View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Workine P a ~ e r8813

DECOMPOSING TFP GROWTH IN THE PRESENCE OF COST INEFFICIENCY,
NONCONSTANT RETURNS TO SCALE, AND TECHNOLOGICAL PROGRESS

by Paul W. Bauer

Paul W. Bauer is an economist at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland. The author would
like to thank Michael Bagshaw and C.A. Knox
Love11 for helpful comments. John R. Swinton
provided valuable research assistance.
Working papers of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland are preliminary materials circulated
to stimulate discussion and critical comment.
The views stated herein are those of the author
and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System.

December 1988

ABSTRACT

Productivity growth is a major source of economic growth; thus, an
understanding of how and why productivity measures change is of great interest
to economists and policymakers. This paper explores the relationship between
observed total factor productivity (TFP) growth, defined using an index number
approach, and examines changes in returns to scale, cost efficiency, and
technology.

Several decompositions are developed, using alternatively

production and cost frontiers.
for multiple outputs.

The last decomposition developed also allows

DECOMPOSING TFP GROWTH IN THE PRESENCE OF COST INEFFICIENCY,
NONCONSTANT RETURNS TO SCALE. AND TECHNOLOGICAL PROGRESS

I. Introduction
Measures of productivity have long enjoyed a great deal of interest among
researchers analyzing firm performance and behavior. The observed growth in
total factor productivity (TFP) is one of the most widely employed measures of
overall productivity. The conventional Divisia index of TFP is defined as1

(1)

TFP

=

- F, where

where y is observed output, F is an aggregate measure of observed input usage,
w, is the price of the i-th input, xi is the observed use of the
i-th input, and C is the observed cost.2
Ohta (1974) and Denny, Fuss, and Waverman (1981), among others, have shown
that in the single-product case, with constant returns to scale and cost
efficiency, TFP growth equals technological progress. With nonconstant
returns to scale and cost efficiency, TFP growth is equal to technological
progress plus a term that adjusts for the degree of returns to scale:

where f is the production function, x is the vector of inputs, t is a time
index, and

ecy

is the cost elasticity with respect to output.

This paper extends the decomposition of observed TFP growth by showing how
changes in cost efficiency over time also affect the observed measure of TFP

growth. The observed measure of TFP is decomposed into various components
roughly stemming from changes in returns to scale, in cost efficiency, and in
technological progress. Biased estimates of firm or industry performance will
result if changes in cost efficiency are ignored. Furthermore, since these
decompositions are derived from an observed quantity, the appropriate
decomposition could be included in the estimation of the frontier as an
additional equation, thus improving the statistical precision of the estimates
by providing additional information and increasing the number of degrees of
freedom.
In section I1 of this paper, TFP growth is decomposed using a production
function approach. Section I11 derives the decomposition using a cost
function approach for both the single-product and multiproduct firm. Section
IV presents some empirical examples of the use of some of these
decompositions, and the conclusion appears in Section V.

11. Production Function Approach
Let the production frontier be defined as

where y* is the maximum amount of output that can be produced with input
vector x at time t.

A Farrell-type, output-based measure of technical efficiency can be
defined as follows:

T
P

=-

J

f (x.,
t) '

where 0 < Tp 5 1.

The first TFP decomposition can be derived as follows. First, take the
natural log of both sides of (5) and totally differentiate it with respect to
time:

(6)

dlnTp =
dt

dlny dt

C
i

alnf(x,t) dxi
dt
axi

+

alnf(x,t)
at

-

This can be rewritten as

where

Tp is

the time rate of change of technical efficiency and &(x, t)

is the time rate of change of technological progress as measured by shifts in
the production frontier over time.
Next,(7) can be rearranged using the definition of observed TFP in (1):

The following substitutions can be made:

(9

ci(x,t)

=

af(x,t)
and
ax,
f(x,'
Xi

where ci(x,t) is the output elasticity of the i-th input and si is the
observed share of the i-th input. This yields the following decomposition:

which decomposes observed TFP growth into change in technical efficiency,
technological progress, and a term that depends on the degree of the inputspecific returns to scale and cost inefficiency.

