View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Working Paper 9407

ANTICIPATING BAILOUTS: THE INCENTIVE-CONFLICT MODEL
AND THE COLLAPSE OF THE OHIO DEPOSIT GUARANTEE FUND
by Ramon P. DeGennaro and James B. Thomson

Ramon P. DeGennaro is an associate professor of finance at
the University of Tennessee, Knoxville. He thanks the John
Fisher Faculty Development Fund for financial support.
James B. Thomson is an assistant vice president and
economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
Working papers of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion
and critical comment. The views stated herein are those of
the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System.

June 1994

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Abstract

The collapse of the Ohio Deposit Guarantee Fund (ODGF) in March 1985
provides a laboratory for examining the financial market's belief in the
incentive-conflict model proposed by Kane (1989). Research in this area has
yet to examine the stock returns of federally insured institutions during
that period in the context of this model.

Thus, it has not addressed the

question of whether financial-market participants recosnize the implications
of the model; that is, whether they anticipate the bailouts it implies.
This paper fills that void.
We find that, on average, stocks of firms insured by the poorly
capitalized Federal Savings and Loan Insurance Corporation (FSLIC) do
reasonably well during the 41-day event window centered on the ODGFfs Bank
Holiday, while stocks of firms insured by the relatively well capitalized
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporations (FDIC) do not. More important,
differences in abnormal returns of FDIC and FSLIC firms are consistent with
a reaffirmation of the incentive-conflictmodel.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

I. Introduction

The collapse of the Ohio Deposit Guarantee Fund (ODGF) in March 1985,
triggered by the failure of E.S.M. Securities (ESM), is the most visible of
a series of events that disrupted financial markets in early 1985. Among
other effects, this incident challenged the credibility of federal
government deposit guarantees.

While others such as Cooperman, Lee, and

Wolfe (1992) have analyzed the effect of this crisis on securities such as
retail certificates of deposit, the implications of the ODGF1s failure for
stockholders of federally insured institutions and taxpayers have not been
fully explored. This paper examines the stock returns of two distinct
classes of financial institutions: those insured by the relatively well
capitalized Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) and those insured
by the relatively weak Federal Savings and Loan Insurance Corporation
(FSLIC). This lets us gauge investors' perceptions of the relative strength
of different government guarantees.
In addition, although the ODGF crisis occurred in 1985, this study is
more than simply an historical analysis. That crisis provides a laboratory
for examining the financial market's belief in Kane's (1989) contention that
self-interested management and politicians have powerful incentives to make
uninsured depositors whole.

Kane and Kaufman (1992) report that the

incentive-conflict model explains events surrounding a similar crisis in
Australia, but they do not examine the stock returns of affected
institutions. Thus, they do not address the separate question of whether
financial-marketparticipants recognized the model's implications; that is,
whether they anticipated the bailouts implied by the model.
fills that void.

This paper

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Kane and Unal (1990) and Thomson (1987a, 1987b) show that investors
incorporate the value of deposit guarantees in the market value of the
firm's equity.

If investors believed that the effects of the ODGF crisis

were confined to members of the ODGF, or that both the FDIC and the FSLIC
could easily weather the storm (perhaps by drawing on implicit government
guarantees), then the stocks of federally guaranteed institutions would show
no effect.

If, in contrast, they believed that the crisis signaled a

weakness in the federal government's resolve to honor those guarantees, then
the stock returns of insured institutions should reflect that assessment,
and firms insured by the decapitalized FSLIC should suffer more than their
FDIC-insured counterparts. Larger declines by FSLIC-insured institutions
could also result from a belief that the influx of ODGF thrifts to FSLIC
would reduce confidence in federal guarantees or lead to higher insurance
premiums.
Finally, if investors viewed the ODGF crisis as reaffirming the
incentive-conflictmodel, thereby signaling continued regulatory forbearance
and a strengthening of implicit guarantees, the stock returns of FSLIC firms
could exceed those of their FDIC counterparts. This is because reaffirming
FDIC guarantees would have been relatively unimportant compared to
reaffirming FSLIC guarantees.

