View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Working Paver 8815

BANKRUPTCY IN THE LIFE-CYCLE CONSUMPTION MODEL

By Kim J. Kowalewski

Kim J. Kowalewski is an economist at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland. He is currently on
leave as a Senior Staff Economist at the Council
of Economic Advisers.
Working Papers of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland are preliminary materials circulated
to stimulate discussion and critical comment.
The views stated herein are those of the author
and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System.

December 1988

BANKRUPTCY IN THE LIFE-CYCLE CONSUMPTION MODEL
I. Introduction
The standard life-cycle model of consumption assumes that loans are always
fully repaid, even when future income is uncertain. Zeldes (1986) shows that
these two assumptions imply, in the context of constant relative risk
aversion, that current consumption is very sensitive to current income. He
concludes that recent tests of the "excess" sensitivity of consumption
spending to transitory income are erroneous because the "excess" sensitivity
evident in the data is a natural outcome of the life-cycle model and not an
indication of liquidity-constrained behavior.
This paper investigates the effects of dropping the assumption that loans
are fully repaid with probability one. It solves, using stochastic dynamic
programming, a four-period, life-cycle model of individual consumption
behavior that includes the possibility of a Chapter 7 or liquidation
bankruptcy. One important characteristic of this model is that the
partial-equilibrium effects of bankruptcy raise the demand for borrowing and
current consumption. This loosens the connection between current consumption
and income, thereby providing a rationale for using "excess" sensitivity of
consumption to unexpected changes in current income as an indicator of
liquidity-constrained behavior.
Bankruptcy creates a discontinuous optimization problem for consumers. A
Chapter 7 bankruptcy implies a different set of consumption opportunities than

2

the constraint imposed by the capital market.

Bankruptcy entails legal fees,

the loss of some assets as payment to creditors, a tarnished credit rating,
and possibly the social stigma associated with the failure to repay one's
debts. In return, bankruptcy reduces the amount of debts to be repaid, stops
wage garnishment and other legal actions of lenders, and allows the bankrupt
consumer to keep certain assets as a "fresh start" to life after bankruptcy.
In the period of the bankruptcy filing, a consumer optimizes with respect to
the bankruptcy constraint, which is different from the constraint he used
before he filed for bankruptcy. In the periods following the bankruptcy
filing, a consumer may again face different constraints if lenders tighten
credit terms to former bankrupts.
Along with bankruptcy, a second feature of the model is an endogenous
borrowing rate of interest. The borrowing interest rate is greater than the
risk-free lending rate by the explicit default risk created by bankruptcy.
The borrowing rate is endogenously set to equate loan demand with supply by
the requirement that creditors expect to earn zero profits from lending to the
consumer. Thus, the borrowing rate generally rises with the amount borrowed
because greater borrowing raises expected loan losses, directly through the
amount borrowed and indirectly through the probability of default.
The next section of this paper discusses the assumptions of the model.
The third section describes the model's structure. The fourth section
discusses the simulation results, and the last section provides summary and
concluding remarks.

3

11. Assumptions of the Theoretical Model
11.1. Definition of Insolvency
One precondition for bankruptcy is financial distress or insolvency, which
may be defined as the inability to pay contractual obligations, such as
mortgage and installment debts and insurance premiums, in full on a timely
basis.

Insolvency can arise for a number of reasons. Unplanned

income losses, spending needs, and interest-rate increases can place
burdensome demands upon a consumer's financial resources. Simple errors by
consumers and lenders in evaluating the ability to repay debts also appear to
be an important reason for insolvency.

For simplicity, only

contractual debt payments appear in the model.
Note that insolvency is not defined here as the condition that debts are
greater than assets. Insolvency is a flow concept, not a stock concept.
Letting y be labor income in period t, A, be the stock of assets owned in
t

period t, and TLP, be total loan payments due in period t, and excluding all
taxes, a consumer is insolvent when discretionary funds (DF,)
negative:
(1)

DF,

=

y,

+ A, -

TLP, < 0.

are strictly

11.2 Exogenous Income Uncertainty
An 'obvious necessary condition for insolvency is uncertainty about the
future. Without uncertainty, consumers cannot borrow more than they can repay
in some states of the world because their future income and creditworthiness
are known to creditors. Only uncertainty about future labor income is assumed
here because it is the most important source of uncertainty to
consumers.

Current-period income is known, but all future income is

unknown and is assumed to be independently distributed over time. The
probability density function of y is denoted ft, and is assumed
t

to be defined over strictly positive y

t.

Min, and maxt are

the minimum and maximum values of the income distribution. Although the
income probability density function is assumed to be exogenous to the
consumer, the probability of insolvency is endogenous because current spending
actions affect the ability to weather future income declines and, hence, to
avoid bankruptcy.
Although information is imperfect, it is symmetric. Consumers know the
credit-supply function, and creditors know the consumer's reputation and
income probability density functions. Hence, there are no moral hazard or
adverse selection problems of consumers intentionally borrowing more than can
be repaid in every state of the world.

5

11.3 No Alternatives to Bankruptcy

A second precondition for bankruptcy is a lack of viable alternatives to
bankruptcy. Insolvency does not always lead to bankruptcy because the
consumer may be able to refinance his debt with his current creditor or with a
new creditor. If the insolvency is more severe, a consumer may be able to use
the services of a consumer-credit advisory service. Many lenders will
cooperate with these services in order to limit bankruptcy-related costs and
maintain valuable customer relationships. Or, an insolvent consumer may have
the option of a wage-earner trusteeship, such as the one administered by the
Municipal Court in Cleveland, Ohio, to forestall legal action and arrange a
debt repayment plan.
To isolate the response of the optimal consumption path to the possibility
of bankruptcy, all of these alternatives will be ignored in this paper. This
restriction imposes a specific, though not unreasonable, assumption on lender
behavior: all insolvent borrowers are forced into bankruptcy. That is, the
consumer files for bankruptcy in period t if and only if Dl?, < 0.