This decomposition yields

the intuitive result that advances in both technological progress and
technical efficiency increase observed TFP growth. While the first two terms
have straightfornard interpretations, the last term requires further
explanation.
This term has two informative properties. First, under cost efficiency,
this term is equal to the last term in (3) , since cost minimization requires

(12)

af = 2,
£or a11
axi

i.

Second, when the firm is cost inefficient, this last term is a bundle composed
of nonconstant returns to scale and both technical and allocative
inefficiency. One can further decompose this term using duality; however, the
cost function approach developed in the next section does this in a much more
straightforward manner. But first, consider the relation between this
decomposition and that of Nishimizu and Page (1982).

Nishimizu and Page derived their decomposition as follows. First, they
define what might be called the "average" production function, g(x,t), as

In contrast to the frontier production function, f(x,t), the observed
production function yields what each firm actually produces. They transform
(13) by taking the natural logarithm and totally differentiating with respect
to time to obtain

(14)

$(x,t)

=

y -

1,

eg,(x,t) xi,

where egi(x,t) is the output elasticity of the i-th input with respect
to the "average" production function.
Nishimizu and Page then employ an alternative approach to defining TFP.
Instead of defining TFP with respect to a Divisia index, they define TFP with
respect to the rate of shift in the "average" production function, g(~,t).~
The next step in deriving their decomposition is to rewrite equation (7)

(15

9

=

'$ +

f(x,t)

+

ri(x,t) i,.

Substituting for y in (14) and simplifying yields

This is the Nishimizu and Page decomposition; equation (16) separates observed
TFP growth into technological progress, change in efficiency, and differences
in output elasticities between the frontier and the interior for a firm
operating in the interior. While (16) is quite similar in form to (ll), there
are two important differences.
First, it must be recalled that Nishimizu and Page employ a different
definition of TFP than the one employed here. They define it to be the rate
of shift in the "average" production function, whereas the decompositions
derived here are based on a definition of observed TFP using the Divisia
index. The potential advantage of the latter approach is that it creates the
possibility of adding another equation to the system to be estimated (in
addition to the cost and input share equations) since the left side of
equation(11) is observed and the right side of equation (11) is a function of
Including the TFP equation in the
the parameters to be e~timated.~
regression increases the number of degrees of freedom (since no new parameters
are added) and also provides information that is not found in the cost or
input demand equations.
Second, the use of an "average" production function, g(x,t), may be of use
conceptually, given Nishimizu and Page's assumption that firms operating away
from the frontier have a good reason for doing so. This is not useful
empirically, however, because g(x,t) cannot be estimated simultaneously with

the frontier production function unless the reason for the deviation from the
frontier is also modeled. Without this type of modeling, the only possible
definition of g(x, t) is

(17)

g(x,t)

=

f(x,t)

-

T,.

This implies that their "average" production function models not only the
frontier production function, but also inefficiency. In other words, it
predicts the level of inefficiency--with the same arguments as the frontier
production function. The cost function TFP decompositions are now derived.

111. Cost Function Approach
The TFP decomposition is first derived in the case of the single-product
firm and is then generalized for the multiproduct firm. Let the singleproduct cost frontier be represented by

where C* is the efficient cost given (y,w,t). Following Farrell (1957), an
overall measure of cost efficiency may be defined as

From these input-based measures of technical and allocative efficiency, one
can derive

(20)

E

=

T . A , which implies

(21)

E

=

T + A ,(which will be used later),

where T and A are the Farrell measures of technical and allocative efficiency,
respectively.
The decomposition of TFP growth can now be derived using the cost function
approach. Taking the natural logarithm of each side of (19), totally
differentiating, and making a few minor substitutions yields

t) .
)
where ~ ~ ~ ( y , w=, tdlnC(y,w,
alny

Using the definition of observed TFP in equation

(I), equation(22) can be simplified as follows:

At this point, note the following:

(26)

c

2 7ki +
WiXi

=

i

c,, and
i

Substituting (27) into (23) yields

Substituting (21) into (28) and making some straightforward substitutions
yields the single-product cost function decomposition of observed TFP:

This expression decomposes TFP growth into terms related to returns to scale,
changes in technical and allocative efficiency, technological progress, and a
residual term (which will be discussed below).

