View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paper 9603
DEMOGRAPHIC CHANGE, GENERATIONAL ACCOUNTS, AND NATIONAL
SAVING IN THE UNITED STATES
by Jagadeesh Gokhale

Jagadeesh Gokhale is an economist at the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland. The author thanks Felicitie Bell for
providing critical data on U.S. population projections and
Laurence Kotlikoff and Robert Willis for helpful comments.
This paper was presented at the September 1995 Conference
on Intergenerational Economic Relations and Demographic
Change, jointly sponsored by the International Union for the
Scientific Study of Population and the East-West Center in
Honolulu, Hawaii.
Working papers of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion
and critical comment. The views stated herein are those of
the authors and are not necessarily those of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System.
Working papers are now available electronically through the
Cleveland Fed’s home page on the World Wide Web:
http://www.clev.frb.org.
May 1996

Abstract
The recently developed method of generational accounting facilitates detailed
measurement of fiscal policy’s impact on the intergenerational distribution of resources.
Earlier studies for the United States, using the Social Security Administration’s intermediate
population projections, concluded that current U.S. fiscal policy embodies a significant
generational imbalance. This paper examines the sensitivity of that imbalance to alternative
population projections. In addition, following a framework for data organization suggested
by the life-cycle hypothesis of consumer behavior, it analyzes the impact of the ongoing and
projected demographic transition on national saving.
The paper finds that the conclusion of imbalance is robust over a wide range of U.S.
population projections involving alternative assumptions about fertility, mortality, and
immigration. It also finds that the ongoing demographic transition may have contributed
significantly to the decline in national saving during the 1980s. However, projected changes
in the population’s age structure are not expected to generate a rebound in national saving.

1

I. Introduction
In recent years, the role of fiscal policy in redistributing resources across generations
has been subjected to intense scrutiny. This is not surprising, because fiscal policy has
played an increasingly important role in transferring resources between generations,
especially in developed economies. 1 Until recently, however, no technique was available for
measuring the extent of intergenerational wealth redistribution via the public channel. This
gap has now been filled by “generational accounting,” a method for estimating prospective
and lifetime resource flows toward or away from different generations as a result of the
government’s tax and spending policies (Auerbach, Gokhale, and Kotlikoff [1991, 1994];
Kotlikoff [1992]).2
A generational account is the present value of taxes (net of transfers) per capita that
members of a given generation may expect to pay to the government during their remaining
lifetime if current fiscal policy is maintained. Generational accounting studies of the United
States reveal a sizable imbalance in U.S. fiscal policy -- that is, the continuation of current
policy for those now alive will entail the imposition of enormously larger fiscal burdens on
generations to come. Similar conclusions emerge from generational accounting analyses for
Italy, Germany, Norway, and Canada.3
Long-range population projections, which are usually fairly reliable over the short
horizon, are a critical input in calculating the accounts. However, long-run trends in

1

Resources are, of course, redistributed across generations through a variety of channels of which public policy is
but one. Markets and families are the other two important institutions that redistribute wealth across generations.
Markets play a role as young savers and new entrepreneurs purchase housing and capital stocks from older
generations and firms. The family plays a role as the old provide inter vivos transfers and bequeath wealth to their
offspring. Intrafamily intergenerational transfers also occur in the form of time and care provided by the young to
the old. For a broader discussion and framework, see Lee (forthcoming).
2
Fehr and Kotlikoff (1995) use a simulation model to measure the relative sizes of direct and indirect wealth
redistribution induced by fiscal policy changes. In many of the cases they analyze, direct redistribution accounts for
most of the total redistribution.
3
See Gokhale, Raffelhüschen, and Walliser (1995) for the case of Germany; Auerbach and others (1992) for the
case of Norway; Oreopoulos (1995) for that of Canada; and Franco and others (1994) for Italy.

2

mortality, fertility, and immigration cannot be estimated precisely beyond a couple of
decades. Despite the important role of population projections, the sensitivity of generational
accounting’s conclusions to alternative population projections has not been investigated to
date. One goal of this paper is to perform such an analysis.
A second goal is to analyze the impact of changes in the age structure of the
population on national saving. Under the life-cycle hypothesis with certainty (Ando and
Modigliani, 1963), an individual’s current consumption depends upon his or her age-specific
propensity to consume out of lifetime resources. If this hypothesis is true, the age structure
of the population becomes a potentially important determinant of national saving.
Understanding the trend in national saving would, then, require the measurement of the total
resources available to each generation (and these would be affected by its generational
account), generation-specific propensities to consume out of those resources, and the current
and projected age structure of the population.
Studies for the United States that use the framework for data organization suggested
by the life-cycle hypothesis (LCH) show that ongoing resource transfers away from young
and future generations, and toward older generations, can explain a sizable fraction of the
recent decline in U.S. saving (Gokhale, Kotlikoff, and Sabelhaus [1995]). However, the
effect on aggregate saving of changes in the population’s age structure has not been explored
in much detail. This paper asks and answers two questions with regard to the impact of
changes in the population’s age structure on national saving: First, to what extent has the
evolving age structure contributed to the decline in U.S. saving since the early 1960s and,
second, what is the probable role of the ongoing demographic transition in determining
future U.S. national saving?

3

This paper first describes the methodology of generational accounting, presents the
accounts for the United States, and describes the sensitivity of the results under alternative
interest-rate and growth-rate assumptions and under alternative projections of federal health
care expenditures. Next, it describes the nature of the demographic transition currently
underway in the United States, and performs sensitivity tests on U.S. generational accounts
under different assumptions regarding future mortality, fertility, and immigration rates.
Finally, the paper utilizes a framework based on the LCH to examine how demographic
change influences national saving in the United States.

