View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Working: Paper 9404
DEPOSITOR PREFERENCE AND THE COST OF
CAPITAL FOR INSURED DEPOSITORY INSTITUTIONS
by William P. Osterberg and James B. Thomson

William P. Osterberg is an economist and James B.Thomson
is an assistant vice president and economist at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
Working papers of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion
and critical comment. The views stated herein are those of
the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System.
March 1994

Abstract
Depositor-preference laws provide depositors with a claim on a failed
depository institution's assets that is senior to unsecured general creditor
claims. Therefore, depositor preference is correctly viewed as changing the
capital structure of banks and thrifts and, consequently, these laws will affect
the cost of capital for depositories. However, depositor preference will not
have an impact on the total value of banks and thrifts unless deposit insurance
is mispriced.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

I. Introduction
It is generally accepted that the subsidy inherent in the current deposit insurance
system creates perverse incentives for risk-taking by insured depository institutions (Kane
119851). The thrift debacle and its attendant financial and political costs have increasingly
focused attention on the dangerous combination of virtually unlimited federal deposit
guarantees and regulatory discretion.
Federal deposit guarantees, the too-big-to-let-fail (TBTLF) doctrine, and capital
forbearance programs have effectively limited the ability of markets to discipline troubled
depository institutions. On the other hand, principal-agent conflicts have often resulted in
government regulatory policies designed to forestall disciplinary actions against troubled
banks and thrifts (Kane 119891; Thomson 119921).
Armed with an increased awareness of the role that regulatory forbearance played in
the thrift debacle and in the record losses in bank closings in the 1980s, Congress passed the
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act (FDICIA) of 1991.' FDICIA
contains four important reforms: First, it requires the implementation of prompt corrective
action for undercapitalized banks and for banks designated to be problem institutions by their
primary federal regulator. Carnell (1992) notes that FDICIA does not remove regulatory
discretion but rather increasingly limits discretion as an institution slides towards insolvency.
Second, FDICIA places limits on Federal Reserve discount window loans to troubled
depositories. Todd (1993) argues that FDICIA7sdiscount window provisions are designed to
prevent the Federal Reserve from propping up insolvent banks through improper solvencybased loans. Third, FDICIA now requires the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC)

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

to charge insured institutions a risk-related deposit-insurance premium. Finally, FDICIA
replaces the TBTLF doctrine with the systemic-risk exception which codifies the terms and
conditions under which the FDIC can bail out uninsured claimants of failed depositories.
Carnell (1992) contends that provisions in FDICIA which require the written authorization of
the Federal Reserve chairman and the secretary of the Treasury for financing systemic-risk
losses by a special assessment on the total liabilities (total deposits) of banks will limit the
abuse of the systemic-risk exception.
Though FDICIA's provisions are either already in place or in the process of being
implemented, Congress added another potentially important reform designed to limit the
FDIC's, and hence the taxpayer's, exposure. Specifically, in the Omnibus Budget
Reconciliation Act of 1993, Congress created a national depositor-preference law.2 Depositorpreference laws change the priority of depositors' (and thus the FDIC's) claims on the assets
of failed banks by making other senior claimants subordinate to depositors. In other words,
Congress implemented depositor preference in an effort to reduce FDIC losses by changing
the capital structure of banks.
This paper provides a theoretical analysis of the impact of depositor-preference laws
on the cost of debt capital for banks and on the value of FDIC deposit guarantee^.^ We
extend the single-period cash-flow version of the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM),
presented by Chen (1978) and modified by Osterberg and Thomson (1990, 1991), to include
depositor preference. In Section 11, we present the model. Section III shows the results of a
single-period analysis of a bank that has both uninsured and insured deposits and subordinated
debt, as derived in Osterberg and Thomson (1991). Section IV extends the analysis of

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Osterberg and Thomson (1991) to include the impact of depositor-preference laws. In
Section IV we investigate the effects of mispriced deposit insurance and of depositorpreference laws on the value of debt capital and on the value of deposit insurance.
Conclusions and policy implications are presented in Section V.