Better-capitalized depository institutions

would also lose from continued forbearance, because insolvent institutions
would continue to compete away lending margins. To the extent that FDICinsured banks were better capitalized than FSLIC-insured firms, the former's
stocks would have a less positive reaction to the government's handling of
the ODGF.

This interpretation implies that investors do not view the events

predicted by the incentive-conflict model as a certainty. That is, they

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

might well believe that government bailouts of depositors are likely and
that capital forbearance will probably continue, but that neither outcome is
inevitable.
Our results show that the ODGF crisis produced much information
important to financial markets, and that it did indeed have different
impacts, depending on the insurer. On average, FSLIC firms did reasonably
well during a 41-day event window centered on the ODGFrs Bank Holiday, while
FDIC firms did not.

Stockholders of FDIC-insured firms began to absorb

losses 19 days prior to the Bank Holiday. They also lost rather heavily
during a two-day event period consisting of the Bank Holiday and the day
before, and during the days shortly after. By comparison, though, FSLICinsured thrifts lost early in the 41-day event window, began to recover
about seven days before the Bank Holiday, and on average gained more than
2.1% during the event window. More important, differences in abnormal
returns of FDIC and FSLIC firms were consistent with a reaffirmation of the
incentive-conflict model.

When government authorities moved towards a

bailout of the ODGF, stock returns on FSLIC-insured institutions exceeded
those of FDIC-insured institutions. When authorities sold off entry
privileges to out-of-statebanks, the relationship was reversed.
This paper is organized as follows: The next section states our
hypotheses and describes our method and data. Section I11 reports the
results. Section IV summarizes our findings.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

11. Hypotheses, Bkthod, and Data

We test the following groups of hypotheses, each group predicting
different stock-return behavior for institutions insured by the FSLIC and
the FDIC:
1. Financial-market participants viewed the guarantees of the
FSLIC and FDIC as a) comparable, or b) at least sufficient to
weather the information released during the ODGF crisis.
2. Financial-market participants a) considered the credibility of

FSLIC guarantees to be weakened by the crisis, or b) feared an
influx of weak ODGF thrifts to the FSLIC that might lead to
higher insurance premiums.
3. Financial-market participants viewed the ODGF crisis as a)
increasing the likelihood of a federal bailout of the FSLIC
fund, or b) reaffirming regulatory forbearance, in accordance
with the incentive-conflictmodel.

Hypothesis 1 implies that abnormal returns on the stocks of FDICinsured institutions would not differ significantly from those of their
FSLIC counterparts. Hypothesis 2 implies that abnormal returns on the
stocks of FSLIC-insured institutions would be lower than those of FDICinsured firms.

Finally, to the extent that investors view government

bailouts as uncertain, Hypothesis 3 implies that abnormal returns on the
stocks of FSLIC-insured institutions would be higher than those of FDICinsured firms. Reaffirming regulatory forbearance for FDIC institutions is
unimportant compared to a similar reaffirmation for those insured by the
decapitalized FSLIC.
Method
We apply a variant of the method used by Mikkelson and Partch (1986) to
obtain our event-study results. Their approach uses the single-index market
model to obtain predicted returns, standardizes the resulting prediction

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

errors, and constructs a Z-statistic to determine the statistical
significance of these standardized prediction errors. Because the equities
of financial institutions are in general more sensitive to interest rates
than other stocks, we augment the market model with the yield on ten-year
government bonds, as suggested by Stone (1974). We estimate the parameters
of the market model using returns from 180 days prior to the event through
21 days prior to the event.

The event-period window begins 20 days before

the event date and continues until 20 days after it. The estimation
equation is:

where
R
= return on security j on day t,
jt
= return on the equal-weighted portfolio, with dividends, provided
Rmt
I

by the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP), on day t,
Yt

= the yield on ten-year government bonds, and

1. Brown and Warner (1980) report that a value-weighted index is more prone
to problems than the equal-weighted index we use, and that using the equalweighted index led to no major difficulties. To check our results, we
replicated portions of our study using a value-weighted index with no
important differences. In their later paper (19851, Brown and Warner
report that even extreme event clustering has relatively little impact,
although with similar industry groups some methods tend to reject the null
of no abnormal performance too often. Using the two-index model in this
paper helps to minimize this potential problem, and Brown and Warner (1985)
report that using more complex approaches could result in potentially large
losses in power. Most important, corrections for event clustering adjust
the standard error of the abnormal returns, not the abnormal return itself.
Given that our paper's main focus is the differences between FDIC and FSLIC
institutions, event clustering is not likely to be a problem.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

