View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Workinp Paper 9120

A DYNAMIC ANALYSIS OF RECENT CHANGES
IN THE RATE OF PART-TIME EMPLOYMENT
by Donald R. Williams

Donald R. Williams is an associate professor
of economics at Kent State University, Kent,
Ohio. This paper was written while he was a
visitor at the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland. The author is grateful to Fran
Horvath of the U.S. Department of Labor,
Bureau of Labor Statistics, for providing the
gross change data and to Thomas Nardone for
helpful comments and additional data.
Working papers of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland are preliminary materials circulated
to stimulate discussion and critical comment.
The views stated herein are those of the
author and not necessarily those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System.

December 1991

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Abstract
The part-time employment rate has declined since the early 1980s,
especially among females. This paper examines the decline over
the 1980-1990 period, with a focus on the gender differential,
using gross change data from the Bureau of Labor Statistics.
Monthly transition rates between full-time employment, part-time
employment, unemployment, and nonparticipation are estimated
according to sex. Trend and cyclical analysis of the transition
rates is conducted to identify the sources of part-time
employment-rate trends and to explore gender differentials in
them. The results suggest that the decline in the rate of parttime employment among females is not so much because unemployed
females are more likely to move into full-time employment, but
rather because females have become more likely to move from parttime to full-time employment and, most important, because they
have become less likely to leave full-time employment once they
get there.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

I. Introduction
A well-known change in the U.S. labor force over the past
three decades has been the rapid growth in the proportion of
workers who are employed part-time.

For example, in 1957 the

part-time employment rate was 12.1 percent, compared with 19.5
This growth corresponds with an international

percent in 1990.'

trend (Thurman and Trah [1990]).

The rate of increase declined

significantly in the late 1970s, however, and although the
current U.S. rate of part-time employment is higher than pre-1970
rates, it has actually fallen since 1980 (from 18.8 percent of
employees in 1980 and a peak of 20.6 percent in 1982 to 18.5
percent in 1990)

.'

This is primarily the result of a marked

decline in the rate of part-time employment among females set
against only moderate increases in the rate among males (see
figure 1).

Still, however, the rate of part-time work among

females is considerably greater than for males.
Although previous analyses of changes in the rate of parttime employment have focused on its srowth, the insights provided
there may be useful in identifying the sources of its decline.
The reasons cited in the literature can be broadly classified

1

Recent papers highlighting this growth include Tilly (1991)
and Ichniowski and Preston (1986).
'calculated from U.S. Department of Labor (1988) and
Employment and Earninas, various issues. I should note the
difference between the proportion of the employed who work parttime, which is the focus of this paper, and the proportion of the
labor force or of the population who work part-time. It is
possible to have the first term fall and the other two rise over
time if the overall employment rate increases sufficiently.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

into those corresponding to supply and demand.

On the supply

side has been the rapid growth of segments of the labor force who
have historically high propensities for part-time employment:
females, teenagers, and older workers.

Their greater preference

for part-time work is usually attributed to a desire for greater
flexibility of scheduling on the one hand and for fewer hours on
the other, due to home responsibilities, school, and health
(Tilly [1991], Nardone [1986]) and the use of part-time
employment as a bridge to retirement (Ruhm [1990]).

One supply-

side factor found @ to have contributed to the growth of parttime work has been the overall growth in unemployment (Tilly
[1991], Ichniowski and Preston [1986]).
Demand-side factors can be placed in two groups.

First is

the argument that firms are increasing their use of part-timers
in order to decrease costs of production, given the technologies
of the firms.

Lower costs arise from the propensity to offer

fewer fringe benefits (Ichniowski and Preston [1986], 9to5
[1986]), the desire to avoid overtime pay (Belous [1989]), the
ability to fend off unions (Tilly [1991], 9to5 [1986]), and the
possibility of greater productivity or efficiency of part-time
workers (Hallaire [1968]). The second type of change in demand
arises from changes in the technologies of firms toward those
that correspond to the kinds of jobs best suited for part-time
work.

Jobs in the retail sector are well suited for part-timers,

for example, with an emphasis on daily or weekly peak hours and
on flexible schedules (Hallaire [1968]), as are low-skilled jobs

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

with routine and repetitive discrete job tasks (Nollen et al.
[1978]).
Of course, there also are interactions between the factors
presented above, such that the growth of the female labor force
may have facilitated the growth of retail trade, and the move
toward low-skilled jobs may have been in response to a growing
low-skilled labor force.
The current view of the sources of growth of part-time
employment concludes that supply may have been most important
through the 1960s and demand through the 1970s (Tilly [1991]).
But what explains the decline since 1980?

Although the teenage

and older populations have been in relative decline as a
proportion of the labor force, the female sector has continued to
grow (albeit at a declining rate).

It is difficult to argue that

firms have become less concerned about decreasing costs over the
past decade.

