View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

332.11 ·
Federal
1982


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Research Library


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

U.S. MONETARY
POLICY AND
FINANCIAL
MARKETS

BY PAUL MEEK
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK
33 LIBERTY STREET
NEW YORK, NY10045


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

U.S. MONETARY POLICY AND FINANCIAL MARKETS
LIBRARY OF CONGRESS CATALOG CARD NUMBER 82-71781
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK
Designed by Howard Mont Associates Inc.

Foreword
Over 25 years ago, Federal Reserve Operations in the Money
and Government Securities Markets by Robert Roosa provided a
generation of students with a graphic picture of open market
operations, and the pulsating life of the money market.
In this volume, Paul Meek, Monetary Adviser, has brought the
story up to date and expanded its scope to include Federal Reserve policy procedures and policy's outward thrust to the economy. In his description and analysis, he has captured something
of the fascination that monetary policy and financial markets
have for policymakers and market participants.
All of us engaged in the policy process find ourselves challenged today more than ever by the rapidity with which changes
in financial markets and economic behavior affect the ways in
which policy exerts its influence. This book provides a useful
introduction to the mysteries of central banking and the vagaries
of human behavior that keep central bankers humble.
Anthony M. Solomon
President
New York City
October 1982


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Acknowledgements
To a young economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of New
York, Bob Roosa's red-covered book was a revelation. In matchless prose he described how the open market desk provided
flexibly the money needed by the economy while simultaneously
affecting its performance. Roosa's trenchant analysis of the defensive and dynamic aspects of operations illuminated the nature of the basic tasks all central banks must perform. A quarter
century later, monetary policy issues and the financial markets
remain as vital and engrossing as when Roosa wrote. The present book carries on a New York Bank tradition of describing
monetary policy from the vantage point of the trading desk
where domestic open market operations are carried out.
The book owes a great deal to the active encouragement of
many colleagues of long standing in the Federal Reserve System.
Alan R. Holmes, formerly Manager of the System open market
account, initiated the enterprise. Peter D. Sternlight, the present
manager for domestic operations, saw it through, patiently offering wise counsel .and felicitous phrases through several drafts.
Paul A. Volcker was very supportive when the project began
during his tenure at the New York Bank. Anthony M. Solomon and
Thomas M. 1imlen kept it rolling. The book, in fact, was well on
its way to completion in October 1979, when changes in open
market procedures brought a halt while both desk officers and
the financial markets gained experience with the new approach.
In the final phase Stephen H. Axilrod, staff director for monetary
and financial policy at the Board of Governors, graciously took
time to read and comment on the manuscript.
Many of my Federal Reserve associates gave me the benefit of
their comments on one or more chapters; the remaining errors
are mine, not theirs. At the New York Bank, I am particularly
indebted to my open market colleagues who have helped me
keep abreast of rapidly changing financial markets and institutions - Bill Cavanaugh, Silvanus Chambers, Mary Clarkin, Diane
Heidt, Ralph Helfrich, Janet Knudsen, Fred Levin, Joan Lovett,
Chris McCurdy, Ann-Marie Meulendyke, Edward Ozog, and Irwin
Sandberg. Others from the bank who gave valuable help include:
Akbar Akhtar, Marcelle Arak, Richard Davis, Kenneth Garbade
(now at N.YU.), Ronald Gray, Richard Hoenig, Roger Kubarych,
Scott Pardee (now at the Discount Corporation of New York),
Lawrence Radecki, Arthur Samansky, Neal Soss, Steven R. Weisbrod, Betsy White and H. David Willey. At the Board of Governors,

Peter Keir, Brian F. Madigan, Norman Mains and James
Symonowski tendered many useful comments.
Any author writing on financial markets depends greatly on
the active players who take the risks of making markets or giving
their own judgments on monetary policy and the economy. My
obligations to many friends in the banks and markets for their
help stretch over many years of stimulating discussions. For the
book itself, I owe a special debt to Al Wojnilower of The First
Boston Corporation for his thoughtful suggestions after a careful
reading of the entire manuscript. On commercial bank asset/
liability management my mentors include: Robert W Stone (Irving Trust Company), Donald Riefler and Rene Branch (Morgan
Guaranty), Wolfgang Schoelkopf (Chase Manhattan), David Barry
(Manufacturers Hanover) and Richard Falk (Citibank). On the
money market, Marcia Stigum's fine book The Money Market was
a great help. I benefited as well from suggestions made by Darwin Beck (First Boston), Donald E. Maude and Maria Ramirez
(Merrill Lynch), William Melton (Irving Trust), Robert Ried (Ried
& Thunberg), George van Cleave ( Goldman, Sachs), and Jerry
Wigdortz (Salomon Brothers).
Daniel Rosen of Public Information handled admirably the
manifold chores involved in bringing the book to publication.
Richard Alford, Tim Lord, and Robert van Wicklen helped in the
final production, as did Phil Krackow and his associates in the
visual aids area of the Bank's research department.
Perhaps the most important credits remain for last. Teresa
Roland and Olga Pasqua labored with unfailingly good spirits
through seemingly endless drafts, struggling with my handwriting, adding punctuation, and keeping drafts on their appointed
rounds. My wife Rachael Lee Meek and my daughter Mary Melati
bore with good grace the burden of writing weekends and my
absentmindedness on other important matters. Shorouk Abbas,
our visiting Egyptian daughter, shared a full measure of that
burden during these last few months.
New York, New York
October 1982


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

U.S. Monetary Policy
and Financial Markets

I

Monetary Policy and
The U.S. Economy
US. Monetary Policy-A Short History
The Current Policy Process
The Commercial Banks
The Money and Capital Markets
The Economic Impact

2

Developing Monetary
Policy Strategy
The Goals of Policy
The Evolution of Policy Strategy
TheFOMC
The Policy Process
1. Economic Models and Monetary Policy
2. The February Meeting
a. Preparation
b. Staff Presentation
c. Adopting an FOMC Strategy

3


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Commercial Banks Managers of Risk
The Business of Banking
Banking Risk
Managing Risk
1. The Profit Plan
2. ALCO- Organization and Function
3. Shaping a Profitable Strategy
Implementing Bank Strategy- the Money Desk

page2

6
8
JO
11
14

page20
20
21
24
26
27
31
32
34

page38
38
40
41
43
45
47
SJ

4

The Money Market
The Function of the Money Market
Banks and The Money Market
1. The Federal Funds Market
2. The CD Market
3. Bankers ' Acceptances
4. The Eurodollar Market
The Non bank Money Market
1. The Treasury Market
a. The Stock in Trade : Government Securities
b. The Role of Dealers
2. The Market for Federally Sponsored
Agency Securities
3. Commercial Paper
4. Municipal Notes

5


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page56
58
61
63
66
69
72
74
74
74
76
81
83
86

The FOMC Meeting - Setting
Operational Strategy

page88

Reports of the Managers
1. The Report on International Developments
2. The Report on Domestic Operations
The Staff Input
1. Economic Outlook
2. Policy Alternatives
FOMC Decision Making
1. Sizing Up the Economic Situation
2. Discussing the Directive
3. The Vote

88
88
90
91
91
92
93
94
95
97

6

The Trading Desk and Its Tasks

page JOO
JOO

Dynamic Operations
Open Market Operations and the Discount Window
Defensive Operations
Adjunct Desk Responsibilities

7

The Conduct of Open Market
Operations

104
105
109

page 114

The Strategy of Reserve Management
1. Outright Operations
2. RPs and MSPs
The Vtew from the Desk
1. Daily Dealer Meetings
2. The Treasury Call
3. Formulating the Day's Program
4. The Trading Room Scene
5. The Conference Call
6. Executing the Daily Program
Communications Within the System

8


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

The Transmission of Monetary Policy:
The Financial Markets

115
116
120
124
125
127
131
134
135
138
141

page 144

A Reserve Strategy-New Challenge to Financial Markets
Monitoring the Fed and the Economy
1. Projecting Reserves, The Money Supply and Desk Activity
2. Economic Forecasting and Related Matters
Decision Making in The Money Market
1. The Banks
2. Dealers and Underwriters in Securities

144
146
147
150
152
152
154

9

The Transmission of Monetary
Policy: The Credit Markets
and The Economy
Monetary Policy and Yield Curves
Policy's Effect on the Economic Sectors
1. The Household Sector
2. The Business Sector
3. State and Local Governments
4. The U.S. Government
The International Dimension
1. US. Economic Expansion
2. U.S. Recession

JO


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Monetary Policy The World Scene

page160
160
163
165
167
169
170
171
173
175

page 178


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

1

Monetary Policy and
the U.S. Economy
Monetary policy is concerned with money and credit, and
their interaction with jobs, production and prices. As the nation's
central bank, the Federal Reserve System has a dual responsibility, which Robert Roosa defined years ago as having defensive
and dynamic features. 1 First, there is the responsibility to defend
the monetary system against both routine and unpredictable
strains, which develop as goods are produced and consumed.
The central bank exercises this defensive function by insuring
that money and credit are readily available to meet the highly
variable day-to-day and week-to-week needs of a market economy. The central bank's dynamic responsibility is to see that
money and credit grow over longer periods in step with the
nation's expanding productive potential. The art of central banking consists of allowing money and credit to flex with society's
demands in the short run without compromising the central
bank's ability to influence them appropriately over a longer
horizon.
Any central bank must operate so that money is available on
short notice, that producers and consumers do not lack the cash
required for the millions of transactions that bind them together.
For the productive machinery to run smoothly in all seasons,
people must be able to acquire money for making payments
without difficulty. To do so, they have to be able to sell liquid
assets for cash or to borrow money with a minimum of uncertainty. The regional Federal Reserve Banks and depository institutions, working together, provide coin, currency and checkable deposits routinely and efficiently wherever they are needed.
Banks and the money market enable people to borrow on short
notice or turn liquid assets into cash.
The challenge to the Federal Reserve lies in combining such
short-run flexibility with its dynamic responsibility for influencing money and credit growth to foster a healthy economy. There
is little reason to be concerned if money and bank credit rise
rapidly for a few weeks or slow down for a month or two. But
central bankers and economists discovered long ago that rapid
monetary and credit growth, if maintained long enough, leads to
inflation while a sustained decline in such growth produces economic recession and deflation. Monetary policymakers meet reg1Robert V. Roosa, Federal Reserve Operations in the Money and Government Securities
Markets, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 1956, pp. 2-3.

page2


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

ularly to decide whether observed short-run developments in
money and credit - and in the economy itself - threaten to
undermine balanced economic growth, reasonable price performance, and equilibrium in international transactions. For them,
money and credit growth is an intermediate objective, one that
lies between the daily business of providing liquidity and their
ultimate concern with the economy's performance.
Federal Reserve policymakers have three primary instruments
for influencing money; credit growth, and the economy. Through
each, they can affect the cost and availability of reserves to
commercial banks and other institutions offering checkable deposits.2 Central bank officials can modify the legal reserve requirements that deposit-taking institutions must meet. Secondly;
they can change the discount rate the twelve regional Federal
Reserve Banks charge banks and other depository institutions
for short-term adjustment credit; they can also change the terms
on extended credit or emergency borrowing. Lastly, policymakers direct open market transactions in U.S. Government and
other securities to govern the pace at which reserves are supplied to the financial system. These open market operations,
carried out by the domestic trading desk of the Federal Reserve
of New York, enable money and credit to respond to the public's
daily; weekly; and monthly demands while still permitting control
of the flow available to the economy over longer periods.
The Federal Reserve's strategy for carrying out its defensive
and dynamic responsibilities centers in the instruction the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) gives to the domestic trading
desk at the New York Reserve Bank.3 For many years defensive
open market operations consisted of supplying sufficient nonbor2
The Consumer Checking Account Equity Act of 1980 permitted nonbank institutions to
offer checking account services in the form of negotiable orders of withdrawal (NOW)
accounts on a nationwide basis, beginning January 1, 1981. The Monetary Control Act of
1980 imposed a phased introduction of reserve requirements on checkable deposits at credit
unions, savings banks, savings and loan associations, and commercial banks, which were
not members of the Federal Reserve System. Commercial banks currently account for the
bulk of reserves, which the Act requires to be maintained, either in the form of vault cash
or deposits at Federal Reserve Banks. Since required reserves provide monetary policy's
fulcrum , this booklet focuses on commercial banks as the primary channel for the
transmission of policy.
3
The Federal Open Market Committee consists of the seven members of the Board of
Governors and five of the 12 presidents of the Federal Reserve Banks.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page3

rowed reserves4 to maintain the Federal funds rate reasonably
steady from week to week, enabling banks to meet changing
demands for money at reasonably steady interest rates; dynamic
operations involved changing the Federal funds rate objective
in order to slow down, or speed up, money and credit growth.5
In late 1979 the Federal Reserve changed its approach.
Dynamic operations then became addressed to supplying nonborrowed reserves at a rate thought consistent with achieving
the growth of money desired over the calendar year. In the new
look, defensive operations became those intended to compensate for seasonal and irregular short-run changes in bank reserves. Such defensive operations allow for seasonal changes in
money demand. They also offset changes in reserve availability
that result from the check collection process and other forces
outside central bank control.
Under the new procedures, dynamic operations automatically
lead to changes in interest rates whenever the economy's demand for money departs significantly from Federal Reserve objectives. A surge in money demand increases the demand for
reserves, results in increased borrowing at the Federal Reserve
discount window, and produces a higher Federal funds rate. A
slackening of money demand has the opposite effect.
The FOMC's procedures must cope with the fact that money
demand is highly variable on a week-to-week basis - even after
seasonal adjustment (see Chart 1, page 5). Since October 1979
the desk has aimed at achieving an average level of nonborrowed
reserves between FOMC meetings. This procedure means that
the pressure on banks to borrow does not change because of
weekly variations in money demand so long as money growth on
average is about as desired over the period.
The Federal Reserve can also add to the pressure being
exerted on the behavior of banks and their customers by changing the trading desk's objective for nonborrowed reserves. Or it
can modify the Federal Reserve discount rate or reserve requirements. As banks and other institutions react to changes in
reserve supplies or the terms on discount window loans, their
response affects financial markets and interest rates almost inWonborrowed reserves of depository institutions are their total reserves (vault cash and
balances at Reserve Banks) less adjustment borrowings from the Reserve Banks. By its
control over nonborrowed reserves the trading desk influences strongly the amount of
borrowing such institutions need to do to cover their weekly reserve requirements.
5
The Federal Funds rate is the interest rate on overnight inter-bank loans.

page4


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Chart 1 Changes in Ml (Seasonally
Adjusted Annual Rates)

From previous week From 3 months earlier From 12 months earlier -

75
50
25

I:
. ~~

0

-··-- r

-

r'

J

1111\111~

ij

i?i

..r

I

L........-~

--

MAY

JUN

JUL

--

F'"' ........r-

11111__

-25
-50
- 75

JAN

FEB MAR APR


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

AUG

SEP

OCT

NOV

DEC

pages

stantaneously. Financial markets carry this impetus forward not
only to the demand for money and credit but also to production,
employment and prices.