II. The Method of Generational Accounting
The method of generational accounting takes the present-value budget constraint of
the government (also known as the government’s intertemporal budget constraint) as its
starting point. This constraint may be written as:
(1)

PVGt = NWGt + PVLt + PVFt.
Equation (1) says that at time t (the current period), the present value of government

purchases of goods and services, PVGt, must be paid for by the sum of three items: The net
wealth of the government, NWGt, the present value of net tax payments by living
generations at time t, PVLt, and the present value of net tax payments by future generations
PVFt. The term “net tax payments” refers to taxes paid to the government net of transfers
received from it. The “generational account” of a generation is a dollar amount, and it is
defined as the actuarially discounted present value of net tax payments per capita over the
generation’s remaining lifetime. Note that equation (1) can be viewed as a financing
constraint. Under a given policy for government purchases and given the government’s
current net worth, future generations must assume the burden of paying for government

4

purchases, which is not covered by the net tax payments made by living generations. The
focus of generational accounting is the trade-off between PVLt, and PVFt. The following
describes the method of estimating the components of equation (1).
The sum of generational accounts over all members of living generations, PVLt, can
be written as:
(2)

D

PVLt = S [hmjt,tpmjt,t + hfjt,tpfjt,t],
jt=0

where D is the maximum age of life. A distinction is made between male and female
generations whose populations are represented by pmjt,t and pfjt,t, and the terms hmjt,t and hfjt,t
represent the generational accounts in year t of male and female generations aged j in year t
(indexed by jt).
The generational account, hxjt,t, where the superscript x stands for male or female, is
defined by:
(3)

hxjt,t

1 t+D-jt
m
x
= ¾¾ S p jt,s [S qxi,jt,s] Rs-t .
i=1
pxjt,t s=t

Here, R = 1/(1+r), and r is the discount rate. In equation (3), qxi,jt,s stands for the per capita
payment (or receipt, when q is negative) of type i in a future period s by a member of the
generation of sex x aged j in year t. The sum within square brackets over the m types of per
capita payments in period s provides the net payment per capita in that period. This term,
times the population of such persons in period s, pxjt,s, provides the total net payment that
individuals of sex x aged j in year t make in year s. For the us, estimates of pxjt,s are those of
the Social Security Administration (SSA). Summing such discounted values for each
period s over the remaining lifetime of individuals aged j in year t provides their total

5

discounted value of net payments. Division by pxjt,t, the population of such persons in year t,
converts this discounted sum to a per capita amount and represents the generational account
of the generation aged j in year t. Note that multiplying the sum of net payments in each
period s by the number of surviving members in period s of the generation aged j in year t,
and finally dividing by their population in period t amounts to actuarially discounting their
future net payments.
For future years, the per capita payments of each type of tax (or transfer) are
estimated either by distributing projected aggregate payments of that type in future years
using relative profiles by age and sex or, if projections of aggregate payments are not
available, by applying a growth factor to similarly estimated per capita payments for the base
year t for which the aggregate payment is available. In the latter case,
(4)

qxi,jt,s = qxi,jt,t(1+g)s-t .
The relative profiles used for distributing base (or future) year aggregate payments

by age and sex are obtained from household surveys that contain the pertinent information.4
These empirically determined relative profiles and the associated aggregate payments and
receipts collectively constitute an element of the time-t intergenerational stance of fiscal
policy, in that they specify the pattern of payments and receipts imposed on different living
generations at time t. The relative profiles are normalized to 1 for males aged 40 in year t (or
s). Hence, the per capita payment for 40-year-old males can be expressed as
(5)

qxi,40t,t

=

Qi,t
¾¾¾¾¾¾¾¾¾ ,
D

S [ rmi,jt,tpmjt,t + rfi,jt,tpfjt,t]
4

In the case of the United States, these data are taken from the University of Michigan’s Survey of Income and
Program Participation, the Census Bureau’s Current Population Survey, the Social Security Administration’s Annual
Statistical Supplement to the Social Security Bulletin, the Health Care Financing Administration, and the Survey of
Current Business. For a discussion of the treatment of individual taxes and transfers, see Auerbach, Gokhale, and
Kotlikoff (1991, 1994).

6
jt=0

where rxi,jt,t represents the amount of payment (or receipt, if negative) of type i that a person
aged j in year t makes relative to the payment of a 40-year-old male in year t, and Qi,t is the
aggregate payment of type i made in year t. Of course,
(6)

qxi,jt,t = qxi,40t,trxi,jt,t,

for x = m,f; jt = 0...D.

This completes the description of the method of estimating the generational accounts
and the aggregate net tax payments, PVLt, of living generations. The term PVGt is estimated
by discounting future projections of aggregate purchases back to period t. If projections of
aggregate future government purchases are not available, PVGt can be estimated by dividing
government purchases at time t into several age-specific categories, assuming that the agespecific purchases per capita for each category will remain constant in the future, and using
population projections to project the path of future aggregate purchases.5 The division of
government purchases into several age-specific categories is determined empirically, and
also represents an element of the current intergenerational stance of fiscal policy.
Government net wealth, NWGt, can be estimated by computing the cumulative sum
of past government deficits. It should be noted that existing assets of the government, like
parks and infrastructure, are a part of net wealth. However, they also represent consumption
of public goods, the present value of which would have to be included in PVGt, if their asset
value is included in NWGt. Because the value of government assets must, by definition,
equal the present value of their consumption flow, the exclusion of assets from both sides of
equation (1) leaves the constraint unchanged. That is, the trade-off between PVLt and PVFt,

5

A large chunk of government purchases, such as those for defense and general administration, cannot be attributed
to specific age groups. These are attributed equally to all individuals alive at time t.