Likely explanations include a slowing of the

transition toward industries and occupations with technologies
which lend themselves to part-time work, coupled with an
increased preference for full-time employment among women.
The goal of this paper is to shed some light on the issues
through an examination of the differences in the levels and
trends in part-time employment in a dynamic context.

In

particular, I focus on the labor-market flows (transitions)
between the states of full-time employment, part-time employment,
unemployment, and nonparticipation, recognizing that the parttime employment rate at a point in time is a function of these

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

flows.

This approach has been used extensively in analyses of

variations in unemployment and labor-force participation rates. 3
Although the analysis is primarily descriptive, it can provide
insights not available from simple time series analyses of the
part-time employment rate alone, nor even from cross-sectional
micro-level data (which would nevertheless be useful in analyzing
.differences in levels)

.

The next section presents a brief description of the flow
approach and the relationship between transition rates and the
part-time employment rate.

This is followed by a simple dynamic

choice model that is extended to include part-time employment.
The model highlights the roles of wages, the value of leisure,
and the rate of offer of new jobs in explaining part-time rate
differentials.

Unpublished gross change data from the Bureau of

Labor Statistics are then used to estimate trends in the
probabilities of transitions between the four labor-market states
noted above, separately by gender.

I also examine gender

differentials in the levels and cyclical responsiveness of the
rates.

11.

The Flow Approach
Define the following three mutually exclusive labor-market

states: full-time employment, part-time employment, and non-

3 ~ analyses
~ r
focusing on the unemployment rate, see Marston
(1976), Ehrenberg (1980), and DeBoer and Seeborg (1989); for
participation rates, see Williams (1985, 1987) and Smith and
Vanski (1978)
Also see Blanchard and Diamond (1990)

.

.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

employment, and let the number of individuals from the population
in each of those states at time t be F,, P,, and Z,,
respectively.

4

Denote the numbers of individuals who make

transitions from state to state during the interval [t,t+l] as
FP,, FZ,, PF,, PZ,, ZF,, and ZP,.

Then the transition rate between

states I,and J at time period t is defined as Aij=IJ,/I,. Six
transition rates describe the flows between the three states.

As

is the case for unemployment and labor-force participation rates,
the part-time employment rate can be expressed as a function of
these rates of flow.

Following Marston (1976) and defining the

steady state as occuring when flows into a state equal flows out
of a state, the steady state part-time employment rate,
PR=P/(P+F), can be written as
-

It is easily shown that the part-time employment rate is directly
related to the rates of transition from full- to part-time (A,,)
and nonemployment to part-time (A,,)

and inversely related to the

rates of transition from part- to full-time (A,,) and part-time
t o nonemployment (A,,).

Consequently, trends in the part-time

employment rate can be related to trends in these transition
rates.

Similarly, gender differences in the levels and trends in

his
purposes.

his

three-state case is presented only for expositional
The full four-state case is presented below.
equation is derived in appendix A.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

the part-time employment rate can be attributed to gender
differences in the levels and trends in the various transition
rates.

The purpose of the empirical analysis below is to

identify the transition rates representing the sources of the
trends in the part-time employment rates and gender differentials
noted above.

That is, we can determine whether the part-time

rate is higher for females than for males because females are
more likely, for example, to make transitions into part-time
employment from nonemployment (A,, is greater for females), or
because they are less likely to make transitions from part-time

.

to full-time employment (A,, is lower for 'females)

111. A Model of Transition Rate Determination
Before examini~gthe empirical evidence, I present a model
of the determination of transition rates, which provides a
framework for interpreting the transition rate differentials
observed.

The model is based on one presented (for full-time
6

employment only) by Mortensen and Neumann (1984).

I will now

allow there to be four labor-market states: unemployment (U),
nonparticipation (N), and F and P as above.

There are now 12

possible transitions between labor-market states.

Individuals

are assumed to choose the labor-market state P, F, U or N that
maximizes the expected present value of future utility, V,

6~he
model is very similar to one presented in Burdett et
al. (1981). None of the work in this area is concerned with the
distinction between full- and part-time employment. Still, the
presentation in this paper draws much from that earlier work.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

derived from the wage y and the value of leisure u.

They make

transitions between states only when the value of future utility
changes, which occurs when the individual receives a new wage
(job) offer or something causes a change in his or her value of
leisure.

These changes are assumed to occur in random intervals.

In this framework, any transition rate Xij can be expressed
as the product of the probability that a new wage (job) offer or
value of leisure has "arrivedn and the probability that the
change is sufficient to cause the worker to prefer another labormarket state:

where qi is the rate at which new wage offerlvalue of leisure
pairs arrive in state I and nij is the probability that state J
will be preferred, given the change in the wage offerlvalue of
leisure pair.