U.S. Monetary Policy
-A Short History

The history of the Federal Reserve System is one of evolving
interest in meshing its defensive responsibilities with the more
dynamic concerns of monetary policy. When the U.S. Congress
established the Federal Reserve in 1914, it did so because the
decentralized banking system of the time seemed unable to provide flexibly for the cash and credit requirements of a growing
economy. The Federal Reserve Act set up a Board of Governors in
Washington and Federal Reserve Banks in 12 regions of the country. The need for an elastic money supply was to be met by
allowing the Reserve Banks to buy securities or to discount loans
made by the commercial banks. Credit to the banks would rise
and fall with business activity, it was thought, providing a selfadjusting mechanism, one which would prevent shortages of
money, or runs on banks, from leading to financial panic and a
breakdown in the economy.
This hands-off approach gave way almost immediately under
the challenge of financing U.S. participation in World War I and
dealing with the postwar inflation. 6 Within its first decade the
Federal Reserve Board acknowledged its responsibility for resisting extremes of either inflation or recession. During the 1920s the
Federal Reserve coped successfully with seasonal changes in
money and credit, which had previously imposed strains on the
financial system. Defensive open market operations in bankers'
acceptances and Government securities supplemented the role
of the discount window in making reserves readily available to
the banks. Interest rates no longer experienced seasonal fluctuations to the degree that had prevailed before 1914. However, the
Federal Reserve was less successful in dealing with cyclical
forces; it failed to restrain the speculative credit boom of 1929,
which culminated in the stock market crash. Federal Reserve
actions to raise interest rates in order to stem a gold outflow in
the fall of 1931 contributed to a catastrophic collapse in the
economy that led to widespread bank failures and raised unemployment from 3 percent of the civilian labor force in 1929 to 25
percent in 1933.
6
Milton Friedman and Anna Jacobson Schwartz, AMonetary History of the United States,
1867-1960, Princeton, 1963, Chapters V and VI.

page6


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

In the 1930s the Federal Government undertook a more active
role in economic affairs. Congress reshaped the financial system
to improve its operation and restore public confidence. It regulated the securities industry, introduced deposit insurance and
margin requirements on stocks, separated investment banking
from commercial banking, and set up Federal housing agencies. It
also established in law the Federal Open Market Committee,
which had developed informally in the 1920s to oversee Federal
Reserve open market operations. Monetary policy contributed
little to spurring economic activity; economic policy relied on
deficit spending by the Federal government to stimulate the
economy. Banks held reserves far in excess of their legal requirements so that open market operations and the discount
window fell into disuse in the 1930s. Yet when World War II began,
open market operations played a key role in underwriting the
defense buildup. Trading desk purchases of Treasury issues at
pegged interest rates expanded bank reserves and financed a
wartime surge in production.
After the war, the nation's resolve to avoid another depression
was embodied in the Employment Act of 1946. The Federal Government, including the Federal Reserve System, actively sought to
achieve reasonably full employment of resources. The economy
shifted resources quickly to civilian production, and by the late
1940's inflationary pressures began to appear. In restraining
money and credit growth, the Federal Reserve was handicapped
by its commitment to support Government securities prices, stabilizing interest rates. In 1951, when the Korean War was adding to
total demand, the Treasury and Federal Reserve reached an accord, which ended price stabilization in the Government securities
market. Federal Reserve open market operations soon became
the most actively used policy instrument for affecting bank reserves and the economy. The discount window became a privileged source of short-term credit to assist individual bank adjustment and to buffer the banking system from unforeseen stresses.
In the 1950's and much of the 1960's, national economic
policies were generally successful in fostering economic growth
with reasonable price stability (see Chart 2, page 8). But in the
1970's the persistence of historically high rates of price inflation
led Congress to give price stability clearer recognition as an
economic goal. Today, the Full Employment and Balanced Growth
Act of 1978, the Humphrey-Hawkins Act, provides the legislative
framework for monetary policy.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 7

Chart 2 Real GNP Growth and
Inflation (since 1949)

%125

JOO
-

Cumulative Real Growth
Annual Inflation

75
50
25

0

%10
8
6
4
2

0

-2
1950

The Cu"ent Policy Process

page8


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

52

54

56

58

60

62

64

66

68

70

72

74

76

78

80

Responsible to the Congress, the Federal Reserve System
works to help achieve society's economic goals: full employment
of a growing work force, rising incomes, and stable prices in a
world of interdependent national economies. But aspirations are
not self-fulfilling. Under the law, monetary policymakers are required to develop annual objectives for monetary and credit
growth with these goals in mind, and to report periodically to the
Congress. In practice, policymaking moved during the 1970's
from emphasizing control of credit extended by banks to focusing on how fast the monetary liabilities of the financial system
grow. The Monetary Control Act of 1980 underscored this change
in analytical focus by imposing reserve requirements on the
checkable liabilities of all depository institutions.
In establishing annual monetary objectives and pursuing
them, policymakers analyze a dynamic economic process whose
direction and momentum are often unclear. The president's economic plans and budget proposals are important, but how consumers and businessmen will spend and save in the quarters
ahead is more often the key to the economy's performance. The
Federal Reserve also has to estimate how use of its own instruments will affect money, credit, and interest rates, and thereby

influence the production of real goods and services.
The policy process centers in the Federal Open Market Committee, which typically meets eight times a year in Washington.
The chairman of the Board of Governors presides over these
meetings when he, his six fellow governors, and the 12 presidents
of the regional Reserve Banks consider the economic outlook
and plan monetary policy. The Committee proper - the voting
members - includes the seven governors of the Board, the president of the New York Reserve Bank, and four other Reserve Bank
presidents, who serve in annual rotation.
Under the Humphrey-Hawkins Act, the chairman reports to the
banking committees of the Congress every February on the objectives the FOMC has set for the growth of various monetary
and credit measures during the current calendar year. In July, he
reports any revisions in that year's objectives, along with preliminary goals for the subsequent year. At every meeting the
Committee adopts instructions to the domestic trading desk at
the New York Fed, prescribing desired growth for selected measures of money over several months. It indicates an expected
initial level of borrowing at the discount window. The Board staff
can then determine the nonborrowed reserve level consistent
with the FOMC's money growth objectives; this level constitutes
the New York trading desk's objective between committee meetings. The committee also instructs the foreign exchange trading
desk at the New York Reserve Bank concerning foreign exchange
operations, an area in which the U.S. Treasury has primary policy
responsibility.
The Committee's supply-oriented reserve strategy means that
stronger-than-desired growth in money will force banks as a
group to borrow more at their district Reserve Banks. Such credit
is available only temporarily while the banks adjust, either by
reducing assets or borrowing elsewhere. As they adjust, the
banks bid up the Federal funds rate and the rates they pay to
attract deposits, quickly affecting the loan terms and portfolio
choices of financial institutions. Holders of money and other financial assets redistribute their assets away from money to
higher yielding assets, tending to return money growth to the
desired dimensions. These financial changes also work to slow
economic growth. Conversely, a persistent shortfall in money
growth leads to reduced bank demand for reserves, a decline in
borrowing at the discount window, and a fall in interest rates. The

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Chart 3 Open Market Operations

and Bank Reserves

Monetary
Targets

Required

Reserves

page9

resultant portfolio adjustments work to spur monetary growth,
increase credit availability and quicken economic activity
(see Chart 3, page 9).

The Commercial Banks

page JO


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Monetary growth reflects continuing interaction between the
central bank, financial institutions, the money market and bank
depositors. The Federal Reserve can govern the pace at which
the trading desk supplies reserves to depository institutions, but
bank customers determine, by and large, how much money they
want to hold, and in what form. Consumers, businessmen, and
governmental bodies adjust their holdings of money with income, payment patterns, the services banks offer, and the rate
of interest available on other obligations. People naturally prefer interest-earning assets like time deposits or money market funds , so long as they can be converted on short notice
into currency and checkable deposits for paying bills, taxes,
or employees.
Banks and other institutions, which make a variety of types of
deposits available to their customers, have little influence on
how their customers use their services in the short run. The
changing demands of their customers for money balances, combined with the different reserve ratios that apply to individual
deposit categories, largely determine the required reserves depository institutions must maintain at the Federal Reserve
Banks, week to week, even month to month. Over the long run, of
course, banks can influence the growth of different types of deposits by changing the terms they offer. When banks offer higher
interest rates on money market certificates or other deposits,
people economize still further on demand deposits, and the
longer such incentives exist, the greater the effect on public
demand for currency and demand deposits.
Banks play a key role in affecting financial markets and the
economy. As the most flexible of financial borrowers and lenders,
banks merchandise credit aggressively to borrowers that range
from retail customers to home buyers, from small local businesses to international corporations, from local school boards to
industrial and developing countries. The banks mobilize loanable
funds by offering deposit services in local markets and by bidding for large balances through negotiable certificates of deposit
(CDs) domestically and Eurodollar deposits in markets abroad.
Profit-oriented, bank management focuses on expanding loans
and other assets. Simultaneously, management tries to maintain,

or increase, the spread by which interest and other income exceeds borrowing and other costs. In the profit calculus, legal
reserve requirements on bank liabilities add to bank costs, a sort
of franchise tax on an industry with controlled entry and official
supervision.
Bankers manage their assets and liabilities so as to maintain a
positive spread between the interest rate earned on assets and
the interest cost of borrowed money. When interest rates are
volatile and the outlook uncertain, bankers typically prefer locking in a positive spread, emphasizing floating rate loans at a
markup over the cost of borrowed money. In periods when they
expect declining interest rates, bankers may move toward intermediate- or longer-term assets with fixed interest rates, financing
them with low cost short-term liabilities. When they expect rising rates, bankers may increase and extend fixed rate liabilities
as early in the cycle of rising rates as seems prudent.
Careful projections assist banks in deciding how to meet burgeoning loan demand or how to invest potential resources. The
pace of economic activity strongly affects the form and intensity
of credit demands, and the extent to which such demands can be
financed through the growth of customer deposits. Bankers must
worry; too, about the impact of fiscal and monetary policy on the
projected outlook. As a bank maps its strategy, it tries to make
sure that investors and regulators will consider the institution's
capital base adequate in relation to its size and the businesses in
which it is engaged.
The banks monitor customer demands, shifting opportunities,
and the behavior of the monetary authorities against prior expectations. For many, Fed-watching is a necessity. Managers of
the money market banks track weekly money supply data and
open market operations for possible clues to the future course of
interest rates. Asset-liability committees meet regularly as bankers try to protect the positive interest spread needed to achieve
the year's profit goals from errors in judging the timing, or extent,
of interest rate changes.
The money market responds immediately to the economy's
changing demands for money, interacting with the Federal Reserve's management of reserves. Broadly defined, the money
market includes the interconnecting markets for debt instruments maturing in less than one year. Financial institutions,
businesses and governments place funds in the market, or bor
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

The Money and Capital Markets

page 11

row from it, to bridge differences in timing between receipts and
payments. They also use it to defer long-term borrowing or lending to a more propitious time.
The money market is truly international; banks bid for, and
lend, dollar funds throughout the world. The foreign exchange
markets link the global dollar market to offshore bank markets in
deutschemarks, Swiss francs, sterling, yen, and other currencies.
They also tie it to national money markets in London, Zurich,
Frankfurt and elsewhere.
The money market stretches from Federal funds, the overnight
market for bank reserves, out to one-year maturities. It merges
into the capital market, a continuum of obligations that extend
as far as 40 years. The dividing line between the money and
capital markets is somewhat arbitrary. More important than
the precise location of such a line is the fact that market influences continually wash across the boundary. For the Federal
Reserve the market's sheer size enables the domestic trading
desk to conduct both dynamic and defensive operations efficiently - and with a degree of visibility seen throughout the
financial markets.
If money and credit preoccupy the central bank, interest rates
are the obsession of financial markets. To dealers and traders,
profitability depends on being nimble, anticipating changes in
rates or catching a move soon after it begins. For fixed income
investors, leadership in the rate-of-return derby goes to those
who divine the rates. For borrowers, the cost of capital provides
the yardstick for measuring the productivity of investment projects. Whatever the central bank's approach to open market operations, market participants have to translate desk actions into
their own decision variable, interest rates.
The Federal Reserve's dynamic policy - maintaining nonborrowed reserves growth consistent with its monetary objectives
- leaves the money market free to reflect the demands, and
interest rate expectations, of those who use the market. Market
participants are as avid a group of Fed-watchers as the banks.
They follow every rise and fall of the money supply, and watch
the trading desk carefully, hoping to distinguish dynamic from
defensive elements whenever the desk intervenes, or fails to do
so. Banks and international corporations transmit the effects
quickly to dollar markets abroad. Foreign exchange traders also
assess the implications of interest rate changes for the dollar's
value relative to other currencies.
page 12


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

The transmission of monetary policy to the capital market for
debt and corporate shares is less predictable than it is to the
money market. A one percentage point increase in the Federal
funds rate will usually result in a roughly comparable increase in
other short-term interest rates, in part because the daily cost of
financing dealer inventories will rise by a similar amount. But
insurance companies, pension funds and others that invest in
intermediate- and long-term securities increasingly seek rates of
return on their investments that they expect to outpace inflation
in the years ahead. In forming expectations of inflation, longterm investors take into account the scale of potential fiscal
deficits and the credibility of the Federal Reserve's efforts to
achieve its monetary growth objectives (see Chart 4).
Chart 4 The Markets for
Reserves, Money, and Capital

Both borrowers and lenders keep moving between the money
and capital markets so that the linkage between short- and longterm interest rates can flex considerably over the business cycle.
Higher short-term rates often make it painless for investors to
defer commitments to long-term securities. On the borrowing

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 13

side, businessmen may rely heavily on short-term financing for
capital spending, as well as working capital, in periods of rising
interest rates. Once they think that the cyclical peak in interest
rates has passed, such borrowers try to fund their obligations
with long-term issues.

The Economic Impact

page 14


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

How then does monetary policy which affects money growth
and credit flows with a lag, influence production, employment,
and prices with still further lags? Some analysts, often identified
as monetarists, expect changes in the money supply itself to
have a strong, and reasonably predictable, impact on economic
activity. Consumers and others, in this view, increase spending on
goods and services when money balances grow more rapidly
than they desire; they cut back on outlays when money balances
fall below desired levels. The actual interactions within the
economy may be complex, but the relation between money and
economic activity is sufficiently reliable that controlling the
money supply is seen as a powerful tool for promoting society's
economic goals.
Others employ more complex models of the economy, in which
financial flows and interest rates interact with monetary growth
to affect production, prices, and the balance of international
transactions. In this version, monetary policy in the United
States influences real economic activity by affecting (1) the cost
and availability of credit for business spending and for state and
local government capital outlays, (2) the net worth and spending
of consumers, and (3) supply and demand in the housing industry. U.S. monetary policy also exerts expansionary or restrictive
effects on the world economy, which feed back to the demand for
U.S. exports (see Chart 5, page 15).
Whatever their own theoretical or visceral model of economic
processes, Federal Reserve officials develop their policy prescriptions in terms of society's main concerns for the economy's
performance. In the first two decades after World War II, they
sought to shift policy's emphasis over the business cycle. Whenever recessions led to higher unemployment, policymakers acted
to spur economic recovery; whenever buoyant aggregate demand threatened an acceleration of price inflation, they acted to
restrain expansion. The very success of national economic
policies in moderating recessions eroded the discipline previously exerted on business and consumer decisions by the chastening memories of the 1930's. In the 1970's, official policies, pri-

Chart 5 Monetary Policy and

the Economy

Monetary
Targets

Non-Bank
Finance

Required

Reserves


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

rv1oney Mkt.
Flows &.Jnt. Rates

Capital Mkt.