Gale and

Hellwig (1985) show that this type of loan contract is incentive-compatible in
a one-period model. In the multiperiod model of this paper, this may not be
optimal lender behavior. Indeed, borrowers may be given a grace period to
make up delinquent payments over time because bankruptcy is costly and hurts
customer relations. A more general model would allow the lender greater
freedom in managing the loan, but this feature would only obscure the main
conclusions of the model.
Voluntary bankruptcy is not allowed in order to keep the model simple.

6
11.4 Chapter 7 Bankruptcy
Chapter 13 of the Bankruptcy Code is not truly bankruptcy, but a
court-sponsored debt repayment plan. The full impact of limited liability is
seen in Chapter 7, which is used by the majority of consumers who file for
bankruptcy. Chapter 7 bankruptcy in this model takes a very simple form. In
return for a discharge of all current debts, the consumer must give creditors
all financial assets, plus current-period labor income in excess of that
period's minimum labor income. That is, the minimum value of the probability
density function for labor income in the period of a bankruptcy filing is the
consumer's exempt assets.

11.5 One Bankruptcy per Lifetime
To keep the analysis simple, consumers may file for bankruptcy only once.
This is not a severe restriction because only four periods are examined and
the bankruptcy law prohibits successive Chapter 7 discharges within six years.
This constraint is enforced by assuming that creditors restrict their lending
to former consumer bankrupts. The restriction takes the form of requiring
consumers to repay all debts with probability one; this is the standard Yaari
(1964) life-cycle model analyzed by Zeldes (1986).

Without the possibility of

default, the cost of borrowing after bankruptcy is the risk-free rate.
This reduced borrowing opportunity is the main cost of bankruptcy in the
model. A more complete model would include other costs of bankruptcy, such as
the loss of nonexempt tangible assets.

11.6 The Characteristics of Assets and Debts
Nonhuman assets are perfectly liquid, predictable, and reversible
financial assets that earn the risk-free rate of interest (R-1).

Consumers

may not own durable goods, but may rent their services. All debt is unsecured
and finances spending on nondurable goods and services. There are no
collateral requirements, and no bequests.
Given that the consumer files for bankruptcy when current income and
assets do not cover current debt payments, the specification of loan
maturities is very important. Single-period loans imply a very strict
bankruptcy rule, and hence, a strict constraint on borrowing. Moreover,
multiperiod loans are the rule rather than the exception for consumer lending.
Hence, the longest possible loan maturities are assumed: a loan taken out in
the first period is repaid in equal installments over the following three
periods; a loan taken out in the second period is repaid over the following
two periods; a loan taken out in the third period is repaid in the fourth and
last period.

Borrowing is not allowed in the last period, and loans cannot be

prepaid.
The periodic loan payment (LP,)

for an N-period loan made in period

t of size B, is computed from the present value formula:
(2)

B,

=

LP,/%

+ LP,/R~~LP,/R~~
+ . . .+ LP,/R:,

where Rb is one plus the borrowing rate of interest.

11.7 Zero-Profit Credit Supply Constraint
The key feature of this model is the possibility of less than full debt
repayment in periods before bankruptcy. The implication is that rational

8
creditors must price default risk; before bankruptcy, the supply of credit to
consumers cannot be the perfectly elastic function of the risk-free rate of
interest found in the Yaari life-cycle model.

A conventional approach is to assume a perfectly competitive, risk-neutral
creditor who maximizes expected discounted profits. Revenues are the
contractual loan payments, plus any proceeds from a bankruptcy judgement, and
costs are the cost of funds. There are no transactions costs, and the supply
of funds available to creditors is perfectly elastic at the risk-free rate of
interest.
The credit-supply constraint is the first-order condition for maximizing
discounted expected profits. It equates the discounted expected cost of funds
lent to the consumer with the discounted expected revenues from the loans,
with the borrowing rate of interest as the equilibrating mechanism. For
simplicity, only one borrowing rate is charged for borrowing in all periods
before bankruptcy. That is, creditors make a contingent contract with
borrowers that specifies one borrowing interest rate and the amounts to be
borrowed in every state of the world each period before bankruptcy.
The price of default risk thus is defined as the addition to the risk-free
interest rate necessary to equate the discounted expected revenues from
lending with the discounted expected cost of funds.

In general, the

credit-supply curve will be upward sloping because additional borrowing raises
expected loan losses. Its slope will depend on the probability density
functions of the consumer's labor income and on the demand for credit.
The structure of the credit-supply constraint can be illustrated with a
three-period problem and a two-point probability function for labor income.

9

Let p

t,k

denote the p r o b a b i l i t y t h a t income i n period t i s low (k=l) or

high (k=2). Assume t h a t bankruptcy i s impossible i n t h e f i r s t period, the
optimal solution implies bankruptcy i n the low-income s t a t e i n periods two and
t h r e e , borrowing (B1) occurs i n the f i r s t period and borrowing
(B2,2) occurs i n the high-income s t a t e i n period two, and t h a t there a r e
no bequests.

The consumer repays B1 i n equal installments (LP1)

i n the following two periods and B2,2 i s f u l l y repaid with i n t e r e s t i n
the t h i r d period.

The debt payment LP1

=

B ~ ( R ~ ) ~ / ( from
~ + Requation
~)
(2).

Creditors match the maturity of t h e i r debts t o t h e i r a s s e t s , repaying
f i r s t - p e r i o d borrowing i n equal installments of CP1 i n periods two and
three and (R)(BZs2)i n period t h r e e .