= a mean-zero, serially uncorrelated error.
jt
We calculate announcement-period prediction errors (PE
c

)

jt

I pj,

estimated coefficients a

using the

and y in equation (I):
j

PE
= R
- (a.
+
jt
jt
3

p j ~ m t+

yjYt)

We calculate standardized prediction errors (SPEs) by dividing each
abnormal return in equation (2) by an estimate of its standard error:

SPE
= PEjt / Sjt,
jt

where

In equation (4), V? equals the residual variance of firm j 's augmented
3

market-model regression given by equation (11, ED equals the number of days
in the estimation period, and

Rm equals the mean market-model return during

the estimation period.
If the Ohio Bank Holiday had no effect on the stock returns of the
financial institutions in our sample, these SPEs are not statistically
different from zero.

If investors perceived this event to be favorable

(unfavorable) to these institutions, then the SPEs are significantly
positive (negative). To form multiday Z-statistics, we sum the standardized
daily returns for each firm across the observation period, average them

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

across firms, and divide by the sample standard deviation, 1/ ( d ~ ) ,
where N
is the number of firms.
A variation of the Mikkelson and Partch approach ([19861, hereafter MP)
has been developed by Boehmer, Musumeci and Paulsen ([19911, hereafter BMP),
who call their variation the standardized-cross-sectionmethod and provide
evidence that it is robust to a variety of statistical problems, including
event clustering.

Because all firms in our sample experience the same event

date, we also use the BMP method. However, this method does not generalize
to multiday return intervals, and BMP report that the MP approach also works
well.

Consistent with this, we find that results from the BMP approach and

the MP method do not differ substantially for one-day event windows.

More

important for our purposes, prediction errors from equation (2) are the same
for both methods, so tests comparing them for FDIC and FSLIC institutions
are not affected. Therefore, we concentrate the present analysis on results
obtained from the MP approach. The BMP results are available on request.
Data
All of our tests use daily stock-return data from the tapes supplied by
the Center for Research in Securities Prices (CRSP) at the University of
Chicago.

we include firms listed on the New York Stock Exchange, the

American Stock Exchange, and those traded over the counter. Of these, 123
are FDIC insured, 66 are FSLIC insured, and one is insured by the Maryland
2
Savings-Share Insurance Corporation (MSSIC).

2. We exclude firms with more than 40 missing returns during the estimation
period, those with more than 10 consecutive missing returns, and those with
a missing return on either the event date or the day before. We treat the
MSSIC thrift as an FSLIC institution because excluding it leads to similar
results.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

111. R e s u l t s

The appendix presents an abbreviated list of important political events
during the 41-day event window surrounding March 15, 1985. A more complete
listing is available on request.
&

On Thursday, February 28, Alexander Grant

Co., an outside auditor, released ESMrs 1984 financial statements, only to

withdraw them the next day, Friday, March 1, which was the final day that
ESM was open. Because auditors spent the weekend studying the firm's books,
it seems likely that news of its problems surfaced that Friday. After ESM
failed, inflicting a loss of $150 million on Home State Savings (compared to
the ODGFrs net worth of about $136 million), the most likely dates for
abnormal returns are Wednesday, March 6 (the first day of heavy runs at Home
State Savings) and Wednesday, March 13 (when the Ohio legislature
insufficiently recapitalized the ODGF) . After the Bank Holiday on Friday,
March 15, when the State of Ohio refused to put its full faith and credit
behind the ODGF, key dates include Monday, March 18 through Wednesday,
March 20. On that Monday, the state legislature passed a bill requiring
ODGF thrifts to obtain federal insurance before reopening. On Tuesday, the
FSLIC promised to speed applications from ODGF thrifts, but imposed higher
capital standards on these applications. On Wednesday, the state
legislature rescued the ODGF.
Table 1 contains the event-study results using the FDIC firms. The
first two columns represent the calendar dates of the event period and the
days in event time (relative to March 15).