Flows&lnt Rates

page 15

vate decisions, and external events gradually made inflation the
principal perceived obstacle to real economic growth and the
amelioration of social conflicts. By the end of the decade, the
Federal Reserve was struggling to achieve credibility for its declared policy of lowering the growth rates of money and credit
over a succession of years to reduce inflation and reverse the
inflationary expectations built up over more than a decade.
With public confidence at low ebb in the ability of policymakers
to fine tune the economy, the Federal Reserve embraced a
strategy of supplying nonborrowed reserves consistent with its
annual monetary objectives to underscore its long-term commitment to reducing monetary growth and inflation.
Such an approach attempts to maintain a steadiness in monetary growth, on which all participants in the economic process
can count. Since monetary growth both influences, and is influenced by, economic activity, it is difficult, if not impossible, to
keep monetary growth steady without more prescience about
future events than economists reliably can provide. While a
reserve-oriented approach does not assure steady monetary
growth from quarter to quarter, it allows interest rates to respond
to changes in monetary growth, whether they reflect changes
in society's asset preferences or in the pulse of economic
life. Policymakers must still judge the extent to which these
automatic responses are to be reinforced, or muted, by other
means.
The monetary policy cycle is hard to divorce from the business cycle in practice, however desirable that may be in theory.
When the economy turns sluggish in times of recession, both
business and consumer demand for money and credit tend to fall
with economic activity. Business credit demand slackens as
businessmen meet an enlarged share of current orders from inventory rather than from new production. As unemployment
rises and income growth diminishes, the increase in consumer
deposits also slows. The Federal Reserve's maintenance of reserve growth in these circumstances causes short-term interest
rates to retreat from the cyclical peaks reached earlier, when
credit demand and the economy were strong. As rates come
down, and the fall can be quite sharp if the economy is really
weak, small time and savings deposits at banks and thrift institutions typically begin to grow more rapidly. Growth in currency and checkable deposits may continue quite sluggish at
this point.
page 16


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

With their costs of deposits falling, financial institutions
usually repay loans and rebuild depleted liquid assets. The decline in short-term rates below long-term rates also encourages
an increase in lending commitments - increasingly with
mortgages that afford the lender some protection against future
increases in the cost of his liabilities. Home buyers find credit
available on better terms. Home building increases along with
associated demands for labor, materials, furniture and other durable consumer goods. Businesses typically respond to the increased availability of longer term credit by refinancing the
short-term debt built up earlier. Banks and other financial institutions also buy Treasury securities heavily, financing enlarged
Federal deficits, which help maintain aggregate demand in recessionary periods.
The economy typically begins to recover when businesses
cease drawing down inventories, and when credit-sensitive industries begin responding to the flow of new orders that follows
an increase in credit availability. The decline in interest rates
accompanying recession and monetary ease usually prompts
investors to bid up stock prices in anticipation of better business
earnings. Partly because of the resultant increase in net worth,
consumers spend more freely. Rising employment and incomes
have even stronger effects in the same direction. Businessmen
respond to the quickening pace of activity by adding to inventories in the first instance, and later by stepping up spending on
new plants and equipment. Expanded foreign lending by U.S.
banks and other lenders of dollars contribute to higher production and income abroad.
At some point the monetary and credit demands generated in
the recovery-expansion phase typically push money supply
growth above the ranges contemplated by the Federal Reserve.
The central bank has to allow such demands to exert prompt
upward pressure on interest rates, if it is to maintain the credibility of its long-term strategy for reducing inflation. If monetary or
economic growth is strong, it may have to reinforce the automatic upward pressure on rates by raising the discount rate or
taking other measures. Higher market interest rates begin to
attract funds from the passbook accounts of banks and thrift
institutions, and raise institutional costs on market-related sixmonth certificates. Prudence usually dictates a slower pace for
loan commitments. Demand from home buyers also slacks off as
mortgage rates - and monthly payments - increase. Housing

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 17

starts decline. The rise in interest rates tends to affect consumer
spending, partly through adverse effects on corporate stock
prices and hence wealth. Higher interest rates may spur increased saving but inflationary fears can also spur consumers to
spend rather than save.
In the credit markets businesses compete aggressively for
funds when capital spending and inventory building outpace the
flow of internal funds. The strength of private demands more
than compensates for the decline in the Treasury's credit requirements as its receipts rise and anti-cyclical spending falls.
State and local governments find financing of long-term projects
more expensive and harder to come by. In time, business cuts
production to restrain inventories, as interest rates rise and the
outlook for sales dims. The money supply and economy turn
sluggish, setting the stage for a policy shift away from restraint.
In practice, the transmission of monetary policy to the real
economy is less predictable and dependable than such simplified
scenarios suggest. The growth of money itself can be an ambiguous guide to the leverage policy is exerting, because of the feedback to money demand from the economy. Moreover, various
measures of money may be affected differently by the interest
rate changes set in motion by the monetary control process.
High interest rates provide incentives to economize on Ml , currency and checkable deposits, and to switch toward those deposits in the more broadly defined M2 that bear market interest
rates. How should the Federal Reserve respond when Ml falls
below its growth objectives while M2 exceeds desired levels?
Does the relation between long-term interest rates and recent
rates of inflation provide additional information on whether
monetary policy is expansionary or restrictive? Policymakers
approach such questions with humility, but recognize that policy
doubts in an inflationary era must be resolved on one side until a
lasting reduction in inflation can be achieved.

page 18


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

2

Developing Monetary
Policy Strategy
The Federal Reserve System is a peculiarly American institution - blessed with checks and balances intended to restrain the
exercise of power, yet fully capable of effective leadership in
making monetary policy. The Board of Governors in Washington
dominates the organizational structure, overseeing 12 Federal
Reserve Banks, which move money and Treasury securities
around the nation, provide banking services to the Federal Government and supervise a substantial number of commercial
banks. The Board consists of seven members, each appointed by
the President and confirmed by the Senate to terms lasting 14
years. The chairman of the Board serves a four-year term by
Presidential appointment, while serving also as a Board member.
Together, the chairman and other governors are solely responsible for one of the three major instruments of monetary policy.
Within the limits authorized by Congress, they establish the ratios
of required reserves to deposits that depository institutions must
maintain. 1 The Board also exercises effective control over the
second major policy instrument, the discount rate charged by the
regional Federal Reserve Banks on loans made to depository
institutions in their district. The boards of directors of the individual Reserve Banks are charged with establishing the rate, but
the Board of Governors has power to "review and determine" the
rate ensuring that its judgment will prevail. Finally, the Board's
seven members serve on the 12-member Federal Open Market
Committee (FOMC). That body controls the most flexible policy
instrument for influencing economic activity-open market operations in Treasury securities and other instruments.

The Goals of Policy

The Federal Reserve System is a creation of the Congress,
which is constitutionally responsible for monetary policy. Monetary policy, of course, is only one important part of national
economic policy. The Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act
of 1978 calls for the President, early in each calendar year, to
establish "annual numerical goals for employment, production,
real income, productivity, and prices" for each of the five years
beginning with the current year. The President also is required to
1
The Board also exercises regulatory power over bank holding companies and other
commercial bank activities. The chairman of the Board is a voting member of the
Depository Institutions Deregulation Committee, which is charged with phasing out
interest rate ceilings for savings-type deposits.

page 20


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

incorporate programs and policies in his budget to reduce unemployment and inflation, and to achieve balance in the Federal
budget over time. The President has authority to extend the
original five-year timetable for reaching these desirable, but
often hard-to-reconcile, goals.
Under the 1978 law, the chairman of the Board appears regularly before Congress to explain the Federal Reserve's policies as
they relate to the President's program. He must report annually
to the banking committees of the Congress by February 20 on
the FOMC's objectives for monetary and credit growth in the
current calendar year. The growth rates the FOMC sets are intermediate objectives, lying between the Federal Reserve's weekly
operating targets for reserves and its ultimate goals for the performance of the real economy and prices. In judging Federal
Reserve performance, the Congress is interested not only in how
money and credit are behaving, but also in how successful monetary policy seems to be in fostering a healthy economy.
In his regular appearances before Congressional committees,
the chairman of the Board articulates how monetary policy relates to the major economic challenges facing the country. In
giving the central bank's strategy for dealing with inflation and
economic growth, he contributes importantly to the public discussion that defines national priorities. The chairman has to
defend the FOMC's choices and to explain deviations of growth
from path when they occur. By July 20 each year, the chairman
presents the FOMC's review of the current year's growth objectives, and also announces preliminary objectives for the next
calendar year. By setting annual goals before the year begins, and
reaffirming or revising them during the year to which they apply,
the FOMC can develop and articulate a longer term strategy. One
such strategy is the reduction of monetary growth rates over a
number of years with a view to reducing inflation.
The current emphasis on quantifying monetary policy objectives evolved gradually. In the 1950s and 1960s the FOMC was
content to specify only its directive to the trading desk, changing
its operating targets as committee members thought necessary
to promote the goals for the economy. While money and credit
growth were often one factor influencing FOMC judgments, the
committee did not set specific objectives for such growth. Its
operational targets were framed primarily in terms of the free

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

The Evolution of Policy Strategy

page 21

reserves of member banks - i.e., the reserves such banks held in
excess of their requirements, less their borrowings at the Federal
Reserve discount window. 2 Free reserves relate closely to the
Federal funds rate and other short-term interest rates; this was,
in effect, an interest rate approach to monetary control. Later,
the FOMC switched to the Federal funds rate explicitly as its
instrument for seeking control.
In this format the FOMC sought to anticipate the economy's
performance and adjust its operational instructions in advance,
allowing for a lag of many months from the time it changed the
desk's targets to the impact on spending decisions and economic
activity. Monetary policy proved quite effective when forecasts
were good and policymakers were prepared to change the Federal funds rate objective sufficiently. Still, the focus on short-term
interest rates tended to provide inadequate guidance to the public - and perhaps to the Committee itself - about the degree
of stimulus the central bank was exerting in recessions or the
restraint it was exercising during booms. Critics insisted that the
Committee would be better served if it focused less on interest
rates and used one or more measures of money as both indicators and objectives of monetary policy.

The FOMC moved in a modest way in 1966 to allow the manager of the System open market account to modify bank reserve
conditions - and the Federal funds rate - between Committee
meetings. The so-called "proviso clause" subtly enabled the
FOMC to specify in advance, movements in a proxy for bank
credit that would trigger an automatic response whenever the
proxy deviated from expectations. This conditional instruction
helped overcome the inertia otherwise inhibiting changes at
meetings, which were then only three weeks apart. But the proviso clause did not, of course, prevent policy mistakes. Monetary
and credit _growth could still become excessive, as occurred in
the wake of the 1968 effort to restore better fiscal balance
through a tax surcharge.
A new phase began in January 1970, after inflation and monetary restraint had raised interest rates to new peaks, and the
economy had begun slowing. In this situation the FOMC gave
priority in its operational instructions to reviving credit growth.
2
Free reserves represent the amount by which banks' nonbo"owed reserves exceed their
required reserves. When nonbo"owed reserves fall short of required reserves, free reserves
become negative, and are refe"ed to as net bo"owed reserves.

page 22


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

It authorized the System manager to vary the Federal funds rate
within prescribed limits between meetings to further this objective. In time the FOMC also switched its primary attention to Ml
from bank credit, and extended its policy horizon to six months.3
The committee's directives to the desk continued to focus on
bank reserves and money market conditions. But the goal was
reasonably steady growth in the monetary and credit aggregates,
with principal attention given to Ml. The committee soon
learned that pursuit of Ml required modeling the demand for
money and forecasting the economic forces that would affect
money demand over several quarters ahead. Effective control of
money depended on being sufficiently confident of these relationships to change the Federal funds rate well in advance of
projected developments. Lacking such confidence, committee
members often temporized, so that economic expansion at times
got ahead of the committee, as in 1972-73, resulting in undesirably rapid monetary growth with attendant inflationary pressures.
In 1975, emerging from the most severe recession of the postwar era, Congress endorsed and carried further the quantitative
emphasis. In a joint resolution it called on the Federal Reserve to
report quarterly to the congressional banking committees on the
growth anticipated in money and credit aggregates over the
ensuing 12 months. Under its provisions the chairman testified
on both the state of the economy and the FOMC's past record
and present monetary objectives. Alternating between the House
and Senate committees, these sessions underscored some of the
difficulties inherent in selecting, and pursuing, a growth rate for
money that was uniquely appropriate to the economic performance desired. For example, the banking committees were concerned in the summer of 1975 that the FOMC's objective of 5 to 7
percent growth in Ml over the next year would prove inadequate
to finance a strong recovery from the 1974-75 recession. In fact,
Ml grew at only a 5.4 percent rate in the year ended in the second
quarter of 1976. Yet real economic growth was strong while inflation slowed more than most forecasters had expected.
The quarterly congressional sessions also brought out the
basic conflicts involved in managing monetary policy in a democratic society. On one side was the desire of many to foster rapid
economic growth even at the risk of adding to inflation, a policy

Chart 6Ml & M2:

Performance vs Objectives
(Percentage Rate of Growth)
9

8
7
6

5

4
Ml~~~~~~~~~~

11
JO

9

8
7
6

5
M2 ~~~~~~~~~
75-76 76-77 77-78 78-79
Monetary Growth Objective (Range) 4th quarter to 4th quarter
0
Actual Rate of Growth
4th quarter to 4th quarter

3
M/ was then defined to include bank demand deposits and currency in the hands of
the public.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page23

that many politicians and economists associated with keeping
interest rates as low as possible. On the other was the desire of
the Federal Reserve and many others to dampen the rate of price
inflation - a policy that required lowering rates of monetary
growth and permitting interest rates to rise when the economy
expanded.
The FOMC gradually lowered its monetary growth objectives
over several years. But actual growth often exceeded its goals particularly for Ml in 1977 and much of 1978 (see Chart 6, page
23). To some degree, the overruns resulted from the FOMC's
decision to move forward each quarter the base from which
monetary growth was measured. This "base drift" meant that
rapid growth in money in one or two quarters did not automatically require slower growth in subsequent quarters. The 1978
Act's call for annual monetary objectives and a regular review
process was intended to reduce this kind of slippage.
The FOMC also found it difficult to allow interest rates to rise
sufficiently to restrain the acceleration of money growth. Repeatedly, both monetary and economic growth exceeded committee expectations. Committee members came to doubt that
the Federal funds rate strategy, at least as it had been employed,

remained an adequate approach to reducing money growth. In
October 1979, with inflation a very serious threat and the credibility of its policy increasingly in doubt, the committee changed
procedures to have the trading desk pursue a path for nonborrowed reserves consistent with desired growth in Ml and M2. 4
Under this procedure, deviations in money from the committee's
chosen path transmit pressure to interest rates automatically in
the direction needed to bring money growth back toward the
annual objectives.

TheFOMC

As noted, the FOMC is responsible for adopting the annual
monetary objectives to be pursued by open market operations.
The committee consists of the seven governors and five Reserve
Bank presidents. The chairman of the Board presides over the
FOMC, while the vice chairman is traditionally the president of
the New York Reserve Bank, which serves as the committee's
age nt in executing open market operations. The New York
Reserve Bank president is by law a permanent member of the
4
Until the aggregates were redefined in February 1980, M2 was defined as Ml plus time and
savings deposits at commercial banks (other than large negotiable CDs).

page 24


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

committee, while presidents of the other 11 Reserve Banks serve
annual terms on a rotational basis. Non-voting presidents attend
each meeting and participate fully in policy discussions.
In its meetings in early February and early July, the committee
adopts the annual objectives for money and credit growth to be
reported to the Congress. These objectives are also reviewed at
half a dozen other meetings during the year. At all eight meetings
the FOMC adopts short-term instructions to the New York
Reserve Bank for conducting open market operations during the
six or seven weeks between meetings. Telephone consultations
and votes by wire are used to amend the operating instructions as
necessary between committee meetings ( see Chart 7).
The presidents who are to be voting members are sworn in,
effective March 1 each year. At its annual business meeting in
March the committee chooses a senior Board officer as secretary.
It also selects one senior officer of the New York Reserve Bank to
be the manager for domestic open market operations, and another to be the manager for foreign exchange operations. The
senior research officers of the Board and of the Reserve Banks
represented on the FOMC are named as the committee's staff.
The Board's staff provides the committee with its principal analysis of financial and economic developments and of monetary
policy's interaction with them. The research staffs of the Reserve
Banks serve as advisers to their respective presidents and as
contributors to research aimed at improving monetary policy.
The FOMC meetings provide a forum for discussing the appropriate use of policy tools. Open market operations need to be
integrated with changes in reserve requirements and the Federal
Reserve discount rate. Accordingly, individual Bank presidents
may comment at Committee meetings on the desirability of
Board actions on the discount rate. The presidents often will
report, too, on how businessmen, bankers, and economists in
their district see the economic outlook and whether their directors favor a change in the discount rate. The governors of the
Board are usually sparing in their comments, since they are
responsible for acting on reserve requirements and the discount
rate. Still the exchange of ideas at such times keeps policy decisions oriented toward common objectives.
The chairman may inform the presidents while they are in
Washington about current developments with regard to economic and banking issues. The Federal Reserve chairman is often

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Chart 7Structure of the Federal
Open Market Committee

NYFRB
Trading Desk

page25

invited by the President to participate in discussions of national
economic policy. The chairman meets weekly with the Secretary
of the Treasury, and periodically with the chairman of the Council
of Economic Advisers and the director of the Office of Management and Budget. The chairman testifies frequently before the
House and Senate banking committees, budget committees,
and the Joint Economic Committee of the Congress; he is
often in touch with congressional leaders on banking matters
and legislation.
Since making monetary policy is a governmental function,
policymakers need to know how decisions at the Federal level are
likely to affect the economy. Such knowledge also helps each
FOMC participant develop a well-rounded view of the Federal
Reserve's role in national economic policymaking. Participants
are themselves articulate spokesmen on economic policy issues
- the governors in their own congressional testimony and extensive speechmaking, the Reserve Bank presidents as leaders
in their regions.
As discussed more fully later, FOMC decisionmaking involves
two stages: setting annual objectives for monetary and credit
growth, and adopting operating instructions to the trading desk
of the New York Reserve Bank. Typically, the chairman testifies
before the congressional banking committees soon after the annual objectives are adopted - usually within a week or two. The
committee publishes its operational directive after the intermeeting period to which it applies, together with a policy record,
which summarizes the economic analysis presented at the meeting and the committee's policy discussions. The delay permits
the staff to prepare, and the committee to approve, that policy
record. It also avoids the abrupt effects that might follow a more
immediate announcement of significant changes, permitting
decisions to be implemented in an orderly and sometimes conditional manner.