7

which is the focus of generational accounting, remains unaffected by the omission of the
value of government assets from NWGt.
Because equation (1) must hold at time t, and because three of the four elements in
that equation have been estimated, one can calculate the fourth term, PVFt, as a residual.
How this residual net payment that must be imposed on unborn generations will actually be
distributed among those generations is not clear from the vantage point of time t. As an
illustrative device, an equal, growth-adjusted distribution of the residual, PVFt, among
members of all future generations is assumed. In so distributing the residual burden, the net
payment by unborn males relative to unborn females is maintained equal to that between
newborn male and female generations (who are treated as members of living generations)
under current policy. Hence
(7)

PVGt - NWGt - PVLt =

¥

S [hm0s,spm0s,s + hf0s,spf0s,s]Rs-t,

s=t+1

where hx0s,s is the value as of period s of the net payment of the generation of sex x aged 0 in
period s, and px0s,s is the population of such individuals in period s. Each future generation’s
aggregate net payment is discounted back to period t. Let fm be 1 and ff=hf0s,s/hm0s,s,
s=t+1,...¥, the net payment of future female generations relative to future male generations.
Further, let hm0s+1,s+1/hm0s,s=(1+g), s=t,...¥. Thus, each future generation is assumed to pay
(1+g) times the net payment of the immediately preceding generation, where (1+g) is the
gross rate of growth of labor productivity. Dividing and multiplying the right-hand side of
equation (7) by hm0t+1,t+1 and manipulating the expression within square brackets yields

(8)

hm0t+1,t+1 =

PVGt - NWGt - PVLt
¾¾¾¾¾¾¾¾¾¾¾¾¾¾ .
¥

S [fmpm0s,s + ffpf0s,s] Rs-t (1+g)s-(t+1)

8
s=t+1

The term on the left-hand side of equation (8) represents the net payment (as of period t) of
the generation born in period t+1.6 Because period t newborns and future generations have
their entire lifetimes ahead of them, it is possible to compare the net payment of the
generation born in period t to that of the average net payment of those born in period t+1.
Note, again, that the latter represents the growth-adjusted burden on all future generations,
since it is computed under the assumption of an equal distribution of the residual burden,
PVLt, across all future generations. The difference between the two measures, computed as
a percentage
(9)

hm0t+1,t+1
P = [ ¾¾¾¾ - 1]´100
hm0t,t(1+g)

provides a measure of the degree of imbalance embedded in current fiscal policy.
An alternative measure of the fiscal burden on a generation is the lifetime net tax
rate that a generation faces under current policy. This is computed as the ratio of the
generational account at birth to the present value of per capita labor income over the
generation’s entire lifetime. Thus, we can express the lifetime net tax rate, t, as
(10)

tjt,t-jt

hxjt,t--jt
= ¾¾¾¾¾ ,
t+D-jt

S e xjt,sRs-(t-jt)

s=t-jt

where txjt,t-jt is the lifetime net tax rate of the generation of sex x aged j in year t, and e xjt,s
stands for this generation’s average labor earnings in year s.7 Note that the summation is

6
Note that the summation in the denominator goes upto infinity. Our population projections extend only through
the year 2200. The calculations are adjusted to account for payments by generations born after the year 2200.
7
Lifetime labor income, rather than total income, is used because income from a normal rate of return on saving out
of labor income reflects only an intertemporal reallocation of lifetime resources and not an increase in those

9

over the entire lifetime of the generation and the present values for both the numerator and
the denominator are computed as of the generation’s year of birth, t-jt. The lifetime net tax
rate represents the fraction of the present value at birth of lifetime labor earnings that will be
paid to the government. Hence, in computing lifetime net tax rates for living generations, it
is necessary to include past as well as future projected labor earnings in the denominator,
and past as well as future projected annual net tax payments in the numerator.

III. Generational Accounts for the United States
Tables 1 and 2 show generational accounts for selected male and female generations
in the United States, taking 1993 as the base year (year t). The computations use the data on
aggregate taxes, transfers, and projections of government purchases through 2030 provided
by the U.S. Office of Management and Budget. Projections of taxes, transfers, and spending
after the year 2030 assume that per capita amounts will grow according to a 1.2 percent
annual rate of productivity growth. Present values are calculated using a 6 percent rate of
discount in all cases.8
The generational accounts (shown in the “net payments” column) for living
generations exhibit significant differences among individuals in different stages of their life
cycles: Younger generations’ net payments are positive because they are in a high working
and earning stage of life, while older generations have negative net payments because they
are retired and receive large amounts of Social Security and health benefits.9 The

resources. Extra-normal returns on saving and receipts from intergenerational transfers should be included in the
denominator in computing lifetime net tax rates. This is not done because of the lack of reliable data.
8
The productivity growth rate chosen is close to that actually experienced over the last four decades. The discount
rate is chosen to reflect that, although future transactions with the government (payment of taxes/receipts of
benefits) are not as risky as the long-term return on private capital (about 9 percent), they are not entirely risk free.
9
Generational accounts for other countries have very similar age profiles. See, for example, Gokhale,
Raffelhüschen, and Walliser (1995) for the case of Germany; Auerbach and others (1992) for the case of Norway;
Franco and others (1994) for the case of Italy; and Oreopoulos (1995) for Canada.