From equation (2) we see that workers who have

high arrival rates will be more likely to make transitions than
those with low arrival rates, ceteris paribus.

The arrival rates

are closest to capturing differences in demand-side factors, to
the extent they reflect differences in the probability of
receiving a job offer.7

The choice probabilities nij,on the

other hand, more closely represent supply-side factors.

The

determinants of the choice probabilities are explored in more

7 ~ o t e ,however, that the value of leisure can also change,
which generally is interpreted as a supply variable.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

detail below.
Choice among Labor-Market States
Rewrite the current wage and value of leisure as y
and u = v

+

=

w

+

el

e2, where w is the mean expected wage, v is the mean

expected value of leisure, and el and e2 are random disturbances
(deviations from the mean).

To simplify notation, let the

currently realized wage offerlvalue of non-market time pair,
(y, u)=(w+el, v+e2), be denoted as (x+e) and define the utility
in state I associated with that pair as Ui(x + e).
Assume that the set of disturbances e changes from time to
time to some value e f at random intervals, at the rate given by
qi(x).

I assume that the time until arrival of the new

disturbance has a negative exponential distribution, such that
the expected time before e changes again is l/qi(x)

.

Let F(e ,e I

)

be the distribution of the new disturbance e f given the current
value, e.

Note that the distribution of disturbances is

independent of the state occupied.8

The worker is assumed to

assess her state occupancy each time she is faced by a new
disturbance e f t choosing the state that yields the highest level
of discounted future utility.
The expected present value of future utility associated with
state i can be written as a function Vi(x,e) of the current
disturbance and the worker's
pair.

stationary wage and value of leisure

The value associated with state i today is the expected

A
' more general specification would allow F(.) to be state
dependent.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

utility derived while currently in state i, plus the expected
value of the state the worker chooses to occupy if and when a new
disturbance arrives.

Under the standard assumption of

intertemporally separable utility, this sum can be written as

where t i is the time of arrival of new information and r is the
discount rate.

The first term can be interpreted as the expected

utility enjoyed in state i prior to the arrival of a new
disturbance.

The second term represents the expected present

value of the optimal state choice after a new wage offerlvalue of
leisure pair has arrived.

When the new disturbance e is

realized, the worker chooses the state k that yields the greatest
expected value.

Taking expectations, the equation can be written

as

where y(x,e) = smax V,(x,e)dF(e,e1).

Now let

be the llacceptance setttAj, the set of disturbances e = (el,e2)
such that state j is at least as desirable as the other states.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

The choice probability from above is simply the probability that
the next disturbance e falls in the acceptance set Aj(x,z),

Note that it is an increasing function of the "sizeI1 of the
We thus can discuss differences in the choice

acceptance set Aj.

probabilities between, for example, males and females in terms of
differences in the sizes of their acceptance sets.
I have noted above that the utilities are state dependent.
In particular, I assume that a worker receives utility from the
wage only when employed, receives utility from leisure only when
not employed full-time, and incurs some cost to searching for
employment when unemployed.

In addition, I assume that the

individuals are risk neutral (wealth maximizers) and write the
respective utilities as follows:
(7a)

up

=

Y

= w + e l
(7b)

=

(7~)

U,=u-c
=

(7d)

+ (1-a)u
a(w + el) + (1-a) (v + e2)

U, = ay

(v

u,, =

u

=

v

+

+

e2)

-

c

e2,

where a is the proportion of time that a part-time worker spends
employed and c is the cost of search (viewed as lost leisure).

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Substitution of these values and the respective arrival rates
into equation (4) yields the four value functions V,, VP, VU, and
VN

The boundaries of the acceptance sets are given by the
values of el and e2 that make the worker indifferent between
states (that is, that equate the respective value functions).
Hypothetical sets of such boundaries are depicted in figure 2.
The relevant (dominant) regions of the boundaries are solid
lines, and partition the (e,, e2) space into the four acceptance
sets A,, Apt Au, and A,.

The sizes of the acceptance sets, and

hence the probability that a given state will be chosen at the
arrival of a new wage or value of leisure, are determined by the
positions of these boundaries.

Equations for the boundaries are

given in appendix B.
Two key assumptions about the relative magnitudes of the
arrival rates have been made in order to construct these
boundaries.

First, it is assumed that there is no job search

when a worker is employed either full- or part-time, so that
there should be no reason to expect the arrival rates to differ
in the F and P states (qF=qp). This causes the boundary between
the full- and part-time acceptance sets to have slope equal to
Second, we must assume that the arrival rate is greater

one.

when a worker is unemployed than when not participating (qu>qN),
or there would never be a reason to prefer U to N. 9
9

Both of these rationales refer only to the wage
disturbance, el, while the arrival rate also applies to the
disturbance in the value of leisure. They are valid if the rate
(continued)
11

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Comparative Statics
In the context of this model, changes (or differences) in
the choice probabilities can arise from changes (differences) in
the values of the four variablesin the utility functions (w, v,
c, and a) and the four arrival rates.

