View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK. CLEVEMND

90005625

Working Paper 8713

A TEST OF TWO VIEWS OF THE REGULATORY MECHANISM:
AVERCH-JOHNSON AND JOSKOW

by Philip Israilevich and Kim J. Kowalewski

Philip Israilevich is an economist at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago. Kim J. Kowalewski is an
economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland.
Working papers of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland are preliminary materials circulated to
stimulate discussion and critical comment. The
views stated herein are those of the authors and
not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Cleveland, the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
or the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System.
December 1987

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

A TEST OF TWO VIEWS OF THE REGULATORY MECHANISM:
AVERCH-JOHNSON AND JOSKOW

I. Introduction
The impact of regulation on the production decisions of electric utilities
was first described by Averch and Johnson (1962).

They argued that rate-of-

return regulation gives utilities the incentive to overcapitalize, that is, to
employ a capital-labor ratio that is larger than one that minimizes costs for
a given output level.'

Courville (1974), Spann (1974), Petersen (1975), and

Cowing (1978), for example, find evidence of an overcapitalization bias using
variations of the Averch and Johnson (A- J) model.
The major challenge to the A-J model concerns the nature of the regulatory
environment. Implicit in the A-J model is a regulator that constantly
monitors capital returns and adjusts electricity prices to keep capital
returns equal to their "fair" levels. Joskow (1974) argues that regulators
are more concerned with nominal electricity prices than with the rate of
return on capital. As long as nominal electricity prices are not increasing,
regulators will not actively enforce the rate-of-return constraint, thereby
eliminating the source of the A-J bias. As evidence in favor of his view,
Joskow finds a positive relationship between changes in the average cost of
electricity production and the frequency of rate hearings initiated by
utilities. He also argues that the implementation of fuel-cost-adjustment
clauses and environmental regulations in the 1970s reflects his more general
view of regulators as political entities rather than as Averch and Johnson's
strict rate-of-return enforcers.
The total impact of these and other constraints on electric utility
production decisions was examined by Atkinson and Halvorsen (1984).

They

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

-

2 -

developed a generalized cost model that includes the impact of additional
regulatory constraints and found empirical evidence of these impacts in a
cross-section sample of electric utilities. However, they did not include
Joskow's view of the regulatory process in their model.
The purpose of this paper is to test Joskow's view of the regulatory
mechanism by estimating a modified version of the Atkinson and Halvorsen
model. The modifications are of two sorts. The first allows for different
regulatory impacts over time as argued'byJoskow. The second permits the use
of panel data and the estimation of total factor productivity (TFP) and its
returns-to-scale and technical-change components. Joskow argues that when the
A-J bias occurs, utilities have less incentive not only to employ an efficient
team of production inputs, but also to innovate or to maintain a high rate of
technical change. Nelson and Wohar (1983) attempted to examine the impact of
regulation on utility technical change, but they could not estimate a direct
regulatory impact on technical change. Our procedure yields such an estimate.
Our data are a panel sample of the seven major electric utilities in Ohio
over the period 1965 to 1982.3 The advantage of this sample is that the
technologies employed by these utilities should be fairly similar; these Ohio
utilities are all privately owned, coal-burning plants and are subject to the
same regulator. Thus, the estimation of a common cost structure for these
utilities should yield a smaller potential for specification bias than is true
of previous studies of electric utilities, whose samples include utilities
that employ varying technologies or face different regulators.
Our results square with Joskow's view. We find considerable circumstantial evidence in Ohio consistent with Joskow's more general regulatory
mechanism. Our estimation results show that these utilities produce electricity less efficiently during the years when Joskow expects regulatory
constraints to be more binding, and that regulation significantly retards the

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

rate of technical change implemented by these utilities. Thus, the emphasis
that regulators and economists place on efficient production using a given
capital stock appears to be misplaced; the retardation of the rate of
technical change implemented by these utilities appears to be an important
source of bias. However, contrary to Joskow's view, we find that regulation
retards the technical change implemented by these utilities to a lesser extent
during the years when regulatory constraints are more tightly binding.
The next section of this paper contrasts the Averch-Johnson and Joskow
views of the regulatory mechanism. After that, the rate hearing experience in
Ohio over the 1965 to 1982 period is discussed and is found to correspond
quite well with Joskow's view of the regulatory mechanism. The fourth part
presents the model and outlines the testing procedures; the fifth section
describes the empirical results. The final section provides summary and
concluding remarks.

11. Averch-Johnson and Joskow Views of the Regulatory Process
It is useful to view the regulatory process in two parts: 1) the
mechanics of setting a utility's electricity price structure, and 2) the
events that initiate a rate hearing or a review of a utility's
electricity price structure. There is little disagreement among economists
about the first part. What brings a utility to a rate hearing and what
motivates a regulator are open questions in the empirical literature. The
predominant answers to these questions were influenced by Averch and Johnson.
They investigated the optimal response of a cost-minimizing utility in static
equilibrium t0.a "fair" rate of return on capital regulatory constraint. They
showed that when the rate of return on capital constraint is binding, and when

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

the "fair" rate of return is larger than the cost of capital, a utility has
the incentive to overcapitalize, that is, to employ a capital-labor ratio that
is larger than one that minimizes costs for the chosen output level.4
Implicit in the A-J model are two assumptions about the behavior of the
regulator. One is that the motivating factor behind regulatory action is the
rate of return on capital; in the A-J model, the constraint on a utility's
profit-maximization actions is that the actual rate of return on capital
earned by a utility is no greater than the "fair" rate. The second i-sthat an
active regulator continually monitors utility returns and pounds on a
utility with a "visible hand" to maintain the equality of a utility's profits
with its "fair" profits. This follows from Averch and Johnson's assumption of
static equilibrium. When a utility's profit is less than its "fair" level of
profits, the regulator calls a rate hearing to raise the "fair" return and,
hence, the utility's price of electricity. When a utility's profits are above
the "fair" level, the regulator calls a rate hearing to lower its "fair"
return and the price of electricity.
With minor amendments, this view of regulatory behavior predominates in
the economics literature, especially in empirical studies of electric utility
behavior, with the exception of Joskow (1974).=

Joskow agrees that rate-

of-return regulation will give a utility the incentive to employ an
inefficient mix of input factors, but he argues that the A-J bias may not
always occur in a dynamic world. In Joskow's view, regulators are political
institutions whose objective is to minimize "conflict and criticism," not to
keep the rate of return on capital equal to the "fair" rate.
One important source of conflict and criticism is an increase in the
nominal price of electricity. Consumers will agitate against increases in
electricity prices because they typically view these increases as pricegouging. If electricity prices are not increasing, and especially if they are