The next two columns list the

daily average abnormal return (AAR) and the MP Z-statistic. The percentage
of positive abnormal returns is next, followed by a binomial 2-statistic to
determine the statistical significance of that value.

Note that this test

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

does not simply test whether the percentage of positive returns differs from
SO%, because stock returns are not equally likely to be positive or
negative.

To control for this, our binomial statistic tests against the

null hypothesis that the percentage of positive returns is the same as that
during the estimation period.

5

Here, that value is 41.2%.

The last column

of the table lists the cumulative abnormal return (CAR) for all 123 firms.
Table 1 also contains five sets of multiday statistics. These five are
for the two-day event window encompassing day -1 and day 0, two six-day
windows (from day - 5 to day 0 and from day 1 to day 6), and two eleven-day
windows (from day -10 to day 0 and from day 1 to day 11).

In all cases, we

also report Z-statistics testing the hypothesis that these returns do not
differ statistically from zero. The longer observation windows are
particularly valuable in studies of financial crises such as that involving
the ODGF, which spanned several days.
Table 1 shows that a great deal of information reached the financial
markets around this time. The MP Z-statistic is significant 12 of 41
times.4 The binomial Z-statistic is significant six times.

Figure 1

graphs the daily AAR and CAR for Table 1. There is no obvious trend in
daily AARs, though the preponderance of negative values leads to a downward
trend in the CAR beginning on day -19 and extending through day 10 before

3. This does not extend to binomial tests of two-day abnormal returns,
because there is more than one way to pair the days, and the results could
differ depending on the choice of pairs. Therefore, the proportion of
positive two-day abnormal returns is tested against 0.5.
4 . Readers will note that the abnormal return and the MP Z-statistic
sometimes have opposite signs, which is possible using this approach. Also,
some care is needed when interpreting the event-study results because of
potential problems with event clustering.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

recovering somewhat towards the end of the event window, finishing-at-39.5
basis points.
Although many events during this time suggest themselves as likely to
generate abnormal returns, and the event-study results reveal that this was
a time of rapid information release, the events identified in the media
rarely seem to be the cause of the individual daysf abnormal returns.
example, the court-ordered closure of ESM on March

4

For

generates a positive

abnormal return, which is significant according to the binomial test.
Conceivably, this represents a flight to quality, benefiting federally
insured dealers in government securities, largely FDIC-insured banks.
is consistent with March 1:

This

If ESM's problems leaked and caused a flight to

quality, then we would expect to observe positive abnormal returns on that
date, as well.

A flight to quality can also explain the positive (although

insignificant) abnormal return on March 6, the day of heavy runs on Home
State.
A flight to quality cannot, however, explain the observed results for
March 15 and March 18-20. The Bank Holiday itself leads to significantly
negative abnormal returns, and the Ohio legislature's action on March 18,
requiring ODGF thrifts to obtain federal insurance, also leads to negative
(though insignificant) returns. The FSLICfspromise to speed the
application process for ODGF thrifts leads to significant losses on Tuesday,
March 19, and the formal rescue of the ODGF the next day leads to
insignificantly negative abnormal returns. A flight to quality is
inconsistent with the four consecutive losses, totaling almost 72 basis
points, by institutions insured by the relatively strong FDIC.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

The largest of these four consecutive losses occurred when the FSLIC
promised to expedite new insurance applications on March 19. One view of
this result is that investors interpreted the FSLIC action as signaling
continued regulatory forbearance, to the detriment of well-capitalized
institutions. Continued forbearance would mean that undercapitalized and
insolvent firms would remain supercompetitors in the sense of Kane's (1989)
zombie institutions. These firms, with little or nothing more to lose,
would continue to bid down spreads on investments for healthy institutions.
The multiday statistics in Table 1 present a less complex picture.
FDIC firms lose almost 30 basis points during the two-day event window
encompassing day -1 and day 0, 16.6 basis points during the six-day period
prior to and including the Bank Holiday, and a statistically significant
49.4 basis points during the six-day period beginning the day after the Bank
Holiday.

