for those generations born before
World War 11 than for those born afterward.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Because of the need to pay for the higher gross transfers as well as government
purchases, the gross tax rate has also risen markedly in the past two decades. This is in
contrast to the net tax rate, which has stayed fairly constant. The gross tax rate for males
and females together is 24.8 percent for the generation born in 1900 versus 45.8 percent
for the generation born in 1991.
of Future Generations Based on Current-Semce~
D. m e Lifmme
. .
. . ' Net .Tax
. Rate
oiecQonsof E ~ ~ & D
Gene
P rabons Net Tax C o n t n m
'

1

The only figures in table 3 that have not yet been discussed are the lifetime net tax
rates to be paid by future generations. These rates are derived assuming a currentservices projection of the future fiscal treatment of existing generations. Specifically, we
add together the remaining (as opposed to lifetime) generational accounts of all existing
generations to arrive at the collective net tax contribution they will have to make to pay
off the government's existing net debt (gross debt minus gross assets) as well as the
present value of its future purchases. By subtracting this contribution from the sum of the
government's net debt and the present value of its purchases, we arrive at the presentvalue amount that future generations will have to pay collectively if current fiscal policies
are maintained.
We transform the aggregate present-value fiscal burden to be imposed on future
generations into a per capita amount by factoring in projections of future population
growth and then assuming that each person born in the future pays the same amount after
adjustment for economic growth. The growth adjustment assumes that, on average,
members of each successive generation pay l+g times the average amount paid by
members of the previous generation, where g is the assumed rate of growth. The amount
future generations will pay over their lifetimes divided by their projected future lifetime
income provides our estimate of their lifetime net tax rate.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

As indicated in table 3, unless either existing Americans are made to pay more on
net over their remaining years or government purchases are reduced, future citizens will be
faced with lifetime net tax rates of 7 1percent -- more than twice the rate projected for
those born in 1991 (again based on current services). Of course, the assumption that
existing generations, including those born in 1991, will pay no more than the amount
suggested by current-services projections is just that -- an assumption. It is made not
because it mirrors reality, but rather to illustrate the extent of the imbalance in U.S.
generational policy. As we discuss in the next subsection, other assumptions about the
evolution of future U.S. fiscal policy, specifically those that place a larger burden on
existing generations, lead to lower lifetime net tax rates for future generations, albeit at the
price of higher rates for those currently living, particularly today's children.
E. Generational Accounting's Me-

about the Demee of Eauity in U.S,

The figures in table 3 indicate that current American children will be burdened
with much higher lifetime net tax rates than the current elderly. The generation born in

1991, for example, could face a 27 percent larger lifetime net tax rate than that facing
Americans born in 1920. This projected discrepancy would be ~ i ~ c a n texacerbated
ly
by any change in U.S. fiscal policy aimed at preventing future generations from paying
more than 70 percent of their lifetime income to the government.
Table 4 illustrates two such changes. The first involves capping federal spending
between 1993 and 2004 for all mandatory programs except Social Security and federal
deposit insurance. Medicare and Medicaid are the two programs that would see the
largest cuts relative to their baseline, current-services projections. The second policy is a
surtax on the federal individual income tax that would extend over the same years as the
cap and that would produce, on a year-by-year basis, the same federal deficit reduction.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Both of these plans would dramatically lower the lifetime net tax rates of future
generations. Under the mandatory cap, future Americans would pay only 41 percent of
their lifetime income to the government; under the surtax, they would pay 46 percent.
However, while both of these means of bringing U.S. generational policy into closer
balance would be applauded by future generations, current generations would be less
enthusiastic. Take the surtax, for example. Children born in 1991 would be forced to pay
40 percent of their lifetime earnings to the government, rather than 34 percent, the

current-services figure. The mandatory cap and surtax policies would also raise the
lifetime net tax rate of today's elderly, although by much less, since the changes in net
taxes during their remaining years are small when discounted back to the years these
generations were born. In the case of the surtax, there is a 53 percent difference in the
lifetime net tax rates of children born in 1991 versus the generation born in 1920.
Is it fair that today's children may have to hand over more than 40 percent of their
lifetime income to the government, while their grandparents will end up paying just onequarter of theirs? The answer depends on several factors. First, today's children will, it
appears, receive more services in the form of educational expenditures and public goods
over their lifetimes than did their elders. Second, certain types of contributions made by
today's elderly, such as their participation in World War I1 or their suffering through the
Great Depression, are not factored into our analysis. Consideration of these special
contributions might suggest that a lower lifetime tax rate for the current elderly is in order.
Third, the steep increase in lifetime tax rates may be justified to the extent that society's
notion of generational equity entails equalizing the after-tax lifetime earnings of current
and future generations.
If, however, society's idea of generational fairness means extracting an equal
proportional sacrifice from every generation, then the numbers in tables 3 and 4 must be
viewed (ignoring differences in public goods and special contributions) as highly
discomforting. They show a trajectory of U.S. generational policy that will force today's