10

generational accounts for very young living generations are much smaller than for those who
are middle aged, because the former are far in time from their working, earning, and hightax-paying years.
The generational account for future generations is very large relative to that for living
newborns (those aged 0 in 1993). The value of P in equation 9 turns out to be 146.1 percent.
That is, future generations must, on average, make net payments that are one and a half times
as large as those of current newborns if current fiscal treatment is extended to the latter
throughout their lifetimes. Thus, under the illustrative assumption of allocating the residual
burden equally among future generations, generational accounting reveals substantial
imbalance in the intergenerational stance of current U.S. fiscal policy.
The last two lines of table 1 show that the lifetime net tax rate facing current
newborns is 33.6 percent, whereas the average rate facing future generations is 82.8
percent.10 The net tax rate for future generations represents the average rate that each
member of all future generations will have to pay in order to balance the government’s
intertemporal budget shown in equation (1). Levying such an enormously high average rate
on future generations is obviously infeasible. Hence, one may conclude that the current U.S.
fiscal policy path is not sustainable.11

10
To calculate lifetime net tax rates on newborn and future generations, it is assumed that future real labor earnings
by age and sex will be the same as those for living generations, except for productivity growth. The latter is
assumed to be 1.2 percent per year, which roughly corresponds to that experienced after World War II.
11
A policy involving a lifetime net tax rate on current newborns that is less than the average net tax rate that all future
generations must bear in order to satisfy constraint (1) is clearly unsustainable. If such a policy is maintained for
some time, each successive newborn generation will contribute less than this average net tax rate, thereby increasing
the average net tax rate that all remaining future generations must pay. Thus, at some future date, the average net tax
rate on all remaining future generations will exceed 100 percent, which is not feasible.

11

IV. Sensitivity of Generational Accounts to Alternative Interest and Growth Rates
Tables 3a and 3b present the lifetime net tax rates on current newborn and future
generations under alternative interest-rate and growth-rate assumptions. The baseline results
are presented in the center columns and rows. Increasing the rate of interest increases the
net tax rates on living newborns because higher interest rates imply that payments far out in
the future receive lower weights. Since labor income and tax payments occur at roughly the
same time during the lifetime, benefit receipts occur later. Hence, higher interest rates reduce
the present value of future benefits by more than they reduce the present values of taxes and
labor income. Hence, lifetime net tax rates are larger when the assumed discount rate is
higher. The net tax rates are lower for higher assumed rates of productivity growth.
The average lifetime net tax rate on future generations is significantly higher than
those on living newborns. It exceeds 100 percent for some interest- and growth-rate
combinations. Table 3c shows the values of P for the different cases. In none of the cases is
P less than 100 percent, implying that future generations may be expected to pay, on average,
twice as much as would current newborns under current fiscal policy.

V. Sensitivity of Generational Accounts to Alternative Health Care Outlay Assumptions
An important and rapidly growing share of government outlays in the United States
is devoted to providing health care insurance and services to the elderly (Medicare) and the
poor (Medicaid). Because recent and projected growth in these two programs is extremely
high relative to the rest of the economy, they account for a significant portion of the
imbalance between the accounts of newborn and future generations. While the high growth
rates in Medicare and Medicaid are expected to continue under current policies, legislation
may be enacted in the future to reduce growth of outlays for these items.

12

The second pair of columns in table 4 show the accounts under the most optimistic
assumption -- that the growth of federal health care outlays is “stabilized,” beginning in 1996.
Stabilization is taken to mean that the growth in outlays equals the growth rate of the
recipient population plus the rate of productivity growth. Under this case, the lifetime net tax
rate on living newborns increases to 38.1 percent and that on future generations declines to
50.5 percent. This implies an imbalance of 33 percent, compared to 146 percent under the
base case. Thus, the rapid projected growth in federal health care outlays goes a long way in
explaining the sizable generational imbalance in current U.S. fiscal policy.
The last pair of columns in table 4 show the results of assuming, more realistically,
that the growth in health care outlays will not be stabilized until the year 2003.12 Delaying the
stabilization of health care outlays until then will substantially increase the lifetime net tax
rates of future generations, and substantially increase the imbalance, now 90 percent.

VI. Sensitivity of Generational Accounts to Alternative Population Projections
Figure 1 shows actual (through 1995) and three alternative SSA projections of the
U.S. population.13 The Alternative II projections are used in the generational accounts
estimates shown in tables 1 and 2. As is clear from figure 1, Alternative I represents a
doubling of the population by the year 2200, compared with Alternative II. Under
Alternative III, the projected population in the year 2200 is half as large as it would be under
Alternative II. Another way of comparing the three alternatives is to compare their

12
As these experiments were in progress, the U.S. Congress and the administration were negotiating a package to
balance the federal budget by the year 2002. Since the new budget agreement is likely to have year-by-year
projections of health care outlays through that year, the next year is selected for beginning the policy of stabilizing
health care outlays.
13
The Social Security Administration projects the U.S. population through the year 2070 for making long-range
actuarial projections for the U.S. Social Security system. In generational accounting calculations, these projections
are used after extending them through the year 2200. The extended projections use assumptions on mortality,
fertility, and immigration applicable in the Social Security Administration’s projections in the year 2070.