Because the part-time

employment rate is most influenced by the rates of transition
into and out of full- and part-time employment, the focus is
primarily on those rates.

For purposes of this discussion I drop

the notation regarding the initial state, and refer to the choice
probability srj as the probability that state J is chosen at the
next arrival of a new wagelvalue of leisure pair, regardless of
the initial state.

In all cases I begin with the situation

depicted in panel (a) of figure 2.
proportion a are not examined.

The effects of changes in

The comparative statics results

are derived by differentiating the equations for the borders with
respect to the variable of interest.
Effects of chanses in the mean waae
An increase in w, the mean wage, causes the acceptance sets
to change, as depicted in figure 3.

The full-timelpart-time,

part-time/nonparticipation, and full-time/unemployment borders
all make parallel shifts downward.

As a result, the full-time

acceptance set is clearly larger, while the part-time set remains
the same size.

From equation (5) we see that the choice

probability r, rises, while the choice probability
sr, does not change.

Consequently, we would expect high-wage

of change of the value of leisure is not state dependent.
12

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

workers to have higher rates of flow into full-time employment
and lower rates of flow out of full-time employment than low-wage
workers, ceteris paribus, while the rates of flow into and out of
part-time employment would not differ.

The net effect is that

high-wage workers will have lower part-time employment rates than
will low-wage workers.

Another way to view it is that an

increase in the mean wage causes full-time employment to become
relatively more attractive than part-time employment, such that
the part-time employment rate falls.
Effects of chanses in the value of leisure
An increase in the mean value of leisure, v, causes all of
the borders to shift to the left, as depicted in figure 4.

The

unemployment and full-time employment acceptance sets decrease in
size, while the part-time set remains the same size.

The

nonparticipation acceptance set, on the other hand, increases.
These changes imply that part-time employment becomes more
attractive relative to full-time employment, such that the parttime employment rate should rise.

Workers with high values of

leisure will have higher rates of flow out of full-time
employment and lower rates of flow into full-time employment than
will those with low values of leisure.
Effects of chanses in costs of search
Under my assumptions of no search while employed, an
increase in the costs of search leaves the part-time acceptance
set unchanged.

The unemployment set decreases, however, with

corresponding increases in the nonparticipation and full-time

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

employment sets.

The figure basically changes from panel (a) to

panel (b) in figure 2.

Since the full-time employment set

increases, the rate of flow into full-time work will rise, and
the rate of flow out of full-time work will fall, such that the
part-time employment rate will decrease.
Chanses in arrival rates
The effects on choice probabilities of changes in the
arrival rates basically come through changes in the slopes of the
borders between the four acceptance sets.

To summarize the

results with respect to A, and A,, we have the following: The
full-time employment choice probability increases with q, and
decreases with q, and q,,, while the part-time employment choice
probability increases with q, and decreases with q,.

The effects

on transition rates are less clear, however, since the transition
rate is the product of the choice probability with the arrival
rate itself (equation 2).

Summary
In section I11 I have presented a model of choice among the
four labor-market states of full- and part-time employment,
unemployment, and nonparticipation, which allows us to derive
relationships between transition rates and variables such as wage
levels, the value of leisure, and costs of search.

Presumably

gender differences and trends in transition rates over time can
be related to differences or trends in these variables.

In the

context of this model, the malelfemale part-time employment rate
differential can result, for example, from well-known gender

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

differentials in wages.

The model also predicts that females

will have higher part-time rates if they have higher values of
leisure (on average).

Sources of the recent decrease in the

part-time employment rate among females therefore also include
rising wages and declining values of leisure.
The model presented here is based on several simplifying
assumptions that might be questioned.

For example, it is assumed

that job search occurs only when workers are unemployed, in the
face of a growing literature stressing the importance of "on-thejob1*search in our economy.

More important, I have ignored the

particular role that on-the-job search while workers are employed
part-time can play in facilitating their moves into full-time
employment, especially among females (Blank [1989]).

Another

weakness of the model is that there is no distinction between the
wages or other characteristics of full- and part-time jobs,
including nonpecuniary rewards or fringe benefits.
factors could be incorporated into the model.

Both of these

I could allow some

lost utility from search while in the part-time state, adding a
term to equation 7b, or I could adjust the definitions of wages
in equations 7a-7c.

Neither of these variations would be

expected to alter the qualitative results presented above,
however.

But finally, I do not distinguish between the arrival

of full- vs. part-time job offers.

As a result, it is somewhat

difficult in the context of this model to imagine that females
might be more likely to be offered part-time employment than
males.

This is a difficult problem, and an inadequacy of the

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

model.

