View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Workinn Paper 9115

ON THE ECONOMETRICS OF WORLD BUSINESS CYCLES
by Finn E. Kydland

Finn E. Kydland is a professor of economics at
Carnegie-Mellon University, Pittsburgh,
Pennsylvania. This paper was written
while he was a visiting scholar at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
Working papers of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland are preliminary materials circulated
to stimulate discussion and critical comment.
The views stated herein are those of the
author and not necessarily those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System.

October 1991

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Introduction
Over the past 10 or 15 years, academic interest in business cycles has
recovered to a level not matched perhaps since the 1930s.

In his editorial

statement in the first issue of Econometric8 in 1933, Ragnar Frisch not only
introduced a new word, econometrics, which he defined as quantitative economic theory, but also listed business cycle theory among four fields of particular interest to econometricians.

This inclusion reflected the views not

only of Frisch, but also of Hayek (1931). Tinbergen (1935), and others. This
interest waned, however, in the 1950s and 1960s.

A major factor leading to

its reawakening was the paper by Robert Lucas (1977) on "Understanding Business Cycles."

Perhaps this course of events was not surprising.

A prerequi-

site for making much progress in this field was dynamic general equilibrium
theory.

By the 1970s, the basic theory had been developed, and neoclassical

growth theory evolved as the dominant framework for business cycle analysis.
Most of the business cycle research has been conducted within closedeconomy frameworks.

Only recently has the focus started to shift toward

international model environments.

In the next section, I describe briefly

the econometrics of the general equilibrium approach to business cycles.

1

The following section includes two applications to international questions.
The final section provides a brief summary.

The Econometric Au~roach
Central to the econometric approach are the computational experiments.
Leading up to these experiments are three steps.

The first is a clear state-

A' more extensive discussion of the econometric approach is
Prescott (1991b).

in Kydland

and

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

ment of the question to be addressed.

For example, some of the recent busi-

ness cycle literature asks how much of the variation in postwar U.S. aggregate economic activity would have remained if technology shocks, also called
Solow (1957) residuals, were the only source of fluctuation.

In business

cycle theory, questions about the source of impulse are, of course, standard.
This phrasing of the question leaves open the possibility that the contributions from different sources may interact.
The next step is to choose a model economy with a bearing on the question at hand.

Other considerations in the model selection are tractability

and computability.

If existing tools overly constrain the freedom to analyze

a suitable model economy, then, of course, the development of new methodology
is needed.

The main point is that model-economy selection depends on the

question being asked and not on the answer.
The model economy must be calibrated.

Unlike the system-of-equations

approach to macroeconomics, under which the parameters are the coefficients
of behavioral equations and are estimated using the data series whose behavior the researcher is studying, the approach here is to determine parameter
values on the basis of non-business-cycle measurements.

The parameters are

those of preferences, technology, information structure, and institutional
arrangements.

For example, with constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES)

functional forms for preferences and technology, there are share parameters
and elasticity parameters.

The former generally follow from average rela-

tions between aggregates that change little from one cycle to another.

These

relations may follow from national income and product accounts data or from
panel data.

Values of elasticity parameters sometimes are implied by dramat-

ic experiments provided by history, such as a change in relative quantities
'-

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

(or the absence thereof) associated with a large change in relative prices.
In some cases, the necessary experiment or information is not yet available
to the researcher.

Before a new parameter is introduced, however, it ought

to be evident that,' at least in principle, it can be measured.
The parameters should not be chosen so as to produce the best fit of the
model to the business cycle data. The goal is to provide the clearest possible answer to the question.

In some cases, deviations of the theory from the

data even provide independent verification of the answer.
Kydland and Prescott (1991a. p. 791).

(See, for example,

Moreover, given the simplicity of

abstractions, some discrepancies or anomalies will remain. Attempting to fit
the model to the data is not helpful in making the anomalies stand out as
clearly as possible, providing motivation for further research.
If all parameters could be accurately calibrated, then in principle only
one computational experiment would be needed:..

In practice, however, the

researcher will not have access to that much information.
additional experiments, with different parameter values
range, may be useful.

Consequently, some
in a reasonable

These experiments may tell us either of two things.

One possibility is that the answer is not sensitive to different values of a
given parameter, in which case its measurement is not urgent. Alternatively,
if the answer is indeed sensitive to values of an imprecisely measured parameter, then efforts directed toward its measurement could have considerable
payoff.
The description of the findings could include a summary of the outcomes
of the experiments along with a quantitative assessment of the precision with
which the question has been answered.

For example, in answer to the question

about the role of technology shocks for the cycle, Kydland and Prescott
'-.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

(1991a) estimate that Solow residuals have accounted for about 70 percent of
U.S. business cycle fluctuations since the Korean War.

The numerical answer

to the research question, of course, is dependent on the model.

The degree

of confidence in the answer depends on the degree of confidence placed in the
economic theory being used and in the underlying measurements.

b ~ ~ l i c a t i o nto
s

International Business Cvcles

In using the neoclassical growth paradigm for addressing international
business cycle questions, several problems arise.
on two.