13

population counts for the year 2200 to the population’s actual size in 1993. Under
Alternative I, the population increases to over three times its current size by the year 2200.
Under Alternative II, it increases by about 50 percent between 1993 and 2200. It declines,
however, under Alternative III, so that the population in 2200 is about 70 percent of its 1993
level. Thus, these three alternatives encompass a reasonably wide range of possibilities for
future population growth.
The SSA designed these three alternative projections to represent low-cost
(Alternative I), intermediate-cost (Alternative II), and high-cost (Alternative III) assumptions
for purposes of computing the long-range actuarial balance of the Social Security system.
Alternative I embodies high fertility, mortality, and immigration rates. Under this alternative,
the high fertility and immigration rates imply that there will be a large number of future
young cohorts who will pay taxes. On the other hand, high mortality rates imply that current
and future old generations will die off quickly, thus receiving a smaller present value of
Social Security benefits. Alternative III embodies the opposite assumptions of low fertility,
mortality, and immigration rates. This high-cost scenario implies that fewer younger
generations in the future that will pay taxes, and more numerous and longer-lived older
generations will receive benefits.
Table 5 reports net payments under Alternatives I, II, and III. A well-known feature
of the mortality rates is that they are extremely low at ages less than 50, and that they rise
rapidly with age thereafter. Hence, most of the difference in mortality rates between the three
alternatives occurs at older ages. As expected, then, living generations’ net payments are
higher under Alternative I than Alternative II. This is because, at each age, a higher
mortality rate implies a lower present value of benefits when old but, because the difference

14

in mortality rates is not large at young ages, tax burdens on the young are not much affected.
Net payments are smaller under Alternative III for the opposite set of reasons.14
The generational account of future generations under Alternative I is smaller than
under Alternative II because the higher fertility rates of the former imply larger future
cohorts among which the residual burden can be distributed. In contrast, the average net
payment burden on future generations is larger under Alternative III because of the lower
fertility rates embodied in it.
Among the three alternatives, the percentage differences between newborn and
future generations range from 120 percent under Alternative I to 175 percent under
Alternative III. Future generations’ lifetime net tax rates range from about 71 percent under
Alternative I to 95 percent under Alternative III. Thus, even under Alternative I’s optimistic
assumptions about population growth, the conclusion that current U.S. fiscal policy contains
a sizable imbalance and is set on an unsustainable course remains true.

VII. Generational Accounts and Private Budgets15
The generational accounts of living generations represent a net drain on their total
resources under current fiscal policy. Generational accounts are, therefore, an element of the
prospective lifetime budget constraints for living generations. The total resources in year t of
an individual aged j in year t can be expressed as
(11)
14

t+D-jt

rxjt,t = w xjt,t + S [e xjt,s + pxjt,s]Rs-t - hxjt,t ,
s=t

The future evolution of fertility, mortality, and immigration rates is uncertain. Small changes in all three could
possibly completely alter the population shares of different generations. This is exemplified in Tuljapurkar and Lee
(forthcoming). An alternative procedure would be to conduct a similar excercise, estimate the distribution of
generational accounts, and compute confidence intervals around the point estimates presented in earlier sections.
Such an analysis is beyond the scope of this paper. However, the procedure followed here may be viewed as a
close substitute.
15
The argument in this section follows that in Gokhale, Kotlikoff, and Sabelhaus (1995).

15

where rxjt,s represents resources per capita, e xjt,s the average labor earnings, pxjt,s the average
pension earnings, and w xjt,s the total net worth, in year s of a member of the generation of sex
x aged j in year t. Thus, a generation’s per capita resources are the sum of its per capita
nonhuman, human, and pension wealth, less its generational account. Relative profiles by
age and sex of labor earnings and of public and private pension benefits are used to
distribute aggregate labor and pension incomes to obtain the human and pension wealth
components of total resources. The procedure for distributing the aggregates is similar to
that given in equations (5) and (6) earlier. The nonhuman wealth component is obtained by
distributing aggregate private net worth by age-sex relative profiles of net worth from micro
data surveys.16 Figure 2 shows the age-sex distribution of resources per capita. As would be
expected, resources of younger women are much lower than those of men, primarily because
of their smaller human wealth stemming from their lower rates of labor-force participation
and earnings.

VIII. Population Age Structure and National Saving
According to the life-cycle hypothesis (LCH), consumption in year t of an individual
aged jt depends upon the average propensity to consume out of lifetime resources at that
age. Thus, aggregate consumption in period t can be expressed as
(12)

16

D

D

Ct = S S cxjt,tpxjt,t = S S axjt,t rxjt,tpxjt,t,
x jt=0

x jt=0

For the U.S., labor earning and pension profiles are based on the Census Bureau’s Current Population Surveys.
The relative profiles for private net worth are from the Federal Reserve System’s Survey of Consumer Finances.
The aggregates distributed according to these profiles are from the National Income and Product Accounts
published in the July 1994 Survey of Current Business, and from the Federal Reserve System’s Balance Sheets of
the U.S. Economy.

16

where c is consumption per capita and a is the average propensity to consume out of
lifetime resources.17 Generation-specific estimates of ajt,t are obtained by distributing
aggregate personal consumption expenditures in period t according to age-sex profiles of
consumption, and dividing the per capita amounts by total resources per capita.18 Figure 3
depicts average propensities to consume by age and sex for the United States as of 1993 (year
t for this analysis). Consistent with the predictions under the LCH, the propensity to
consume increases with age. For males it increases from 2.0 percent at age 20 to nearly 15
percent by age 80. For female generations, it increases from just under 4.0 percent for 20year-olds to over 17 percent for 80-year-olds. Women’s consumption propensities are much
higher than men’s, especially at younger ages. This reflects the fact that the current
consumption of women relative to men inadequately reflects their lower total resources
because of lower lifetime labor earnings -- a result of the substantial joint consumption of
goods and services that occurs within families.
The net national saving rate can be expressed as
(13)