11. The Model

To examine the effects of depositor preference on the cost of debt and equity capital
for banks, we utilize the single-period CAPM valuation equation employed by Chen (1978)
and by Osterberg and Thomson (1990, 1991). In this model, the value of a firm is the
present value of its future cash flows. The value of the debt and equity of a firm are in turn
the present value of these claims on the firm's cash flows. Certain cash flows are discounted
at the risk-free rate of interest. Uncertain cash flows are converted to certainty-equivalent
cash flows by deducting a risk premium from the expected cash flow. From the CAPM the
risk premium is simply the market price of risk, multiplied by the covariance of the uncertain
cash flow with the market portfolio.
Our primary assumptions are 1) the risk-free rate of interest is constant, 2) capital
markets are perfectly competitive, 3) expectations are homogeneous with respect to the
probability distributions of the yields on risky assets, 4) investors are risk averse, seeking to
maximize the utility of terminal wealth, and 5) there are no taxes or bankruptcy costs.
In Sections 111 through V we utilize the following definitions:

Bi = Total promised payment to insured depositors.

B, = Total promised payment to uninsured depositors.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

G = Total promised payment to general creditors.
z = Total promised payment to the FDIC ( p ~ ~ ) . ~
B = Total promised payment to depositors and the FDIC (Bi+BU+z).
p = Deposit insurance premium per dollar of insured deposits.
S = Total promised payment to subordinated debtholders.
D = Total promised payment in the absence of depositor preference laws (B,+B,i~G+S+z).
K = Total promised payment with depositor preference laws (B,+B,+G+S+z).
Y,,, Y,,, Y,, Y,, Ye, and Y,

= End-of-period cash flows to insured depositors, uninsured

depositors, general creditors, subordinated debtholders, stockholders, and the FDIC,
respectively.
Vbi, Vbu,VG, V,, Ve, and V,

= Values of insured deposits, uninsured deposits, general

creditors, subordinated debt, bank equity, and the FDIC claim, respectively.
V, = Value of the bank.
E(Rbi), E(R,,), E(&), E(K), and E(R2 = The expected rates of return on insured and
uninsured deposits, general creditors, subordinated debt, and equity, respectively.
r = The risk-free rate (R = 1 + r).

X = The end-of-period gross return on bank assets.
F(X) = Cumulative probability distribution function for X.

h = The market risk premium.
COV(X,R,,,) = Systematic or nondiversifiable risk.
CEQ(X) = Certainty-equivalent of X [=Em)

R,,,

= Return

on the market portfolio.

- hCOV(X,k)].

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

We assume that all debt instruments are discount instruments, so the total promised payment
to all depositors and subordinated debtholders includes both principal and interest. In
addition, we assume that the deposit insurance premium is paid at the end of the p e r i ~ d . ~

111. Banks' Cost of Capital and the Value of Deposit Insurance: No Depositor
Preference
In this section we present results from Osterberg and Thomson (1991) for a bank with
insured deposits, uninsured deposits, and subordinated debt. The FDIC charges a fixed
insurance premium of p on each dollar of insured deposits. The total liability claims against
the bank, D, is the sum of the end-of-period promised payments to the uninsured depositors,
B,, insured depositors, B,, general creditors, G, subordinated debtholders, S, and the FDIC,
z (pB,). We assume that the FDIC underprices its deposit guarantees on average, and that in
the absence of regulatory taxes (Buser, Chen, and Kane [1981]), the FDIC provides a subsidy
that reduces the cost of capital for banks and increases their value.
Given these assumptions, it is clear that the end-of-period cash flows to the insured
depositors, Y,, equal the promised payments to insured depositors, B,, in every state.
Therefore, regardless of a bank's capital structure, the value, expected return, and cost of one
dollar of insured deposits are defined as Vbi= R-'B,, E(R,,) = r, and r

+ p, respectively.