This decomposition is

consistent with expectations; in particular, the expectation that increases in
cost efficiency increase observed TFP.
The last term clearly reflects the presence of allocative inefficiency.
If the firm is allocatively efficient, then si=si(y,w,t), and this term is
equal to zero. This term is also equal to zero when input prices change at
the same rate, since

~ [ S ~ - S , ( ~t)]=O.
,W,
i

Some insight into this term

can be obtained by noting that in the presence of allocative inefficiency,
since the observed input shares, si,are not equal to the efficient input
shares, si(y,w,t), the aggregate index of input usage F (used to define
observed TFP) does not weight the observed inputs according to the costminimizing input shares. The last term corrects for any bias this may have on
observed TFP.

A multiproduct version of the decomposition can also be derived. For the
multiproduct firm, observed TFP is usually defined as6

(30)

TFP

=

9P

P

- I?, where jr

=

PjYj
1-9
R i.

and F

1 WiXi
c kip
i

j

where

=

9 is a revenue-weighted index of output, F is a cost share index of

aggregate input usage, wi is the price of the i-th input, xi is the
observed use of the i-th input, and C is the observed cost.
Using the same basic steps used in the single-product case above for
handling cost inefficiency and in Denny, Fuss, and Waverman(1981) for
handling multiple outputs, observed TFP for a multiproduct firm can be shown
to be equal to the following:

+

1i

P

c

[si-si(y,w,z,t)] wi + (y -y ) , where y

=

This expression decomposes TFP growth into terms related to ray returns to
scale, changes in technical and allocative efficiency, and technological
progress. The next-to-last term has the same properties as the last term in
equation (25).

The last term simply measures any effect that nonmarginal cost

pricing may have on the observed measure of TFP. Denny, Fuss, and Waverman
have shown that F=yc under marginal cost pricing and proportional markup
pricing.
These TFP decompositions provide useful conceptual and empirical tools for
assigning the observed changes in TFP growth to the various root sources.
Note that the cost function approach provides a more complete partitioning of
the sources of observed TFP growth than the production approach did.

IV. Empirical Application
This section illustrates a use of one of the multiproduct TFP
decompositions. The example is drawn from the U.S. airline industry, and
these results are discussed more fully in Bauer (1988).

First, the model that

was estimated and the data set that was employed are briefly discussed; then
the empirical results and the TFP decomposition are presented.
The translog system of cost and input share equations that was estimated
is presented below (omitting firm and time subscripts):

where y is a vector of outputs, w is a vector of input prices, z is a vector
of network characteristics, and t is a time index. The translog functional
form was selected on the basis of its being a second-order approximation to
any cost function about a point of expansion(here, the sample means) .'
Note that the network and time variables were not interacted with input prices
in order to reduce the number of parameters to a manageable level and to
lessen the effects of multicollinearity. Symmetry and linear homogeneity in
input prices impose the following restrictions on the cost system:

By construction, lsi(y,w)=l, so that one input share equation must be
i

dropped before estimation to avoid singularity. Barten (1969) has
shown that asymptotically, the parameter estimates are invariant as to which
input share equation is dropped.

The following distributional assumptions are imposed. The inefficiency
term,
mode

p

%t,

is assumed to follow a truncated-normal distribution with

and underlying variance oU2 such that

term, vnt, is assumed to be independent of

I+,2 0.

The noise

xtand to follow a

normal distribution with mean zero and variance ov2. The disturbances on
the input share equations are assumed to follow a multivariate normal
distribution: wnt = (wlnt7
. . . , +-l,nt) '

cv

N(a, n) .

The likelihood function for this system can be written as8
(35)

lnL

=

- TNM ln(2n)
2

- (TN)

-

lno"

T,N lnlnl

-

ln[l-F*((-a) (A-~+I)"~)]

-

(writ-a)'
1
t n

n-l

(writ-a).

Maximum likelihood estimates can be obtained for all the parameters in (35),
and these estimates will be asymptotically efficient. A number of
specification tests can be performed using likelihood ratio tests similar to
those proposed by Stevenson (1980).
The data set employed in this paper was constructed by Robin Sickles using
the AIMS 41 form that all interstate airlines were required to submit
periodically as part of the Civil Aeronautics Board's regulation of the
industry. Included are 12 firms and 48 quarters of data from 1970:IQ to
1981:IVQ. The airline industry is considered to produce revenue passenger ton
miles (y ) and revenue cargo ton miles (yc) using four inputs: labor (L),
P

capital (K),

energy (E),

and materials (M).