For the eleven-day window prior to and including the Bank Holiday,

FDIC-insured institutions gain an insignificant 19.4 basis points, but this
is offset by a loss of almost 34 basis points during the following 11
trading days. In brief, the stocks of FDIC-insured institutions suffer
losses that are both statistically and economically significant on the Bank
Holiday and during the period shortly thereafter.
Table 2 presents the results for FSLIC-insured thrifts.

Only two days

(February 26 and April 8) show significantly negative abnormal returns
(compared to seven for FDIC institutions), and even a casual glance at the

CAR reveals that these institutions did better than their FDIC-insured
counterparts. As Figure 1 shows for FDIC institutions, the CAR turns
negative very early in the event window and remains negative, finishing at
-0.395%. In contrast, Figure 2 reveals that FSLIC firms have negative CARS

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

only for several days prior to the Bank Holiday and, after recovering before
the event itself, the CAR finishes at a positive 2.137%.

Further, there are

no negative multiday prediction errors for FSLIC institutions. FDIC firms
suffer statistically significant losses on the event day and after, whereas
FSLIC firms enjoy statistically significant gains during the 11-day period
preceding the Bank Holiday, and still more gains thereafter.
However, a formal test of the hypothesis that the daily abnormal return
of FDIC-insured firms is equal to that of firms insured by the FSLIC is
somewhat inconclusive. We conduct both a t-test and the nonparametric
median test, each using all observations on abnormal returns from all
institutions. The t-statistic is -1.21, which is not significant, while the
statistic for the median test is -4.34, which is significant at the 1%
level. We note that about a quarter of the observations in these tests
precede the failure of ESM; there is no obvious reason for observations from
this period to be different across insurers. Using observations beginning
on the date of ESM1s closing, the t-statistic is -1.61, which just misses
significance at the 10% level, and the statistic for the median test is
3.71, which remains significant.
There is further evidence that financial-market participants
distinguished between FDIC- and FSLIC-insured institutions: The difference
between the abnormal returns of these groups is statistically reliable on
seven days. The rightmost column of Table 2 presents t-tests of the
difference between the abnormal returns on FDIC- and FSLIC-insured
institutions. On four days the abnormal returns on FSLIC firms exceed those
on FDIC institutions, and on three days the ranking is reversed.

Further,

most of the differences, especially those occurring after ESM failed and the

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

crisis began, occur on days likely to generate disparities of the
appropriate size and sign.
For example, on March 12 the Federal Reserve agreed to help ODGF
institutions prepare the documents necessary for FSLIC insurance. If
financial markets interpreted this as signaling continued regulatory
forbearance, FSLIC thrifts would be expected to benefit more than those
insured by the solvent FDIC.

Indeed, abnormal returns on the stocks of

FSLIC-insured thrifts were statistically larger than those of their FDICinsured counterparts on March 12. On April 4, the Ohio legislature
considered an $85 million guarantee to prospective buyers of Home State,
which probably signaled an impending bailout of the ODGF, as predicted by
the incentive-conflict model.

This, too, would have reaffirmed the implicit

guarantee behind the insolvent FSLIC, and, as on March 12, average stock
returns on FSLIC institutions were better than on their FDIC counterparts.
The incentive-conflict model also predicts that politicians are likely
to sell off entry privileges as the result of a crisis. The Ohio
legislature did indeed open the state to interstate banking, but not until
October 1988, well after the end of our event window.

However, the Maryland

state legislature approved a bill on ~ p r i l8, 1985 that allowed out-of-state
banks to set up full-service banks in Maryland.

One would expect this to

cause the stock returns of FDIC-insured institutions to exceed those of
FSLIC-insured thrifts.

This is indeed the case: The t-statistic testing

the difference in abnormal returns is 3.49, the most significant of all
dates in the sample.
The difference in abnormal returns on April 15 is also readily
explained, although not by events related to the ODGF.

On April 15 the

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Wall Street Journal reported that the Federal Home Loan Bank Board would
recommend curbs on thrifts' junk-bond holdings.