Uninsured Depositors
The end-of-period cash flows to the uninsured depositors depend on the promised
payment to the uninsured depositors and on the total level of promised payments net of the
subordinated debt:

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm
b
'u

if

= Bu

X>D-S=Bi+Bu+G+z

BuW(D - S) if

D-S>X>O

0

O>X

if

While the total promised payments to debtholders and the FDIC equal D, the effective
bankruptcy threshold for uninsured depositors is D less the claims of the subordinated
debtholders. The value of and the required rate of return on uninsured deposits are

D-S

1 -F(D -8+[l/(D-S)IE ( X )
E(R,,)

=

R

0

- 1.0.

D-S

1 -F(D -S)+[1/(D-91CEQ

0

(X)

Equation (2) shows that the cost of debt (uninsured deposit) capital is a function of the bank's
systematic risk, as measured by kCOV(X, &),total promised payments to depositors and the
FDIC, (D-S), the probability that losses will exceed the level of subordinated debt, F(D-S),
and the risk-free rate of return. Osterberg and Thomson (1990, 1991) show that when the
FDIC misprices its guarantees, the cost of uninsured deposit capital also depends on the
deposit mix, because underpriced (overpriced) deposit guarantees lower (raise) both the
effective bankruptcy threshold for senior claims, F(D-S), and the bankruptcy threshold, F(D).
Furthermore, underpriced (overpriced) deposit guarantees increase (decrease) the claims of the
uninsured depositors relative to senior claims, BJ(D-S), and relative to total claims, BJD.
The size of this effect is a function of the FDIC's pricing error per dollar of insured deposits
and of the weight of insured deposits in the senior creditor pool.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

General Creditors
General creditors have the same priority of claim as uninsured depositors;
consequently, they will have similar end-of-period cash flows.

As before, the total promised payments equal D and the effective bankruptcy threshold is
D-S. The value of and the required rate of return on senior nondeposit debt is:

D -S

E(RJ

=

R

l-F(D-S)+[lI(D-S)IE

(X)
D-S

- 1.0.

(4)

Equation (4) shows that the cost of nondeposit debt (general credit) capital is a function of
the same factors as uninsured deposits, including: the bank's systematic risk, hCOV(X,R,J,
total promised payments to senior creditors and the FDIC, (D-S), the probability that losses
will exceed the level of subordinated debt, F(D-S), and the risk-free rate of return. In
addition, it will also depend on the size of the deposit-insurance subsidy.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Subordinated Debtholders
The end-of-period expected cash flows accruing to the subordinated debtholders are

Y,= S

if

X>D

X+S-D

if

D>X>D-S

0

if

D-S>X.

The value of the subordinated debt and the required rate of return on subordinated debt
capital are

D

Vs

=

R - l { ~ [-F(D-S)]
l
-D[F(D)-F(D-S)] +CEQ

D-S

( X ) },

D

E(Rs)

=

R

S[1 -F(D -S)] -D[F(D)-F(D -S)] +E ( X )
D -S
D

S[1 -F(D -591 -K[F(D) -F(D -S)] +CEQ

D -S

- 1.0.

(6)

(X)

Equations (5) and (6) show that the cost and value of subordinated debt capital depend on the
probability of bankruptcy, F(D), the face value of the subordinated debt, S, total promised
payments, D, and the probability that senior claimants will not be repaid in full, F(D-S).
Note that the last two terms in equation (6) represent the claims of subordinated debtholders
in states where they are the residual claimants.
Equitvholders
The end-of-period cash flows accruing to stockholders are

Ye= X-D

0

if

X>D

if

D > X.

The value of equity and the expected return to stockholders are

8

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

The FDIC's Claim
The net value of deposit insurance is simply the value of the FDIC's claim on the
bank. In the absence of depositor-preference laws, the end-of-period cash flows to the FDIC
and the value of its position are
YFDIC= Z

if

X>D-S

(B,+z)X/(D-S) - Bi if

D-S>X>O

-Bi

0 > X, and

if

,v

D-S

=

R - ~ { Z V - F ( D - +~ ~ C E 0Q(x) - BF(D-S)I.