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

children to bear a much larger burden than today's elderly ever had to (or ever will have
to). And the picture for tomorrow's children is even bleaker.
Regardless of how one views the numbers in tables 3 and 4, it is worth pointing
out that they probably understate the generational differences in economic well-being
generated by U.S. fiscal policy. The reason is that they do not take into account what
economists call general equilibrium fleets onfactor prices. In adopting the generational
policy identified in table 3, the U.S. government has permitted earlier generations to
consume more over their lifetimes than would otherwise have been the case. The
argument for this policy was that every dollar the government allowed these generations
to keep meant another dollar available to finance additional consumption. By consuming
more, however, these generations have also lowered total U.S. saving (see Gokhale
[1993]). While there are certainly other factors at play in explaining the recent drop-off in
U.S. saving rates, generational policy is surely a prime contributor. The United States is
now saving at record low rates. In 1991, for example, Americans put away only 1.7
percent of their earnings, dramatically lower than the almost 9 percent rate observed, on
average, between 1950 and 1969.
Lower saving means lower investment, which in turn means that the U.S. capital
stock will grow at a slower rate than the work force. Since labor productivity depends on
the amount of capital available per worker, and since real U.S. wages reflect the nation's
labor productivity, the decline in saving is responsible for lowering real wage growth. It is
also responsible for raising the real return to capital, since it has made capital scarce
relative to labor, the other factor of production. Those who have been most harmed by
slower real wage growth are today's young and middle-aged workers, who have seen their
real hourly pay pick up very slowly over the past two decades. If the low rate of U.S.
saving continues, today's children will also experience minimal growth in their real wages
once they enter the work force. Since the late 1970s, on the other hand, the real return to

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

capital has been quite high. This is an important point because the foremost beneficiaries
have been today's elderly, the primary holders of U.S. capital over the last 20 years.
While simulation studies of stylized economies, such as Auerbach and Kotlikoff

(1987),have shown that policy-induced general equilibrium changes in factor prices occur
slowly over time, they have also demonstrated that such changes can be of fitst-order
importance in redistributing across generations. Thus, if one were able to factor in these
feedback effects reliably, the difference in the treatment of today's elderly versus today's
children would likely be greatly accentuated.

V. Conclusion
This paper has examined a variety of evidence, all of which points to a deterioration in
the standard of living of American children relative to adults, particularly the current
elderly. Our findings indicate a rapid increase in the lifetime net tax rates of Americans
born over the course of this century. Those born at the turn of the century can expect to
pay just over a fifth of their lifetime income to the government; for those born at the
beginning of the next century, that figure is likely to swell to well over one-half.
Does this considerable disparity in the lifetime net tax rates of different generations
imply that U.S. fiscal policy is generationally unsound? The answer depends on society's
notion of generational equity, on how the special contributions of particular generations
are assessed, and on the level of benefits being provided to different generations as a result
of the government's purchases of goods and services. If society believes that generational
equity entails, other things being equal, the same proportional net tax sacrifice

from each

generation, then there is no question that the federal government's treatment of today's and
tomorrow's children relative to the current elderly is highly inequitable.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

References
Auerbach, Alan J. Dynamic Fiscal Policy. New York: Cambridge University Press,
1987.

,Jagadeesh Gokhale, and Laurence J. Kotlikoff. "Generational Accounts:
A Meaningful Alternative to Deficit Accounting," in David Bradford, ed., Tax
Policy and the Economy, vol. 5. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1991, pp.
55- 110.
Boskin, Michael J., Laurence J. Kotlikoff, and Michael Knetter. "Changes in the Age
Distribution of Income in the United States, 1968-1984," Working Paper No. 58,
Stanford University, Center for Economic Policy Research, October 1985.
Ellwood, David T. Poor Support: Poverty in the American Family. New York: Basic
Books, 1988.
Gokhale, Jagadeesh. "The Decline in U.S. Saving Rates: A Cause for Concern?"
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Commentary, September 15, 1993.
Kotlikoff, Laurence J. Generational Accounting: Knowing Who Pays and Whenfor
What We Spend. New York: The Free Press, 1992.