Ct
Gt
St
¾¾ = 1 - ¾¾ - ¾¾ .
NNPt NNPt
NNPt

Here, St stands for aggregate saving, Gt for government purchases, Ct for aggregate personal
consumption expenditures, and NNPt for the net national product in period t. Together with
the fact that propensities to consume increase with age, equations (12) and (13) imply that
the age structure of the population may be potentially important in determining the aggregate
17

We assume that average and marginal propensities to consume out of lifetime resources are equal and depend
only on age -- a result that emerges when lifetime utility is maximized subject to the lifetime budget constraint under
the life-cyle hypothesis with certainty.
18
Aggregate personal consumption expenditures are those from the National Inome and Product Accounts, and the
relative profiles for distributing the aggregate are based on the Census Bureau’s Consumer Expenditure Surveys
1987-1990. For a detailed description of the method of allocating consumption within households, see Gokhale,
Kotlikoff, and Sabelhaus (1995).

17

saving rate. Figure 4 shows male and female population counts for every twentieth year
between 1900 and 2080.19 The charts clearly show the significant baby boom that begins in
the 1940s and traverses the age distribution over time. As is well known, the occurrence of
that baby boom, together with a lengthening average life span, is expected to increase the
fraction of the elderly in the population.
Given that the elderly consume more out of lifetime resources than do the young, a
significant change in the share of the elderly may be expected to boost aggregate
consumption and reduce aggregate saving. How large is this effect? To investigate this,
population counts for year t, pxjt,t in equation (12) are replaced by those consistent with the
population age distribution for year s, s¹t, while at the same time maintaining the total
population at its year-t level. This experiment isolates the impact on the net national saving
rate of changes in the age distribution of the total population, assuming that age-specific
propensities to consume and per capita resources remain at their year-t (1993) levels.
Figure 5 depicts saving rates that result from substituting the year-s age structure of
the population into equation (12) for s ranging from 1960 to 2030. This time span is chosen
because the oldest baby boomers entered the labor force during the early 1960s and the
youngest boomers will have retired by 2030. The figure suggests that the impact of the
population’s age structure on national saving can be quite substantial. It also shows that
changes in this structure may have contributed significantly to the decline in U.S. national
saving rates that began in the mid 1970s and continued through the 1980s and early 1990s.20

19

Population counts after 1995 are from the Social Security Administration’s population projections, and extensions
of these projections made by the author as described earlier.
20
The changing age structure prior to 1975 should have increased U.S. saving rates. However, other factors like
shifting age-resource profiles in favor of older generations may have helped to maintain saving rates. See Gokhale,
Kotlikoff, and Sabelhaus (1995) for a description of the evolution of U.S. saving rates during the post-war period,
and for an analysis of other factors affecting national saving.

18

In 1993, the aggregate saving rate was 2.7 percent. With the population age structure
that existed in the late 1970s, when a significant fraction of the population (the baby-boom
generation) was in its low-consumption-propensity years, the 1993 saving rate could have
been over 85 percent higher than its actual 1993 level. Figure 5 also shows that the
population structure in the coming century is not likely to provide a fillip to national saving.
Just after the turn of the century, members of the baby boomlet that will follow the baby
boomers are expected to reach ages when consumption propensities are low, while the baby
boomers themselves will not yet have entered ages with significantly higher consumption
propensities. Using the population age structure from the year 2010 produces only a slight
uptick in the saving rate. Substituting in the age structure projected after 2010, however,
produces a decline, reflecting a predominant increase in the number of baby boomers at
ages with high consumption propensities.

IX. Conclusion
The technique of generational accounting enables the measurement of the
intergenerational resource transfers that occur through fiscal policy. A generational
accounting analysis of the United States shows that the nation’s fiscal policy is unsustainable,
in that its continuation will require placing immense fiscal burdens on future generations.
This conclusion remains robust over a reasonably wide range of future discount- and
growth-rate assumptions and over optimistic federal health care outlay and population
projections. Under optimistic health care projections, about half of future generations’
lifetime labor earnings will have to be taxed away, on average. Under optimistic
demographic projections, 70 percent will have to be taken away.

19

The ongoing demographic transition in the United States most likely boosted national
saving prior to 1980, and probably accounted for a sizable part of the decline in U.S. national
saving rates thereafter. Any future increase in the number of young individuals with low
consumption propensities will be outweighed by the entry of the baby boomers into ages
with high consumption propensities. As a result, future demographic changes are likely to
exert further downward pressure on national saving.