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

-

5 -

falling, consumers are indifferent to the profits earned by a utility. Thus,
Joskow argues that utilities that are able to adjust their production and
investment decisions to raise their earned rates of return without raising
electricity prices will not be thwarted by the regulator. In this case, there
may be little A-J bias. On the other hand, Joskow argues that regulators do
not initiate any actions to raise the rate of return on a utility's capital
when it is below the "fair" rate unless requested to do so by the utility.
Before a rate increase is granted, the utility will earn a return on capital
below the "fair" return. In this case, an A-J bias may appear.
Thus, in contrast to the active A-J regulator, the Joskow regulator is
passive, adjusting the rate of return on a utility's capital only when
requested to do so by a utility or by a consumer advocate. Earned profits may
deviate from "fair" profits over time if input prices, electricity demand, and
other factors change, but the regulator does not institute a price change to
re-equate earned profits with "fair" profits until the next rate hearing. In
the meantime, a utility can alter its production and investment decisions in
ways opposite to those predicted by the A-J model; The "fair" rate of return
in Joskow's view is a means to an end (uncontroversial electricity prices),
not an end in itself. After reviewing the regulatory experience across the

U.S. between the 1950s and early 1970s, Joskow concludes that:
Contrary to the popular view, it does not appear that regulatory
agencies have been concerned with regulating rates of return per se. The
primary concern of regulatory commissions has been to keep nominal
prices from increasing. Firms which can increase their earned rates
of return without raising prices or by lowering prices (depending on
changing cost and demand characteristics) have been permitted to earn
virtually any rate of return that they can. Formal regulatory action in
the form of rate of return review is primarily triggered by firms
attempting to raise the level of their rates or to make major changes in
the structure of their rates. The rate of return is then used to
establish a new set of ceiling prices which the firm must live with until
another regulatory hearing is triggered. General price reductions do
not trigger regulatory review, but are routinely approved without formal
rate of return review.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

This regulatory process is therefore extremely passive. Regulators take
no action regarding prices unless major increases or structural changes are
initiated by the firms under its jurisdiction. In short, it is the
firms themselves which trigger a regulatory rate of return review. There
is no "allowed" rate of return that regulatory commissions are continuously
monitoring and at some specified point enforcing. (Joskow, 1974, p. 298)
Because they work in a political environment, public utility commissions
face other sources of conflict and criticism, which have resulted in two
additional constraints on utility behavior. First, in the mid-1970s, when
energy costs increased rapidly, utilities requested rate hearings in greater
numbers than in the past. This increased caseload put a large burden on these
regulatory agencies, who were accustomed to only a few hearings in a year.
The time lag between the request for a rate hearing and a change in
electricity prices increased, and many utilities were forced to request
another rate hearing immediately after their previous hearing. In order to
shorten this lag and to appease utilities, regulators instituted fuel-costadjustment clauses that permitted utilities to pass higher fuel costs to
consumers without the need for a formal rate hearing. Second, environmental
advocates successfully agitated public utility commissions to establish limits
on the amount of pollution emitted by fossil-fueled utilities. These two
constraints complicate the analysis of the impact of a rate-of-return
constraint on utility behavior.

111. Rate Hearings and Average Costs of Ohio Utilities: 1965 to 1982
Some evidence consistent with Joskow's view of the regulatory mechanism is
found in the history of rate hearings in Ohio between 1965 and 1982. To put
this evidence into perspective, refer to the figure on page 26, which shows
the behavior of the average price per kilowatt-hour of electricity charged,
and the quantity of kilowatt-hours sold, by the seven major Ohio electric
utilities.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

For the purposes of t h i s discussion, three d i s t i n c t periods of- d i f f e r e n t
nominal e l e c t r i c i t y price and consumption behavior can be seen: 1965 t o 1968,
1969 t o 1975, and 1976 to 1982.6 Within each period, the directions of

change i n price and quantity were the same f o r each u t i l i t y i n the sample.
During the 1965 t o 1968 period, the average p r i c e of e l e c t r i c i t y changed very
l i t t l e and e l e c t r i c i t y s a l e s rose considerably.

During the 1969 t o 1975

period, theaverage annual growth r a t e of e l e c t r i c i t y sales slowed, while t h a t
of prices increased greatly.

Between 1976 and 1982, e l e c t r i c i t y s a l e s

declined f o r the f i r s t time i n Ohio's h i s t o r y , while prices increased a t t h e i r
f a s t e s t average annual percentage r a t e .
The figure also shows the percentage of the seven u t i l i t i e s requesting
r a t e hearings i n each year.

In -the f i r s t period, u t i l i t i e s rarely requested

r a t e hearings, and t h e i r average costs were f a l l i n g .

This behavior

corresponds with Joskow's f i r s t proposition: "During periods of f a l l i n g
average cost we expect t o observe v i r t u a l l y no regulatory r a t e of return
reviews" (p. 299).

The average price of e l e c t r i c i t y also was f a l l i n g during

t h i s period, consistent with Joskow's second proposition: "During periods of
f a l l i n g average costs we expect to obsewe constant or f a l l i n g prices charged
by regulated firms" (p. 299).

Given t h a t there were few r a t e hearings i n t h i s

period, it i s plausible t h a t u t i l i t y returns on capital were greater than or
equal t o what the " f a i r " returns the Public U t i l i t i e s Commission of Ohio
(PUCO) would have defined'had they been requested t o do so.'

According t o

Joskow, i f actual returns were lower than the " f a i r " return, then the
u t i l i t i e s would have asked f o r price increases.