IV. Data

The data are from table 4 of the unpublished IIGross Change
Tables,I1 available from the U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of
Labor Statistics (BLS).10

The table indicates, in a given

month, the employment status of the civilian labor force by
employment status in the previous month, for the entire
population and by sex.

The estimates are calculated by BLS using

data from the Current Population Survey.

Unlike other gross

change tables, table 4 differentiates between full- and part-time
employment status.

11

The data used in this paper are from the

tables for January 1980 through July 1989, the most recent
available month.

The figures are not seasonally adjusted.

These

raw flow data are used to calculate monthly transition rates
between the four labor-market states, for the entire sample time
period, by sex.
The average monthly transition rates for this sample time
'O~or a description of the gross change data in general and
their problems, see Flaim and Hogue (1985); for a method to
adjust the data, see Abowd and Zellner (1985). I use the raw,
unadjusted data in this analysis.
11

The table gives the number employed full-time, part-time
for economic reasons, and
part-time, the number with
jobs but not at work (broken down by reason), the number
unemployed, and the number out of the labor force (by reason).
Unlike published figures in Em~lovmentand Earninas, in these
tables those with jobs but not at work have not been allocated to
the full- and part-time employment categories. In the empirical
analysis that follows, I have allocated them according to the
ratio used by the BLS for its published tables, which is based on
whether the individual llusuallyll
worked full- or part-time.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

period are presented in table 1.

The estimates suggest that

there is considerable movement between states over time.

For

example, on average about 42 percent of the males in part-time
employment in one month moved to another state in the next month.
The highest rates of flow are from part-time (P) to full-time (F)
employment for males and from unemployment (U) to
nonparticipation (N) for females.

Note that these rates are not

indicative of the raw magnitudes of the flows, since they are
conditioned on the number of people initially in the state.
There are some significant gender differentials in the
average transition probabilities in this time period.

The most

striking is that males are much more likely than females to make
transitions from P to F, and less likely to make the F to P
transition.

Males also are more likely to make the U to F

transition.

Indeed, the relative odds than an unemployed worker

will move to full-time as opposed to part-time employment are
about 1 112 times as high for males as they are for females.

All

of these differences cause the part-time employment rate to be
lower for males than for females.

Another gender difference is

that males are significantly less likely to make the transition
from U to N, which has been noted in previous work.
One of the insights provided by this analysis is that the
gender differential in part-time employment rates is a function
of the rates of flow out of states as well as the rates of flow
into states.

It is true that males are much more likely than

females to enter full-time employment from the other states.

But

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

in addition, males are less likely to leave full-time employment
once they get there.

Less than 6 percent of full-time employed

males made a transition out of that state in the average month,
compared t o about 10 percent of full-time employed females.
contributes to males having a higher full-time rate.

This

Similarly,

although females are more likely to enter part-time employment

''

from other states (except nonparticipation) ,

they are less

likely to leave it once they get there (31 percent exit rate for
females vs. 42 percent for males).

Note that females are less

likely than males to make transitions from part-time employment
into unemployment and nonparticipation, as well as into full-time
employment.

These differences in transition rate levels will be

examined again in the discussion in section VI.

The following

section examines trends and the cyclical variability of the
rates.

V. Empirical Analysis
Using the flow data for the January 1980 to July 1989
period, we have a monthly time series of 115 observations for
each of the 12 transition rates, for both males and females.

The

empirical analysis is simply to estimate the parameters of the
following equation for each transition, by sex:

12

Using the absolute rates
likelyttthan males to make the
consider that rate relative to
however, then females are more

in the table, females are I1less
N to P transition. If you
the rate of flow of N to F,
likely to end up part-time.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

log ( A i j)

=

a + BITIMEt+ B,log (URATt-,)

+ I? (Monthly

Dummies) ,

where TIME takes the value 1 in January 1980 and URAT is the
unemployment rate for males with spouse present, a commonly used
measure for business cycle effects.

A vector of monthly dummy

variables is used to capture seasonal variations in the
transition rates, with December being the excluded month.
The natural log of the transition and unemployment rates is
used such that the coefficient B2 represents the elasticity of
the transition rate with respect to the unemployment rate.

This

makes comparisons of cyclical responsiveness fairly
straightforward, both across rates and across gender groups.

The

trend coefficient (B1) can be interpreted as the average rate of
growth of the transition rate.

A lagged (rather than

contemporaneous) unemployment rate is used simply to mitigate the
effect of the simultaneous nature of the determination of the
flow and unemployment rates.

A specification also was estimated

using the contemporaneous rate, which yielded results
qualitatively the same as those presented below.
Five of the transition rate series exhibited evidence of
first-order serial correlation for at least one gender group.
For those transitions, the parameters were estimated assuming a
first-order autoregressive process, using the Prais-Winsten
procedure.

The parameters were estimated using ordinary least

squares (OLS) for the remaining seven transition rates.