Here, I shall concentrate

First, with technology shocks as a major impulse, one must allow for

the possibility that Solow residuals in different countries interact somehow.
There are at least two basic ways in which that can happen.
technology innovations are correlated across countries.

One is that

Another is that an

innovation in either country over time spills over to other countries.

This

suggests the estimation of interrelated technology-shock processes.
A related issue is that the data needed for computing Solow residuals in
different countries may not be consistent.

Most countries have collected

quarterly data for substantially shorter periods than has the United States.
Moreover, the quality of either the output or the input data may be questionable.

Most countries do not report quarterly capital-stock data.

The exper-

ience from the United States, however, suggests that omitting the capital
input makes little difference for the measurement of Solow residuals.
may be two reasons:

There

First, the capital stock fluctuates relatively little;

and second, its cyclical behavior is essentially uncorrelated with that of
output.

The case of the labor input could be more serious, however.

countries have not collected comprehensive hours-per-worker data.
8 -

Many

In the

-

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

United States, roughly one-third of the total hours variation takes this
form. For now, however, we make do with employment data.
The second problem relates to the need for relaxing the assumption of
homogeneous goods. Examples of relevant classifications of goods are traded
versus nontraded goods and consumption versus investment goods. A difficulty
is that, with .most potentially useful classifications, large quantities of
the same class of goods are simultaneously being shipped in both directions
between any pair of countries or group of countries.
The Role of International Borrowing

A natural question to ask is whether a significant bias exists when the
role of technology shocks is estimated from closed-economy models. A missing
feature, then, is the possibility of shifting resources to the country with
relatively high technology.

At

the same time, risk-sharing in the form of

borrowing or lending through international trade theoretically may make the
consumption paths quite similar.

Indeed, one can construct simple multi-

country economies in which the consumption paths are perfectly correlated
while the output paths are not.

This result would not hold with leisure

entering preferences in a nonseparable way, and other model features as well
could modify the result.

A

question is, then, whether allowing for world

trade affects the quantitative estimate of the role of technology shocks.
Presumably, this question could be. asked while maintaining a framework of
only one traded good, so that one would not need to take a stand on the
second problem mentioned at the beginning of this section.

This is what

Backus, Kehoe, and Kydland (1991a) set out to do.
Experiments with a calibrated two-country economy based on estimated
technology-shock processes with spillover effects demonstrated anomalies of
'-

-

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

such magnitude relative to the data that the original question could not
reasonably be asked in this simple extension-of the closed-economy framework.
The theoretical flow of resources across borders simply responded too much to
productivity differences, while too much risk-sharing was taking place.

In

the data for the United States versus almost any other major country, the
correlation between consumption in the two countries is about the same or
lower than the correlation between the two countries' outputs. In the model,
the consumption correlation was much too large. Consequently, we shifted our
focus to asking what salient features of international data would be consistent with a simple real business cycle theory and how robust the anomalies are
to parameter variation within reasonable ranges. It turns out, for example,
that the consumption anomaly remains if a transport cost or tariff is introduced that slows down international trade.

In fact, with the estimated

spillover effects, it remains even with absolutely no trade.
Why I s There a J-Curve?

Some devaluation studies have shown that the trade balance initially
moves against the devaluing country, but then, after a few quarters, improves
steadily. This pattern over time resembles a tilted J, and hence its name.
Attempts at an explanation tend to focus on various sources of inertia, such
as import quantities being slow to respond to price changes, perhaps because
of delivery lags or costs of changing suppliers.

More generally, if we plot

the correlation coefficient between contemporaneous terms of trade and leads
and lags of the trade balance, the picture for most major countries also
looks like a tilted J. The example of the U.K. in Figure 1 is typllcal. The
question asked in Backus, Kehoe, and Kydland (1991b) is whether this pattern
can be reconciled with a general equilibrium framework in which technology
*-

-

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

shocks are a major source of fluctuations.
To have a theoretical concept of terms of. trade, one obviously needs at
least two traded goods. This means that one is faced with the second problem
mentioned at the beginning of this section. In embarking on this project, we
did not feel we had the information required to use trade classifications
such as consumption versus investment goods.
Tesar [1991]).

(See, however, Stockman and

Instead, we adopted a modeling approach with a long tradition

in computable models in international trade.
(1969) assumption.

We made use of the Armington

Following him, home-produced goods simply are assumed to

be different from foreign-produced goods. Domestic goods need at least some
imported goods to be useful. Thus, omitting time subscripts, one can write
c1 + x1

=

C2 + X2 =

G(al, bl)

and

G(b2, a2),

where ci and x are consumption and investment in country i, i-1,2; and a
i
i
and b

i

are the quantities of the home- and foreign-produced goods, respec-

tively, used in country i. These quantities are constrained by
al + a2

- F(kl , nl)

b1 + b2

- F(k2.

and

n2i,

where k and n are the capital and labor inputs in country i. Using a CES
i
i
function for the aggregator function, G I the share parameters follow from
average import or export shares, leaving the elasticity of substitution to be
determined.

Whalley (1985) cites dozens of studies at various levels of
-

aggregation that have produced estimates of this elasticity. Generally, they
are larger than one, with a central tendency toward 1.5.