Hence Joskow's t h i r d

proposition: "During periods of f a l l i n g average costs we expect t o observe
r i s i n g or constant ( p r o f i t maximizing) r a t e s of return" (p. 299).
-

During the 1969 t o 1975 period, average costs increased s l i g h t l y , t r i g gering a modest increase i n the frequency of hearings, while during the 1976

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

to 1982 period, the average costs increased tremendously. Production costs
increased in the late 1960s because of inflation stimulated by economic
policies; they increased very quickly and unexpectedly in the mid-1970s
because of inflation engendered by worldwide food shortages and by the Arab
oil embargo. For a given electricity price, such increases in operating costs
drove utility profits below their "fair" levels. Utilities promptly responded
to these cost increases by requesting electricity price increases that, in
most cases, were granted by the PUCO. The frequency of hearings increased
sharply as utilities had trouble keeping up with the effects of the rapid rise
in costs. Viewing the 1969 to 1975 period as a transition from a period of
falling average costs to one of rising average costs, the modest increase in
rate hearings during this period is consistent with Joskow's fifth
proposition:
The transition from a period of falling average costs to one of rising
average costs for a particular regulated industry will at first yield no
observable increase in the number of rate of return reviews filed by the
regulatory agency, but as cost increases continue more and more rate of
return reviews are triggered as firms seek price increases to keep their
earned rates of return at least at the level that they expect the commission will allow in a formal regulatory hearing. (p. 300)
For estimation purposes, the 1965 to 1982 interval was divided into two
periods: 1965 to 1973 and 1974 to 1982. Testable hypotheses of the A-J and
Joskow views deal with the absolute and relative production inefficiencies of
the utilities in these two periods. The near absence of regulatory hearings
in the first period would suggest, to both Joskow and A-J, that earned rates
of return of these utilities were at least as great as "fair" rates of return.
Averch and Johnson would argue that earned rates of return were lower than
monopoly rates of return and, hence, that the A-J bias should exist in the
first period. On the other hand, Joskow would argue that earned rates of
return may have been close to monopoly rates. If this were true, then because
monopoly rates are consistent with efficient production, there may have been

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

very little A-J bias in the first period. Indeed, as Joskow argues in his
seventh proposition, production may have been very efficient in the first
period because reducing costs would have contributed to higher earned rates of
return that were not taken away by regulators:
During periods of falling or constant nominal average cost firms have an
incentive to produce efficiently since all profits may be kept as long as
prices stay below the level established by the regulatory commission
in the last formal rate of return review. (p. 303)
The high frequency of hearings in the 1974 to 1982 period suggests that
earned rates of return for these utilities were lower than "fair" rates of
return for most of the period. Because these earned rates were even further
away from monopolistic rates of return, Joskow would argue that it is more
likely that there are inefficiencies of the A-J type in the second period.
His proposition eight says: "During periods of rising average cost A-J type
biases may begin to become important" (p. 304).

He does not exclude the

possibility that firms may continue to try to be as efficient as they were in
the first period in order to earn greater than "fair" rates of return.
However, he argues that:
Unless the direction of the cost path can be changed, however, the continuous interaction of firms and regulators in formal regulatory hearings,
resulting from the necessity to raise output prices, is exactly the situation for which the A-J type model (with some modifications) would hold. I
would therefore expect that it is under this situation of continuously
rising output prices, triggering rate of return reviews that the A-J type
models and the associated results are most useful. (p. 304)
Thus, Joskow would ar.gue that utilities would try to organize their production more efficiently in the first period than in the second period. His
concept of production efficiency includes the static notion of employing
currently available production inputs in the least-cost way for any given
level of output (that is, employing the least-cost combination of inputs along
a given isoquant) and the dynamic notion of investing in more productive
capital and management techniques over time (to push the family of isoquants

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

toward the origin).

Averch and Johnson deal only with the static notion of

productive inefficiency because their model analyzes a static equilibrium.
They would argue that the amounts of this static inefficiency are the same in
both periods because they assume a regulator who maintains the earned rate of
return on capital at its "fair" rate.
The distinction between the static and dynamic notions of production
efficiency is important. When a public utility commission conducts a rate
hearing, it pays attention only to the static notion of production efficiency.
Indeed, most models of regulatory impact deal only with the static notion.
However, it is conceivable that regulation also affects the rate of technical
change implemented by utilities; if regulation biases the amount of capital
employed by a utility, it also may bias the type of capital employed. Regulatory impacts on overall inefficiency and on the rate of technical change are
estimated below.

IV. Empirical Model
A. The Generalized or Shadow Cost Model
The A-J and Joskow views are examined using a modified version of the
Atkinson and Halvorsen(1984) generalized long-run cost function approach with
capital (K) , labor (L) , and fuel (F) as inputs.

Atkinson and Halvorsen

argued that the long-run neoclassical cost-function approach is incorrect for
a regulated firm because it assumes the firm is minimizing cost in a perfectly
competitive world constrained only to produce a given level of output.g
When the firm is subject to a number of regulatory constraints, the marginal
product of each input does not equal the market price of the input, but the
market price of the input plus the marginal changes in the additional constraints weighted by their Lagrange multipliers. Atkinson and Halvorsen use
the term "shadow" prices to refer to these modified market input prices. The

-

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

-

11

-

exact specification of these shadow prices depends on the exact form of the
additional constraints. Atkinson and Halvorsen approximated these shadow
prices by simple proportional relationships with market prices; that is, the
shadow price of input i P:

=

kipi,where Pi is its market price

and ki is a constant.
The generalized or shadow cost function is simply the neoclassical cost
function with P: substituted for Pi:

where CS is the shadow total cost of electricity production;
pf is the shadow price of input factor i, i

Q

is output of electricity; and

T

is time.

=

K, L, F;

Instead of minimizing long-run actual costs, a utility is assumed to minimize
long-run shadow costs by equating the shadow marginal cost of each
input with the amount of the input used. If the additional constraints are
not binding, then the ki equal one and minimizing shadow costs is equivalent
to minimizing actual costs. If the ki do not equal one, then the firm is
not operating at the lowest point of its long-run average cost curve.
An observable cost function based on the shadow cost function can be
derived as follows. First, recall the accounting identity for actual cost:

where Xi is the quantity of input i used in production. Similarly, the
accounting identity for shadow cost is:

The shadow cost share equations:

PQ.xi

Mi = -

c

for i

=

K, L, F

can be rewritten as:
(2

C"M;

pixi =

ki

for i = K, L, F

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

-

12

-

and summed over all i to obtain:

Taking logarithms of both sides of (3a) yields:

That is, the logarithm of actual cost equals the logarithm of shadow cost plus
the logarithm of the sum of the shadow cost shares each weighted by the
inverse of its respective ki.
To express each shadow cost share as a function of its corresponding
actual cost share, first divide both sides of (2) by ca:

and substitute (3a)

into (4) :

for i = K, L, F.