The Policy Process

page 26


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

At its meeting in early February, the FOMC adopts a monetary
policy strategy for the current year. It brings together different
approaches to economic analysis, as well as the informed judgment of the 12 voting members and the 7 nonvoting presidents.
The policy process stretches what economists know to the limit;
the answers they give to key questions often vary with their
analytical approach.
The questions policymakers want answered are straightfor-

ward enough. What are the likely economic consequences over
the next two or three years of the FOMC's choice of particular
rates of growth in the monetary and credit aggregates? Will gross
national product (GNP), after adjustment for inflation, grow faster, or slower, than its trend rate of growth? Will employment rise
more, or less, rapidly than the civilian labor force, and produce a
decline, or rise, in the unemployment rate? Will prices tend to
increase more, or less, rapidly than in the recent past? Will U.S.
trade and payments with the rest of the world move nearer to
balance? Will the dollar be steady in the foreign exchange markets? What would be the impact on production, employment, and
prices of raising, or lowering, the growth of money and credit by
one percentage point? And, if the economy behaves differently
than expected, do the advisers expect the odds to favor a
stronger, or a weaker, economy?
To answer these questions, economists at the Board and the
Reserve Banks evaluate developments systematically within a
theoretical framework of how monetary policy affects a dynamic
economy. System economists are a diverse group when it comes
to theorizing about this process, often disagreeing about the
speed and strength of monetary policy effects and the best
means of controlling the growth in money and credit. It may help
flesh out some of the basic issues to sketch quickly two different
analytical approaches. They share much common ground, but
there are also significant differences between them.
One approach visualizes the aggregate income and output
generated by the economy as the sum of the spending decisions
of the major economic groups - consumers, businessmen, governmental bodies, and the rest of the world. The Board staff uses
an econometric model developed along these lines for reference,
when preparing forecasts for the FOMC. Monetary policy in this
formulation exerts its major force through interest rates, abetted
somewhat by credit availability effects. Open market operations
seek to supply nonborrowed reserves at a rate consistent with
the FOMC's monetary growth objectives. The banking system's
demand for total reserves, interacting with this supply of reserves, produces changes in discount window borrowing and
the Federal funds rate. A shortfall in bank demand for reserves
in relation to supply, for example, will cause the Federal funds
rate and other short-term rates to decline and result, with
allowance for lags, in a rise in money supply, bank credit,

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

I. Economic Models and
Monetary Policy

page 27

page 28

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

and the flow of funds to thrift institutions.
In this view, achieving desired rates of growth in money and
credit is subject to considerable uncertainty because of the wide
range of adjustments possible in investor portfolios. The actions
of banks and other investors, however, lead in time to a decline in
long-term interest rates and yields on corporate stock, which
affect the cost of capital. Through the financial flows and spending decisions set in motion, monetary policy exerts leverage on
the economy.
The large econometric model used by the Board staff simulates the economy through more than 100 equations, which
utilize quarterly data on 10 major spending, pricing and employment sectors.5 Monetary policy influences both nominal interest
rates and real interest rates, i.e., interest rates adjusted for inflationary expectations. The effect on rates and financial flows carries through in the model to consumer spending on automobiles
and other durable goods, on nondurable goods and services, and
on residential construction (see Chart 8, page 29). Other equations detail the forces influencing business spending on new
structures and equipment, and the construction of multifamily
housing. Interest rates on municipal securities influence state
and local capital expenditures to some degree. Fiscal policy the tax and spending decisions of the Federal Government exerts powerful lagged effects of its own. While interest rates
provide the driving force for monetary policy in the model, the
staff can determine the profiles of interest rates consistent with
different rates of monetary growth.
Such a model underscores the importance of projecting the
future behavior of consumers, businessmen and government in
order to set an appropriate course for monetary policy. If one
underestimates government spending or consumer demand at a
particular income level, then the demands for money and credit
in financial markets are likely to be larger than anticipated at
each level of interest rates. The FOMC's instructions to the desk
constitute a supply schedule for nonborrowed reserves. But
growth in the demand for money and credit can be so strong that
the rise in interest rates generated automatically may not be
sufficient to bring the growth in the monetary aggregates back in
line. Monetary growth can still exceed the FOMC's objectives for
See George G. Kaufman, Mone~ the Financial System and the Economy (Houghton
Mifflin, Chicago, 1981), Chapter 15, pp. 398-407.
5

Chart 8 'Transmission of
Monetary Policy I

Prices &
Wages

Money Targets

Jn~

Expectottons

.' ·:~::t:,·; ·_

,\,~.;;,~t,:,

/'::;r;,,
) , ,?E

>;-~~ii;;j

a considerable period. Conversely, if changes in consumer attitudes or business inventory policy lead to weakening demands
for money and credit, growth in these aggregates will probably
fall below the Committee's goals, possibly for some months. Even

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 29

page 30

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

with a supply-oriented reserves strategy, policymakers still have
to decide whether to speed up the monetary adjustment process by changing reserve paths, the discount rate or reserve
requirements.
Another school of economic analysis seeks to finesse some of
the difficulties of economic forecasting by concentrating on
money as the driving force of monetary policy. The monetarists
see the FOMC as exerting strong direct effects on spending, employment, and prices by varying the rate of growth in money - in
either the Ml or M2 definition. Consumers are seen as rapidly
adjusting their spending to a change in the rate of monetary
growth. Increased money balances lead consumers to spend for
goods and services in order to restore money holdings to a desired relationship to income.
Monetarists do not believe that economists know enough
about the structure of the economy or how expectations influence behavior to build satisfactory large scale models. They prefer instead to concentrate on a few key relationships. In this
approach, answers to most of the key policy questions are
sought with a small model driven by money, fiscal policy, the rate
of utilization of the labor force, and the economy's productive
potential. The staff of the St. Louis Reserve Bank has incorporated such an approach into an 8-equation quarterly model. Compared to the Board's more complex structural model, this model
suggests that changes in monetary growth exert stronger and
more immediate effects on output, employment and prices. The
monetarists expect only a modest feedback from the economy to
the demand for money and hence, visualize monetary growth as
essentially supply determined. In their view the money supply
can be controlled with considerable precision by specifying the
rate at which the total reserves of the banking system are allowed to grow. Other monetarists prefer to focus on the monetary base, which adds currency in circulation to total reserves.
One of the key arguments between other economists and the
monetarists is over how quickly the Federal Reserve can control
monetary growth. Nonmonetarists, believing there is considerable feedback from the economy to money demand, consider
week-to-week and month-to-month variability in money growth
desirable , even inevitable, in a market economy, which
economizes the use of money. Many monetarists find disturbing
the size of monthly and quarterly variations in money growth,
believing they reflect inadequate control procedures, which can

undermine the attainment of monetary goals. Monetarists generally espouse institutional changes they believe will force
changes in bank and customer behavior more rapidly than in the
past; they believe control of money within a month or two is both
feasible and desirable. The procedures adopted in October 1979
went a considerable distance in the monetarist direction by establishing a supply schedule for nonborrowed reserves. But
judgment remains important in adjusting one or more of the
three policy instruments to quicken portfolio adjustments.
a. Preparation. The FOMC's policy process begins with the
preparation of three major documents to be circulated a few days
before the meeting to those who will attend. The green book
presents both the Board staff's detailed appraisal of the forces
currently at work in the major economic sectors and financial
markets, and a summary analysis of the economic outlook over
the next two or three years. The red book gives a roundup from
the 12 Federal Reserve Banks of regional business and professional views of current and prospective developments. Finally, the
blue book provides a Board staff menu of alternative paths for
the key monetary aggregates over the whole year when these are
being considered in February and July. At each meeting, it sets
out alternate scenarios for short-run operations.
In February, the FOMC members have in hand the green book's
quantitative forecasts of about 40 key economic and financial
variables through the current and following calendar year, assuming monetary growth at the rates tentatively adopted the
previous July. While the forecast draws on the historic relationships contained in the structural econometric model, making the
forecast is essentially a judgmental process, in which the senior
staff incorporates its current estimates of Federal budget impact
and of how other sectors are likely to behave. At the meeting
itself, the staff presents alternative scenarios of how changing
the monetary growth objectives from those adopted the previous
July would affect the economic outcome. Such scenarios usually
involve forecasting key economic variables including real GNP,
unemployment and prices two to three years into the future. The
blue book outlines alternative families of growth rates for Ml, M2,
M3, and bank credit and the expected implications of different
choices for the income velocity of money.
In the blue book prepared for the February meeting, the staff
focuses on the financial relationships linking specific growth

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

2. The February Meeting

page31

rates for money and credit to the market for bank reserves and
interest rates. The staff advises the committee on the likely
interest rate consequences of pursuing in the current year the
monetary growth rates adopted the preceding July. Typically, the
analysis will include the projected behavior of the rates on Federal funds , 3-month Treasury bills, corporate bonds and
mortgages. To aid its judgment, the staff draws on simulations of
the money demand of the quarterly model and of a more elaborate monthly model of the process of financial portfolio adjustment. Judgment has become even more important in recent
years because of the rapidity of institutional change. In the blue
book the staff also provides the Committee with optional specifications for determining the nonborrowed reserve path to be
pursued by the trading desk between meetings. (The FOMC's
consideration of such options is discussed in Chapter 5.)
Before every meeting, each Reserve Bank president and his
staff go over the array of policy options on which he will comment at the committee meeting. His senior research officers may
present their own review of economic and financial developments, delineating their differences with the Board staff's economic outlook. At the New York Reserve Bank additional attention is regularly given to the international economic situation,
the balance of payments and the foreign exchange markets, as
well as to Treasury borrowing and other demands falling on the
financial markets. Preparatory policy discussions center on the
same issues that will be addressed at the FOMC meeting, especially the implication of different monetary growth rates for employment and inflation over the current and following year. The
presidents and their staffs then turn to the growth rates to be
sought in the aggregates over the next several months, and the
likely implications for interest rates, given the projected demand
for money.
b. Staff presentation. When the Committee convenes, the
meeting necessarily has to be rather formal if the seven Board
members and 12 presidents are going to be able to speak to the
issues before them. The committee first hears a report by the
manager for foreign exchange operations on developments in the
currency markets and acts on any recommendations he has regarding foreign exchange operations. Then the manager for
domestic open market operations reports on trading desk activity under the committee's instructions since the last meeting.
The committee has the opportunity to raise questions about
page32


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

operations before deciding whether to approve them or not.
The Board staff summarizes its forecast of economic and
financial developments in both the current year and the year
following, on the assumption of monetary growth at the rates
tentatively adopted the previous July. These estimates are reviewed in relation to the Administration's own estimates of prospective output, employment and prices. The Board staff highlights the major forces influencing personal consumption expenditures, business fixed investment, housing, and government
spending at present. The analysis may touch on the extent to
which demographic factors or inflationary expectations are
boosting consumer spending and home construction. Business
capital spending plans are evaluated, and differences with the
Administration's outlook for the Federal budget are pointed out.
The staff projects employment, trends in labor productivity, wage
settlements, and the expected impact of these on unit labor
costs and prices. The international staff presents its views of the
output, growth and price performances expected abroad in relation to U.S performance, and the implications for the balance of
payments and the dollar's exchange rate.
The staff goes on to outline the credit flows and interest rates
associated with the tentative aggregate targets and projected
economic growth, as well as the expected behavior of prices and
unemployment. To assist in the FOMC's consideration of alterna-

tive growth rates for the aggregates, the staff also presents model
simulations of what the effects would be on prices, unemployment and interest rates of changing the rates of monetary and
credit growth from the preliminary targets set the previous July.
The staff director for monetary policy leads off the discussion
of the policy options facing the committee. On the one hand, he
is concerned with the reasonableness of the relationship between money growth at the pace sought by the committee and
the projected behavior of the economy. Does the growth of
money appear adequate to finance the projected growth of GNP
at current prices, without implying a rate of turnover, or income
velocity, of money that appears unusual compared to its behavior at similar points in other business cycles? The staff director
does not assume that money and GNP will grow at linked rates
over a two-year period, however stable the relationship, and velocity, may appear over longer periods. His presentation describes
the way the monetary and real components of the staff's outlook
fit together. If the relationships among different monetary aggre
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page33

gates has changed since the previous July, he gives the staff
estimates of how the committee may need to change the growth
ranges it adopts in order to maintain internal consistency.6 On
the other hand, the staff director also advises the FOMC on the
interest rates expected to result from pursuit of the aggregate
objectives. Does he foresee a change in the demand for money at
the income levels projected? Or, stated differently, are interest
rates likely to rise more, or less, than the econometric models
suggest as the desk pursues the committee's monetary objectives? Against this background, the staff director presents the
pros and cons for adjusting the FOMC's objectives for the monetary aggregates from those tentatively adopted the previous July.
c. Adopting an FOMC Strategy. The chairman calls for a general discussion of the ranges of money and credit growth to be
adopted for the current calendar year. Each of the governors and
presidents who speak usually gives his personal assessment of
the economic outlook before spelling out the growth objectives
he or she considers appropriate. The policymakers bring a wide
range of business, academic, and governmental experience to
these deliberations. Different intellectual approaches to monetary policy are as prevalent on the committee as within the
research staffs that serve its members. Policymakers are likely to
be more concerned than their staffs with policy's relation to the
political process through which society shapes its goals and
programs. Collectively, they assess not only what policy is appropriate, but also the degree of freedom the central bank has to
pursue its chosen policy within the conflicting pressures stemming from the public, the Congress, and the Administration. The
stature of any central bank depends primarily on how well it
employs its own freedom of action to build a record deserving
The Federal Reserve substantially revised its definitions of money in early 1980 to include
nonbank liabilities serving the different functions of money as well as the bank liabilities
previously included in the Ml and M2 definitions. Ml, the definition generally considered
closest to the medium-of-exchange function of money, reappeared as MIA, closely akin to
the old Ml. MJB, slated to become the new Ml, consisted of MIA plus other checkable
deposits, principally in accounts allowing negotiated orders of withdrawal (NOW) and
automatic transfers from savings (ATS) at banks and thrift institutions, and share drafts at
credit unions. The new M2 was expanded. It includes MJB, time and savings deposits at all
depository institutions, overnight repurchase agreements (RPs) at commercial banks,
overnight Eurodollar deposits at the Caribbean branches of US. banks, and shares in
money market mutual funds. The new M3 includes the new M2, large denomination time
deposits (CDs) at all depository institutions, and term RPs at commercial banks and
savings and loan associations.
6

page34


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

public support. The central bank also has a responsibility to
make known, to the extent possible, its views on fiscal policy,
which may significantly affect its ability to carry out an effective
monetary policy.
In discussing the economic outlook, policymakers usually
focus on those elements that suggest a stronger, or weaker, outcome than that projected by the Board staff. Often these differences reflect special knowledge of housing, business capital
spending, or the economic strength of a particular section of the
country. Many times they result from different readings of how
the consumer, business or government sectors are behaving.
Those who see interest rates providing the primary thrust of
monetary policy tend to give particular attention to the sectors
most sensitive to interest rate changes. Those who lean toward
the monetarist analysis are likely to be influenced strongly by
the recent growth of money in the Ml or M2 definition. Each
policymaker's estimate of the outlook is subtly influenced by his
or her personal views as to the appropriate, or achievable, balance between price stability and economic expansion. Those
who see price stability as necessary to sustained economic expansion may concentrate on whatever elements could add to
inflationary pressures. Conversely, those who are concerned that
economic weakness could undermine a sustained expansion,
may stress measures or sectors that are slowing down. While the
economic assessments most often reflect changing individual
views of the outlook itself, sometimes they also involve differing
perceptions of how to achieve the country's goals.
Each policymaker considers the annual growth objectives
against the economic outlook as he sees it. Since 19 principals
participate in the meeting, the discussion tends to focus on the
Ml and M2 definitions of money, which are the most meaningful
for short-run operations. Members tend to leave it to the staff to
see that the M3 and bank credit ranges presented in the blue
book are modified to conform to the FOMC's Ml and M2 choices.
Participants approach their choice of a longer term strategy,
mindful of how the aggregates have performed in relation to past
objectives. In 1978, for example, there was some desire to continue lowering the ranges for monetary growth as evidence of the
FOMC's commitment to reduce inflation. Simultaneously, the fact
that Ml in particular had overshot the FOMC's objectives for an
extended period made the credibility of such a move suspect.
The committee elected to leave the range unchanged.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page35