Labor is an aggregate of 55

separate labor accounts; capital is a combination of flight equipment, ground

equipment, and landing fees; energy is the quantity of fuel used converted to

BTU equivalents; and materials is an aggregate of 56 different accounts
composed mainly of advertising, insurance, commissions, and passenger
meals.
The network through which airlines supply their outputs has an important
influence on the cost of providing that output. The average load factor,
zldf, for a given airline in a given time period is the proportion of an

airline's capacity that is actually sold in that time period. The average
stage length, zStgl, is the average distance of an airline's flights in
a given quarter. These two network characteristics are incorporated into the
two translog cost models as presented in equation (32).
From table 1 it can be seen that all but two of the parameter estimates
are statistically significant. The parameters reported here are from a model
slightly more restricted than the one developed in section 111. Instead of
the more general truncated-normal distribution, the half-normal distribution
was assumed, which is equivalent to restricting p=0.

This restriction could

not be rejected using a t-test based on the results of the more general model.
Table 2 reports the results of the TFP decomposition technique. Observed
TFP grew on average for all of the firms, although there was a great deal of
variation across firms. Much of this increase is the result of technological
progress that ran at a rate of 0.274 percent per quarter, as reported earlier.
The scale effect was a significant source of TFP gains for the smaller
airlines, which were free to grow under the regulatcry reform process, but not
for the four largest airlines. The inefficiency effects varied consider'ably
from airline to airline, but were generally small. Over time, changes in the
airlines' networks have generally boosted productivity. The average load

factors and stage lengths of the airlines have risen (although unevenly across
airlines), each resulting in increases in observed TFP of about the same order
of magnitude as those stemming from technological progress.
The biases in the observed measure of TFP as a result of nonrnarginal cost
pricing (the output effect) and observed input shares not being equal to the
least-cost input shares(the price effect) are found to have a small effect on
observed TFP. A "pure" measure of TFP growth could be constructed by summing
the scale, cost efficiency, technological change, and network effects. In
general, these estimates indicate that the observed measure of TFP is a biased
estimate of technological progress, not just because of the scale and output
effects (as Denny, Fuss, and Waverman have shown), but also because of the
efficiency, network, and input price effects.

V. Conclusion
Observed TFP growth has been decomposed into scale, change in efficiency,
and technological progress effects using both production and cost function
approaches for both single-product and multiproduct firms. The production
function approach was compared to the decomposition of Nishimizu and Page
(1982) and was found to have at least the possible advantage that the observed
TFP equation might be added to the system of equations to be estimated. In
addition, the decomposition derived here does not depend on the artificial
construction of an "average" production function. In this respect, the
decomposition proposed here seems to be more firmly based in cost theory and
efficiency measurement.
The decompositions of TFP developed here will have at least two uses in
empirical work. First, there is the potential that the TFP equation could be

added to the system of equations to be estimated. Since this equation
provides information not contained in the others and increases the number of
degrees of freedom, better estimates of technology (as embodied in the
production or cost function) and the level of cost efficiency will be
obtained. Second, it will also be of use in interpreting and explaining
empirical results. For example, TFP growth has been negative in some
industries in recent years--a fact that is sometimes difficult to explain in a
framework that does not allow for cost inefficiency (see Gollop and Roberts
[1981]). Using this decomposition, negative TFP growth could turn out to be a

result of declines in cost efficiency, both technical and allocative.

Footnotes

Variables with a dot over them are defined as follows:

i

=

dlnz
dt .

See Jorgenson and Griliches (1967), Richter (1966), Hulten (1973),
Diewert (1976), and Denny, Fuss, and Waverman (1981), among others, for
uses of this definition.
Returns to scale can be defined as follows: RTS

=

1i ei(x, t) .

For a discussion of the various approaches to defining TFP growth, see
Diewert (1981).
Exactly how to implement this potential advantage both econometrically
and practically has not yet been solved.
See Denny, Fuss, and Waverman (1981).