Atkinson and Halvorsen estimate a system comprising (3b)

and two of the

three equations in (5) but without a time trend because they use cross-section
data. We add the appropriate time variables to the shadow cost equation and
add a shadow TFP (TFP')

equation to our system in order to improve the

efficiency of the shadow cost equation coefficient estimates. Actual TFP is
measured as the change in the average cost of production that is not due to
changes in input prices. It reflects the overall productivity of all inputs
rather than the productivity of a single input such as labor. The neoclassical approach to the measurement of TFP assumes an optimal distribution of
production resources in a firm, which may be an inappropriate assumption
for
regulated electric utilities. The generalized cost-function approach yields a
shadow estimate of TFP that is consistent with regulated behavior. The most
important variable for the purposes of examining Joskow's view on productivity

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

-

13

-

behavior is the pure technical change component of TFP.

Gollop and Roberts

(1981), among others, argue that this component is a better measure of
productivity than TFP.
The TFP' equation is derived as follows. First, take the time
derivative of (la):

According to Shephard's Lemma, the elasticity of actual total cost with
respect to the market price of input i is equal to the share of input i in
total cost:

A modified Shephard's Lemma for.the shadow cost function is:

Dividing both sides of (6) by

cS and using(8)

yields a functional

relationship between the percentage change in shadow cost and the percentage
changes in the P:, Q, and T:

where a dot over a variable indicates the rate of change, v; is the
elasticity of shadow cost with respect to output (alncS/aln~), and

9

is the rate of change in shadow cost, holding all other variables

constant (BlncS/a~).
scale, and

-4is the

(1-v8) is a measure of shadow returns to
measure of shadow technical change of interest in

this paper.
Next, following the traditional definition of actual TFP as a Divisia
index of factor inputs, the rate of change in TFP'

(us)can be

defined as:

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy
.

-

14

-

Totally differentiating the accounting identity (lb) with respect to time and
using Shephard 's Lemma yields:

Equations (10) and (11) imply:

and using (9):

Finally, because

Ci M ~ 1, the above expression can be
=

rewritten in terms of one of the

xi,say x=:

Equation (12a) cannot be used for estimation purposes because WS is not
observed. It can be used to obtain an equation explaining the actual rate of
change in TFP as a function of

w',

but (12b) is easier to estimate.

The general specification of our estimation model includes the total cost
equation (3b) , the

TFP equation (12b).

and M; share equations from (5) , and the
The estimation model is based upon the translog

functional form. The translog shadow cost function is:

7gT(lnQ)T
with P:

=

+

1

%T2,

kip, and the usual linear homogeneity restrictions:

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

7

=

0

and

9

iJ

foralliandj.

y..=y..
1J

J1

Using Shephard's Lemma (a), the shadow cost share equations are:

Substituting (13), (14), and the definition of P; into (3b) yields an
estimable cost equation. Substituting (14) and the definition of P:
into (5) yields estimable cost share equations. Finally, an estimable TFP
equation is obtained by substituting(14) and the following v; and

9 expressions into

(12b):

Two modifications are made to these equations. First, separate values for
the ki coefficients were estimated for the 1965 to 1973 and 1974 to 1982
periods in order to estimate a shift in regulatory impact. The ki
coefficient estimates for the 1974 to 1982 period are denoted with a subscript

" S"
Second, % and

hswere normalized to one because the shadow cost

system is homogeneous of degree zero in the ki. This means that only
relative price efficiency can be examined using the ki,by testing ki=
kj=l and kis=kjs=lfor i,j

=

K,F. Differences in absolute price

efficiency between the two periods, relevant for a test of Averch-Johnson
versus Joskow, cannot be tested using differences between ki and kis.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

Nevertheless, the model can serve to test Averch-Johnson against Joskow, as
described below.lo
These translog equations form a nonlinear, seemingly unrelated regression
system. It is similar to that of Gollop and Roberts (1981), only generalized
to allow for the impact of all types of regulation on utility behavior. The
maximum likelihood LSQ option of TSP, version 4.OE, was used to estimate this
translog system.

B. Data
Data for labor input and the price of labor are taken from Financial
Statistics of Selected Electric Utilities, 1982, Department of Energy
(DOE/EIA-0437(82)),

February 1984. The quantity of labor is the number of

electric department employees, with a part-time worker counted as one-half of
a full-time worker. The labor price is defined as the ratio of labor expense
to the quantity of labor, where labor expense is total salaries and wages
charged to electric operation.
The fuel price data come from Standard and Poor's Compustat Services,
Inc., Utility Compustat 11. Fuel operation expense is the total cost of
fuel used exclusively for the production of electricity. The price of fuel is
the average cost of fuel per million Btu, which is the total cost of fuel used
for electricity production divided by its total Btu content in millions. The
quantity of fuel input is millions of Btu, defined as the ratio of fuel
operating expenses to the average cost per million Btu.
The data for the capital price and capital stock come from various issues
of Statistics of Privately Owned Electric Utilities in the United
States, U.S. Federal Power Commission. The capital price measure is the
conventional market price of capital, which is a function of the long-term
debt interest rate, the required return on equity capital, the preferred stock
dividend rate, the depreciation rate, and the Handy-Whitman index. The

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

capital stock is computed using a perpetual inventory method.ll The
depreciation rate is based on a 30-year average service life.12 The
product of capital price and capital stock is the total capital costs.
Total cost is the sum of labor, fuel, and capital costs.

V. Empirical Evidence

A. Model Characteristics
The results of estimating the model over the 1965 to 1982 period are shown
in table 1. Before testing the regulation bias hypotheses, it is useful to
examine the sense of the estimated model. A quick glance at the t-statistics
-

shows that the explanatory variables are just that - - only two of the 25
estimated coefficients have t-statistics less than 2 in absolute value. Apart
from the ki,the statistical significance of the coefficients does not
necessarily provide strong evidence about the adequacy of the estimated model.
Instead, characteristics of the production technology implied by the
coefficients provide better clues of model plausibility. The estimated
returns to scale are a good check of model adequacy for utilities because
utilities ought to display increasing returns to scale given the large fixed
costs required to supply electricity over an extensive geographic market.
Table 2 reports the estimates of the elasticity of cost with respect to
output averaged over all firms for each year. The shadow estimate is the
elasticity of shadow cost with respect to output from (15).