In making policy choices, committee members know the difficulties the staff confronts in specifying the relation between
money growth and nominal GNP, on the one hand, and the relation between growth in bank reserves and money, on the other.
An individual policymaker may agree that the staff's projection of
the economy's performance is both reasonable and desirable.
The member may still conclude that money will have to grow
more rapidly than the staff judges necessary, because he does
not expect the same shift in the money demand function as the
staff. Another member might approach the same point differently.
He or she might believe that a rise in interest rates, which the
staff associates with achieving the money growth objective, will
keep the economy from attaining the economic performance the
staff projects and the committee member wishes to see. At times
members will agree essentially with the staff's formulation of
interest rate, monetary and GNP relationships, but want to speed
up monetary growth because they feel that excess capacity is
sufficient to warrant more rapid economic expansion. At other
times, individuals may see the slowing of the monetary aggregates as an opportunity to reduce the growth ranges adopted as
policy objectives. Others may be apprehensive that allowing
shortfalls in growth to persist will lead to a recession, and
perhaps to an overly stimulative fiscal policy.
A starting point for the committee's deliberations is the blue
book formulation of two or three families of mutually consistent
growth rates for Ml, M2, M3, and bank credit. Each participant
either signifies agreement with one of these options or proposes
different ranges, typically for Ml and M2. Sometimes speakers
will expect the relationship between Ml and M2 growth to differ
from the staff's estimates. Some may express a desire for widening the growth ranges because of their uncertainty about the
behavior of the demand for money. All are concerned about the
relation between past performance and the new annual objectives.
The committee's wide ranging discussion underscores the
complexities and uncertainties affecting decentralized decision
making in a flexible and efficient market economy. Still the committee must decide, recognizing that it may neither achieve the
monetary and credit objectives it sets, nor the economic performance its members wish. When the voting members give the
actual growth ranges they favor for the calendar year, their views
are often closer than one might expect from the diversity of their
page 36


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

analyses. After the decision, the chairman can usually present
ranges for Ml, M2, M3 and bank credit that will command majority support. Further discussion indicates whether a modification
of the chairman's proposal will pick up additional support. The
committee's decisions emerge with considerable give and take
along the way. There is a strong desire to be as united as possible
in setting the year's objectives. The agreement is on the growth
rate ranges themselves. Members of the voting majority may
well entertain different expectations of what achievement of
those objectives will mean to the economy's performance.
The members still must develop instructions to the trading
desk in New York for pursuing the desired objectives. Before
going on to the FOMC's operational strategy and how it is carried
out in Chapters 5, 6, and 7, it will be helpful to describe the
commercial banking system and the money market, which together carry forward monetary policy's influence to affect both
financial and economic decisions.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page37

3

Commercial Banks Managers Of Risk
Commercial banks transmit monetary policy to the money
market and the economy. They also respond to the demands
other economic players make on a dynamic financial system.
Aided by the Federal Reserve's provision of reserves for seasonal
purposes, the banks provide credit, currency and bank deposits
on short notice, enabling their customers to make the myriad
payments of modern economic life. Their demand deposits rise
by billions of dollars one week when payment needs expand,
only to fall back in the next, as dollar recipients pay bills of their
own or move into interest-earning assets in the money market.
Yet the very flexibility that permits daily and seasonal demands
for funds to be accommodated readily can lead to problems. The
banking system's responsiveness to the demand for its services
can lead to excessive growth in money and credit in boom times,
or to inadequate money and credit growth in times of economic
slack. The Federal Reserve must continually monitor bank behavior as it pursues its own annual objectives for money and
credit growth.

The Business of Banking

page38

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Bankers face the challenge of managing profitably a large
number of interlocking financial businesses in a society of
changing needs and tastes. Economists may focus analytical attention on the deposits of commercial banks and the relation
between money and economic activity. Bankers themselves concentrate on borrowing and lending funds, and providing investment management and other financial services. They actively
market deposit and payment services and then apply the funds
attracted to make loans and acquire mortgages and securities.
Banks compete actively for both funds and loans with each other
and other institutions in the financial markets. Government regulation and supervision provide a framework intended to assure
depositors that individual banks have the unquestioned ability to
repay their obligations as they fall due.
Commercial banks are at the heart of the financial system,
distinguished by the breadth of their involvement in the deposit,
loan and other financial markets. Until recently; they had a near
monopoly of the checking accounts that serve the community as
a principal means of payment. Banks provide retail accounts to
consumers and small businesses, payroll and check collection
services to businesses of all sizes, and foreign exchange facilities
to those who need to make payments in other currencies.

Through their retail branches, banks attract a major share of the
nation's savings deposits, competing with credit unions, savings
and loan association, and savings banks within the limits allowed
by law and interest-rate regulation. The banks also compete for
funds in organized markets - buying Federal funds from other
financial institutions, borrowing through the sale of Government
securities under repurchase agreements, and issuing negotiable
certificates of deposit (CDs) for 14 days or more. They also bid
for Eurodollar deposits through offshore branches and international banking facilities set up in the United States.
In the loan markets, major banks traditionally have emphasized business lending. For many years most loans involved
short-term lending to finance inventories, seasonal farm credit
needs, and foreign trade, either directly or through the acceptance of drafts drawn on banks (bankers' acceptances).
Product lines have broadened since to include term loans of up
to ten years, and complicated leasing deals with business ranging from small domestic enterprises to international companies building new plants in overseas markets. In business lending the banks compete with finance and insurance companies as
well as the commercial paper and corporate bond markets.
Some banks, including major international institutions, concentrate their energies on serving the needs of the business
sector. Such "wholesale" banks may make only limited efforts to
compete with those that provide "retail" deposit and loan services to consumers through extensive branch networks. For
many banks consumer installment loans and credit cards provide major outlets for available funds - in competition with finance companies and other institutions. Banks are also a large
factor in home improvement loans and home mortgages, which
are the primary activity of savings banks and savings and loan
associations. Mortgages on business and commercial property
also are important. Commercial banks are large scale underwriters of, and investors in, the securities issued by the Federal
Government, federally sponsored credit agencies, and state and
local governments. Since the 1960's loans to the overseas operations of U.S. companies and to foreign businesses and governments have grown rapidly; from both the home office and
overseas bank branches. Conversely; agencies, branches and
subsidiaries of foreign banks constitute a large presence in the
United States. For the most part, they operate in the money and

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page39

foreign exchange markets, and lend money to domestic corporations. A few also have entered the retail side of the banking
business on a large scale.
When operating in deposit and loan markets, commercial
bankers must manage a variety of risks, keeping in view nearterm profitability, longer run growth, and capital adequacy. There
is a continuing temptation to borrow more funds whenever prudent lending or investing can increase the return to the shareholders. But leveraging bank capital more heavily can worry
stock analysts and shareholders if earnings appear likely to become more variable.
Bank supervisors study in depth each bank's effectiveness in
managing risk. Reporting to each bank's board of directors, they
note particularly any areas that need attention and give their
own assessment of the adequacy of the bank's capital to finance
growth and assure the safety of deposits. The opinions of bank
supervisors gain extra weight from their power to approve new
branches, mergers, and bank holding company ventures into
such closely related financial activities as mortgage and finance
companies.
Large depositors as well are vitally interested in the capital
base of the banks and their prudence. The deposit insurance of
the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation covers only $100,000
per depositor. If banks begin to have earning troubles, they may
experience difficulty in rolling over outstanding CDs, or borrowing from other banks in the Federal funds markets. In the
extreme, as in the case of Franklin National Bank in 1974, the
run-off of deposits can contribute to the rapid demise of a
large institution.

Banking Risks

page 40

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Bankers have a number of different risks that have to be managed. First, there is the credit risk - the risk that the borrower
will be unable to repay his loans. A primary function of a bank
loan officer is to evaluate this risk - for loans made to individuals, businesses, or foreign government agencies. Lenders cannot
expect, of course, to avoid losses entirely. The task of management is to lend prudently so that losses will be more than covered by the excess of loan charges over cost for the whole loan
portfolio, allowing an adequate margin for profit. Then there is
the interest rate risk. Earnings can be dramatically reduced if a
bank with a large volume of fixed interest rate assets encounters
a sharp rise in short-term borrowing costs. This risk is typically

called "mismatching the book"; managing the book involves
weighing the running gain from borrowing short and lending
long, against the risk short-term interest rates will rise so rapidly
that the spread will disappear or turn negative. Finally, banks
must manage their liquidity risk. They must be able to meet
unexpected demands for cash, money transfers or loans without
hesitation or delay. Some banks provide adequate liquidity by
holding secondary reserves, like Treasury bills, that can be sold
when needed. Others depend on borrowing through the CD or
Federal funds markets to meet cash drains. Most banks depend
in some degree on the Federal Reserve discount window to rebuild their reserve accounts when bank or customer activities
lead to a sudden loss of reserves.
Banks typically organize internal committees to oversee the
management of the various risks.1 A credit committee of the
lending function generally specifies the loan policies, supervises
the evaluation of credit risks, and reviews and approves all major
credit lines. With international lending so important to large
banks, the evaluation of country risk is an important concern.
Often the senior loan officer will be freed from major administrative responsibilities to chair the committee and be an independent judge of new loan initiatives.
To manage interest rate risk, major banks depend on an assetliability committee (ALCO), on which lending, investing, borrowing, and staff functions are represented (see Chart 9, page 42).
This committee coordinates, or directs, changes in the maturities and types of bank assets and liabilities to sustain
profitability in a changing economic environment. The committee also keeps close watch on liquidity and the bank's ability to
meet demands made on it by selling assets or borrowing money.
The choices made by bank asset-liability committees over the
cycle, are a principal means by which Federal Reserve actions
affect financial markets and the economy.
The asset-liability committee is responsible for shaping basic
borrowing and lending strategy, as well as its execution and adjustment to changing circumstances. The cyclical patterns of the
economy, credit demands, and monetary policy, and the opportunities and risk they present for the bank, are a major preoccu-

Managing Risk

1
A large money market bank, as described here, has a systematic, often formal, approach
to the process, but banks of all sizes have similar risks to manage.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 41

pation. When the economy and loan demand become slack,
money growth is likely to weaken and short-term interest rates
are likely to fall as the Federal Reserve continues to provide
nonborrowed reserves to the banks. At such times intermediate,
or longer term fixed-interest loans, securities or mortgages offer
both a large yield pickup over short-term money costs and the
possibility of a capital gain, if interest rates continue to decline.
The short-term rewards of mismatching the book are great, while
the risks of a rise in short-term rates may be small, in the early
stages of a typical economic recovery.
Chart 9 Asset/Liability Management in a Large Commercial Bank

External

Internal

=

Forecast

\
As the economy picks up speed, loan demand from the bank's
customers usually increases, often at a faster clip than demand
and savings deposits rise. When money growth begins to exceed
the Federal Reserve's objective, demands for money and credit
will exert upward pressure on the Federal funds rate and other
short-term rates. Then, the asset-liability committee seeks to
shift the bank's portfolio toward short-term or floating rate loans,
which will provide greater income as interest rates rise. Simulta-

page 42


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

neously, it is likely to fund the bank with somewhat longer CDs or
the sale of Treasury and other securities, which are expected to
drop in price when interest rates rise.
Positioning the bank to take advantage of changes in credit
and demand and interest rates is critical to the sustained growth
in earnings that is the objective of bank management. The volatility of interest rates since October 1979 has made banks much
less confident of their ability to forecast interest rates and mismatch their book. Accordingly, they have placed greater emphasis on pricing loans on a floating rate basis with a view to locking
in a profitable spread whatever happens to interest rate levels.
The asset-liability committee often works within the framework provided by the bank's annual profit planning process. Each
bank's approach to profit planning reflects its organization of the
businesses in which it is engaged. Major banks tend to be organized along both geographic and functional lines, with senior
officers responsible for major groups of activity. Typically, one
major area of responsibility is retail banking, in which internal
administration of the branch network is broken down geographically. The national group is another, serving the bank's corporate
and governmental clients, and banking correspondents. Domestic
wholesale lending is a principal activity. The international group
performs similar functions for customers abroad, handles foreign
exchange operations, and supervises the borrowing and lending
operations of foreign branches.
A key functional group looks after investments - the bank's
mortgage and securities portfolio, its securities trading activities,
and the money desk, which has the responsibility for funding the
bank and making money market loans. The controller's group is
responsible for taxes, accounting, budget and capital planning,
and internal auditing. A separate operations group takes care
of the enormous volume of back office work involved in providing bank services. Staff functions meet the bank's needs for personnel management, economic research, public relations and
legal counsel.
Profit planning involves the chairman, president and the senior
officers in a concerted effort to chart the course of the bank's
planned growth over the next year. Annually, in September or
October, each senior officer in charge of a major group makes a
detailed projection of how the assets and liabilities under his or
her supervision are expected to evolve during the following

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

I. The Profit Plan

page43

page 44

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

calendar year, together with estimates of the expense and manpower needed to achieve the plan. The common input to planning at this stage is a forecast of the economy prepared by the
economics department. Also, there is a projection of one or more
key short-term interest rates, a projection often prepared with
advice from the lending, investment and fund-raising areas of
the bank.
The interest rate forecast is a basic input to the plan. Many
banks use the 3-month CD rate (scaled up for reserve requirements and deposit insurance) as the internal cost of funds to be
charged to the lending and investment operations; others include
a charge for the cost of capital as well. The same rate serves as
the internal rate credited to the fund-raising operation of the
bank; the difference between the adjusted CD rate and the projected rate at which it expects to borrow on all liabilities represents the profit margin expected from liability management. For
offshore loans, the London interbank offering rate for threemonth maturities - LIBOR - performs the same basic role in
internal accounting. (Borrowers are frequently given the choice
of tying their loans to the one-month, three-month, or six-month
Eurodollar rate.)
The loan and investment groups prepare detailed revenue estimates for their operations. They apply their own forecast earning rates, scaled up from the base rate forecast, to the average
portfolio they expect for a large number of loan and investment
categories. Forecasts by the economics department of the growth
of demand, savings and time deposits - and the likely interest
costs involved - provide the retail side of the bank with basic
information needed for its own plan.
The group plans give the chairman and president a first look at
how each senior officer sees his group's performance over the
next year. The expense forecasts are the first step in the internal
budget process. After detailed study of these tentative plans, top
management draws up expense guidelines to govern the next
stage of the process. When the group plans for acquiring assets
are combined, the liability manager may discover that he must
borrow more than he had originally planned. After a second pass
by the senior officers, the chairman and president review each
group's proposed plan for the year with the responsible officer,
making detailed suggestions for change. The planned growth of
the bank also may raise questions of capital adequacy, necessitating study of the relative merits of selling different types of

equity or debt and the most appropriate timing for such a move.
After a third pass at the planning material, the bank adopts a
formal profit plan for the year. Thereafter, the chairman and
president track the performance of each group in relation to its
own plan. Deviations are expected. If taxable income begins to
exceed plan, for example, new decisions will be needed on how
much income to shelter from taxation and the way it will be
done. A bank might increase its holdings of tax-exempt municipal notes or bonds beyond the levels provided for in the plan.
Other deviations may arise because economic activity and Federal Reserve policy evolve differently than expected. The plan
provides a common framework for making decisions, not a precise chart of the year's course.
The asset-liability committee (ALCO) is the focal point for the
continuing adjustment of the maturity and terms of the bank's
loans, investments and borrowings (see Chart 10, page 46). While
the chairman and president are usually members of the committee, it is often chaired by the senior officer who oversees the
investment portfolio and fund raising activities, the area of
greatest flexibility for changing the asset-liability mix of the
bank. In other banks, the treasurer or chief financial officer of the
bank may chair the committee. Other members include those in
charge of domestic and international lending, and, in some banks,
the chief trust officer. Another member is often the senior loan
officer, who chairs the credit committee, which establishes loan
terms and policies. The bank's chief economist and two or three
officers closely involved in the money market operations of the
bank round out the group.
In some banks ALCO meets weekly, in others once or twice a
month. In some it plays essentially a monitoring and coordinating role, a forum in which senior officers review the bank's global
balance sheet, the economic and interest rate outlook, the state
of loan demand, and avenues for adjustment. Decision making in
such banks remains the responsibility of individual group managers who are responsible to the chairman and president for
their function's performance. In others, ALCO meetings have detailed agenda, take up specific proposals for action, and hand
down binding guidelines for asset and liability operations. Such a
committee may even have its own secretary and a small staff.
In its regular meetings ALCO examines the possibilities for
maintaining, or improving, the positive rate spread between

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

2. ALCO-Organization and
Function

page 45

interest accruals and interest costs. In some banks the group also
reviews the bank's foreign currency exposure, and sets limits on
how far branches can be out of balance for the major currencies.
The committee usually focuses on a simplified global balance
sheet with perhaps 15 to 20 asset categories and a similar
number of liability groups. At some institutions, detail may be
available, if needed, on as many as 100 categories of each.