Not surprisingly, FSLIC

institutions on average did worse than FDIC institutions on that day.
These results are not due to outliers, nor are they due to
distributional properties of the returns. Deleting the most extreme outlier
in these seven cases eliminates statistical significance only once, on
March 12. Using the nonparametric Wilcoxon test, abnormal returns on FDIC
institutions differ from FSLIC thrifts eight times instead of seven.
Of the three groups of hypotheses we consider, the incentive-conflict
model is most consistent with the relatively strong performance of FSLIC
institutions compared to that of their FDIC counterparts during the Ohio
thrift crisis. According to this interpretation, the events of the period
reaffirm the federal government's implicit backing of the FSLIC fund, as
would be consistent with the incentive-conflict model. The FSLIC was widely
suspected to be insolvent by March 1985; the FDIC was strong by comparison.
Even if investors believed the predictions of the incentive-conflict model,
they likely retained at least some doubt as to the strength of the
government's backing of the FSLIC fund. However, after the State of Ohio
rescued the ODGF, which it was not legally required to do, investors
probably viewed the federal government's implicit guarantee of the FSLIC to
be much stronger than before.
This interpretation does require that investors not place complete
confidence in the incentive-conflict model.

That is, implicit guarantees

and taxpayer-funded bailouts may be natural outgrowths of elected officials'
incentives to delay recognizing problems and to shift costs to the taxpayer,

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

but they are not considered inevitable, nor are depositors certain to be
made whole.
This interpretation gains force because data constraints require us to
select stock institutions; we obviously cannot examine the stock returns of
mutual institutions. Given the year when the ODGF crisis occurred, most of
our sample thrifts were likely to be recent conversions from mutual to stock
charters. Recent conversions probably have stronger capital positions than
do thrifts in general.

If the market viewed the ODGF crisis as increasing

the likelihood that the federal government would continue to forbear and to
ignore the growing thrift-industry problems, it could reasonably expect such
forbearance to act as a tax on better-capitalized firms, regardless of
insurer, as zombie institutions would remain supercompetitors. Despite this
and despite the unavoidable selection bias towards better-capitalized
thrifts, our sample of FSLIC-insured thrifts enjoys higher stock returns
than does our FDIC-insured sample.

IV. Slmmary and Cauclusiaus

This paper explores the effect of the collapse of the Ohio Deposit
Guarantee Fund on insured financial institutions. We find evidence that
this crisis produced much information important to financial markets, and,
more important, that the markets treated FSLIC-insured thrifts differently
from FDIC-insured institutions. FSLIC-insured thrifts enjoyed statistically
significant, positive abnormal returns during the 11-day period prior to and
including the Bank Holiday; FDIC institutions lost during the six-day period
including and after the Bank Holiday. The cumulative average residual of

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

FSLIC-insured thrifts is 2.137%, while for FDIC-insured institutions the
figure is -0.395%.
These results might seem counterintuitive, because by 1985 the FSLIC
was widely recognized to be insolvent. One might have expected the stocks
of FDIC firms to perform better than their FSLIC counterparts as investors
fled to safer investments. We find the opposite. We argue that our finding
is consistent with Kane's (1989) incentive-conflictmodel, which asserts
that taxpayer-funded bailouts are a natural outgrowth of the moral-hazard
problem that taxpayers face. Elected officials have incentives to delay
recognition of problems and to shift costs to the taxpayer. The state
bailout of the ODGF might have illustrated this point to investors, who
revised their estimates of the federal government's intentions to continue
capital forbearance and its implicit guarantee of the FSLIC fund. The case
in favor of the incentive-conflict model gains force from t-tests for
differences between the abnormal returns of the two groups. These tests
frequently detect differences of the size and sign predicted by the model.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Appendix: Important Political Events Surrounding March 15, 1985
Thursday, February 28, 1985
Alexander Grant & Co., ESM's outside auditor, releases a "clean
unqualified opinionn of ESM1s 1984 financial statements.
Friday, March 1, 1985
Alexander Grant & Co. withdraws ESM's 1984 financial statements,
released the previous day. Auditors scrutinize its books all weekend.
Monday, March 4, 1985
ESM1s auditor says its financial statements Ifmaynot be relied upon,"
and ESM is ordered closed by a federal court. The SEC files fraud
charges and a federal district judge appoints a receiver.
Wednesday, March 6, 1985
A run on Home State begins, lasting through March 8.
Friday, March 8, 1985
Home State borrows from the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland and
announces that it will be closed Saturday, March 9.
Saturday, March 9, 1985
Auditors report a $145 million insolvency at Home State, which closes,
driving the ODGF insolvent.
Monday, March 11, 1985
Runs continue on ODGF thrifts. The Federal Reserve helps ODGF thrifts
with document preparation to borrow from the discount window. Mr.
Thomas Tew, ESM1s court-appointed receiver, says that 13 local
governments and customers of five ODGF institutions face losses of $315
million.
Wednesday, March 13, 1985
A bill recapitalizing the ODGF with state funds is signed into law
during the evening, but funding levels are grossly insufficient and
heavy runs continue at four ODGF thrifts. Federal Reserve Chairman
Paul Volcker assures Ohio thrift executives that the Fed will provide
cash advances at the discount rate.
9"I'ursday, March 14, 1985
Major runs occur at six ODGF thrifts. The FSLIC offers insurance to
ODGF institutions, but capital hurdles are too high and the process
could take months. At an 8 p.m. press conference, Kenneth Cox, Ohio
Director of Commerce, refuses to answer directly questions as to
whether ODGF funds are unconditionally guaranteed by the state, and
Federal Home Loan Bank Board chairman Edwin Gray refuses to provide
immediate backing to ODGF firms that want federal insurance.
Friday, March 15, 1985
At a 7:30 a.m. press conference, Ohio Governor Richard F. Celeste
announces a Bank Holiday, to last "at leastu three days. The State of
Ohio refuses to put its full faith and credit behind the thrifts.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Monday, March
The Ohio
passes a
they can