Then the discounted expected c o s t

of funds t o the c r e d i t o r i s :
CP1/R + C ~ , / R ~+ P2,,(R) ( B ~ , ~ ) / R ~ ,

and t h e discounted expected r e t u r n from lending i s :
(P2 . 1 ) (Y2-min2)/R+ ( P ~ ,(LP1)/R
~)
+ (pZJ2)( P ~ ,(y3-min3)/RZ
~)

+ (P2 , 2 (P3.2 (LP1 + (R)(B~,J)/R'.
If the consumer owned any a s s e t s a t the time of the bankruptcy f i l i n g , some
portion of these a s s e t s would figure i n t o the loan r e t u r n .

111. Model Structure
The objective is t o maximize the expected present discounted value of
u t i l i t y from consumption over periods one through T , which is four.

The

consumer begins with an endowment of human and nonhuman wealth, never having
f i l e d f o r bankruptcy, and there i s no p o s s i b i l i t y of bankruptcy i n the f i r s t

10
period. Current-period income is known when the consumption decision is made.
Arrangements are made to borrow in the first three periods, and the cost of
borrowing may rise with the amount of borrowing. There is no inflation and no
taxes.
The structure of the model can be understood by imagining a solution tree
in discrete time.

The initial branch of the tree is followed over

time unless the consumer cannot meet all of his debt payments. If forced into
bankruptcy, the consumer moves onto a new branch of the tree where bankruptcy
costs are paid and all debts at the time of the bankruptcy filing are
discharged. Once on this new branch, the consumer can never leave it; the
consumer faces a strict borrowing constraint that excludes the possibility of
additional bankruptcy filings. Clearly, the solutions along these
post-bankruptcy branches are independent of those along the initial branch,
but not vice versa.
The four-period solution tree is shown in figure 1. The nodes along each
branch are labelled ( t,j) , where t denotes the time period and j denotes the
branch number. Branch 0 is the initial branch where bankruptcy is never
filed. A branch number greater than 0 refers to the post-bankruptcy branches
and indicates the period in which the consumer filed for bankruptcy. For
example, the coordinate (3,2) refers to the third period along branch number
two and indicates that the consumer filed for bankruptcy in period two. Thus,
the time index t is greater than or equal to j along any post-bankruptcy
branch. This notation will be used in the formal model specification below.
The model is structured as a two-state, dynamic programming problem with
two sets of constraints. The two-state variables are discretionary funds and

a bankruptcy indicator variable that denotes the period of a bankruptcy
filing. For notational convenience, these two-state variables can be co~nbined
into one, DFttj,,which denotes discretionary funds at time t along
branch j, using the above notation. Consistent with the earlier definition,
DFt,j= Yt

- TLP,, j, where A,-,,

+

is

financial assets in period t-1 along branch j and TLPtPjis total loan
payments due in period t along branch j. The two sets of constraints are the
zero-profit credit supply constraint and the constraints on consumption in the
various states. The control variables are new borrowing and new acquisitions
of financial assets for each state of the world in each period.
Let V(DFtPj) denote the maximum present discounted value of utility
from period t to T along branch j. For the post-bankruptcy branches (j > 0)
and t < T ,
max U (mint+Bt,-At,) +SEV (DFt+,, ) , t

=

j> 0

B ,A
( 3 ) V(DFt,j)

=

max U(DFt,j+Bt, -4,j)+6EV(DFt+l,j), t > j >O
B ,A
for nonzero j and t = T,

U(mi9)
V(DFT,j)

for T

=

j,

=

U(DFTSj) for T > j > 0 ;
where S is the inverse of 1 plus the rate of time preference; B,,j is new
borrowing on branch j during period t; U() is the utility of consumption
function, defined over nonnegative consumption and twice differentiable with U' >
0, U"

<

0;

E is the expectation operator over labor income. In the period of

the bankruptcy filing (t

=

j), consumption equals exempt assets plus new

borrowing because previous-period net wealth was eliminated by the bankruptcy
filing.1° In the periods following a bankruptcy filing (t > j) ,
consumption equals labor income, plus new borrowing, minus total loan payments

due in the period, minus new saving in the financial asset. There is no decision
in the last period because there is no bequest motive.
Apart from the shift in the consumption constraint in the period of a
bankruptcy filing,(3) is essentially the simple Yaari (1964) model with perfect
capital markets; discretionary funds are always strictly greater than zero along
these branches. The maximum expected present discounted value of utility, from
period j to T, along branch j > 0 will be denoted as PDWBrj
For the solutions of interest along the initial branch (j

=

0) and t < T,

subject to the zero-profit, credit-supply constraint, where

For t

=

T,

The transition equation for the state variable DFtJjis

DF,,

=

mint
, j=t,
where D is the difference operator and DTLP,,

=

LP,, j.

The major difference between equations (3) and (4) lies in the EV()
terms. Because there is no possibility of bankruptcy along the
post-bankruptcy branches, the future utility term assumes a simple form in
equation (3).