Chart JO ALCO Decision Making
Interest
Rate

Balance

Sheet

Forecast

Forecast

Pricing of Loans
(Fixed and/or
Variable)

Allocoting Funds
Jlcross Different
Maturity Dates

.Adjusting
Maturity

FED Watching

Meeting 'v\leekly

Reserve
Requirements

Managing Money
Market Loans
& Purchased Funds
(Repos.CDs & Funds)

In a volatile interest rate environment ALCO seeks to lock in
an interest rate spread and take measured risks in mismatching
the book. It accordingly groups both assets and liabilities with a
view to their sensitivity to interest rate changes. Loans might be
grouped into money market loans - including broker-dealer
loans, holdings of bankers' acceptances, and Eurodollar deposits
- and nonmoney market loans. The latter might be broken down
further between term loans, international loans and other loans.
Especially important is the pricing structure of these loans. A
two-year term loan may be illiquid but will not represent much
page 46


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

interest rate risk if it is repriced at intervals of three or six
months. Investments are broken down by type (Treasury, Federal
agency, municipal) and by maturity. On the liability side, major
groupings might be purchased funds, demand deposits, savings
deposits and foreign branch deposits. Purchased funds (including CDs) might include further subdivisions of Federal funds,
term funds with maturities of less than 14 days, and term funds
with longer maturities. The variability of costs with interest rate
changes is a primary concern.
A typical ALCO meeting involves a review of the bank's global
position, highlighting recent changes in the balance sheet. The
economist presents the latest projections of domestic economic
activity, supplemented at times by a similar review of other industrial economies. He also gives the group his current view on
interest rates, noting the extent to which rates are expected to
deviate from the profile incorporated in the annual profit plan.
This touches off a round robin discussion of interest rates; some
banks have participants give the probability they attach to forecasts of key rates 3 to 12 months hence. Against this background
ALCO takes up the outlook for loan demand, starting with the
projections prepared by the economics department. The lending
functions report major transactions in the pipeline and comment
on whether the projection is likely to prove too low or too high.
Often the key question is whether the bank's prime lending rate
for domestic business loans should be changed.
The discussion moves briskly from point to point and around
the room. Decisions on loan pricing affect not only the current
year's earnings, but also the longer term competitive position of
the bank. If the bank raises its posted rates, will it lose loan
customers to other banks? What is the trade-off between maintaining a wide rate spread over costs and the potential loss of
customers to the commercial paper market or foreign banks? To
cope with volatile interest rates, major banks have gradually
relied more heavily on market-based pricing, attempting to build
in a profitable spread between loan rates and bank costs. Customers have been given a range of borrowing options from which
to choose. An overnight rate is often quoted to large borrowers,
who draw on their bank lines for a few days to even out, or
supplement, their use of commercial paper. The rate quoted is
usually a markup over the Federal funds rate of about 25 basis
points plus an additional spread related to credit risk. Banks also

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

3. Shaping a profitable strategy

page 47

often quote fixed rates for loans lasting as long as 60 to 90 days,
basing the rate on the cost of CDs of corresponding maturity,
including the cost of reserve requirements and FDIC insurance.
Again, the base rate quoted the most creditworthy customers
would allow a profitable spread for the bank, and the spread
would increase with perceived credit risk. Finally, on term loans,
banks tend to give their customers several flexible rate options.
One option is prime rate pricing, in which the loan's cost rises or
falls with movements in the bank's prime rate. Other options
involve repricing at intervals of 30, 60, 90 or 180 days at a markup
over either the London inter-bank offering rate (LIBOR) or the
all-inclusive cost of domestic CDs of comparable maturity.
From ALCO's vantage point, market based pricing can help a
bank insulate its earnings from variations in interest rates. To do
so, the bank matches its loans with liabilities whose maturities
correspond to the dates for repricing the loan. ALCO can then
concentrate on whether the bank should mismatch its book in
view of the rate outlook. If it expects interest rates to be volatile,
ALCO tries to keep the bank's book in reasonable balance. A
rising rate outlook, if held with conviction, may lead to a
lengthening of liabilities; a falling rate outlook, to shorter funding. The objective of the exercise is to reduce the volatility of
bank earnings, while continuing to make interest rate judgments
at the margin that enhance earnings.
A schedule of maturing assets and liabilities spotlights decisions for ALCO that canot be delayed. Maturing Treasury securities provide one example. Is the bank to roll over its holding, add
to it, or let a major part mature? The coming maturities of
mortgage and other loans also offer an opportunity to change
the allocation of assets, or to improve bank liquidity, by reducing
the volume of purchased funds. The schedule of maturing term
Federal funds, time deposits, CDs, Eurodollars, and commercial
paper sold by the parent holding companies poses another set of
decisions. Does the outlook for interest rates and loan demand
suggest letting the volume of purchased funds decline? Or is now
the time to bid for 6-month CDs and Eurodollars in size, prefinancing the next six weeks of maturities in a single week?
ALCO's job is to produce an integrated strategy, which operates on both sides of the balance sheet. To assist its deliberations, the liability manager may prepare alternative plans for
action, showing the effect each would have on the interest rate
spread and bank earnings under different interest rate profiles.
page 48


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Many banks focus on the gap between interest-sensitive assets
and interest-sensitive liabilities in assessing their rate exposure.
For example, if there were a negative gap equal to 10 percent of
assets and the bank's net interest margin were 4 percent, then a
rise of 2 percentage points in the bank's interest costs would
reduce earnings by 5 percent. 2 Some banks have gone well beyond such a simplified gap analysis, constructing a model of the
bank's asset and liability structure line by line. ALCO can then
compute quickly the effects on earnings of projected changes in
interest rates, or of selling 6-month CDs compared to purchasing
Federal funds.
On the asset side, if ALCO concludes that interest rates are
topping out or heading lower, the bank can take the initiative holding bankers' acceptances in portfolio, taking on fixed-rate
term loans, relaxing mortgage terms, acquiring securities in the
market, and making fixed-term Eurodollar placements. The bank
also can enter futures contracts to acquire CDs, Treasury bills,
bonds and mortgage-backed securities of the Government National Mortgage Association (GNMA) - anticipating savings or
other money inflows. On the liability side, the bank can rely more
on Federal funds, short-term CDs, and Eurodollars to roll over
maturities and finance the asset buildup. By allowing the average
maturity of its liabilities to fall, it can increase the expected
favorable effect from falling interest rates. The bank can reduce

advertising of longer term savings certificates or even cease offering them if competitive conditions permit. If ALCO, instead,
expects interest rates to rise, alternative plans are likely to feature combinations of actions that extend maturities of bank
liabilities, reduce fixed-rate assets, and expand the share of floating rate assets in the portfolio.
The theory is reasonably straightforward, but forecasting
business loan growth and interest rates is a chancy business.
Major banks often have been disappointed by loan demand,
because larger companies use commercial paper or because
the economy is not as strong as expected. At other times, loan
demand is intense - for example when corporations seek to
defer long-term borrowing in the bond market.
Interest rates, too, can behave unexpectedly for extended
periods. The Federal funds rate and other short-term rates may
rise sharply, when the Federal Reserve seeks to moderate overly
2

See Sanford Rose, "Gleanings from a Major Study ", American Banker, January 5, 1982.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page49

rapid money supply growth, only to fall later when money growth
slows down. In any case, competitors are likely to form similar
expectations so that one must be agile to achieve a superior
performance. When interest rates are generally expected to rise,
that will be reflected in market yields; six-month CDs already will
cost more than three-month CDs and one-year CDs still more.
Seven-year Treasury notes acquired last year for the portfolio
will already be selling below cost. When ALCO decides to modify
the bank's asset-liability mix, it may be because it believes interest rates are going to rise higher or faster than the market as a
whole expects. But it could equally well be experiencing a surge
in loan demand peculiar to the bank or the need to bid on
five-year CD money from a petroleum exporting nation.
Increasing interest rate volatility has made ALCOs much more
cautious in recent years about assuming the interest rate risks
involved in banking. As noted earlier, banks have gravitated
toward market-based pricing formulas to reduce their exposure
to such risks. This shifts a major part of the risk to the borrower.
Banks must keep close check on the ability of their borrowers to
shoulder the interest rate risk; otherwise, they may find the
credit risk of loans is higher than they assumed. While borrowers
can hedge such risks, if they choose, in the financial futures
market, such hedging has largely been confined to commodities-oriented businesses that have experience in futures markets. Banks may well begin to hedge such risks more effectively
themselves in the futures markets as a means of offering business borrowers greater stability in the rates the banks charge.
In reaching decisions, ALCO members know that large banks,
like battleships, cannot turn on a dime. Changes in loan terms, in
particular, have to filter through the corps of loan officers with
whatever modifications are necessary in the interest of longstanding customer relationships. There are limits as well to the
speed with which large amounts of six-month or longer CDs and
Eurodollars can be sold. A big push can flood the market with
paper, inflict losses on the first dealers or customers to buy it,
and raise customer concerns if there are any problems associated with the name of the bank. Bankers keep a close watch on
their share of the market in everything from Federal funds to CDs
and Eurodollars so that they will have a good idea of what size
operations the market and customers will tolerate readily. Being
aggressive at times can even strengthen a bank's reputation for
astuteness. But overdoing CD sales repeatedly may necessitate
page 50


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

paying a premium rate, and once lost, a top quality standing is
hard to win back. ALCO's members will seek to avoid a course
that could cause the bank's good name to be questioned.
The task confronting ALCO is not unlike that facing the Federal
Open Market Committee. It must shape present strategy in the
light of its reading of the economic outlook with all the uncertainties and conflicting opinions involved. Its strategy must
capitalize on the bank's organizational strengths, but be flexible
enough to change promptly when its forecasts of loan demand
and deposit growth go awry. ALCO monitors the situation closely.
Mid-course corrections, once decided, depend importantly on
the skill of the bank's operators in financial markets. They must
not only carry out the strategic and tactical moves that affect the
markets, but also keep the policymakers informed of market
developments. The money desk may encounter market limits on
the volume of CDs it can sell, and thereby constrain the policymaker's freedom of action. Not surprisingly, ALCO's moves, like
the FOMC's, usually involve a series of moderate adjustments to a
well-plotted strategy rather than dramatic changes of direction.
In carrying out strategy, the money desk of the commercial
bank plays a vital role, one akin to the role of the trading desk at
the New York Reserve Bank in carrying out open market operations. Its workaday concerns have defensive and dynamic qualities of their own. Defensively, the money desk must manage the
bank's reserve position, seeing that reserve requirements are
covered for the statement week ending Wednesday - but with as
little uninvested excess as possible. Dynamically, the money desk
and its international counterpart must take on, and/or lay off,
funds in accordance with ALCO's changing strategy.
In its routine operations, the money desk projects the regular
ebb and flow of customer deposits and transactions affecting the
bank's reserve position. While such estimates provide a point of
departure, the money desk relies in the final analysis on an internal information network to spot big gains or losses to its reserve
account at its Federal Reserve Bank. These may result from net
deposit flows, customer transfers of funds by wire, loan extensions, or changes in the net financing needs of the investment
and trading areas of the bank.
The money desk can vary the terms it sets on collateralized
loans, or repurchase agreements, with dealers in government,
municipal and corporate securities. Changing the posted dealer

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Implementing Bank Strategy
- the Money Desk

page 51

loan rate is a time-honored means of adjusting position. The
money desk typically uses the bank's portfolio of Government
securities to offer corporate and other customers overnight or
term repurchase contracts (RPs ). Moreover, it also sells CDs for
the bank and commercial paper for the holding company. The
money desk directs the strategy for acquiring Eurodollar funds
for the head office through major foreign branches. It essentially
carries out the funding operations that are booked at branches in
the Nassau and the Cayman Islands for tax or other reasons. The
money desk also handles the funding of the bank's international
banking facilities in domestic centers, through which offshore
business can be serviced without the reserve requirement and
tax costs of domestic institutions.
The officer supervising the money desk directs daily tactics
within a weekly strategy, which in some banks is worked out with
the aid of a separate money position committee. Under lagged
reserve accounting, reserve requirements for each statement
week are calculated by applying the appropriate percentage to
the different categories of bank deposits on the books two
statement weeks earlier.3 Vault cash held two weeks earlier
counts toward meeting the requirements and there may be a
modest carryover deficiency or surplus from the preceding
statement week to take into account. What remains is the specific average balance to be maintained in the bank's Federal
Reserve account for the week beginning on Thursday.
The officer in charge - or the money position committee will pin down the approach to be used in rolling over CDs, commercial paper, and RPs, and in making dealer loans in the weeks
ahead. Adjusting the basic projections for these plans indicates
the amount of Federal funds that the desk will then need to
borrow on average in the interbank market during the week. The
bank's money market economist will also give his forecast of the
expected need for the Federal Reserve trading desk to add or
withdraw reserves from the banking system during the statement
week. If the Fed is expected to add a lot of reserves through RPs,
for example, that will often reduce dealer financing requirements
and ease the reserve positions of the major money market banks.
The group will discuss the likely course of the Federal funds rate
over the week. Finally, the officer-in-charge will decide whether
3
Under a proposed change to contemporaneous reserve accounting, the reserve maintenance period for checkable deposits will lag the reserve calculation period by two days.

page 52


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

the Federal funds trader is to err on the long, or the short, side in
daily operations early in the week. In this decision the officer will
bear in mind that a shortfall from expectations may well have to
be covered at the Federal Reserve discount window.
The Federal funds trader of a major bank usually starts each
day with an estimate of the bank's closing position at its Federal
Reserve Bank the night before. The trader may not be confident
of that position until noon, but the Federal funds market is in full
swing by 9:30 a.m. In the meantime, he or she may cover a
portion of the week's deficit under the approach already developed. At hand are estimates of the major transactions that will
go for, or against, the bank that day from RPs, CDs, or Eurodollars, as well as from customer and other transactions. The net
inflow from direct transactions in Federal funds with correspondent banks is reasonably predictable; hence he knows the remaining net amount that must be bought, or sold, in the broker's
market. The trader tries to gauge from broker comments and the
bank's own direct trades with out-of-town banks whether the
Federal funds rate is firm and likely to rise, or whether waiting a
bit will allow needs to be covered 1/4 or 1/2 of a percentage point
cheaper. He may even sell to put downward pressure on the rate
if he thinks he can buy back at a lower rate later in the day. As the
day goes on, the trader's own picture becomes clearer and he or
she tries to buy enough funds to come out about on target.
On Wednesday, of course, the trader has to bring the Fed
balance to a level needed to meet the average level required for
the week, after allowance for any excesses or deficiencies carried
in from the previous week. It is an especially tricky day. Reserves
in the system are likely to be either overly abundant with a
resultant tendency for the Federal funds rate to fall. Or they are
apt to be short, producing upward rate pressure. The trader's
success in contributing to bank profits depends importantly on
whether he or she can wind up more often than not in a position
to balance out with cheap money on easy Wednesdays, and avoid
having to pay up on tight Wednesdays. The Federal Reserve
serves as the lender of last resort on those occasions when the
bank finds itself suddenly short because of unexpected transactions, or the trader cannot find funds in sufficient volume late in
the day before the Fed's wires close. Or the bank's officers may
have concluded that they can risk borrowing at the discount
window because of their limited recourse to it in the recent past.
The dynamic role of the money desk is twofold. It feeds infor
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 53

mation to ALCO on Federal Reserve behavior and market attitudes, and it also executes ALCO's decisions to change the
bank's asset-liability mix. Fed-watching calls for projecting the
central bank's need to absorb or supply reserves if borrowings at
the discount window - and the Federal funds rate - are to remain about at the levels of recent weeks.
As treated more fully in Chapter 7, a money market economist
produces a running commentary on the Fed trading desk's actions. Projections of the weekly money supply data and the
cumulative trend of money growth help him decide whether the
desk is supplying nonborrowed reserves more, or less, aggressively in relations to the demand of banks for reserves to cover
their requirements. The economist also estimates how much the
pressure on the banking system will change in the weeks ahead
because of supply-determined changes in discount or surcharge
rates. ALCO members themselves keep abreast of what Federal
funds brokers, government securities dealers, and other Wall
Street analysts are thinking. Members will also have their own
reading of the current monetary and economic reports coming in
and the balance of views within the FOMC. But the view from the
firing line is important, both for its relevance to asset-liability
decisions, and for the real limitations the market may place on
the adjustments that can be carried out.
The money desk's execution of ALCO's decisions - the
dynamic part of its job - sometimes requires pressing toward
vague market limits of what a single bank can accomplish on its
own behalf in adding to, or extending, CD maturities. Each bank
tends to develop its own approach to liability management. Some
banks make every effort to confine CD and commercial paper
sales to customers served by their own sales force. They try to
build customer loyalty by splitting, in effect, the bid-ask spread
quoted by dealers in the secondary market. While this approach
aims at keeping down the floating market supply of the bank's
paper, nimble corporate treasurers can often take down paper
when rates are moving quickly for immediate resale at a profit
to dealers. Other banks prefer direct sales to customers, but
also mobilize on occasion the extensive sales forces of several
dealers to place a lot of paper quickly. Then they will post
higher rates and sell to all comers - dealers and customers
alike. Still other banks - especially regional ones - regularly
sell paper to dealers as a means of utilizing the dealers' sales
forces for distributing their paper. Within a bank's approach,
page 54