-

Using .this'value as a benchmark, a calibrated two-country economy indeed
produces the J-curve pattern.

The intuition is that when the home country
d .

.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

experiences a favorable technology shock, output of home-produced goods rises
relative to foreign-produced goods, resulting in an increase in the terms of
trade.

At the same time, with positive serial correlation in technology

changes, this she-ck signals high future productivity of capital, which is
exploited initially by a net increase in imports.

In other words, the in-

crease in the sum of what the home country wishes to consume and invest
exceeds the output increase

--

the trade balance becomes negative.

Over

time, investment slows, and the productivity differential narrows, resulting
in the trade balance eventually becoming positive.

As in the data for most

countries, the United States being an exception (see figure I), the benchmark
economy's contemporaneous correlation between terms of trade and net exports
is negative.
Some have suggested that the elasticity of substitution between homeand foreign-produced goods varies across countries.

For example, supposedly

it is larger for the United States than for most European countries. With a
larger elasticity, say three or four instead of 1.5, the model still produces
a J-curve pattern, but the contemporaneous correlation then is positive.
Again, the description of the findings would be incomplete without a
presentation of the discrepancies or anomalies relative to the data.

In this

case, while the J-curve arises naturally through interaction between the
technology-shock processes and the dynamics of capital formation, the volatility of the terms of trade is substantially greater in the data than in the
model.

Zimmermann (1991) finds that this general pattern persists in three/

country models with differences across countries in size and/or-proximity.
Some of the deviation from theory may be the result of a measurement problem
associated with the export and import price indices used.

A recent study by
1

-

-

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

~lte&an (1989) shows that for the 1980s. a decade for which data are available to construct better indices, t h e ~ ealternative indices display substantially less volatility. Yet, even with such a modification in measurements,
the model volatility of the terms of trade still would be substantially
larger than that in the data.

Summary
In this paper, I describe briefly an econometric (that is, quantitativetheoretic) approach to business cycles along with two examples of applications to questions or issues in international business cycles.

The focus is

on its use in obtaining quantitative answers to well-defined questions.
Moreover, since much .of the progress in economic science is motivated by
remaining deviations or anomalies relative to established theory, I emphasize
that disciplined use of this econometric approach indeed enables the researcher to document such deviations clearly.
The model economies referred to are formulated within the neoclassical
growth framework, which has come to dominate in business cycle theory.

In

economies with only technology shocks as impulses, use is made of measurements of the degree of interrelation between these shocks across countries,
including spillovers over time. A finding is that the tilted J-curve pattern
we see in the cross correlations between contemporaneous terms of trade and
the trade balance, going from leads of several quarters to lags of several
quarters, arises naturally in such economies. An example of a deviation is a
robust tendency in the model economies for the volatility of the terms of
trade to be too low.

Another deviation is that, in the model environments,

the correlation between domestic and foreign consumption is much higher than
'_

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

that between domestic and foreign output.

In the data for the United States

versus other major countries, however, these correlations are either about
the same or reversed i n r e l a t i v e magnitudes.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Figure 1:

Correlations of terms of trade with net exports at lag j, j

Source:

Backus, Kehoe, and Kydland (1991b).

-

-8,8

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

References Alterman, W. "Price Trends in U.S. Trade: New Data, New Insights," Working
Paper, Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1989.
Armington, P. "A Theory of Demand for Products Distinguished by Place of
Production," Staff Papers 27, International Monetary Fund, 1969,
pp. 488-526.
Backus, D.K., P.J. Kehoe, and F.E. Kydland. "International Real Business
Cycles," Journal of Political Economy, 1991a, forthcoming.

. "Dynamics of the Trade Balance and the Terms of Trade:
the J-Curve Revisited," Working Paper, Federal Reserve Bank of
Minneapolis, 1991b.
Hayek, F.A. Prices and Production.

London: George Routledge and Sons, 1931.

Kydland, F.E., and E.C. Prescott. "Hours and Employment Variation in Business
Cycle Theory," Economic Theory 1, 1991a, pp. 63-81.

. "The Econometrics of the General Equilibrium Approach to Business
Cycles," Scandinavian Journal of Economics 93, 1991b, pp. 161-78.
Lucas, R.E. Jr. "Understanding Business Cycles," in K. Brunner and A.H.
Meltzer, eds., Stabilization of the Domestic and International
Economy. Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1977, pp . 7-29.
Solow, R.M.

"Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function," Review

of Economics and Statistics 39, 1957, pp. 312-20.

Stockman, A.C., and L.L. Tesar. "Tastes and Technology in a Two-Country Model
of the Business Cycle: Explaining International Co-Movements,"
Working Paper 9019, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, 1991.
Tinbergen, J. "Annual Survey: Suggestions on Quantitative Business Cycle
Theory," Econornetrica 3, 1935, pp. 241-308.
Whalley, J. Trade Liberalization among Major Trading Areas.
Mass.: MIT Press, 1985.

Cambridge,

Zimmerman, C. "International Real Business Cycles among Heterogeneous
Countries," Working Paper, Carnegie-Mellon University, 1991.