However, the possibility of a future bankruptcy filing is a key

element of the branch 0 decision problem. The consumer must balance certain
consumption today with uncertain consumption tomorrow, where the uncertainty

13
about tomorrow's consumption is complicated by the possibility of bankruptcy.
If the consumer never borrows enough to raise the probability of bankruptcy
above zero, equation (4) reduces to the simple Yaari life-cycle model.
The probability of bankruptcy in each period, P,, is defined as
follows. Because income is independently distributed over time, the
probability, Q,, reaching node (t,O), for any period t, is simply the
product of the marginal probabilities of nonnegative discretionary funds
during the first t periods:

The probability of filing for bankruptcy in period t is the product of
the probability of not filing for bankruptcy in the first t-1 periods and the
probability that discretionary funds are negative period t:
P,

=

Q,-,[Pr(DF,,o

< 0)1,

where the bracketed term on the right is defined to be one when t is one.
Note that the sum of P, and Q, is not one. The difference is the
probability of filing for bankruptcy sometime before period t
It is interesting to note that the specification of the dynamic program
implicitly uses these conditional densities in the formation of the
expectations. This is readily apparent by expanding all of the terms of
equation (4) and writing the objective function as the discounted sum of
expected utility. The reason comes from the nonlinear shift in the program
after bankruptcy. The probability of following a particular path in the tree,
that is, obtaining a particular level of utility, depends on previous and
current actions. For example, the probability of obtaining the utility value
from branch two (bankruptcy in the second period) in period four is the

14
probability of a bankruptcy filing in the second period times the density
function of income in the fourth period.

IV. Simulation Results
Because a general, closed-form solution does not exist for this problem,
numerical solution of a particular specification is the only feasible solution
technique. The utility function of the simulation model is assumed to exhibit
constant relative risk aversion:
U(Ci,j)

=

(l/(l-A)) (Ci,
j)l-A.

In accordance with estimation results reported by Zeldes (1986), the value of

A is three in all the simulations. The rate of time preference is 20.0
percent, the risk-free rate of interest is five percent, and initial wealth is
zero. The probability density function of y is assumed to be a
t

three-point, discrete distribution, with
Yt,i

=

(Meany,) ei,

for i=1,2,3,

where Meany, is the mean value of y and ei is an
t'
independent, identically distributed random variable with a mean of one and a
probability function:
ei

probability

The Meany, values are:
Period

-----1
2
3

4

Meany
----100
250
400
200.

15

A symmetric distribution for ei was chosen for simplicity, and the
MeanY, values were chosen to mimic a textbook life-cycle income
profile.
Details of the simulation model and its solution are given in Kowalewski
(1989).

IV.l Baseline Simulation
There are four main characteristics of the bankruptcy model. First,
relative to the Yaari model, the possibility of bankruptcy shifts consumption
from periods late in the life cycle to periods early in the life cycle. As
shown in table 1, first-period consumption in the bankruptcy model simulation
is about 39 percent greater than first-period consumption in the Yaari model,
and the mean value of second-period consumption is over 14 percent greater.
Indeed, the time pattern of consumption in the bankruptcy model is similar to
that of the certainty equivalent model, also shown in table 1. Consumption is
shifted from late to early periods in the life cycle when the rate of time
preference is greater than the rate of interest.

l1

This stands in

sharp contrast to expected consumption in the Yaari model, which is more
closely correlated with labor income.
Second, bankruptcy's role as insurance (Arrow 1971) against adverse labor
income draws lowers the variance of consumption in every period. The variance
of consumption is about 52 percent less in the second period, almost 31
percent less in the third period, and about 10 percent less in the last
period.
Third, the present value of expected future utility is greater in the
bankruptcy model than in the Yaari model.

16
Finally, default risk drives a wedge between the borrowing and risk-free
rate of interest. The optimal amount of borrowing in the bankruptcy model
implies a nonzero probability of bankruptcy in all future periods, with the
probabilities falling over time. In the second period, bankruptcy occurs with
a probability of 0.02, when the minimum value of labor income results. In the
third period, bankruptcy occurs with a probability of 0.0192, when
second-period labor income is its mean value and third-period labor income is
its minimum value. Bankruptcy occurs in the fourth period with a probability
of 0.000008, when second-period labor income is its largest value and both
third- and fourth-period labor income are their minimum values. These
probabilities create a wedge of 1.725 percentage points between the borrowing
and lending rates of interest in the baseline simulation.

l2

IV.2 Chanees in the Risk-Free Rate of Interest
Increases in the risk-free rate will raise the borrowing rate of interest
directly and indirectly through the default risk premium. This section
discusses the impact of changes in the risk-free rate of interest, with all of
the other parameters held at their baseline values. Seven experiments were
run using odd values of the risk-free rate between 1 and 13 percent. The
results are shown in table 2.
The top half of table 2 shows that the borrowing rate and the risk premium
increase with the risk-free rate. The relationship between either the risk
premium or the borrowing rate of interest and the risk-free rate is linear in
this range. A 2 percentage point increase in the risk-free rate raises the
risk premium by 0.04 percentage point and the borrowing rate by 2.04
percentage points. The linearity of these relationships is partly due to the

17
assumption of symmetric information. Models with adverse selection, for
example Stiglitz and Weiss (1981), would show a nonlinear relationship between
the risk-free rate and the borrowing rate of interest. At some sufficiently
great interest rate in these models, it is optimal to ration credit by
quantity and not by price.
Another reason why the relationships are linear is that the probabilities
of bankruptcy in all future periods do not vary across the simulations. The
simple, three-point probability function for labor income leaves ample room
for borrowing to vary without a change in the probabilities of bankruptcy. If
the income probability function were continuous and not uniform, the
relationships would not be linear, with successive increases in the risk-free
rate implying ever-larger increases in the risk premium and in the borrowing
rate of interest.
The bottom half of table 2 compares the elasticities of first-period
borrowing and consumption with respect to the risk-free rate in the bankruptcy
and Yaari models. The Yaari results assume borrowing and lending rates are
equal to the risk-free rate of five percent. The elasticities for both
borrowing and consumption are negative and quite small for both models over
this range of risk-free interest rates. First-period borrowing in the
bankruptcy model is less sensitive to changes in the risk-free rate than i.t is
in the Yaari model.

l3

First-period consumption is slightly more

elastic in the bankruptcy model, but the differences in the two sets of
elasticities is very small. Indeed, the difference between the consumption
elasticities is too small to serve reliably as the basis of an econometric
test of the two models.