20

References
Ando, A. and Modigliani, F. (1963) “The ‘Life Cycle’ hypothesis of saving: Aggregate
implications and tests.” American Economic Review, vol. 53, no. 1, part 1, 55-84.
Auerbach, A., Gokhale, J., and Kotlikoff, L. (1991) “Generational accounts: A meaningful
alternative to deficit accounting.” D. Bradford, ed. Tax Policy and the Economy, National
Bureau of Economic Research, 6, 55-110.
Auerbach, A., Gokhale, J., and Kotlikoff, L. (1994) “Generational accounting: A meaningful
way to evaluate fiscal policy.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 8, no. 1, 73-94.
Auerbach, A., Gokhale, J., Kotlikoff, L., and Steigum, E. (1992) “Generational accounting in
Norway: Is the nation over-consuming its petroleum wealth?” Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland, Working Paper No. 9205.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (1994) Balance Sheets of the U.S.
Economy 1945-1993 (1994), Flow of Funds, Washington, D.C.
Franco, D., Gokhale, J., Guiso, L., Kotlikoff, L., and Sartor, N. (1994) “Generational
accounting: The case of Italy.” A. Ando, L. Guiso, and I. Visco, eds. Saving and the
Accumulation of Wealth: Essays on Italian Household and Government Saving Behaviour,
Cambridge University Press, 128-160.
Gokhale, J., Kotlikoff, L. and Sabelhaus, J. (forthcoming) “Understanding the postwar
decline in United States saving: A cohort analysis.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity.
Gokhale, J., Raffelhüschen, B., and Walliser, J. (1995) “The burden of German unification: a
generational accounting approach.” FinanzArchiv, Neue Folge, Band 52, Heft 2.
Kotlikoff, L. (1992) Generational accounting: Knowing Who Pays, and When, for What We
Spend, The Free Press, New York.
Lee, R. (forthcoming) “A cross-cultural perspective on intergenerational transfers and the
economic life cycle.” In the proceedings of the September 1995 International Union for the
Scientific Study of Population/East-West Center Conference on Intergenerational Economic
Relations and Demographic Change.
Oreopoulos, P. (1995) “A generational accounting approach to Canadian public policy.”
Manuscript, Huron College, University of Western Ontario.
Survey Research Center, University of Michigan (1963 and 1983), Survey of Consumer
Finances, Ann Arbor, Michigan.
Tuljapurkar, S. and Lee, R. (forthcoming) “Demographic Uncertainty and the OASDI Fund.”
In the proceedings of the September 1995 International Union for the Scientific Study of

21

Population/East-West Center Conference on Intergenerational Economic Relations and
Demographic Change.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, (various years), Current Population
Survey, Washington D.C.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis (various years), Survey of
Current Business, Washington, D.C.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census (various years) Survey of Income and
Program Participation, Washington D.C.
U.S. Social Security Administration (various years) Annual Statistical Supplement to the
Social Security Bulletin, Washington, D.C.

22
Table 1. The composition of male generational accounts (r=.06, g=.012)
(Present values in thousands of 1993 dollars)
___________________________________________________________________________________________________

generation's
age in 1993

net
payment

0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
45
50
55
60
65
70
75
80
85
90

86.8
106.9
130.2
160.0
188.6
199.5
195.4
182.5
158.4
119.4
67.7
6.9
-57.2
-105.2
-108.4
-100.6
-85.8
-75.3
-57.6

Future
generations

tax payments
_________________________________

transfer receipts
_________________________

labor
income
taxes

OASDI

39.8
49.1
60.0
73.7
86.6
92.1
90.7
86.1
78.0
65.8
50.6
34.0
18.1
7.2
3.1
1.6
0.9
0.6
0.5

capital
income
taxes

payroll
taxes

9.6
12.1
15.2
19.2
24.1
28.5
33.7
39.9
45.0
47.7
48.2
46.2
42.5
37.3
29.5
19.8
9.9
0.0
0.0

38.2
47.7
59.0
73.7
88.1
94.4
92.9
88.0
79.8
67.6
52.5
35.5
18.9
7.2
3.2
1.6
0.9
0.7
0.5

excise
taxes
34.4
40.1
46.2
52.7
57.0
57.1
55.9
54.6
53.3
50.1
45.7
40.2
34.1
28.2
22.6
17.1
11.9
7.9
6.2

8.8
10.9
12.9
14.9
16.7
19.8
23.7
28.9
35.7
43.8
54.2
67.4
83.8
93.6
85.7
71.5
54.3
41.8
32.8

health

22.5
26.3
31.0
36.4
40.8
42.5
44.3
48.0
53.4
60.1
67.8
75.1
81.0
86.3
76.6
65.4
52.5
40.9
30.6

welfare

3.9
5.0
6.3
8.0
9.7
10.3
9.9
9.2
8.6
7.9
7.3
6.6
5.9
5.1
4.5
3.7
2.7
1.8
1.4

213.6

Lifetime net tax rate on future generations:
82.80
Lifetime net tax rate on age 0 generations:
33.64
Percentage difference, future vs. age 0:
146.13
_____________________________________________________________________________________________________
Source: Author’s calculations.

23
Table 2. The composition of female generational accounts (r=.06, g=.012)
(Present values in thousands of 1993 dollars)
_____________________________________________________________________________________________________
tax payments
_________________________________

transfer receipts
_________________________

generation's
age in 1993

net
payment

labor
income
taxes

capital
income
taxes

payroll
taxes

excise
taxes

OASDI

health

welfare

0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
45
50
55
60
65
70
75
80
85
90

53.0
64.3
77.2
93.1
109.2
114.7
109.2
97.3
76.0
42.4
-0.8
-50.4
-101.5
-139.5
-140.5
-131.1
-111.3
-88.3
-64.4

23.0
28.3
34.6
42.3
49.4
51.1
48.4
44.3
39.1
31.8
23.4
14.7
7.3
2.6
1.0
0.5
0.3
0.1
0.1

10.2
12.8
16.1
20.4
25.5
30.7
35.8
41.2
44.5
45.3
44.1
41.8
38.2
32.1
22.6
12.4
4.7
0.0
0.0

23.2
29.0
35.9
44.7
53.2
55.7
53.1
49.0
43.6
35.8
26.7
16.9
8.5
3.0
1.2
0.5
0.3
0.1
0.1

33.1
38.5
43.9
49.4
53.2
53.8
53.3
52.8
51.4
48.5
44.3
39.3
33.7
28.0
22.8
17.3
12.6
9.4
7.1

8.4
10.3
12.2
14.0
15.7
18.8
22.4
27.4
33.8
41.8
52.3
66.0
83.2
92.2
84.9
72.0
57.0
42.8
32.4

18.4
21.6
25.6
30.4
34.6
38.5
43.2
50.1
59.1
70.0
81.2
92.5
102.0
109.6
100.0
87.1
69.9
53.4
38.1

9.8
12.3
15.4
19.2
21.7
19.4
15.8
12.5
9.7
7.3
5.7
4.6
3.9
3.5
3.1
2.6
2.2
1.7
1.3

Future
generations
130.4
_____________________________________________________________________________________________________
Source: Author’s calculations.