18, 1985
legislature, acting on a Sunday request by Governor Celeste,
bill requiring ODGF thrifts to have federal insurance before
reopen.

Tuesday, March 19, 1985
The FSLIC promises to speed applications from ODGF thrifts, but imposes
higher capital standards than those required for existing insured
institutions.
Wednesday, March 20, 1985
During the early morning, the Ohio legislature passes a bill allowing
ODGF thrifts to open with the possibility of limited withdrawals, and
indemnifying FSLIC for losses incurred in ODGF institutions through
July 1, 1987. Federal Reserve discount assistance is republicized.
Thursday, April 4 , 1985
The Ohio legislature considers providing a financial guarantee of as
much as $85 million to prospective buyers of Home State Savings Bank.
Sources: Cooperman, Lee, and Wolfe (1992), Kane (1992), and various issues
of Barronls, the New York Times, and the Wall Street Journal.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

References
Boehmer, E., J. Musumeci and A.B. Poulsen, 1991, Event Study Methodology
under Conditions of Event-Induced Variance. Journal of Financial
Economics 30, 253-272.
Brown, S.J. and J.B. Warner, 1980, Measuring Security Price Performance,
Journal of Financial Economics 8, 205-258.

, 1985, Using Daily Stock Returns: The Case of Event Studies,
Journal of Financial Economics 14, 3-31.
Cooperman, E.S., W.B. Lee and G.A. Wolfe, 1992, The 1985 Ohio Thrift Crisis,
the FSLIC1s Solvency, and Rate Contagion for Retail CDs. Journal of
Finance 47, 919-941.
Kane, E.J., 1989, The S&L Insurance Mess: How Did It HaDDen?
Urban Institute Press.

Washington:

, 1992, How Incentive-Incompatible Deposit-Insurance Funds Fail,
Research in Financial Services, Public and Private Policv 4, 51-91.
Kane, E.J. and G.G. Kaufman, 1992, Incentive Conflict in Deposit-Insurance
Regulation: Evidence from Australia, Proceedinqs of a Conference on Bank
Structure and Competition, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 42-67.
Kane, E.J. and H. Unal, 1990, Modeling Structural and Temporal Variation in
the Market's Valuation of Banking Firms, Journal of Finance 45, 113-136.
Mikkelson, W.H., and M.M. Partch, 1986, Valuation Effects of Security
Offerings and the Issuance Process, Journal of Financial Economics 15,
31-60.
Stone, B.K., Systematic Interest-Rate Risk in a Two-Index Model of Returns,
1974, Journal of Financial and Ouantitative Analysis 9, 709-721.
Thomson, J.B., 1987a, The Use of Market Information in Pricing Deposit
Insurance. Journal of Money, Credit and Bankinq 19, 528-537.