IV.3

Changes in Initial Wealth

The baseline results indicate that the possibility of bankruptcy loosens
the relationship between income and consumption found in the Yaari model. As
a corollary, the possibility of bankruptcy generally will lower the marginal
propensity to consume (MPC) changes in initial wealth. Table 3(a) displays
the MPCs of the bankruptcy, Yaari, and certainty-equivalence models. The
far left column of the table shows first-period income levels used for the
simulations. The MPCs for each model were computed by dividing the successive
differences of these income levels into the successive differences of their
corresponding first-period consumption levels.
The differences among these MPCs are rather dramatic. Although the values
of first- and second-period consumption shown in table 1 are very close in the
bankruptcy and certainty-equivalence models, the MPCs of the two models are
very dissimilar. The MPCs of the certainty-equivalence model are the lowest
of the three models and are constant across income values. The MPCs of the
Yaari model are the largest, except when labor income is 175, and they fall
monotonically as income rises. The MPCs from the bankruptcy model generally
fall between those of the other two models and show an irregular pattern as
income rises. They rise from 0.321, when income is 50, to 0.537 when income
is 100. They fall for the next two income values, rise when income is 175,
and fall when income is 200. When income is 225, the MPC is negative and less
than 1, but it increases for income value 250.l 4
The irregular pattern of the MPCs from the bankruptcy model is due to the
possibility of bankruptcy, and not to the endogenous borrowing rate of
interest. This should be clear from the low interest rate elasticities shown
in table 2. Moreover, table 3(b) compares the MPCs from the bankruptcy model

19
when the borrowing rate is endogenous with those from the bankruptcy model
when the borrowing rate is exogenously fixed at the risk-free rate of five
percent. The MPCs assuming an exogenous borrowing rate have a greater
variance, suggesting that the endogenous borrowing rate moderates the
consumption response of the model.
Table 4 shows how the borrowing interest rate, the probabilities of
bankruptcy, expected borrowing, and expected consumption change as
first-period labor income changes.

For example, when income increases fro11125

to 50, first-period borrowing falls 16.972 units, expected second-period
borrowing increases 1.187 units, and so on. The same interpretation holds for
the consumption changes. The levels of consumption and borrowing are shown
for income equal to 25. Borrowing is either the purchase of new debt or new
financial assets; a negative value of borrowing indicates saving in a
financial asset.
The time pattern of expected consumption varies greatly as first-period
income increases. For income values 50 and 75, increases in income are fairly
well-spread across time. The changes are front-loaded because the rate of
time preference is greater than the borrowing interest rate. For income
values 100 to 200, most of the change in expected consumption occurs in the
first two periods. When income is 225, it is close to the expected value of
second-period income and it shifts expected consumption away from the first
two periods. First-period consumption falls by 27.3 units, producing the
negative MPC; second-period expected consumption falls 31.1 units; and
third- and fourth-period expected consumption increase by 54.9 and 37.1 units,
respectively. This shift in expected consumption implies a shift in expected
borrowing, which lowers the probability of bankruptcy in the second period and

20
thi borrowing rate of interest by 88 basis points. When income is 250, the
change in income again is fairly well-spread across time. Indeed, expected
consumption is fairly even across time, as shown in table 3(c).
Table 4 also shows the impact of the discrete nature of the labor income
probability function. Between income values 25 and 125, the borrowing rate
falls slightly with the amount of first-period borrowing because the
probabilities of bankruptcy remain unchanged. When income is 150, the
borrowing rate falls a relatively large amount because the drop in the demand
for borrowing in the first period lowers the probability of bankruptcy in the
second period from 0.02 to zero. The borrowing rate increases slightly for
the next two income values before it falls, with the probability of bankruptcy
in the third period, at income value 225. For all income values except 175,
200, and 250, the borrowing rate falls with first-period borrowing. This
surprising result may be due to the fact that the credit-supply constraint is
an inverse cubic equation. This nonlinearity may give the distribution of
borrowing across time and states of nature a large impact on the borrowing
rate of interest.

IV.4 Changes in the Probability Density Function of Labor Income
Changes in the probability density function of labor income may have two
effects. First, a known change in the variance of future income will lead
risk-averse consumers to shift the time pattern of consumption. Second, a
known change in the probabilities of bankruptcy will change the borrowing rate
of interest. In particular, an increase in the probability of a bad income
draw will raise the borrowing interest rate and shift consumption from early
to later periods in the life cycle.

21
Table 5 displays the results from symmetrically increasing the tails of
the ei distribution, and compares the first-period borrowing and
consumption elasticities in the bankruptcy and Yaari models. The top half of
table 5 indicates that the borrowing rate of interest is a positive function
of the tail probability. The bottom half of the table indicates that the
resulting shifts in first-period borrowing and consumption are extremely small
in the bankruptcy model.

22

IV.5 Changes in the Cost of Bankruptcy
An increase in the cost of bankruptcy in this model will lower the demand
for borrowing and hence the borrowing rate of interest. In the aggregate, a
greater cost of bankruptcy will lower average bankruptcy filings. The easiest
way to change the cost of bankruptcy in this model is to change the amount of
labor income that may be kept by the consumer after bankruptcy. Table 6
displays the results of allowing the consumer to keep 25, 50, 75, and 100
percent of his minimum labor income after bankruptcy.
The results indicate that as the cost of bankruptcy increases, the demand
for borrowing and the borrowing rate of interest decrease. The magnitudes of
the differences should not be taken as reasonable estimates of real-world
impacts. The small difference between the results for exempt assets fractions
0.25 and 0.50, and that for 0.74 and 1.00, are due to the small size of exempt
assets. The baseline simulation assumes that exempt assets are 100 percent of
the minimum value of the labor-income distribution in the period of the
bankruptcy filing. These minimum values are already small numbers, and taking
fractions of them yields small changes. The relatively large difference
between the results for exempt-asset fractions 0.50 and 0.75 again is due to
the discrete nature of the labor income density function.
The results in table 6 square with the increase in consumer bankruptcy
filings after the Bankruptcy Reform Act of 1978 became effective in October,
1979. This act lowered the cost of bankruptcy to consumers, and came at a
time when real consumer income growth was slowing, debt burdens were high, and
portfolios were very illiquid.