The

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

estimated coefficients and their standard errors for the trend
and cyclical variables are presented in table 2 (the coefficients
for the seasonal dummies are available upon request).

The

Durbin-Watson statistics are from the initial OLS regressions.
Analysis of Trends
Referring first to the trend estimates, for males there are
negative and significant trends in the probabilities of
transitions from F to U, P to N, U to F, N to F, N to P, and N to
U.

There is a significant positive trend in the probability of

transition from U to P.

Some of these trends have contributed to

the slight overall increase in the rate of part-time employment
exhibited by males in the 1980-90 period (for example, the
increase in A,

and decreases in A,

and A,,),

while others have

worked against it and explain the decreasing rate since 1983 (for
example, the decreases in A,,

and A,,)

.

The transition rates for females have exhibited significant
negative trends for the F to U, F to N, P to U,and P to N
transitions.

All of these signify a greater degree of attachment

t o work among females; that is, females are less likely to leave
employment, for both full- and part-time.

The magnitudes of the

coefficients indicate that the trends have been strongest in the
flows from full-time employment, which contributes to the decline
in the part-time employment rate.

Also contributing to this

decline are the positive trends in the probabilities of
transitions from P to F and N to F.

But at the same time, the

rates of flow from U to P and N to P also increased (reflecting

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

the increased labor-force participation among females), which
would tend to increase the part-time employment rate.
Note that there is no evidence of a significant positive
trend in the U to F transition rate (indeed, the trend
coefficient is of the opposite sign).

The growth of female full-

time employment therefore is not the result of an increase in the
proportion of unemployed females finding full-time employment.
Rather, the growth has been the result of the joint product of
increases in the proportion of females moving from part-time to
full-time employment and decreases in the proportion leaving
full-time employment when they get there.
Finally, as an aside, there are significant gender
differences in transition rate trends that should be highlighted.
First, there is a significant (.01 level) difference in the trend
coefficient for the F to N transition, with females exhibiting a
greater decline.

Similarly, the trend coefficient is

significantly larger (in absolute value) for females for the
transition from P to N.

The coefficients for all of the

transitions from nonparticipation are significantly different,
even exhibiting different signs for N to P and N to F.
Cyclical Variability
Although the focus of the paper has not been on the cyclical
variability of the part-time employment rate for either gender
group, one of the most striking features of table 2 is the strong
cyclical responsiveness of nearly all of the transition rates.
For both males and females, there are strong decreases in the

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

rates of flow out of unemployment as unemployment rates rise (as
would be expected), and increases in the rate of flow into
unemployment from all of the other states.

For both sexes, there

is a difference between the responsiveness of the flows into and
out of full- and part-time employment.

Flows from U to F are

more cyclically sensitive than those from U to P I while flows
from P to U are more cyclically sensitive than those from F to U.
Consistent with evidence regarding hours adjustments over
the business cycle, the rate of flow from F to P increases in an
economic downturn.

The rate of flow from P to F decreases as the

unemployment rate rises, but only for females.

The findings

regarding the cyclical responsiveness of the N to U and U to N
transitions are consistent with those from earlier time periods
(Williams [1985], Deboer and Seeborg [1989]).
There are significant gender differences in the cyclical
responsiveness of several of the transition rates.

The effect of

an increase in the unemployment rate is significantly greater for
males for the F to P I P to U, P to N, U to N, and N to F
transitions.

These findings are consistent with earlier work,

which did not differentiate between fulband part-time employment
(Williams [1985], DeBoer and Seeborg [1989]).

They have

implications for that work, however, since the gender differences
in exit rates from employment appear to be from part-time rather
than full-time employment, at least for the time period studied
here.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

VI.

Discussion of the Results
As is noted above, this paper is primarily descriptive in

nature, with the simple identification of trends and gender
differences in transition probabilities as its goal.

The results

suggest that there are several key transition rates contributing
to the gender differential in the level of the part-time
employment rate and to trends in that rate over the 1980-90
period.

First, the female part-time employment rate is higher

than the male rate because females have higher probabilities of
transitions from F to P and N, and lower probabilities of
transitions from P to F or U, and a lower probability of
transition from U to F.

But at the same time, the female part-

time rate has been falling because the F to U and F to N rates
are falling while the P to F and N to F rates have been rising.
In the context of the model presented in section 111, the
sources of these differences and trends are likely the following:
first, the gender differentials in the F to P, P to F, and U to F
transition rates could result from higher wages among males and
higher values of leisure among females.

They could also result

from higher rates of arrival of full-time (vs. part-time) job
offers for males, a factor not explicit in the model.

One source

of a higher value of leisure among females is the unequal
distribution of responsibilities at home, including housekeeping,
cooking, and child care.
It is possible that changes in wages are one source of the
trends in transition rates as well, since the wages of females

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

have been rising relative to males.