The actual

estimate is the shadow elasticity adjusted for the difference between actual
and shadow costs:

If returns to scale are increasing, then the cost elasticity is less than one.
As shown in table 2, the cost elasticities averaged over firms indicate

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

-

18

-

increasing returns to scale over the whole sample period. Both the shadow and
the actual elasticities behave similarly over time: the size of the increasing
returns to scale grows moderately over the first period and shrinks over the
second, and returns to scale are greater on average in the second period.
These results are consistent with the behavior of output over these periods.
In the first period, as output was increasing, these utilities were operating
on lower portions of their average cost curves, where returns to scale are
lower. In the second period, as output grew more slowly and eventually fell,
these utilities operated on higher portions of their average cost curves,
where returns to scale are higher. These results are the opposite of those of
Gollop and Roberts (1981), who do not allow for a regulatory bias. They find
an increase in returns to scale in the first period and a drop in returns to
scale in 1974-75, the last years of their sample.
As further evidence, constant returns to scale and homogeneity of the cost
function are tested. Homogeneity means that scale economies are the same for
firms of all sizes in all years, and constant returns to scale means that
there are no cost savings to increasing plant size. Homogeneity requires that
-y

=-y =-y =-y =O;
LQ FQ TQ QQ

constant returns requires homogeneity plus

PQ=l.

Both homogeneity and

constant returns to scale are rejected at better than the 0.5 percent
significance level.

.

The estimated actual and shadow cost shares for the inputs are shown in
tables 3a and 3b, respectively. The actual cost shares show that capital was
the largest component of actual cost in the first period, and that labor
became the largest cost component in the second period; fuel was the smallest
-

cost component in both periods. The shadow cost shares show that capital and
labor were the largest and smallest cost components, respectively, in both
periods. The difference between the actual and shadow cost shares is rather

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

-

19

-

dramatic, and again reflects the ratio of shadow to actual cost from (4) and

(5).

The large difference suggests that looking at the actual cost shares

will give a misleading picture of the reaction of these utilities to changes
in regulated prices.
Table 4 shows the decomposition of the growth rate of actual average cost
into its components. This decomposition is similar to that for the growth
rate of shadow cost (11):

The first column of table 4 shows the average growth rate of actual average
cost for each year. The next three columns are the M;P~ terms for
the three inputs; the fifth column shows the contribution of the returns to
scale term ($-1)~using vt from (16) ; the sixth shows the contribution
of the technical change term v;:

The last column is simply the difference between the first column and the sum
of the next five. This remainder is not zero, because the five components on
the right-hand side of (17) are estimated. Note that this remainder is not
derived from any of the estimated regression equations.
Every cost component except scale economies on average added to the growth
of average costs in both periods. Capital and fuel were the largest contributors to average cost growth in both periods, and capital and technical change
accounted for much of the increase in the growth rate of average costs between
the two periods. The remainder is about one-sixth the size of the average
growth rate of average costs in the first period, but it is very small in the
second. This suggests that the shadow cost model fits the second period much
better than the first.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

-

20

-

Estimated values for actual and shadow TFP and its components are shown in
tables 5a and 5b. The shadow TFP measure is the partial derivative of shadow
average cost with respect to time, which is the sum of two terms, the first
reflecting scale economies and the second representing technical change:
(19) TFP~= (1-V;)Q

-

v;.

Actual TFP (TFP~)comes from (19) but with v; from (16) replacing v6, and

9 from (18)

replacing v;.

The results in table 5a show that scale economies have

boosted T F P ~growth in every year except 1980, though the gain was significantly less in the second period. However, technical change was negative in
every year but 1965, pulling the growth of TFP~down, especially in the
second period. The results for TFP', shown in table 5b, are qualitatively
similar to those of TFPa and its components, though it is interesting that

9 was slightly positive on average in the

first period.

The most notable characteristic about both technical change estimates is
their strong downward trend.13 This rather uniform decline is due to
the strong estimated time trend yTT. That shadow input prices have
little influence on technical change is not surprising, because electricity
production offers little input substitutability in the short and medium runs.

B. Regulatory Impact
The estimation results in table 1 show that all of the log(ki) are
individually significantly different from zero at better than the 0.5% significance level. The joint test of the statistical insignificance of all four of
the log(ki) is rejected at better than the 0.5 percent significance level.
Thus, relative price efficiency is rejected over the whole sample, and the
neoclassical cost function approach for regulated firms employed by Gollop and
Roberts (1981)

and others is inappropriate for this sample.l4

A test of the A-J view and a test of the implications of Joskow's view is
whether production inefficiencies due to regulation differ in the 1965 to 1973

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

-

21

-

and the 1974 to 1982 periods. The A-J view is that the inefficiencies should
be the same in each period, while the Joskow view is that there should be
greater inefficiencies in the second period than in the first. The true cost
of regulation, and hence the magnitude of the inefficiencies created by
regulation, cannot be estimated, because there is no evidence to suggest how
the utilities would have organized their production had regulation not existed
over the sample period. For example, the activities of production and
distribution might have been separated, different amounts of capital might
have been employed, and different technologies might have been chosen.l5
Hence, it is impossible to know what these firms' cost functions and
associated returns to scale and productivities would have been.
However, "instantaneous" tatal and dynamic inefficiency estimates can be
computed. The total measure compares actual utility costs predicted by the
estimated model with the actual costs predicted by the model, but with
and

&

%

set equal to one in both periods. That is, current production costs

for actual levels of output, which are generated by current production
techniques and regulatory constraints, are compared with the costs generated
with the same production techniques and for the same actual output levels, but
without the regulatory constraints. This estimate, also examined by Atkinson
and Halvorsen, measures movement along the isoquant to the efficient input
mix.
An estimate of the dynamic notion of inefficiency can be obtained by
examining the technical change experienced by these utilities with and without
regulation. As above, technical change with regulation is that implied by the
estimated model; technical change without regulation is that implied by the
estimated model, but with all ki set equal to one. The difference does not
have a real-world counterpart or explanation, but it does indicate the
direction of regulatory bias.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

-

22 -

Note that our measure of the regulatory impact on technical change is
different from that of Nelson and Wohar (1983).