Equation (9) shows that the net value of deposit insurance is a function of the
composition of the senior claims, the bank's systematic risk, the presence of junior debt
claims in the bank's capital structure, the risk-free rate of return, the effective probability of
bankruptcy, F(D-S), the level of promised payments to insured depositors, and the deposit
insurance premium. In fact, equation (9) can be interpreted as showing that the equity-like
buffer provided by subordinated debt affects the value of the FDIC's position by changing the
probability that the put options corresponding to the FDIC guarantee will be "in the money"
at the end of the period. Equation (9) also makes clear that if deposit insurance is to be
priced fairly,V,,,

= 0, the premium will be influenced by the degree to which the bank funds

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

itself with claims junior to insured deposits.
Osterberg and Thomson (1990) show that the value of the uninsured bank is
R"CEQ,(X). The value of the insured bank, V,, equals the value of the uninsured bank minus
equation (9), which is the value of the FDIC's claim.
D -S

V, = R

CEQ,(X) +B~F(D
-8- z [ l - F(D-81-[(Bi+z)/(D- m C E Q

0

(x)1.

(10)

Equation (10) shows that the structure of a bank's debt (in terms of priority of payment)
affects the value of the bank only through the net value of deposit insurance to the bank (the
last three terms on the right side of equation [lo]). Thus, if deposit insurance is always
correctly priced (that is, its net value to the bank is zero), the structure of a bank's liability
claims has no impact on bank value.

IV. Banks' Cost of Capital and the Value of the Insurance Fund: Depositor Preference
In this section we rederive the results when depositor-preference laws are in existence.
The effect of depositor-preference laws is to make the claims of general creditors subordinate
to those of uninsured depositors and of the FDIC. As in Section III, we assume that the FDIC
charges a flat-rate insurance premium of p on each dollar of insured deposits and that on
average the FDIC underprices its deposit guarantees. The total liability claims against the
bank, K, is the sum of the end-of-period promised payments to the uninsured depositors, B,,
the insured depositors, Bi, general creditors, G, subordinated debtholders, S, and the FDIC,
z (mi).

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Uninsured Depositors
The end-of-period cash flows to the uninsured depositors depend on the promised
payment to the uninsured depositors and on the total level of promised payments net of the
subordinated debt and claims of subordinated creditors:
Ybu = Bu

if

X>B=Bi+Bu+z

BuX/B

if

B>X>O

0

if

O>X

While the total promised payments to debtholders and the FDIC equal K, the effective
bankruptcy threshold for uninsured depositors is B (= K-G-S).

The value of and the

required rate of return on uninsured deposits are

B

Vbu = R -'{ Bu[l-F(B)]+(B,,/B)CEQ
o (X)1,

From the standpoint of uninsured deposit capital, depositor-preference laws have the same
impact as a requirement that banks issue subordinated debt. That is, when uninsured
depositors and the FDIC are given a claim in bankruptcy that is senior to that of general
creditors, the effective bankruptcy threshold for uninsured depositors is lowered from D-S to
K-G-S.

For uninsured depositors (and, as we shall, see for the FDIC), the pecking order of

junior claims beneath them is irrelevant in valuing their claims.
To find the impact of depositor preference on the value of uninsured deposits, we

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

control for possible change in total promised payments by normalizing the expected cash
flows by the level of uninsured deposits, and compare uninsured deposits in banks in the
presence and absence of depositor-preference laws. We then separate the expected cash flow
to an uninsured deposit (with a par value of one dollar) in the presence of depositorpreference debt into two instruments: one that is identical to the uninsured deposit in
Section III, and a second that has the following end-of-period payoffs and value:

AY,, = 0

if

X>D-S

1 - X/(D-S)

if

D-S > X > B

X/B - XI@-S)

if

B>X>O

0

if

O>X

Equation (13) is positive; to see this, note that the first term in the brackets is strictly greater
than the third term. Moreover, since by definition D - S > B, the middle term is also
positive. Therefore, depositor preference must increase the value of a dollar of insured
deposits.
General Creditors
Under depositor preference, general creditors have a claim that is junior to depositors
and to the FDIC but senior to subordinated creditors; hence, end-of-period cash flows to
general creditors are