,and John Sabelhaus. "Whose Consumption Has Increased?" The Urban
Institute, rnimeo, January 1993.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Table 1
Flow of Transfers and Taxes t o Different Generations in 1970
Males
Net
Payment
-48
55
160
213
3,3 95
10,417
13,658
15,627
14,686
3,5 70
-2 16
469

Tax Pavments
Labor Capital Payroll
Income Income
Taxes
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
1,204
95
915
3,996
1,562
3,038
4,382
4,170
3,331
4,016
6,645
3,053
3,100
7,621
2,357
581
6,547
442
4,590
124
94
4,073
0
0

Transfer Receipts
Excise
Taxes
3 03
407
513
672
1,502
2,327
2,299
2,523
2,411
1,771
1,312
1,342

OASDIa
5
48
110
225
103
34
79
175
398
4,369
4,490
3,219

Health
47
22
21
44
44
146
146
147
147
1,177
1,591
1,721

Welfare
298
280
220
188
175
325
299
288
258
223
255
5

Females
Net
Pavment
- 1 19
49
166
190
2,293
3,351
4,705
6,552
6,673
605
-649
,2,085

Tax Payments
Labor Capital Payroll
Income Income
Taxes
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
789
600
290
644
847
1,004
1,346
763
1,138
2,607
865
922
3,465
70 1
160
3,490
121
32
2,669
25
0
0
27 1

aOld-age and survivors disability insurance.
Source: Authors' calculations.

Transfer Receipts
Excise
Taxes
301
409
5 18
676
1,391
2,071
2,035
2,392
2,2 10
1,954
1,616
1,567

OASDIa Health
5
42
48
19
109
17
223
43
99
43
26
58
69
58
129
121
369
121
3,840
1,160
3,269
1,594
2,025
1,767

Welfare
3 73
29 1
224
218
344
4 17
316
201
136
120
128
129

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Table 2
Flow of Transfers and Taxes t o Different Generations in 1990
Males
Net
Payment
10
164
330
4 10
3,987
12,082
18,656
22,194
19,237
96 1
-4,246
-4,373

Tax Payments
Labor Capital Payroll Excise
Income Income
Taxes Taxes
0
0
0
460
0
0
0
565
0
0
0
750
0
0
0
1,044
133
1,317
1,712
1,204
2,176
4,463
2,353
4,080
5,386
5,808
5,890
2,648
5,357
9,256
5,858
2,932
3,558
10,616
3,891
2,838
9 , l 19
564
2,563
5 15
177
6,393
194
2,206
5,673
0
0
1,659

Transfer Receipts
OASDIa Health
5
160
57
77
139
71
289
151
12
151
75
495
181
495
330
496
795
496
3,68 1
7,725
7,797
4,973
6,297
5,387

Welfare
2 83
265
209
193
2 17
420
400
382
374
3 93
445
21

Females
Net
Payment
-59
195
388
437
2,697
6,099
8,65 1
9,745
8,758
-3,055
-6,209
-9,273

Labor
Income
0
0
0
0
870
2,178
2,464
2,028
1,259
167
52
0

Tax Payments
Capital Payroll Excise
Income
Taxes Taxes
0
0
444
0
0
595
0
0
799
0
0
1,050
952
0
1,561
405
2,382
2,075
1,875
2,695
2,451
3,632
2,218
2,760
4,826
1,377
2,579
4,862
182
2,201
3,717
57
1,685
377
0
1,574

aOld-age and survivors disability insurance.
Source: Authors' calculations.

Transfer Receipts
OASDIa
5
57
139
288
11
50
116
166
65 8
6,625
6,502
5,442

Health
143
66
58
146
146
197
197
408
408
3,622
4,985
5,545

Welfare
354
276
2 13
207
528
694
52 1
319
2 17
220
23 3
237

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Table 3
Lifetime Net Tax Rates for Generations Born since 1900

Year
Generation
Was Born
1900
1910
1920
1930
1940
1950
1960
1970
1980
1990
1991
Future
Generations

Net
Tax
Rate
17.8
21.8
24.2
26.4
28.2
30.6
32.3
33.6
34.1
33.9
33.9

Males
Gross
Gross
Tax Transfer
Rate
Rate
19.6
1.8
24.6
2.8
27.7
3.5
30.5
4.1
33.0
4.8
36.8
6.2
39.6
7.2
41.7
8.1
42.4
8.3
42.7
8.7
42.7
8.8

Source: Authors' calculations.