24
_________________________________________________________________________________________
Table 3a. Lifetime net tax rates for 1993 newborn generations under alternative
interest rate and growth rate assumptions

growth rate
(percent)

interest rate (percent)
____________________________________
3.0
6.0
9.0

0.7

29.5

1.2

22.7

40.4
33.6

46.5
39.7

1.7
16.9
27.9
33.8
__________________________________________________________________________________________
Source: Author’s calculations.

__________________________________________________________________________________________
Table 3b. Lifetime net tax rates for future generations under alternative interest rate and
growth rate assumptions
interest rate (percent)
____________________________________
3.0
6.0
9.0
growth rate
(percent)
0.7

65.1

103.8

1.2

49.9

82.8

175.8
142.5

1.7
37.7
65.7
115.2
__________________________________________________________________________________________
Source: Author’s calculations.

__________________________________________________________________________________________
Table 3c. Percentage difference in net tax burdens: future generations versus current newborns
under alternative interest and growth rate assumptions
interest rate (percent)
____________________________________
3.0

6.0

0.7

120.3

157.2

1.2

119.7

growth rate
(percent)

146.1

9.0

277.8
259.1

1.7
122.4
135.8
241.0
__________________________________________________________________________________________
Source: Author’s calculations.

25
Table 4. Generational accounts under alternative federal health care outlay projections
base case
_______________
male
female
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
45
50
55
60
65
70
75
80
85
90
Future
Generations
Percentage
difference

86.8
106.9
130.2
160.0
188.6
199.5
195.4
182.5
158.4
119.4
67.7
6.9
-57.2
-105.2
-108.4
-100.6
-85.8
-75.3
-57.6

53.0
64.3
77.2
93.1
109.2
114.7
109.2
97.3
76.0
42.4
-0.8
-50.4
-101.5
-139.5
-140.5
-131.1
-111.3
-88.3
-64.4

health care
stabilization
begins in 1996
_______________
male
female
96.8
118.6
143.8
175.5
205.2
216.8
213.9
203.1
182.1
147.0
99.3
40.8
-24.6
-78.1
-88.0
-86.8
-77.5
-70.8
-55.4

health care
stabilization
begins in 2003
_______________
male
female

61.4
74.3
88.9
106.9
125.0
132.4
129.2
120.9
104.1
75.8
38.5
-6.9
-58.0
-101.1
-109.7
-109.0
-97.5
-80.9
-61.0

91.5
112.3
136.3
166.8
195.9
207.3
203.9
192.3
170.2
133.7
84.2
23.2
-44.0
-95.7
-102.6
-97.6
-84.6
-74.9
-57.5

57.1
69.2
82.9
99.9
117.0
123.5
119.2
109.2
90.5
60.2
20.2
-28.8
-82.6
-124.5
-130.2
-125.2
-108.7
-87.4
-64.3

213.6
130.4
_______________

128.5
81.5
_______________

173.7
108.4
_______________

146.1

32.8

89.8

Lifetime net tax rates:
Newborn
Future generations

33.6
82.8

38.1
50.5

______________________________________________________________________________
Source: Author’s calculations.

35.8
67.9

26
Table 5. Generational accounts under alternative population projections (r=.06, g=.012)
(Present values in thousands of 1993 dollars)
_____________________________________________________________________________________________________
Alternative I
_______________________
generation's
Age in 1993
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
45
50
55
60
65
70
75
80
85
90
Future
generations
Percentage
difference

male

female

86.8
107.2
131.0
161.9
190.4
199.7
194.8
181.7
157.7
118.9
67.6
7.4
-55.9
-103.3
-106.2
-98.5
-84.2
-74.2
-56.9

52.7
64.1
77.2
93.5
109.5
114.3
108.4
96.5
75.4
42.0
-0.7
-49.8
-99.9
-136.9
-137.4
-128.1
-109.0
-86.8
-63.6

Alternative II
_______________________
male

female

86.8
106.9
130.2
160.0
188.6
199.5
195.4
182.5
158.4
119.4
67.7
6.9
-57.2
-105.2
-108.4
-100.6
-85.8
-75.3
-57.6

53.0
64.3
77.2
93.1
109.2
114.7
109.2
97.3
76.0
42.4
-0.8
-50.4
-101.5
-139.5
-140.5
-131.1
-111.3
-88.3
-64.4

Alternative III
_______________________
male

female

86.8
106.7
129.8
158.7
186.9
198.6
194.8
182.3
158.6
119.7
67.7
6.3
-58.4
-107.0
-110.5
-102.6
-87.4
-76.4
-58.2

53.0
64.3
77.0
92.7
108.8
114.6
109.4
97.6
76.2
42.4
-1.0
-51.2
-103.1
-141.8
-143.4
-133.9
-113.6
-89.8
-65.2

191.2
116.1
__________________

213.6
130.4
__________________

239.4
146.2
__________________

120.3

146.1

175.7

Lifetime net tax rates:
Newborn
32.3
33.6
34.5
Future generations
71.1
82.8
95.0
____________________________________________________________________________________________________
Source: Author’s calculations.

Source: Author’s calculations.

Source: Author’s calculations.