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Y,=

G

if

X>K-S=Bi+B,,+G+z

X-B

if

K-S>X>B

0

if

B>X

The total promised payments to debtholders and to the FDIC equal K, and the effective
bankruptcy threshold is K - S. The value of and the required rate of return on general
creditor claims are

K-S

VG = R-'{~[l-F(K-S)]-B[F(K-S)-F(B)]+CEQ
(X)},
B

K-S

G [ 1 -F(K-S)] -B[F(K-S) -F(B)]+E
E(RG) = R

(X)

B
K-S

G [ l -F(K-S)] -B[F(K-S) -F(B)] +CEQ

B

- 1.0.
(X)

Equations (14) and (15) show that nondeposit debt (general credit) behaves like subordinated
debt (equations [5] and [6]), except that general creditors are afforded protection from loss by
the presence of subordinated debt. The value of general creditors' claims depends on the
effective bankruptcy threshold, F(K-S), the face value of their claims, G, total promised
payments to senior claimants, B, and the probability that senior claimants will not be repaid

'

in full, F(B). Note that when earnings fall between B and K-S, general creditors are the
residual claimants, and their claim will behave like an equity claim.
Following the procedure used in the previous subsection, we construct the replicating
portfolio for a general-creditor claim (with a par value of one dollar) under depositor
preference. The impact of depositor preference on the value of general-creditor claims
depends on whether K > D, or D > K. We assume that K 2 D. Let Ve(X I D) and Ve(X I .K)

13

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

be the value of equity when total liability claims are D and K, respectively. If D > K, then
Ve(X I D) < Ve(X I K), and stockholders could increase the value of their claim by voluntarily
issuing general-creditor claims that are subordinate to deposits. Hence, K must be greater
than D and, by implication, K-S > D-S.

The expected cash flow to a general-creditor claim

(with a par value of one dollar) in the presence of depositor preference is divided into one
claim that is identical to the general 'creditor claim in Section 111, and a second that -has the
following end-of-period payoffs and value:
BYG = 0

if

X>K-S

(X-B)/G - 1

if

K-S > X > D-S

(X-B)/G - X/(D-S)

if

D-S > X > B

if

B>X>O

if

0 > X,

-X/(D-S )
0

A V,

=

R-'{ -[F(K-S) -F(D-S)] - $[F(K-S) -F(B)]

+

-$EQ

K-S
B (X)

D -S
- ~
D -SC

(16)

E oQ( x ) } < 0.

Equation (16) is clearly negative. The first and last terms inside the braces on the right- hand
side of the equation are both negative, since K > D. In addition, the second term is negative
and larger in absolute value than the third. Hence, AVG is unambiguously negative, and
depositor preference decreases the value of a general-creditor claim (with a par value of one
dollar).
Subordinated Debt
Under depositor preference, the end-of-period expected cash flows accruing to the

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

subordinated debtholders are
Y, =

S

if

X>K

X+S-K

if

K>X>K-S

0

if

K-S>X.

The value of the subordinated debt and the required rate of return on subordinated debt
capital are simply equations (5) and (6), modified to reflect that K is the total promised
payment instead of D.

V'

K
=

R-YS[l -F(K-S)] - mF(K)-F(K-S)] + CEQ

K-S

(X)},

K

E(Rs)

=

R

S[l-F(K-S)I-mF(K)-F(K-S)]+E
(X)
K-S
K

- 1.0.