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

the money desk must maintain good relations with customers and dealers by trying to be fair.
A sense of market timing, and the courage of one's convictions,
are prerequisites for good performance in the highly competitive
world of liability management. Frequently, a bank will find that
another bank has beat it to the punch with an aggressive CD
program, thus forcing it to decide whether to push ahead and put
further upward pressure on rates. Alternatively, it may hold off
for a time, risking a decline in availability, or rise in rates, in
hopes that the market will settle back. Good managers learn
to reverse direction quickly when they make mistakes, but also
to push ahead aggressively when they catch the tide running
their way.
For the money desk - and the bank - the defensive and
dynamic aspects of operations fuse into a seamless pattern of
action. ALCO members, by virtue of their own management
responsibilities, track the strategic changes flowing from within
their subordinate groups. There is a daily flow of selected information and analysis from the money desk and the investment
areas to senior management. A few phone calls can win a change
of emphasis without a formal ALCO meeting. The money desk,
too, finds most dynamic changes mean doing a bit more, or a bit
less, in relation to maturing liabilities rather than a crash program to restructure liabilities en masse. Other market participants often will not be able to be sure of a bank's marginal
changes of emphasis since they will not know the maturities that
have to be funded. Over time the bank's views on the interest rate
outlook will be known and shape the market's judgment of management's astuteness. The money desk, in particular, represents
the bank to the financial markets, and its professionalism and
reputation will have much to do with a bank's standing in the
financial community.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 55

4

The Money Market

1

The money market is not one market but many interlocking
markets, in which borrowers raise funds to finance their operations. Conventionally, the money market is defined to include
debt maturities of up to one year while the capital market includes longer maturities and equity shares. In both markets specialists facilitate the original issuance of securities and stand
ready to buy and sell issues already outstanding (see Table 1,
page 57).
The money market helps the participants in the economic
process cope with the financial uncertainties they face in daily
life. First, it helps bridge differences in the timing of payments
and receipts in a market economy. Borrowers rely on it for seasonal or short-term cash requirements; lenders use it to even out
differences between the flow of loan repayments and the takedown of new loans. Secondly, the money market permits borrowers and lenders to time their use of the capital markets in accordance with their forecasts of long-term interest rates. Borrowers
can use the money market to postpone issuing long-term debt,
while lenders can place funds there temporarily when they expect investments in stocks or bonds to be more attractive later.
The money markets here and abroad also help international corporations and others to manage the risks of conducting business
and maintaining investments in many currencies.
For the Federal Reserve the money market serves still another
function, its point of entry for open market operations in Treasury and Federal Agency securities. Defensively, these operations
help the market to turn short-term assets into cash -to provide
liquidity to participants with highly variable needs for money.
Dynamically, open market operations seek to affect money and
credit growth through the money market in ways that will modify
the business cycle.
A key service of the money market is to convert short-term
assets to cash at an acceptable cost. Dealers have developed
over the years to provide that kind of liquidity to debt instruments, once they have been issued. In the early stages of financial development, banks provide various deposit options, and the
economic players have to manage their assets to meet their own
am particularly indebted in this chapter to Marcia Stigum's fine book, The Money
Market: Myth, Reality and Practice (Dow Jones-Irwin, Homewood, Illinois, 1978), for its
wealth of descriptive material on the operational practices of the different markets.
1
/

page 56


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Table 1: The Money Market

Instruments

Typical
Maturities

Principal
Borrowers

Secondary
Market

Federal Funds

Chiefly 1business day

Banks

None

Negotiable Certificates
of Deposit (CDs)
Bankers Acceptances

1, 2, 3 and 6 months

Banks

Active

90Days

Financial & bus. enterprises

Active

Eurodollars:
Time Deposits
(non-negotiable)
CDs (negotiable)

Banks
Overnight, 1 week &
& 1to 6 months

Banks

None

1to 6Months

Banks

Moderately
active

Treasury Bills

3 to 12 Months

U.S. Government

Very active

Repurchase Agreements

1Day, 1week, 3-6 months

Banks, securities dealers
other owners ofgovt's.

Very active primary
market for short maturities

Futures Contracts (Treasury
Bills, CD's, And Eurodollars)

3-18Months

Dealers, Banks (Users)

Active arbitrage with
cash market

Discount Notes

30-360Days

Coupon Securities

6-9 Months

Federally sponsored
agencies:
Farm Credit System
Federal Home Loan Banks
Federal National Mortgage Assn.

Active

Commercial Paper

30-270Days

Financial & bus. enterprises

Limited

Municipal Notes

30 Days to 1year

State & local gov ts.

Moderately active for
large issuers

Federal Agencies

Limited

probable needs or rely on bank credit. Today, active bank competition for funds in the market for bank reserves, CDs, Eurodollars,
and bankers' acceptances is a natural extension of the provision
of deposit services to garner balances. A holder of negotiable CDs
or other debt instruments no longer needs to wait until his asset
matures to get cash; he can sell the asset for cash to a dealer,

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 57

who buys and sells at a narrow spread. The greater the routine
activity in a sector of the money market, the smaller the transactions cost the investor incurs.
High grade borrowers use the market to borrow funds directly
from investors, emancipating themselves in the process from
being overly dependent on financial institutions. Business and
financial corporations, and Federally sponsored credit agencies
borrow in the commercial paper market. The U.S. Government
issues Treasury bills while the sponsored Federal agencies sell
other short-term paper. The dealer market in Treasury issues
encompasses the most active sector of the money market, and
its operations are described at length in the second half of
the chapter.
The money market is international in character. Banks of
many nations bid for dollar deposits and lend dollars throughout
the world. Foreign borrowers also raise funds in the bankers'
acceptance and commercial paper markets. Foreign central
banks and others hold U.S. dollar assets in large volume as a
cushion against the vagaries of international economic life.
The Functions of the

Money Market

page 58


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

The money market plays a key role in the operation of the U.S.
economy. The forces of supply and demand determine both the
rates of return on money and its close substitutes, and the costs
of short-term borrowing. Looking through the veil of intermediation, the ultimate borrowers include consumers buying on credit
and businesses financing inventories or new plants. Governmental units, as well as foreign corporations and governments, also cover their short- or long-term needs in the
financial markets. The ultimate sources of funds are the savings
of the various sectors from current income, augmented by the
monetary and credit expansion the monetary system makes
possible.
The money market and its institutions provide the public with
money or money substitutes in the process of moving funds from
savers to spenders in the economy. Commercial banks and thrift
institutions offer a great variety of retail deposit services to attract the working balances and savings of the society. They act as
intermediaries in the savings-investment process, accepting
demand and savings deposits on reasonably stable, advertised
terms and investing them in a variety of assets. Their ability to
collect funds at retail depends on their ability to place funds in
the loan markets they serve.

As noted in the previous chapter, commercial banks are particularly active in the wholesale money market, funding their
lending operations through CDs, Euro-dollars, bankers'
acceptances and commercial paper. Money market mutual
funds interpose another layer of intermediation, offering check
redemption privileges to their shareholders and charging management fees for investing in money market instruments. In the
wholesale market, banks and Government securities dealers offer
investors repurchase agreements (repos) at a competitive rate of
return by selling securities under contracts providing for their
repurchase from one day to several months later.
As money markets develop, high quality borrowers become
able to borrow directly from investors who want to hold an asset
with a high degree of moneyness, or liquidity. On average, over
the course of the interest-rate cycle, investors are willing to
accept a lower rate of return on short-term assets than on longer
term obligations, which carry a greater risk of loss if sold before
maturity. A borrower who has a top quality credit rating can
capitalize on this preference for liquidity by selling his shortterm obligations to investors at a lower rate than he would have
to pay a bank. The rate paid will reflect the creditworthiness of
the borrower, the taxability of the interest received, and supplydemand forces at work in the market. The pre-eminent direct
borrower is the United States Treasury, which auctions 3- and
6-month Treasury bills weekly and I-year bills every four weeks.
The Federally sponsored credit agencies issue commercial paper
and other securities to finance their own lending to farmers ,
savings and loan associations, and the housing industry. Finally,
an impressive array of private business and financial firms have
achieved credit ratings sufficiently high to make their commercial paper salable to investors either directly or through commercial paper dealers.
The money market's short-term credit facilities permit farmers, merchants and industrialists to finance the production and
distribution of their products. Government units can bridge timing differences between disbursements and tax receipts, while
consumers can use automatic credit facilities to cover spending
in anticipation of income. Borrowers are also constantly faced
with deciding whether to borrow short term or long term at
existing interest rates; even when borrowing is for capital investment, they can usually finance short term if they expect
interest rates to fall. Finally, international corporations and many

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 59

governments have to decide as well in which currencies to borrow and to maintain liquid assets.
Lenders confront the same issues. How much should be committed to the routine financing of consumer credit, business
working capital needs, or short-term government finance? What
margin of resources should be placed in the money market to
await better future opportunities in the stock and bond markets?
How much should asset portfolios be diversified by currency?
The money market exists, of course, to bring the demands for
short-term credit into balance with the funds available - at
interest rates that reflect credit risks and consensus expectations
of future interest rates and exchange rates.
The Federal Reserve exerts leverage on the financial system
and economic decision-making by changing the cost and availablility of the reserves available to the banking system. Open market operations provide the flow of nonborrowed reserves deemed
consistent with the central bank's annual monetary objectives,
while changes in the discount rate and reserve requirements
affect the cost of reserves to the banks. Monetary stimulation in a
recession involves maintaining the flow of reserves to the financial system; as credit demands subside, the Federal funds rate
and other short-term rates fall below long-term interest rates,
encouraging a pickup in monetary and credit growth that will
stimulate economic activity. The economic expansion itself spurs
demands for short-term credit and money, which interact wih the
nonborrowed reserves being supplied by the Federal Reserve.
Money market rates rise relative to rates on longer maturities
(see Chart 11 , page 61). As the cost of short-term debt rises,
economic participants economize on their holdings of money,
and businessmen manage more efficiently their inventories of
goods in process.
Interest rates alone are nonetheless a poor guide to whether
monetary policy is exerting stimulus or restraint because they
reflect the economy, as well as influence it. In a period of recession, for example, when businessmen shift from building inventories to reducing them, the decline in short-term interest rates
may well reflect the slowdown itself, rather than monetary policy
actions. If money and bank credit growth are sluggish, more
vigorous Federal Reserve efforts to pump in reserves and push
interest rates lower may be called for, provided inflationary expectations are under control. Similarly, periods of economic
boom bring their own rising credit demands and upward pres-

page 60


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

sures on interest rates. Monetary policy may not be sufficiently
restrictive if money and credit growth begin to accelerate. To be
effective, monetary restraint has to permit interest rates to rise
above existing expectations for inflation - in other words,
achieve positive real interest rates.
Chart 11 Interest Rates over the

Business Cycle
TBill c==J
20 Year Bond -

l

Economic cycle - peak to trough
Interest Rates
i

peak of
economic cycle

trough of
economic cycle

time

The Federal Reserve System and major commercial banks
around the country are the pumping stations that keep money
circulating in the U.S. economy, channeling it through the money
market to the points of greatest demand. The Federal Reserve
provides reserves flexibly to the banks. They and the money

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Banks and the Money Market

page 61

market provide money on demand in exchange for interest earning assets or IOU's. Having specified reserve requirements for
depository institutions, the System manages nonborrowed reserves to allow for seasonal fluctuations in money demand as
well as the growth desired by the FOMC. The discount window
serves both to buffer unforeseen stresses and to exert pressure
on interest rates when money demands are too strong or too
weak. The Federal Reserve's telegraphic network, over which
funds and Government securities move between banks, makes
the domestic money market a truly national one. The Reserve
Banks also maintain a national book-entry system for Treasury
securities. In some periods the Treasury and Federal Reserve also
have used operations in the market for dollars and foreign currencies to provide a degree of continuity to the rates at which
one currency can be exchanged for another.
The major banks participate in the money market themselves
and furnish the back office and credit facilities needed by the
nonbank players. The money market banks and their parent holding companies include eight or nine in New York and perhaps
twice as many in Chicago, San Francisco, and other major centers. They are the mainstays of the markets for Federal funds,
bankers' acceptances, CDs and Eurodollars. They are active also
in the markets for repurchase agreements (repos), bank commercial paper, and tax-exempt notes. Money market banks are
typically the principal domestic traders in the worldwide foreign
exchange market. Beyond this they provide deposit and safekeeping facilities to major corporations and others, helping them to
manage their cash and other assets efficiently. Many banks act as
dealers in money market securities, while others actively service
customer investment needs through a short-term investment
desk. A few banks in New York City serve dealers in money market instruments as clearing agents - receiving and delivering
securities for them against payment. Several city banks serve as
residual lenders to nonbank dealers in money market securities,
but out-of-town banks and nonbank customers account for the
major share of such lending.
Regional banks and affiliates of foreign banks are active, too, in
trading Federal funds and issuing CDs and bankers' acceptances.
The regional banks serve many local businesses and banks in
their own area, providing their customers with immediate access
to the international money market. The foreign banks provide the
same recourse to the U.S. money market for head offices and
page 62


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

global branch networks as well as for overseas clients and their
growing U.S. operations. While regional banks operate in the
foreign exchange markets, it is a major activity for the foreign
banks. Other U.S. banks are primarily customers of the money
market rather than movers and shakers.
Bank-centered components of the money market include the
Federal funds market, the CD and Eurodollar markets, and the
bankers' acceptance market. The markets in Treasury securities
and other short-term debt instruments are treated later in the
chapter.
Borrowing banks purchase ( or borrow) funds in this interbank
market to meet their reserve requirements in the short run or
finance loans and investments in the longer run. Such borrowings are subject neither to reserve requirements nor the legal
prohibition against paying of interest on demand deposits. 2 Lending banks typically view Federal funds sales as a part of their
liquidity, varying their sales with the ebb and flow of reserves
through their Federal Reserve accounts. Most banks tend to be
either net borrowers (buyers) or net lenders (sellers) of funds
more or less permanently, although some shift back and forth.
The net borrowers are typically asset-driven banks, which scour
the world for profitable loans and investments and then seek to

1. The Federal Funds Market

finance them as cheaply as possible. 3 The net lenders are more

likely to be liability-driven banks, operating in the textbook fashion of responding to the flow of funds attracted from customers.
The net sellers also typically include nonmember and resident
foreign banks, thrift institutions, credit unions, Federally sponsored credit banks, and international banking institutions - institutions defined as banks for this purpose by the Board of
Governors. The latter institutions often keep a part of their liquidity in the Federal funds market. The call report of the Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) indicated Federal funds
sold and securities purchased under overnight repos were $146
billion at the end of 1981.
2
/n October 1979 purchases of Federal funds from nonmembers and other banks were
included in the managed liabilities of member banks, and made subject to a marginal
reserve requirement. The distinction was later dropped.