l5

Initially, the sharp increase in

bankruptcy filings was due to the insolvent consumers at the margin.

l6

Since then, consumer bankruptcy filings have remained at an historically

23

high level because lower bankruptcy costs increased consumer willingness to
borrow, which was accommodated by consumer lenders.

l7

V. Summary and Conclusions
This paper develops and analyzes a life-cycle model that incorporates the
possibility of insolvency and its resolution with bankruptcy. Insolvency is
defined as the inability to repay debts in full out of current income and
nonhuman wealth. After-tax labor income is an exogenous random variable, but
the probability of insolvency is endogenous to the consumer. The consumer
maximizes the present discounted value of expected utility subject to the
usual cash flow constraint and a zero-profit credit supply constraint, which
equates the demand and supply of credit with the borrowing rate of interest.
Loan maturities are generally not one-period, but the number of periods
remaining in the life cycle when the loans are made.
Once insolvent, the consumer is immediately forced into a Chapter 7
bankruptcy by creditors. There are two costs of bankruptcy in the model. One
is the payment of the delinquent debts with any current-period income greater
than its minimum value that period, plus any nonhuman assets. The other, more
important cost, is a change in the borrowing constraint: after bankruptcy, all
debts must be repaid with probability one. In return for these costs, the
bankrupt consumer is discharged from all debts.
The relaxed credit-supply constraint in the bankruptcy model loosens the
dependence of current consumption on current income relative to that in the
Yaari model. The time path of expected consumption closely follows that of
expected labor income in the Yaari model. The time path of consumption in the

24

bankruptcy model is less closely related to that of income, but it is not
divorced as in the certainty equivalence model. Indeed, the marginal
propensities to consume in the bankruptcy model generally lie between those of
the certainty equivalence and Yaari models. An interesting feature of the
model is that the marginal propensity to consume may be negative, as increases
in current income shift consumption from periods early in the life cycle to
later ones.
Increases in the risk-free rate of interest raise the borrowing rate of
interest and lower the demand for borrowing. The elasticities of current
consumption with respect to the risk-free rate are small and only marginally
larger than those of the Yaari life-cycle model. Increases in the variance of
future labor income, or equivalently, increases in the probability of
bankruptcy, increase the borrowing rate of interest and lower the demand for
borrowing. Finally, an increase in the cost of bankruptcy lowers the demand
for borrowing and the borrowing interest rate.
The findings of this paper provide support for the strategy of testing for
the "excess sensitivity" of current consumption to unexpected changes in
current income (see Kowalewski [1985b]).

Zeldes (1986) has argued that these

tests are invalid because they assume certainty equivalence, which reduces the
income sensitivity of consumption. His computer simulations, and those in
this paper, show that the excess sensitivity is a characteristic of the Yaari
model without certainty equivalence. Adding bankruptcy to the Yaari model
without certainty equivalence reduces the income sensitivity of consumption,
thereby adding support to the research strategy. Nevertheless, the findings

25

of the "excess sensitivity" papers may be biased because the
certainty-equivalence model is not a good approximation to the model with
bankruptcy.
The model of this paper can be extended in four important ways. One is
the addition of tangible assets. The loss of certain tangible assets in
bankruptcy is an important cost of bankruptcy, especially if liquidity
constraints tighten after bankruptcy.
A second extension makes consumption needs a stochastic variable.
Accidents and medical problems are an important source of financial problems
for consumers who file for bankruptcy. Stochastic consumption needs would
lower the demand for borrowing and increase the sensitivity of current
consumption to changes in current income.
A third extension is the allowance for asymmetric information. The risk
premia found in this paper are very small because they capture the uncertainty
only about future income, not about the distribution of income or the
integrity of the borrower. The addition of asymmetric information would
increase the risk premia and would provide an estimate of the value of
information to creditors.
Finally, another extension is the allowance for general equilibrium. This
requires, at a minimum, that the cost of funds paid by creditors rise with the
amount of borrowing.

FIGURE 1

FOUR-PERIOD SOLUTION TREE

Period
Source :

Author

0

1

2

3

4

BASELINE SIMULATION RESULTS
BANKRUPTCY AND YAARI MODELS

Expected
Income
100
250
400
200

Period
1
2
3
4

Period
1
2
3

4

Expected Consumption
Certainty
Yaari
Bankruv tcv
Equivalence
248.761
178.982
249.867
235.353
205.586
238.990
214.555
278.386
228.585
238.656
285.228
218.634

Variance of
Expected Consumption
Bankruvtcv
Yaari
NA
NA
325.634
674.586
1118.576
1614.701
1612.294
1783.803

Probability
of
Bankruv tcv
NA
0.020000
0.019200
0.000008

Present Discounted Value of Expected Future Utility
Bankru~tcv
Yaari
-3.03939E-5 -3.846273-5
Interest Rates in the Bankruptcy Model
Borrowing
6.725%

Source: Author

Risk-Free
5.000%

TABLE 2
THE RISK-FREE RATE OF INTEREST SIMULATIONS

The Relationship Between the Risk-free Rate
and the Borrowing Rate

Risk- free Rate Risk Premium
1.000%
1.646%
3.000%
1.685%
5.000%
1.725%
1.764%
7.000%
9.000%
1.803%
1.843%
11.000%
13.000%
1.882%