(18)

s[1-F(K-S)I - a F ( K ) -F(K-S)] +CEQK-s ( X )

Total promised payments under depositor preference, K, may not equal total promised
payments in the absence of depositor preference, D, because depositor preference changes the
risk faced by depositors, the FDIC, and general creditors. Therefore, while subordinated debt
is not directly affected by depositor-preference laws, it is indirectly affected through changes
in the level of promised payments and the probability of bankruptcy.
Assuming K 2 D, the differences between the cash flows accruing to a one-dollar parvalue claim of subordinated debt, in the absence of and with depositor preference, h e

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

AV, = 0

(D-K)/S
(D-X)/S

-1

K

if

X >K

if

D > X > K-S

if

K-S > X > D-S

K-S

A Vs = (RS)-'{CEQ ( X ) - CEQ
D

D-S

(X)

- S[F(K-S)-F(D-S)]

(19)

Given K 2 D, equation (19) is nonpositive because the net cash flows for all possible ranges
of X in AV, are nonpositive. Therefore, if depositor preference increases the total promised
payments by the bank, the value of a one-dollar-par-value claim of subordinated debtholders
will be reduced through the impact of depositor preference on the bankruptcy threshold.
Equityholders
As with the subordinated debtholders, depositor preference influences the value of
stockholder claims through its impact on the bankruptcy threshold, K. Under depositor
preference, the end-of-period cash flows accruing to stockholders are

Ye= X - K
0

if

X >K

if

K > X.

The value of equity and the expected return to stockholders are

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

The difference between the value of equity under depositor preference and without depositor
preference is simply the difference between equation (20) and equation (7).
K

A Ve

=

R

D[F(K)-F(D)] + ( D-K)[l - F ( a - CEQ ( X ) } s 0.

(22)

D

As with subordinated debt, the value of equity is affected by depositor preference when

K

#

D. That is, when the imposition of depositor preference increases the level of total

promised payments (and by implication the probability of bankruptcy), the value of the bank's
equity falls. To see this, note that the first term inside the brackets is greater in absolute
value than the second term.
The FDIC's Claim
As before, the net value of deposit insurance is simply the value of the FDIC's claim
on the bank. Under depositor preference, the end-of-period cash flows to the FDIC and the
value of its position are

YFDIC
=Z
(B,+z)X/B - Bi
-Bi

if

X>B

if

B>X>O

if

0 > X, and

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

As with the uninsured deposits, the impact of a depositor-preference law is indistinguishable
from a subordinated-debt requirement. Depositor preference affects the net value of the
FDIC's claim by changing the senior claimants' probability of loss and by changing the
weight of the FDIC in the pool of senior claims.
The change in the value of the FDIC guarantee on a one-dollar-par-value deposit is the
value of the security which has the following cash flows (where p = z/Bi):

AY,,,=

0

if

X>D-S

p - (1 + p)X/(D - S) + 1

if

D-S>X>B

(l+p)X/B - (l+p)X/(D - S)

if

B>X>O

0

if

O>X

'

Equation (24) is positive; to see this, note that the first term in the brackets is strictly greater
than the second term. Since we assume that the FDIC on average underprices its guarantees,
the FDIC claim on the bank is negative; hence, the size of the FDIC subsidy is smaller under
depositor preference.
Finally, the effect of depositor preference on the value of the bank is entirely through
its effect on the net value of deposit insurance.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Thus, if deposit insurance is always correctly priced (that is, if its net value to the bank is
zero), depositor preference has no impact on bank value. However, it does change the fair
value of deposit insurance and, hence, must be accounted for when setting the premium.