In their model, TFP is the

sum of the technical-change term, the returns-to-scale term, and a separate
regulatory impact. Without regulation, TFP is the sum of only the returns-toscale and technical-change terms. This naturally begs the question of how
regulation affects TFP if it does not affect the components of TFP.
Obviously, Nelson and Wohar cannot test for a regulatory impact on technical
change. Their measures of a regulatory impact on technical change are purely
hypothetical, based on the difference between different TFP values calculated
using assumed, not estimated, values for the regulatory impact coefficient,
and their returns-to-scale and regulatory impact terms. The reader is left to
wonder why the authors believed that regulation does not affect the
returns-to-scale term.
Two sets of measures can be examined for a regulatory impact: actual and
shadow. As shown in Israilevich and Kowalewski (1987), the actual cost and
the actual and shadow returns-to-scale and technical-change equations are
homogeneous of degree zero in the ki,while the shadow cost equation is not.
Thus, either the actual or the shadow returns-to-scale and technical-change
measures can be used to examine the regulatory bias. The regulatory bias to
the translog shadow measures is a constant for each variable in each period.
This can be seen by subtracting the translog shadow equation for any of these
variables from the same equation, but with the ki set equal to one. The
reason is that the cost-minimization model is set in a static equilibrium
framework. The regulatory biases to the actual variables are not constant
because they differ from the shadow measures by a proportional function of the
ratio of shadow to actual cost. This ratio, and hence the degree of

-

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

regulatory bias, varies over time. We prefer to use the actual measures to
examine the regulatory bias for this reason and because the shadow measures
have no real-world meaning.
Our inefficiency estimates reject Averch and Johnson's view and do not
reject Joskow's view. As shown in table 6, the total inefficiency measure
differs between the two periods, contrary to Averch and Johnson's view.
Moreover, the direction of change between the two periods is what Joskow would
expect - - total inefficiency is about 16 percentage points greater in the
second period. In the first period, total inefficiency steadily increases
from about 61.5 percent to 73.8 percent and averages about 66.6 percent. In
the second period, it steadily increases from 74.9 percent to 87.4 percent and
averages about 82.6 percent.
These total inefficiency estimates give the appearance of being overly
large in magnitude. Atkinson and Halvorsen find much smaller inefficiency
losses (9.0 percent) in their cross-section sample of 1970 firms, which
includes two of our firms.16 However, the Atkinson and Halvorsen result
captures only the static portion of total inefficiency costs because they do
not use time variables in their cost equation. Our estimates include the
dynamic inefficiency costs, and hence are more representative of the total
costs of regulation.
The difference between the Atkinson and Halvorsen result and ours suggests
that the dynamic inefficiency may be quite large. Indeed, as shown in table
7, we find that regulation may have retarded the growth of technical change on
average by about 0.64 percentage point per year in the first period and
by 0.44 percentage point per year in the second. This an important
result, and one that has been neglected by economists and regulators alike.
Regulation not only affects the efficient utilization of existing production
inputs, but it also affects the implementation of efficient capital and

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

-

24

-

management techniques over time. Unlike our total inefficiency estimates, the
dynamic portion of our total inefficiency estimate rejects Joskow's view of
greater regulatory bias in the second period.
This regulatory bias on technical change is opposite to the casual
impression given by the trends in actual and shadow technical change shown in
tables 5a and 5b. The strong downward trends in both technical change
measures, especially given the total inefficiency cost estimates shown in
table 6, might lead some analysts to infer that tighter regulatory constraints
contributed to the slowdown in technical change in the second period.
However, table 7 shows that the regulatory bias on technical change was less
in the second period.
Finally, an interesting result in table 7 is that regulation biased
returns to scale upward on average in both periods. Contrary to Joskow's
view, the regulatory bias on returns to scale is smaller in the second period.
Netting out the two components, TFP was biased down by 0.46 percentage point
per year in the first period and by about 0.33 percentage point per year in
the second. This result also rejects Joskow's view of greater dynamic
inefficiency in the second period.

VI. Swnmary and Conclusions
Electric utility regulators attempt to maintain a competitive price for
electricity by adjusting the rate of return on a utility's capital. At first
blush, this price-setting scheme appears sensible. It seems reasonably
efficient to allow utilities to pass along operating costs and to cover their
cost of capital. However, there are potentially serious problems with this
type of regulation related to consumer reactions to price increases and to the
types of incentives given to utilities. First, price increases may lower the
consumption of electricity, which may reduce earned rates of return below

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

-

25

-

"fair" rates and trigger a price increase, which in turn may lower consumption
and trigger another price increase, and so on. That is, the proper response
to falling utility profits because of lower demand may not be to raise prices.
Second, utilities may be able to effect price increases by using "too
much" capital, that is, by overcapitalizing, which inflates their rate base.
Indeed, rate increases lower the risk of capital investment below the risk
level of unregulated industries, clearly giving utilities the incentive to
overcapitalize. This potential bias was recognized by Averch and Johnson, and
many empirical studies that adopted their model found an overcapitalization
bias.
Finally, the ability to pass along operating cost increases that originated from productivity declines suggests that utilities may not have the
incentive to raise productivity. This dynamic source of inefficiency was
recognized by Joskow, who also argued that the regulatory mechanism is more
complicated than that assumed by Averch and Johnson.
This paper is the first, to our knowledge, to explicitly test the AverchJohnson view against Joskow's more general view. Using a modified version of
the generalized long-run cost function derived by Atkinson and Halvorsen
and a sample of the seven major electric utilities in Ohio over the 1965 to
1982 period, substantial evidence is found against the A-J view. Our total
inefficiency measure shows that regulatory constraints were more binding
during the years in which Joskow expects.them to be more binding. We also
find that regulation substantially retards the rate of technical change
experienced by these utilities. However, the retardation in technical change
is greater during the years when Joskow expects regulation to be less binding.
This is the first demonstration of a regulatory impact on technical change.
-

It clearly suggests that regulators ought to pay closer attention to the
incentives they give utilities to innovate.l7

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

-

26

-

PRICE, AVERAGE COST, AND RATE HEARING FREQUENCY

Electricity
peY'

30%
25%
20%
15%
10%
5%
0%
- 5%

=I5

1

66

I

I

I

I

I

Average

%
65

I

I

I

I

I

I

Cost

da11ar-

~ 1 I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I
67
69
71
73
75
77
79
81
68
70
72
74
76
78
80
82
66
year

Rate

H

i

year

SOURCE: The authors.

I

6'7
69
71
7'3'75
77
79
81
68
70
72
74
76
78
80
82
year

ourrent

30%
25%
2 0%
15%
10%
5%
0%
- 5

Price

k1loVVECtt-he-r

I

Frequency

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

TABLE 1
COEFFICIENT ESTIMATES
Coefficient

-----------

Estimate

---------

2.309321
2.408440
2.504495
1.756207
-7.593048
.I308763

log(h)
log(&)
log($)
log(bs)
Q

SL

SF
ST

PQ
TLK
YFK
YE,
YLQ
YFQ

Std. Error

-----------.I192982
.I239441
.2273822
.2103573
1.780928
.2288987D-01
.7871482D-01
.2978847D-01
.3934191
.5171896D-02
.1416839D-01
.4092725D-02
.1919976D-02
.9527101D-02

~ L T

VET
~ Q T

TQQ
YTT

COEFFICIENTS COMPUTED FROM PARAMETER RESTRICTIONS
Coefficient

----------SK
%K

~ F E

r~~
~ K Q
YKT

Estimate

Std. Error

T-Statistic

1.4586
6.46143-02
1.06233-01

8.03743-02
1.69563-02
1.40533-02

18.1472
3.8108
7.5588

-3.42733-02
-8.61253-02
1.14703-03

5.43513-03
9.56773-03
1.05543-03

-6.3058
-9.0017
1.0869

----------

----------

-----------

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

TABLE 2
ESTIMATED ELASTICITY OF COST WITH RESPECT TO OUTPUT
(averaged over firms)

Year

NOTE:

Actual

Shadow

The e l a s t i c i t y of shadow cost with respect t o output is computed using
% from equation (15). The e l a s t i c i t y of actual c o s t i s
computed from equation (16).