Borrowing Rate
2.646%
4.685%
6.725%
8.764%
10.803%
12.843%
14.882%

Risk-free Interest Rate Elasticities for
First-period Borrowing and Consumption

Risk-free Rate
1.000%
3.000%
5.000%
7.000%
9.000%
11.000%
13.000%

Source: Author

BANKRUPTCY MODEL
Borrowing Consum~tion
NA
NA
-0.015
-0.009
- 0.040
- 0.024
-0.076
- 0.045
-0.097
-0.057
-0.119
-0.069
-0.139
-0.080

YAARI MODEL
Borrowing Consumtion
NA
NA
-0.017
-0.008
-0.050
-0.023
-0.083
-0.036
-0.114
- 0.049
-0.145
-0.062
-0.175
-0.073

TABLE 3
MARGINAL PROPENSITIES TO CONSUME
CHANGES IN INITIAL WEALTH

First-Period
Income
25
50
75
100
125
150
175
200
225
250

Certainty
Equivalence
NA
0.286
0.286
0.286
0.286
0.286
0.286
0.286
0.286
0.286

Bankruvtcv
NA
0.321
0.364
0.537
0.506
0.503
0.527
0.413
-1.092
0.319

Yaari
NA
0.661
0.630
0.598
0.566
0.536
0.509
0.485
0.464
0.446

Endogenous
First-Period
Exogenous
Borrowing
- Rate
Borrowing Rate
Income
50
0.316
0.321
0.364
0.371
0.518
0.537
0.506
0.362
0.503
0.563
0.527
0.495
0.413
0.538
-1.092
-1.230
0.319
0.320

Expected Consumption
Period
1
2
3
4
Source: Author

First-Period Income
100
150
200
248.761 273.981 297.487
235.353 264.655 291.416
214.555 212.978 213.014
238.656 236.694 237.821

225
270.181
260.315
267.964
274.963

250
278.146
267.886
274.132
279.860

TABLE 4

CHANGES IN INITIAL WEALTH
BANKRUPTCY MODEL

Probability Change in
Borrowing
Interest
of
Expected
Income Rate Period Bankru~tcv Borrowing
193.196*
0.00000
25
6.748%
1
2
0.02000
29.124*
3
0.01920
-111.779*
4
0.00001
0.OOO*
50
6.744%
1
0.00000
- 16.972
2
0.02000
1.187
3
0.01920
1.418
4
0.00001
0.000
75
6.737%
1
0.00000
-15.890
2.626
2
0.02000
1.037
3
0.01920
4
0.00001
0.000
100
6.725%
1
0.00000
-11.573
7.689
2
0.02000
3
0.01920
0.007
0.000
4
0.00001
-12.360
125
6.711%
1
0.00000
8.212
2
0.02000
3
0.01920
0.007
0.000
4
0.00001
-12.421
150
5.891%
1
0.00000
2
0.00000
12.106
3
0.01960
0.189
4
0.00039
0.000
- 11.814
175
5.924%
1
0.00000
7.731
2
0.00000
0.032
3
0.01960
0.000
4
0.00039
-14.680
200
5.964%
1
0.00000
2
0.00000
9.188
-0.571
3
0.01960
4
0.00001
0.000
225
5.084%
1
0.00000
-52.305
-50.931
2
0.00000
8.704
3
0.00040
0.000
4
0.00039
-17.035
250
5.105%
1
0.00000
1.310
2
0.00000
0.619
3
0.00040
0.000
4
0.00039
*Levels
Source: Author

Change in
Expected
Consum~tion
218.196*
207.311*
202.083*
231.230*
8.028
7.501
6.968
4.061
9.110
8.539
5.418
3.291
13.427
12.002
0.087
0.073
12.640
12.818
0.093
0.079
12.579
16.484
-1.670
- 2.041
13.186
12.116
0.187
0.122
10.320
14.646
-0.151
1.005
-27.305
-31.101
54.949
37.143
7.965
7.571
6.168
4.897

TABLE 5
THE EFFECTS OF CHANGES IN THE PROBABILITY
DENSITY FUNCTION OF LABOR INCOME

Tail
Probability
0.02
0.04
0.06
0.08
0.10
0.12

Variance
0.025
0.050
0.074
0.099
0.124
0.149

Borrowing
Rate
6.725%
8.500%
10.326%
12.201%
14.125%
16.095%

Change in
Rate
NA
1.775%
1.826%
1.875%
1.924%
1.970%

First-period Borrowing and Consumption Elasticities
Tail
BANKRUPTCY MODEL
YAARI MODEL
Probability Borrowing Consum~tion Borrowing Consum~tion
0.02
NA
NA
NA
NA
0.04
-0.020
-0.045
-0.169
-0.075
0.06
-0.034
- 0.046
-0.273
-0.108
0.08
-0.057
-0.061
-0.366
-0.132
- 0.064
-0.059
-0.456
0.10
-0.151
-0.084
-0.070
- 0.548
0.12
-0.168

Source:

Author

TABLE 6
CHANGES IN THE COST OF BANKRUPTCY
Exempt
Asset
Percentage
25.0%
50.0%
75.0%
100.0%

Source:

Author

Borrowing
128.926
128.978
148.692
148.761

Consumvtion
228.926
228.978
248.692
248.761

Borrowing
Interest
Rate
5.04862%
5.04877%
6.72473%
6.72481%

FOOTNOTES

33

'some consumer lenders argue that insolvency is no longer a precondition
for bankruptcy. The Bankruptcy Reform Act of 1978 removed all legal
preconditions for bankruptcy, and many lenders feel that the large increase in
personal bankruptcy filings after the Act became effective in October, 1979 is
evidence that consumers have abused the law by taking advantage of this change
and the Act's liberalized exemption limits. Nevertheless, the solution of
this abuser problem is trivial and will be ignored.
2 ~ e efor example, Stanley and Girth (1971).
30ther sources of uncertainty are possible but complicate the analysis.
Stochastic consumption needs raises the possibility of multiple bankruptcy
filings per lifetime, which greatly increases the number of solutions required
for a problem of given horizon length. Adding stochastic interest rates
magnifies the "curse of dimensionality."
4 ~ e eKowalewski (1982) for a description of this and other alternatives to
bankruptcy.
5~oreover,a "grace period" variation is a trivial debt restructuring
problem unless there is uncertainty about the availability of the grace
period.
6

Due to asymmetric information, it is likely that consumers must pay a
greater interest rate after bankruptcy. The use of the risk-free rate is a
logical consequence of the assumed borrowing restriction; it is not an crucial
assumption because the disutility from the borrowing restriction more than
offsets the utility from a lower borrowing rate. A more complete model would
allow multiple bankruptcies and greater borrowing interest rates after
bankruptcy.
70ne interest rate for all borrowing before bankruptcy is not restrictive
because there is no moral hazard or adverse selection problems. A more
realistic assumption would be asymmetric information, which would admit the
possibility of credit rationing and time-varying interest rates before
bankruptcy. Learning behavior by creditors would be a desirable and
complementary feature to add to the model. The assumption of symmetric
information is a useful first step that helps to isolate the impact of limited
liability.
'using a simple portfolio balance approach, the default premium also may be
defined as the extra percentage return necessary to equate the discounted
expected loan return with the discounted return from lending the same amount
at the risk-free rate of interest. Note that this default premium is not a
risk premium as defined by Pratt (1964) because the utility of profits
function is linear in profits.

he

decision-tree framework of this model is similar to those of Foley and
Hellwig (1975) and Watkins (1978).
Both take the same view of a consumer
following a tree of consumption opportunities, whose branches are determined
by discrete, nonlinear changes in the intertemporal budget set. These changes
are determined by the employment status of the consumer, which is an

FOOTNOTES

34

exogenous, stochastic process; insolvency and bankruptcy are ignored.
1°1t may seem odd that the consumer is allowed to borrow in the period of a
bankruptcy filing. However, it is logically consistent given the assumption
of symmetric information and the constraint that all debts incurred after
bankruptcy are fully repaid with probability one. Prohibiting borrowing in
the period of a bankruptcy filing would magnify the impact of bankruptcy in
the simulation results shown below.
'%he
increase in expected consumption in the last period of the bankruptcy
model may be due to the lower probability of bankruptcy in that period.
1 2 ~ h esize of this wedge may seem small until it is realized that the wedge
is only the default premium under symmetric information, and does not include
transactions costs or the additional costs created by asymmetric information.
1 3 ~ h einterest-rate elasticities are somewhat larger if the borrowing rate
is used.
14iilthough the MPCs from the bankruptcy and Yaari models are different at
these income levels, it is likely that the MPCs from the bankruptcy model
approach, and eventually equal, those of the Yaari model as first-period
income increases without limit. With sufficiently great first-period income,
the consumer will have no need to borrow more than he would have if he was
required, as in the Yaari model, to repay all debts with probability one.
15see Kowalewski (1982) for a discussion of the financial position of
households in the late 1970s and early 1980s.
1 6 ~ h einitial sharp increase also may be due to consumers anticipating the
passage of the act. These consumers may have postponed a bankruptcy filing in
order to file under the new act or increased their borrowing before the
effective date of the act.
1 7 ~ h estrength in consumer borrowing since 1982 is discussed in Kowalewski
(1986).

REFERENCES
Arrow, Kenneth J. Essays in the Theory of Risk-Bearing.
Publishing Company, 1971.

Chicago: Markham

Foley, Duncan and Martin Hellwig. "Asset Management with Trading Uncertainty."
Review of Economic Studies. 42 (July 1975): 327-346.
Gale, Douglas and Martin Hellwig. "Incentive-Compatible Debt Contracts: The
One-Period Problem." Review of Economic Studies. 52 (October 1985):
647-663.
Kowalewski, K.J. "Personal Bankruptcy: Theory and Evidence." Economic Review.
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
(Spring 1982): 1-29.
Kowalewski, K.J. "Stochastic Interest Rates in the Life-Cycle/ Permanent
Income cum Rational Expectations Model." Economic Review. Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland (Spring 1985b): 2-19.
Kowalewski, K.J. "Is the Consumer Over-Extended?" Economic Commentary.
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, November 15, 1986.
Kowalewski, Kim J. "Personal Bankruptcy: Theory and Evidence." Ph.D.
Dissertation, Yale University, 1989.
Pratt, John W. "Risk Aversion in the Small and in the Large." Econometrica.
Vol. 32 (January-April 1964): 122-36.
Stanley, David T. and Marjorie Girth. Bankruptcy: Problem, Process, Reform.
Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1971.
Stiglitz, Joseph E. and Andrew Weiss. "Credit Rationing in Markets with
Imperfect Information." American Economic Review. 71 (June, 1981):
393-410.
Watkins, Thayer. "A Property of Optimal Consumption Policies for
Decision-Making Under Uncertainty." Southern Economic Journal. 44 (April
1978): 752-761.
Yaari, Menahem E. "On the Consumer's Lifetime Allocation Process."
International Economic Review. 5 (September 1964): 304-317.
Zeldes, Stephen P. "Optimal Consumption with Stochastic Income: Deviations
from Certainty Equivalence." Mimeo, The Wharton School, University of
Pennsylvania (1986).