Net
Tax
Rate
35.3
35.7
34.0
34.4
32.7
30.6
31.5
32.5
33.1
32.9
32.8

Females
Gross
Gross
Tax
Transfer
Rate
Rate
43.9
8.7
49.6
13.9
50.4
16.5
52.8
18.5
50.6
17.9
46.9
16.3
47.9
16.4
50.3
17.8
51.6
18.5
52.0
19.1
52.0
19.2

Net
Tax
Rate
21.5
24.7
26.3
28.1
29.3
30.6
32.1
33.2
33.8
33.6
33.5

Males & Females
Combined
Gross
Gross
Tax Transfer
Rate
Rate
24.8
3.3
29.8
5.2
32.5
6.2
35.3
7.2
37.3
8.0
39.9
9.3
42.3
10.2
11.3
44.5
45.5
11.7
45.7
12.2
45.8
12.2

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

Table 4
Lifetime Net Tax Rates for Generations Born since 1900:
Baseline Case, Mandatory Caps on Entitlements, and Income Tax Surtax
Females

Males
Year
Generation
Was Born
1900
1910
1920
1930
1940
1950
1960
1970
1980
1990
1991
Future
Generations

Baseline
17.8
21.8
24.2
26.4
28.2
30.6
32.3
33.6
34.1
33.9
33.9

Caps
17.8
21.8
24.4
26.8
28.9
31.5
33.6
35.3
36.5
36.6
3 6.6

Source: Authors' calculations.

Males & Females
Combined

Surtax
17.8
21.8
24.3
26.4
28.5
31.6
34.6
37.6
39.9
40.7
40.8

Baseline
35.3
3 5.7
34.0
34.4
32.7
30.6
31.5
32.5
33.1
32.9
32.8

Caps
35.3
35.9
34.8
36.5
35.2
32.9
34.2
3 5.7
37.0
37.4
37.3

Surtax
35.3
35.7
34.0
34.5
33.2
3 1.5
33.5
35.9
38.2
39.0
39.1

Baseline
21.5
24.7
26.3
28.1
29.3
30.6
32.1
33.2
33.8
33.6
33.5

Caps
21.5
24.7
26.6
28.9
30.4
31.9
33.8
35.4
36.6
36.9
36.9

Surtax
21.5
24.7
26.3
28.2
29.7
31.6
34.2
37.1
39.3
40.2
40.2

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

FIGURE 1: POVERTY RATES, 1959-90

Percent

Source: U.S. Census Bureau, Current Population Reports.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

FIGURE 2: RELATIVE CONSUMPTION PROFILES, MALES

Age Group
Sources: Consumer Expenditure Surveys, 1972-73 and 1984-89; and National
Income and Product Accounts.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

FIGURE 3: RELATIVE CONSUMPTION PROFILES, FEMALES

Ratio to 40-Year-Old Males

Age Group
Sources: Consumer Expenditure Surveys, 1972-73and 1984-89; and National
Income and Product Accounts.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

FIGURE 4: RATIO OF INCOME PER HOUSEHOLD TO INCOME
PER HOUSEHOLD OF 35 TO 44 YEAR-OLD AGE GROUP
Ratio

Age Group

1 .I4
1.10
1.06

45-54

1.02
0.98
0.94
0.90

55-64

0.86
0.82
0.78
0.74
25-34
0.70
0.66
0.62
0.58
6%

0.54
0.50
0.46
0.42
0.38

15-24

0.34

I
1968

I
1970

I
1972

1974

I

I

I

I

1976

1978

1980

1982

Source: Boskin, Kotlikoff, and Knetter (1985).

>

1984

http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/Workpaper/Index.cfm

--

FIGURE 5: HOUSEHOLDS 65 AND OVER SHARE OF INCOME AND
MAJOR COMPONENTS OF INCOME, AND RATIO OF PER
HOUSEHOLD INCOME AND MAJOR COMPONENTS TO 35 TO
44 YEAR-OLD AGE GROUP
Grour, Total per Household
35-44 Total per Household (dashed lines)

Group share of total (solid lines)

1

Social Security Income

Property Income
I

Total Income
0.06

- --

---

-

---. .

--.

0.05

0.20

--

0.04

Labor Earnings

Source: Boskin, Kotlikoff, and Knetter (1985).

0.1 6