' Though the

translog functional form is a second-order approximation of
the cost function at a point, it is generally only a first-order
approximation of the economic measures of technology derived from the cost
function. For example, note that the observed input shares are only a
linear function of the regressors, being the first derivative of the log of
the cost function.

Strictly speaking, it is incorrect to model the disturbances in the cost
and input share equations as being independent, given the interdependence
However, as Schmidt (1984) pointed out, these
of alnAJalnwint and %,.
terms will tend to be uncorrelated, since both negative and positive
deviations from efficient shares raise costs.
For a more detailed description of this data set see Sickles (1985).

Table 1
MLE Parameter Estimates
Parameters

Estimate

Asymptotic Standard Error

*Not statistically significant at the 0.01 level of significance.
Source: Author's calculations.

Table 2
TFP Decomposition
(Average quarterly rate of change, in percent)

Airline TFP

Scale
Effect

Output
Effect

Eff. Technical Price
Effect Change
Effect

Load
Factor

Stage
Length

AA
AL

BR

co
DL

EA
F'L

NC

oz
PI
UA
WA

Source: Author's calculations.
The key to the carrier abbreviations are as follows:
American AA
AL
USAir
Braniff BR

Continental CO
Delta
DL
EA
Eastern

Frontier
FL
North Central NC
Ozark
OZ

Piedmont PI
United
UA
Western WA

References
Bauer, Paul W. "TFP Growth, Change in Efficiency, and Technological
Progress in the U.S. Airline Industry: 1970 to 1981," Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland Working- Paoer 8804, June 1988.
Denny, Michael, Melvyn Fuss, and Leonard Waverman. "The Measurement
and Interpretation of Total Factor Productivity in Regulated
Industries, with an Application to Canadian Telecommunications," in
Productivitv Measurement in Regulated Industries, T.G. Cowing and R.E.
Stevenson, eds., New York: Academic Press, 1981, pp. 179-218.
Diewert, W,E. "Exact and Superlative Index Numbers,'' Journal of
Econometrics, 4 (May 1976), pp. 115-145.
Diewert, W.E. "The Theory of Total Factor Productivity Measurement in
Regulated Industries," in Productivitv Measurement in Regulated
Industries, T.G. Cowing and R.E. Stevenson, eds., New York: Academic
Press 1981, pp. 17-44.
Fare, R., S. Grosskopf, and C.A. Knox Lovell. The Measurement of the
Efficiency of Production, Boston: Kluwer-NijhoffPublishing Co.,
1985.
Farrell, M.J. "The Measurement of Productive Efficiency," Journal of the
Royal Statistical Societv, General Series A, vol. 120, part 3 (1957),
pp. 253-281.
Gollop, Frank M., and Mark J. Roberts. "The Sources of Economic Growth
in the U.S. Electric Power Industry," in Productivitv Measurement in
Re~ulatedIndustries, T.G. Cowing and R. E. Stevenson eds., New York:
Academic Press, 1981, pp. 107-143.
Hulten, C.R. "Divisia Index Numbers," Econometrica, vol. 41 (November
1973), pp. 1017-1026.
Jorgenson, D.W., and 2. Griliches. "The Explanation of Productivity
Change," Review of Economic Studies, vol. 34 (July 1967), pp. 249-283.
Nishimizu, Mieko, and John M. Page. "Total Factor Productivity Growth,
Technological Progress and Technical Efficiency Change: Dimensions of
Productivity Change in Yugoslavia, 1965-78," The Economic Journal,
vol. 92 (December 1982), pp. 920-936.
Ohta, M. "A Note on the Duality Between Production and Cost Functions:
Rates of Return to Scale and Rates of Technical Progress," Economic
Studies Quarterlv, vol. 25 (December 1974), pp. 63-65.

Richter, M.K. "Invariance Axioms and Economic Indexes," Econometrica,
vol. 34 (October 1966), pp. 739-755.
Sickles, Robin C. "A Nonlinear Multivariate Error Components Analysis of
Technology and Specific Factor Productivity Growth with an Application
to the U.S. Airlines," Journal of Econometrics, vol. 27, no. 1 (January
1985), pp. 61-78.
Stevenson, Rodney E. "Likelihood Functions for Generalized Stochastic
Frontier Estimation," Journal of Econometrics, vol. 13, no. 1 (May
1980), pp. 57-66.