V. Conclusions
Using the cash-flow version of the CAPM, we show how depositor-preference laws
affect the value and pricing of stakeholder claims on insured banks. By effectively changing
the capital structure of the bank, depositor-preference laws increase the value of uninsured
deposit claims and reduce the size of the FDIC subsidy. General creditors,.subordinated
debtholders, and equityholders all see the value of their one-dollar-par claims reduced.
The impact of depositor-preference laws on the value of deposit insurance is the same
as a mandatory subordinated-debt requirement. In each case, depositors and the FDIC are
afforded an extra layer of loss buffer by the existence of debt claims which are junior to their
own.6
The influence of depositor preference on the required rates of return for bank liabilities
depends crucially on the extent' of deposit-insurance mispricing, as well as on the magnitude
of the general-creditor claims. Like subordinated debt, depositor-preference laws cannot
reduce the deposit-insurance subsidy unless insurance is mispriced.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Notes
1. DeGennaro and Thomson (1994) show that capital forbearance increased the total taxpayer
bill in the thrift debacle by more than 500 percent.
2. Title I11 of the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1993 instituted depositor preference for
all insured depository institutions by amending Section l l ( d ) ( l l ) of the Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation Act [12 U.S.C. 1821(d)(l l)]. At the time when national depositor
preference was enacted, 29 states had similar laws covering state-chartered banks, and 18 had
depositor-preference statutes covering state-chartered thrift institutions.
3. An empirical study of the impact of depositor-preference laws can be found in Hirschhom and
Zervos (1990).
4. For simplicity, we express the premium as a function of insured deposits. The results of
interest would not be materially affected by adopting the more realistic assumption that premiums
are levied on total domestic deposits, both insured and uninsured.

5. For simplicity, we assume that the deposit-insurance premium is an end-of-period claim on
the bank. This is equivalent to assuming that the premium is subordinate to Bi and that, in effect,
the bank receives coverage while not necessarily paying the full premium. However, while this
assumption does affect how the deposit-insurance subsidy enters into the expressions in this paper
and the actual size of the subsidy, it does not qualitatively affect the results.
6. However, unlike a mandatory subordinated-debt requirement, holders of general-creditor
claims could conceivably restructure their claims by taking collateral, and thereby improve their
position relative to depositors and the FDIC. Hirschhorn and Zervos (1990) find that for thrifts
in states with depositor-preference laws, general creditors are more likely to be collateralized;
hence, in those states these laws afforded little protection to depositors.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

References
Buser, S. A., A. H. Chen, and E. J. Kane, 1981, Federal Deposit Insurance, Regulatory
Policy, and Optimal Bank Capital, Journal of Finance 36, 51-60.
Carnell, R. S., 1992, A Partial Antidote to Perverse Incentives: The FDIC Improvement Act
of 1991, Papers presented at the Conference on Rebuilding Public Confidence through
Financial Reform, Ohio State University (June 25).
Chen, A. H., 1978, Recent Developments in the Cost of Debt Capital, Journal of Finance 33,
863-877.
DeGennaro, R. P., and J. B. Thomson, 1994, Capital Forbearance and Thrifts: An Ex Post
Examination of Regulatory Gambling, Journal of Financial Services Research 8
(forthcoming).
Hirschhorn, E., and D. Zervos, 1990, Policies to Change the Priority of Claimants: The Case
of Depositor Preference Laws, Journal of Financial Services Research 4, 111- 126.
Kane, E. J., 1985, The Gathering Crisis in Federal Deposit Insurance, (Cambridge, MA:
MIT Press).
Kane, E.J., 1989, The S&L Insurance Mess: How Did It Happen? (Washington, DC: The
Urban Institute).
Osterberg, W. P., and J. B. Thomson, 1990, Deposit Insurance and the Cost of Capital, in
Research in Finance 8, ed. A. H. Chen (Greenwich, CN: JAI Press Inc.), 255-270.
Osterberg, W. P., and J. B. Thomson, 1991, The Effect of Subordinated Debt and Surety
Bonds on the Cost of Capital for Banks and on the Value of Federal Deposit Insurance,
Journal of Banking and Finance 15 (September), 939-953.
Thomson, J. B., 1987, The Use of Market Information in Pricing Deposit Insurance, Journal
of Money, Credit and Banking 19, 528-532.
Thomson, J. B., 1992, A Market-Based Approach to Reforming Bank Regulation and Federal
Deposit Insurance, in Research in Financial Services: Private and Public Policy 4, ed. G.
Kaufman (Greenwich, CN: JAI Press Inc.), 93-109.
Todd, W. F., '1993, Discount Window Provisions of the Federal Deposit Insurance
Corporation Improvement Act of 1991, Banking Policy Report (March 1).