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

TABLE 3a
ESTIMATED ACTUAL COST SHARES
(averaged over firms)

Year

Capital

------- -------

Labor

------

1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973

0.5494
0.5381
0.5345
0.5245
0.5154
0.4981
0.4790
0.4668
0.4536

0.2824
0.2938
0.2932
0.3047
0.3085
0.3203
0.3433
0.3572
0.3694

0.1682
0.1681
0.1723
0.1707
0.1761
0.1816
0.1777
0.1760
0.1770

----

Fuel

NOTE: The actual cost shares are computed using equation (7).

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

TABLE 3b
ESTIMATED SHADOW COST SHARES
(averaged o v e r f i r m s )

Fue 1

Capital

-------

------

------

1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973

0.7076
0.7021
0.6957
0.6915
0.6815
0.6665
0.6605
0.6569
0.6483

0.0372
0.0389
0.0386
0.0405
0.0410
0.0430
0.0476
0.0508
0.0532

0.2552
0.2590
0.2657
0.2680
0.2774
0.2905
0.2919
0.2923
0.2985

----

-

Labor

Year

NOTE: The shadow c o s t s h a r e s are computed u s i n g e q u a t i o n ( 1 4 ) .

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

TABLE 4
ESTIMATED COMPONENTS OF THE RATE OF CHANGE
IN ACTUAL AVERAGE COST
(percentage change, averaged over firms)

Year
---1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973

NOTE:

Average
Cost
Capital

-------

-------

-2.435% 3.210%
0.217
- 0.066
5.040
2.337
2.412
1.974
6.503
11.563
19.067 10.720
9.920
8.679
8.069
9.714

Labor

Fuel

Scale
Econ.

Tech.
Change

Remainder

0.733
2.046
6.117
4.822
2.512
3.689

-2.963
- 2.418
-1.353
-0.742
-2.250
-2.857

0.719
1.054
1.327
1.587
1.912
2.241

-1.384
-1.296
-1.326
2.397
-1.253
-1.833

------ ------- ------- --------0.516% - 2.888% 0.038% -3.413%
1.083 - 2.012
0.129
0.362

These figures are computed using equation (17).
The sum of the
capital, labor, fuel, scale economies, and technical change columns is
the estimated percentage change in actual average cost. The difference
between the average cost column and this estimated percentage change is
the remainder.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

TABLE 5a
ESTIMATED ACTUAL TOTAL FACTOR PRODUCTIVITY
AND COMPONENTS
( p e r c e n t a g e change, a v e r a g e d o v e r f i r m s )

Year

Total
Factor
Produc .

1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973

2.5797%
2.8500
1.6501
2.2433
1.3636
0.0256
-0.8451
0.3383
0.6156

----

--------

Scale
Econ.

Tech.
Change
.-------

0.312%
-0.038
-0.362
-0.719
- 1.054
-1.327
-1.587
-1.912
- 2.241

NOTE: A c t u a l t o t a l f a c t o r p r o d u c t i v i t y and i t s two components are computed
from e q u a t i o n (19) b u t w i t h $ from (16) r e p l a c i n g vc a n d
v; from (18) r e p l a c i n g v;.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

TABLE 5b
ESTIMATED SHADOW TOTAL FACTOR PRODUCTIVITY
AND COMPONENTS
(percentage change)

Year

----

1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973

NOTE:

Total
Factor
Produc .

Scale
Econ.

Tech.
Change

-------1.3841%
1.0200
0.6974
0.3259
- 0.0121
-0.2976
-0.5876
-0.9304
- 1.2743

Shadow total factor productivity and its components are computed using
equation (19).

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

TABLE 6
TOTAL REGULATORY IMPACT
ON ACTUAL COST

Year

Estimated
Actual
Cost

No
Regulation
Actual
Cost

Regulatory
Impact

1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973

102.614
114.387
121.560
140.683
156.215
185.397
223.909
267.667
329.468

63.958
70.675
75.208
86.073
95.322
111.908
132.645
157.020
191.387

61.529%
62.980
62.872
64.390
64.921
66.579
69.875
71.987
73.815

----

--------

---------

----------

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

TABLE 7
REGULATORY IMPACT ON ACTUAL
TOTAL FACTOR PRODUCTIVITY
(percentage change)

Year

Total
Factor
Produc

.

--------

-0.4696%
- 0.4120
-0.5156
-0.4020
-0.4514
-0.5337
-0.5463
-0.4313
-0.3850

Scale
Econ.

Tech.
Change

--------0.6837%
-0.6691
-0.6713
-0.6573
-0.6539
- 0.6409
-0.6113
-0.5936
-0.5789

NOTE: The columns show t h e d i f f e r e n c e between t h e estimated a c t u a l measures
and t h e estimated a c t u a l measures w i t h t h e ki a l l s e t equal t o . o n e .

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

FOOTNOTES
lThis interpretation of the Averch-Johnson result is due to Baumol and
Klevorick (1970).
2That is, Courville (1974), Spann (1974), Petersen (1975), Cowing (1978),
and Nelson and Wohar (1983), for example, test only for an overcapitalization
bias against an alternative hypothesis of no bias. Of these papers, only
Nelson and Wohar do not find an overcapitalization bias.
3~he
seven major electric utilities in Ohio are Ohio Power; Cincinnati Gas
and Electric; Cleveland Electric Illuminating; Columbus and Southern Ohio
Electric; Dayton Power and Light; Ohio Edison; and Toledo Edison. Over the
1965 to 1982 period, they accounted for about 90 percent of electric power
sales in Ohio.
4~ctually,Baumol and Klevorick (1970) argue that Averch and Johnson did
not prove this as a general-result. Note that if there are additional
production factors, then the amount of capital relative to these other inputs
also will be higher than for the cost-minimizing firm.
5~ slight modification to the Averch-Johnson regulatory process was the
introduction of a "regulatory lag"; see, for example, Bailey and Coleman
(1971) and Baumol and Klevorick (1970).