According to the model, this

trend would increase (relative to males) the female rates of flow
into, and decrease the rates of flow out of, full-time
employment.

But this hypothesis is somewhat weakened by the fact

that the female/male earnings ratio was also rising (though at
variable rates) during a long period during which the female
part-time rate was increasing.

A similar statement could be made

with regard to the hypothesis that the trends we observe are the
result of a decline in the value of leisure among females.
Nevertheless, both the rising wage and falling value of leisure
hypotheses are consistent with the finding that the female rates
of flow out of full-time employment have been falling.
Another hypothesis regarding the decline of part-time
employment is that the rate of offer of full-time jobs has been
rising.

This is not especially convincing, however, since we

find no evidence that the U to F transition rate has been rising,
although it is consistent with the results for the N to F and P
to F transitions.

The role for the hypothesis is further

diminished, however, to the extent that a major cause of the
decrease in the part-time employment rate is the tendency for
females to be more likely to stay in full-time jobs rather than
more likely to get them.

VII.

Summary and Concluding Remarks
This paper has examined recent changes in the rate of part-

time employment in the United States from a new perspective,

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

focusing on changes in the probabilities of making transitions
between full-time employment, part-time employment, unemployment,
and nonparticipation.

Using monthly gross change data for the

1980-89 time period, I find that several transition rates have
exhibited trends that contribute to the declining propensity to
work part-time, especially among females.

The results point to

one important source of this change: a decreased propensity to
leave full-time employment, as well as an increased propensity to
enter it.

A model of labor-market dynamics presented here suggests
that changes in wages, in the value of leisure, and in the rate
of offer of full-time jobs all could have contributed to the
trends in transition rates that are the source of the decline of
part-time employment among females.

Testing these hypotheses is

a topic for further research, which could proceed in two main
directions.

First, more variables could be added to the time-

series regressions presented here.

A more fruitful direction,

however, would be to analyze the transition behavior for a sample
of individuals from a longitudinal data set, such as the National
Longitudinal Survey or Panel Study of Income Dynamics.

In

particular, the analysis should estimate the influence of
variables such as wages, number of children, and the availability
of child care on individual transition probabilities, following
the now common techniques proposed by Heckman, Singer, and

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

others.13

Given the lengths of the panels, it would also be

possible to examine changes in the influence of the variables
over time

.

Regardless of the methodology, major focuses of further
research should be the increased duration of full-time employment
among females on the one hand, and the increased rate of flow
from part-time to full-time employment on the other.

Regarding

perhaps both of these phenomena is an additional hypothesis, that
females are simply more "career orientedvvthan in the past, which
has led them t o choose jobs that are more stable and that provide
more opportunity for career advancement.

Cause and effect are as

always difficult t o disentangle, and perhaps this is just
reflective of the higher wagellower value of leisure hypotheses.
Nonetheless, it is a factor that also should be examined in
detail.

13slank (1989) presents estimates of the parameters of
hazard functions for a sample of females from the PSID. Although
she includes several variables that I would want to include,
there is no control for wages.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

REFERENCES
Abowd, John M., and Arnold Zellner. 1985. @@EstimatingGross
Labor Force Flows,@tJournal of Business and Economic
Statistics 3:254-83.
Belous, Richard S. 1989. The contingent Economv: The Growth of
the Temporarv, Part-time and Subcontracted Workforce,
Washington, D.C.: National Planning Association.
Blanchard, Olivier J., and Peter Diamond. 1990. "The Cyclical
Behavior of the Gross Flows of U.S. Workers,@@Brookinqs
Papers on Economic Activitv (2):85-143.
Blank, Rebecca M. 1989. @@TheRole of Part-Time Work in Women's
Labor Market Choices over Timelt@American Economic Review 79
(2): 295-99.
Burdett, Kenneth, Nicholas M. Kiefer, Dale T. Mortensen, and
George R. Neumann. 1981. "A Markov Model of Employment,
Unemployment, and Labor Force Participation,@@Northwestern
University Discussion Paper No. 483, May.
DeBoer, Larry, and Michael C. Seeborg. 1989. ItTheUnemployment
Rates of Men and Women: A Transition Probability Analysis,"
Industrial and Labor Relations Review 42 (3):404-414.
Ehrenberg, Ronald D. 1980. @@TheDemographic Structure of
Unemployment Rates and Labor Market Transition
Probabilities," in Ronald G. Ehrenberg, ed., Research in
Labor Economics, vol. 4. Greenwich, Conn:JAI Press.
Flaim, Paul O., and Carma R. Hogue. 1985. @@MeasuringLabor
Monthlv
Force Flows: A Conference Examines the Problemstt@
Labor Review 108 (7):7-17.
Hallaire, Jean. 1968. Part-time Em~lovment: Its Extent and Its
Problems, Paris: OECD.
Ichniowski, Bernard E., and Anne E. Preston. 1986. @@NewTrends
~~
of the 38th Annual
in Part-time E m p l ~ y m e n t ,Proceedinss
Meetinq, Industrial Relations Research Association, 60-67.
Marston, Stephen T. 1976. wEmployment Instability and High
Unemployment Rates,@@Brookinqs PaDers on Economic Activitv
no. 1, 169-203.
Mortensen, Dale T., and George R. Neumann. 1984. IvChoice or
Chance? A Structural Interpretation of Individual Labor
Market Histories," in N.W. Nielson and G. R. Neumann,
editors, Labor Market Dvnamics and Unem~lovment,Prague:
Springer-Verlag.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Nardone, Thomas J. 1986. "Part-Time Workers: Who Are They?"
Monthly Labor Review (February):13-19.
9to5, National Association of Working Women.
the Marsins, Cleveland, Ohio.