, 1987b, FSLIC Forbearances to Stockholders and the Value of Savings
and Loan Shares, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Review, 3rd
Quarter, 26-35.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 1. Event Day: March 15, 1985 (ODGF Bank Holiday), FDIC-insured ~ i r m s
Number of companies used in estimation:

123

Average daily percent positive during the
estimation period (from 180 days prior to the
event though 21 days prior to the event) :

Date

Event
Day

Daily AAR

Z-Stat.

% POS.

Binomial
Z-Statistic

CAR

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

=

Average percent prediction error for day -1 through day 0
Z-Statistic for day -1 through day 0
Percent positive prediction errors, day -1 through day 0
Binomial Z-statistic for day -1 through day 0

=
=
=

-0.299
-1.956*
32 -520
-3.877*

Average percent prediction error for day -5 through day 0
Z-Statistic for day -5 through day 0

=
=

-0.166
-0.152

Average percent prediction error for day 1 through day 6
Z-Statistic for day 1 through day 6

=

-0.494
-3.021*

Average percent prediction error for day -10 through day 0
2-Statistic for day -10 through day 0

=
=

0.194
1.435

Average percent prediction error for day 1 through day 11
Z-Statistic for day 1 through day 11

=
=

-0.339
-1.482

=

* indicates significance at the 5% level.
Event Day:

Day relative to the event date.

Daily AAR:

Average abnormal return for the day.

Z-Stat:

Z-statistic testing the hypothesis that the Daily AAR is
zero.

Pos:

Percent of abnormal returns greater than zero on the day.

%

Binomial Z-Stat: Binomial statistic testing the hypothesis that the
proportion of positive abnormal returns on the day is
greater than the proportion during the estimation period.
CAR:

Cumulative abnormal return.

Source: Authors' calculations.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 2. Event Day: March 15, 1985 (ODGF Bank ~oliday),FSLIC-insured Firms
Number of companies used in estimation:

67

Average daily percent positive during the
estimation period (from 180 days prior to the
event though 21 days prior to the event) :
Date

Event
Day

~ a i l y A A R Z-Stat.

%

Pos.

Binomial
Z-Statistic

t-Test,
FDIC vs.
FSLIC
-0.57
-0.90
1.07
-0.33
-2.42*
0 -34
-0.15
2.36*
0.55
0.19
0 -77
0.13
1.09
-1.48
-0.88
-1.43
0.59
-2.08*
-0.33
-0.10
-1.25
-0.32
- 0.06
-0.47
-0.13
-0.60
- 1.96*
-0.19
-0.18
-0.03
-0.06
0 -49
0.35
-0.85
-3.Ol*
3.49*
-0.79
1.26
-1.42
-1.46
2.06*

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Average percent prediction error for day -1 through day 0
Z-Statistic for day -1 through day 0
Percent positive prediction errors, day -1 through day 0
Binomial Z-statistic for day -1 through day 0
Average percent prediction error for day -5 through day 0
Z-Statistic for day -5 through day 0
Average percent prediction error for day 1 through day 6
Z-Statistic for day 1 through day 6
Average percent prediction error for day -10 through day 0
Z-Statistic for day -10 through day 0
Average percent prediction error for day 1 through day 11
Z-Statistic for day 1 through day 11
- -

-

* indicates significance at the 5% level.
Event Day:

Day relative to the event date.

Daily AAR:

Average abnormal return for the day.

Z-Stat:

Z-statistic testing the hypothesis that the Daily AAR is zero.

%

Pos:

Percent of abnormal returns greater than zero on the day.

Binomial Z-Stat: Binomial statistic testing the hypothesis that the proportion
of positive abnormal returns on the day is greater than the
proportion during the estimation period.

CAR:

Cumulative abnormal return.

In the rightmost column, positive values signify that the abnormal returns for
FDIC institutions exceed the abnormal returns for FSLIC institutions.
Source: Authors' calculations.

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Figure 2
FSLIC-Insured Firms
AAR

%
CAR

d

-20 -18 -16 -14 -12 -10

-8

-6

-4

-2

0

2

Event Day
Source: Authors' calculations.

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20