6~he
average price shown in the figure is not the regulated price, but the
ratio of average total revenue for the seven utilities to their average total
sales. In general, different consumers face different regulated price schedules, and utilities serving different geographic markets may be allowed to
charge different prices for the same category of consumer.
7 ~ can
t never be known whether earned returns were greater than "fair1'
returns because there were no rate hearings for all firms during these years.
80ther production inputs, such as materials, managerial skills, and
available infrastructure, for example, are excluded because there are no
reliable data for these factors.
g~evertheless,
some authors, for example Gollop and Roberts (1981,1983) ,
use the neoclassical approach to study electric utilities.
strict test of Averch and Johnson's view using the ki is % not
equal to 1 and hSnot equal to one, because Averch and Johnson consider
only a rate-of-return regulatory constraint. If these hypotheses cannot be
rejected, then Nelson and Wohar (1983) and other papers that test only this
constraint are potentially incorrect.
llsee Cowing, Small, and Stevenson(1981) for the equations used to
compute the capital stock and capital price variables.
12capital Stock Estimates for Input -Output Industries: Methods and
Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor
Statistics, 1979.

Data, Bulletin 2034, U.S.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

-

37 -

FOOTNOTES
1 3 strong
~

downward trend in the rates of technical change experienced
by utilities also was found by Nelson and Wohar (1983), Gollop and Roberts
(1981), and Gollop and Jorgenson (1980), all of whom used samples that ended
in the 1970s. Thus, the results reported here confirm these earlier findings
for the late 1970s and early 1980s.
14The strict test of Averch and Johnson's view is rejected; % and
kFs are jointly statistically different from zero at better than a 0.5
percent significance level.
''under
the current regulatory environment, the production and
distribution of electricity must be handled by each utility. Moreover, the
transferal of electric power across state lines also is impeded.
161t is likely that our estimates are more accurate for Ohio because
our sample includes only Ohio firms, which are fairly similar in a number of
important respects, as mentioned earlier.

he

poor technical-change performance also may be due to increased
investment in nuclear power plants over this period, which drew funds away
from conventional power-generation capital investments.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

REFERENCES
Atkinson, Scott E., and Robert Halvorsen. "Parametric Efficiency Tests,
Economies of Scale, and Input Demand in U.S. Electric Power Generation,"
International Economic Review, vol. 25, no. 3 (October 1984), 647-62.
Averch, Harvey, and Leland L. Johnson. "Behavior of the Firm under Regulatory
Constraint," American Economic Review, vol. 52, no. 5 (December 1962),
1052 - 69.
Bailey, E.E., and R.D. Coleman. "The Effect of Lagged Regulation in an
Averch-Johnson Model," The Bell Journal of Economics and Management
Science, vol. 2, no. 1 (Spring 1971),, 278-92.
Baumol, William J., and Alvin K. Klevorick. "Input Choices and Rate-of-Return
Regulation: An Overview of the Discussion," The Bell Journal of Economics
and Mana=ement science, vol. 1, no. 2 (Autumn 1970), 162 -90.
Berndt, Ernst R., and Melvyn A. Fuss. "Productivity Measurement with
Adjustments for Variations in Capacity Utilization and Other Forms of
Temporary Equilibrium," Journal of Econometrics, vol. 33, no. 1/2
(October/November 1986), 7-30.
Christensen, L.R., and Dale W. Jorgenson. "U.S. Real Product and Real Factor
Input, 1929-1967," The Review of Income and Wealth, series 16, no. 1
(March 1970), 19-50.
Courville, Leon. "Regulation and Efficiency in the Electric Utility Industry,"
The Bell Journal of Economics and Management
Science, vol. 5, no. 1
(Spring 1974), 53-74.
Cowing, Thomas G. "The Effectiveness of Rate-of-Return Regulation: An
Empirical Test Using Profit Functions," in M. Fuss and D. McFadden, Eds.,
Production Economics: A Dual Avvroach to Theory and Avvlication,
Amsterdam: North Holland Publishing Company, 1978.
Cowing, Thomas G., Jeffery Small, and Rodney E. Stevenson. "Comparative
Measures of Total Factor Productivity in the Regulated Sector: The
Electric Utility Industry," in T.G. Cowing and R.E. Stevenson, Eds.,
Productivity Measurement in Regulated Industries, New York: Academic
Press, 1981.
Fare, Rolf, and James Logan. "Shephard's Lemma and Rate of Return Regulation,"
Economics Letters, vol. 12 (1983), 121-25.
Gollop, Frank M., and Dale Jorgenson. "U.S. Productivity Growth by Industry,
1947-1973," in J.W. Kendrick and B.N. Vaccara, Eds., Studies in Income and
Wealth, National Bureau of Economic Research, Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 1980.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper
Best available copy

Gollop, Frank M., and Mark J. Roberts. "The Sources of Economic Growth in the
U.S. Electric Power Industry," in T.G. Cowing and R.E. Stevenson, Eds.,
Productivity Measurement in Regulated Industries, New York: Academic
Press, 1981.
Gollop, Frank M., and Mark J. Roberts. "Environmental Regulations and
Productivity Growth: The Case of Fossil-Fueled Electric Power Generation,"
Journal of Political Economy, vol. 91, no. 4 (August 1983), 654-74.
Israilevich, Philip and K.J. Kowalewski. "Estimating Total Factor Productivity
in a Generalized Cost System," Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Working;
P a ~ e r8702, March 1987.
Joskow, Paul L. "Inflation and Environmental Concern: Structural Change in the
Process of Public Utility Price Regulation," The Journal of Law and
Economics, vol. 17 (October 1974), 291-327.
Nelson, Randy A., and Mark E. Wohar. "Regulation, Scale Economies, and
Productivity in Steam-Electric Generation," International Economic Review,
vol. 24, no. 1 (February 1983), 57-79.
Petersen, H. Craig. "An ~ m ~ i r i c aTest
l
of Regulatory Effects," The Bell
Journal of Economics and Management Science, vol. 6, no. 1 (Spring 1975),
111-26.
Spann, R.M. "Rate of Return Regulation and Efficiency in Production: An
Empirical Test of the Averch-Johnson Thesis," The Bell Journal of
Economics and Management Science, vol. 5, no. 1 (Spring 1974), 38-52.