1986.

Workins at

Nollen, Stanley D., Brenda Broz Eddy, and Virginia Hider Martin.
1978. Permanent Part-time Em~lovment,New York: Praeger.
Ruhm, Christopher J. 1990. "Bridge Jobs and Partial
Retirement," Journal of Labor Economics 8 (4):482-501.
Smith, Ralph, and Jean Vanski. 1978. "The Volatility of the
Teenage Labor Market: Labor Force Entry, Exit, and
Unemployment FlowsfWtin U.S. Department of Labor, Conference
Report on Youth Unemplovment: Its Measurement and Meaninq,
Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office.
Thurman, Joseph E., and Gabriele Trah. 1990. "Part-time Work in
International Perspective," International Labour Review 129
(1)
Tilly, Chris. 1991. "Reasons for the Continuing Growth of Parttime Employment," Monthlv Labor Review (March): 10-18.
U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 1988.
Labor Force Statistics Derived from the Current Population
Survey, 1948-87, Bulletin 2307, Washington, D.C.: Government
Printing Office.

.

Em~lovmentand Earninss, monthly, Washington, D.C.:
Government Printing Office.
Williams, Donald R. 1985. "Employment in Recession and
Recovery: A Demographic Flow Analysis," Monthlv Labor Review
108 (3) (March):35-42.

.

1987. Labor Force Particbation of Black and White
Youth, Ann Arbor, Mich.: UMI Research Press.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 1: Means and Standard Deviations of Monthly Transition Rates, by Sex
Percent Making Transit,ion
Transition
F to P

Males
Mean
St Dev
-3.58 0.47

Females
-Mean S t Dev
7.47 1.06

F to U
F to N
P to F
P to U
P to N
U to F
U to P
U to N
N to F
N to P

N to U

Note: F=full-time employed, P=part-time employed, U=unemployed, N=not in
labor force.
Source: Author's calculations from BLS gross change data, Jan. 1980-July 1989.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 2: Regression Results (Equation 8)
Coef'ficients
(Standard Errors)
MALES
Transition

Interce~t TIME

LodURAT)

R-Square
.5500

D.W.
2.204

'Estimates based on assumption of first-order autoregressive process. The DurbinWatson (D.W.) statistics are from the original OLS regressions.
Note: Coefficients significantly different from zero at (a) .lo, (b) .05, or (c) .O1 level.
Source: Author's calculations.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Table 2: Regression Results (Equation 8), continued
Coefficients
(Standard Errors)
FEMALES
Transition

Intercept

TIME

Log(URAT)

R-Square

D.W.

F to P

'Estimates based on assumption of first-order autoregressive process. The DurbinWatson (D.W.) statistics are from the original OLS regressions.
Note: Coefficients significantly different from zero at (a) .lo, (b) .05, or (c) .O1 level.
Source: Author's calculations.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Figure 1: Part-Time Employment Rate, 1972-1 990
Percent part-time

-----.
Females
/--

/--e - 4

-.-Ad

'.

------

25

Source: Author's calculations from data in U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau
of Labor Statistics, Employment and Earnings, various issues.

Tota.1

-----Males

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Figure 2: Hypothetical Acceptance Sets

a+

Source: Author.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Figure 3: Effect of an Increase in the Average Wage

Source: Author

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

Figure 4: Effect of an Increase in tlie Value of Leisure

Source: Author.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

APPENDIX A
DERIVATION OF THE PART-TIME EMPLOYMENT RATE
In the steady state, the flow into a state is equal to the flow
from a state. For part-time, this condition implies

and for full-time,

Multiply equation A1 by AxF and equation A2 by Ax,,
A2 from A1 to get

and subtract

Solving this equation for P, substituting for P in PR = P/(P+F),
and rearranging terms yields equation (1) in the text.

www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/index.cfm

APPENDIX B
EQUATIONS FOR THE ACCEPTANCE SET BORDERS