See Paul Meek and Jack W Cox, "The Banking System - Its Behavior in the Short Run';
Essays in Domestic and International Finance (Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 1969),
pp. 50-57.
3


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 63

As noted in Chapter 3, the funds market is a bank's first line of
defense in meeting its reserve requirements in the statement
week, which ends on Wednesday; its protective backstop is the
discount window of its Reserve Bank. Each bank must maintain
reserves for the week equal to a specified proportion of its demand and time deposit liabilities during the statement week that
ended two weeks earlier.4 The cash held in its vaults two weeks
earlier counts toward the requirement, leaving the rest to be
made up by average deposit balances held at the Reserve Bank.
Failure to meet requirements involves a penalty rate on deficiencies incurred as well as the displeasure of the Reserve Bank.
Member banks are permitted to carry over deficiencies of up to
2 percent of required reserves, provided they cover them by a
corresponding surplus in the following week; surpluses can be
carried over to the same limited extent.
The Federal funds market operates over the telephone. The
participating banks deal as principals while a half dozen brokers
help match the banks needing funds with those in temporary
surplus. Perhaps 100 or so major banks, asset-driven institutions
in daily search of funds, are willing buyers from their correspondent banks on a regular open account basis; they also make
accommodative sales of funds as needed. Typically, on purchases
ranging upward from $50,000 to many millions of dollars, the
banks will pay correspondents either the bid rate or somewhat
less; they tend to sell to correspondents at the offered side of the
market. Since most loans are unsecured, banks maintain credit
limits bank by bank on the amount they will lend. In practice,
most correspondents sell on a daily basis, reducing or increasing
such sales as required to balance their own position. Regional
banks, too, cultivate smaller correspondent banks to garner the
reasonably stable flow of funds available from such liabilitydriven institutions.
Brokers provide an essential service to the several hundred
banks that are regular participants. The major Federal funds brokers take bids and offers from banks by phone, typically in
amounts of $5 million or more, charging each party to the trade
50 cents per $1 million. The broker notifies each participant to a
4
The two-week lag between the reserve calculation and reserve maintenance periods was
introduced in 1968. In 1983 the reserve maintenance period is to be extended to two weeks
ending on alternate J#?dnesdays, while the reserve calculation period for checkable deposits will end two days earlier.

page 64


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

trade. The selling bank then notifies its District Reserve Bank to
debit its account and wire the funds to the buying bank. The
transaction is typically reversed the next day and the interest is
paid ( see Chart 12).
Chart 12 Fed Funds Transaction

;=.

<

<

:

!;

~~

"

~

/.,,

~ :~~~

Y..

,

.
~

(with Broker)

bids

_:{'.

. ~~ .
~~ ::•! ~,~;~:1~~~

notifies

The transaction is reversed •
the following day.

"'

7.

Uires funds to
buying bank's
account at
its district
reserve bank

Brokers keep participants posted on the current rate at which
Federal funds are trading and how they see the market "15 per
cent bid -15 1/4 per cent offered, better bid than offered," might
be the call. A broker will try to get bidders to step up their rate or
sellers to accept a lower rate, when his sheets reflect a heavy
concentration on one side or the other. The brokers keep the
domestic trading desk of the New York Reserve Bank informed
throughout the day of the balance between supply and demand.
They may also give customers their best judgment as to the
Federal Reserve's possible intervention to affect reserves. And
they quickly report any evidence of Reserve Bank action. Daily
volume of the brokers reporting to the Federal Reserve Bank of
New York was about $30 billion near the end of 1981.
Most activity in the market involves purchases and sales for
one business day, but trading for future delivery and for an extended term also takes place. Trading for future delivery used to

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 65

be substantial when banks were arbitraging between the Eurodollar and Federal funds markets around weekends.5 This activity,
made profitable by the savings on reserve requirements it produced, declined substantially after the Federal Reserve asked
banks in late 1980 to refrain from such activity. The move of
the New York Clearing House Association to the same day settlement of transactions in late 1981 made such arbitrage activity
more difficult.
The market for term Federal funds is a wholesale market, involving maturities of a few days to several months. To domestic
banks, buying funds for a 30-, 60-, or 90-day term is equivalent to
the sale of a CD, except that such a borrowing does not carry
reserve requirement and deposit insurance costs. Banks can thus
pay a higher rate to other banks than if they were selling their
own CDs. Resident foreign banks often place funds raised abroad
in this way when the rate spread is favorable. Some banks
situated abroad, including central banks, lend Federal funds
whenever the rate is higher than that available on repurchase
agreements. Savings and loan associations, and the supervising
Federal Home Loan Banks, also use the term funds market to
invest liquid reserves. Domestic commercial banks at times sell
term funds when they think they would be able to cover the sale
daily in the overnight market at a profit, but this approach has
often proved costly when interest rates rise.

2. The CD Market

Since its introduction in 1961, the negotiable bank certificate of
deposit, or CD, has served domestic banks as a major source of
funds. Banks borrow through CDs principally from nonbanks.
The CD offers investors a higher market rate of interest than a
U.S. Treasury bill, together with the liquidity provided by an
active secondary market (see Chart 13, page 67). CDs form an
important segment of the short-term portfolios of corporations,
state and local governments, foreign central banks, and other
financial entities, including money market mutual funds. The
success of the domestic CD has been followed by the growth of
an active market for Eurodollar CDs, first in London and later
in New York. There is also a growing market in New York for the
This provided a cash item in process of collection on Friday, which is deductible from
deposits. The 3-day savings this afforded on reserve requirements was only partly offset by
a one-day increase in deposits on Monday when a cashier's check was used to repay the
loan.
5

page 66


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

CDs of resident foreign banks, known as Yankee CDs. Moreover,
large domestic savings and loan associations have also become
issuers.
The CD market proper consists of the issuing banks, the dealers making markets in CDs to banks and investors, and the investors themselves. The issuing banks are divided by the market
into a number of tiers. CDs of the top tier of about ten major
domestic banks command the lowest rates and the most active
secondary market. The second tier contains another 10 or 20
banks that may have to pay 10 to 20 basis points more than the
top tier. Their CDs are actively traded, but at somewhat wider bid
and offer spreads than the first tier; dealers are a bit more reluctant to position them. The third tier includes regional and resident foreign banks whose CDs trade reasonably frequently but
20 to 50 basis points higher in rate than the first tier. Yankee
CDs and those of large savings and loan associations - chiefly
in California and Florida - usually trade at or above the rate
prevailing on regional bank CDs. Many other banks issue
CDs primarily to local businesses and government units and
these appear infrequently in the secondary market. The yield
spreads from the top banks to other issues typically widen in
unsettled markets and close when markets are steady or rates
are declining.
The market is essentially a negotiated one between banks and
their customers. The active banks post the rates at which they
are prepared to accept deposits for the most popular maturities
-1, 2, 3 and 6 months. Major banks usually have a small sales
force to keep up with customer needs and to call around quickly
if the bank decides to sell a large volume by offering an attractive
rate. CDs that enjoy a secondary market are typically issued and
redeemed in New York City; out-of-town banks do so through
their correspondents. Such CDs usually are issued in $5 million
units at par with interest paid at maturity, although $1 million
pieces are common; pieces as small as $100,000 are issued, but
trade at price concessions in the secondary market. CDs sold at a
discount like Treasury bills have also made their appearance.
Three- and six-month CDs are the most popular, and marketable,
maturities.
Variable rate CDs are actively issued because of the advantages they possess for both the buyer and the issuer. They generally offer a monthly or quarterly markup over the secondary

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Chart 13 Rates: 3 Month CDs vs

Federal Funds

peak of

economic cycle

trough of

economic cycle

Federal Funds Rate 3 Month CD Rate C=::J

page 67

market rate on one- or three-month CDs reported by the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York. For example, a six-month variable
might consist of six one-month CDs, each bearing a rate 15 basis
points higher than the one-month secondary rate on the issuedate; repricing at the same spread would occur on five subsequent monthly dates. The buyer then has an instrument that
will trade near par because it is always within a month of resetting at a market rate, a feature very attractive to money market
mutual funds and others who do not want to speculate on interest rates. The issuer is able to borrow money more cheaply than
on a straight six-month CD. Banks also issue rollover CDs (the
"roly poly"), providing the buyer with a series of six-month CDs
covering three years or longer with a uniform rate on each
maturity that is slightly lower than the rate at which the bank
would sell the longer maturity. The six-month maturities offer
greater liquidity in the secondary market, but the market risk of
a fixed coupon is about the same as for the longer maturity
instrument.
About 30 dealers are reasonably active in making a secondary
market in CDs. Over half are nonbank firms, most of them active
in Treasury securities and other short-term instruments. Bank
dealers also make markets in CDs, though Federal Reserve regulations prevent a bank from buying back its own CDs. Dealers
normally maintain inventories of the first, and some second tier,
names for their retail customers, financing them through bank
loans or repurchase agreements. Financing rates are generally
higher than those prevailing on Treasury securities, in recognition of their lesser marketability and somewhat greater credit
risk. Dealers quote bid and offer spreads to retail customers that
range upward from 10 basis points depending on market conditions. The market is very competitive. Large customers, such as
the money market mutual funds , can often buy secondary issues
at 2 or 3 basis points below the bid side of the market.
Dealers manage the interest rate risk of their positions by
active trading with customers and other dealers and by hedging
positions in the cash or futures markets. Daily transactions in the
dealer market averaged about $5 billion at the end of 1981. Dealers actively engaged in the secondary market often use brokers
to trade with each other. The top ten names constitute good
delivery on interdealer runs, while other names are traded "off
the run". Dealers hedge positions by going short Treasury bills in
either the cash or future market. The hedge is far from perfect,
page 68


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

since bill and CD rates often move by quite different amounts. In
1981 trading began in a futures contract for the CDs of top-name
banks with trading most active on the International Money Market in Chicago.
The Federal Reserve Act in 1913 authorized U.S. banks for the
first time to engage in acceptance financing of the domestic and
foreign trade of their customers. Nurtured by the Federal Reserve, the market in bankers' acceptances burgeoned to finance
a significant share of trade denominated in dollars, involving the
U.S. and foreign countries (see Box A, pages 70-71). Federal Reserve regulations continue to govern the issuance of most acceptances, limiting their use to short-term, self-liquidating
commercial transactions. Acceptances in excess of 100 percent
of the bank's capital and surplus are subject to Federal Reserve
requirements, an effective limit on the amount of acceptance
credit extended.
The bankers' acceptance available from banks or the dealer
market is a prime short-term investment since both the bank and
its customer are legally obligated to pay it at maturity. Acceptances are written in round lots of $1 million to $5 million
with still larger transactions usually broken into a number of
such pieces for ease in marketing to major investors; pieces
down to $25,000 are a popular outlet for individual investors
when interest rates are high. Over 20 firms make active markets,
buying acceptances from the accepting banks and retailing them
to corporations, government agencies, foreign investors, banks,
and other financial institutions. Secondary market trading of the
larger pieces has grown significantly with dealers typically quoting a bid-offer spread of 10 basis points. Dealers also use brokers
to facilitate trading with other dealers, preserving their own
anonymity; the cost is one basis point to the originator of the
trade. Dealers finance their positions with bank loans or repurchase agreements with a wide variety of investors.
Bankers' acceptances, like CDs, trade in a tiered market that
reflects principally the size of the accepting banks. The first tier
consists of about ten of the larger banks. Beyond that there is a
broad amorphous grouping of perhaps 50 banks - including
some foreign branches and agencies as well as the Edge Act
Corporations of banks outside New York. Acceptances of these
banks trade at rates ranging from 1/8 to 1/2 percentage points
higher than top tier banks. A smaller group of banks trade in
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

3. Bankers' Acceptances

page 69

Box A Financing Through

Bankers' Acceptances
Chart14

-

GOODS
- - - - - - (NOW) - - - - - --

If an Importer and an Exporter arrange a
delayed payment transaction, the seller
must assume the risk that the buyer
may be unable to pay.. .

but if the same basic transaction is
arranged with a bank guaranteeing
payment, the risk is transferred
to the bank.
Substantial Credit Risk
Minor Credit Risk
•
Typically an acceptance is purchased (discounted) first by
the accepting bank and then
resolli (rediscounted) to
another investor.

CASH

(LATER)

f

i;ic_

15

~ =uMEN~
/P
.

(LATER)~ .. ... . .
.._
~

(N:~EPTED
TIME DRAFT
(NOW)
ACCEPTANCE

(~) ~

Chart reprinted from William Melton and
Jean Mahr, "Bankers' Acceptances';
Quarterly Review (Federal Reserve Bank
of New York), Summer 1981 p 40.

CASH
(NOW)

(Nt

[
MATURED---ACCEPTANCE
(LATER)

frequently at even wider spreads. Japanese agency banks are
notable participants, financing at a premium rate not only trade
between Japan and the U.S., but between Japan and other countries as well. Other originators are the Edge Act subsidiaries of
major U.S. banks, which conduct international business for the
parent company.
The Federal Reserve remains an important factor in the
acceptance market. Its regulations establish the elibigility of
acceptances either for sale to the Federal Reserve trading desk
under repurchase agreement or for discounting at the discount
windows of the Reserve Banks. Eligibility at the window is limited
to transactions involving original maturities of six months or
less for foreign and domestic trade, or for storage. Also eligible
are dollar-exchange acceptances drawn by approved countries

page 70


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

In the course of international trade, importers and exporters
find it advantageous to organize transactions in such a way that
the importer does not pay until a specified date in the future.
However, in the absence of information on the creditworthiness
of the importer, the exporter may be reluctant to extend the
credit. Bankers' acceptances are financial instruments which
bridge this difficulty; they substitute the bank's creditworthiness
for that of the importer. The bank acts as intermediary by
guaranteeing to make the payment for the goods on the specified
date. The bank guarantees payment by "accepting" a time draft
( or order to pay) drawn on it by the exporter. The bank charges
the importer a fee, which is usually about 50 basis points but
may be larger or smaller, depending on competitive conditions
and the creditworthiness of the importer. The accepting bank
either sells the acceptance at a discount to a dealer in the secondary market or holds it in its portfolio as an investment.
In either case the exporter receives immediate payment for
his shipment. At maturity the bank receives payment from the
importer and pays the holder of the acceptances (see Chart 14,
page 70) Acceptances are also used to finance trade between
foreign countries as well as other transactions.

for three months or less to finance seasonal needs. Reserve
requirements apply to bills originally written to mature in
over six months, and to finance bills issued to raise working
capital.
For over 60 years the Federal Reserve trading desk in New York
was an active buyer of acceptances for the System's own account. In 1977 the Federal Open Market Committee decided that
its active support of the market was no longer necessary. The
System continues to buy acceptances under short-term repurchase agreements when this suits its reserve management purposes. The trading desk also buys acceptances outright for
foreign central banks on their instructions, but the New York
Reserve Bank no longer guarantees them for such accounts
as it did before late 1974.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 71

4. The Eurodollar market

The U.S. money market is the national component of a global
money market denominated in dollars. The international dimension is provided by the Eurodollar market, in which banks of all
nations, the Eurobanks, take dollar deposits maturing from the
next day to 5 years or more in the future. The market has two
main components. On the one hand, the banks bid for the deposits of international corporations, investors, and governmental
units to fund the loans being made to businesses and governments. On the other, the banks bid for the deposits of other
banks, or place funds with them, using the interbank market to
manage the balance between the maturities of their assets and
their liabilities. The Eurobanks - which include the foreign
branches and international banking facilities of U.S. banks operate outside the reserve requirements and FDIC assessments
that affect U.S. domestic banks. Accordingly, they can take deposits maturing within 14 days and pay depositors a higher interest
rate than U.S. banks for the same all-inclusive cost. The
Eurobanks are a very dynamic element in the world monetary
system by virtue of this competitive advantage.

Chart 15 Rates: Eurodollar vs
3 Month CDs

International banks use the Euromarket to finance the major
part of the overseas lending in dollars done by, or booked at, their
foreign branches. The Euromarket also provides a significant
source of financing for domestic banking operations in periods of
heavy loan demand; it is also an important outlet for surplus
funds, when domestic lending opportunities fall off. U.S. banks,
and resident foreign banks, help keep Eurodollar rates closely
parallel to those in the domestic money market. Changes in Federal funds, and other short-term U.S., rates rapidly affect the
Eurodollar market. Both the overnight rate and the key 6-month
Eurodollar rate move in tandem with their domestic counterparts
( see Chart 15).
The mainstay of the Eurodollar market in London and around
the world is the non-negotiable, fixed-term time deposit. The
major banks post the rates at which they are willing to bid for,
and offer, deposits of the most popular maturities - money on
call, overnight, one week, 1 to 6 months, and 1 to 5 years. In
London, a 15 3/4 - 5/8 quote for 6-month money indicates that
the bank is willing to place money at 15 3/4 percent or pay 15 5/8
percent. Banks do a sizable volume of business directly with
customers, raising the bid if more funds are needed. The bulk of
deposits taken are within one year, but multiple year maturities

peak of

economic cycle

Eurodollar Rate
C=:J CDRate

page 72

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

trough of

economic cycle

are considerably more common than in the domestic CD market,
partly reflecting placements by members of OPEC.
In contrast to the U.S. CD market, brokers play a major role.
They work assiduously to bring bidders and placers of funds
together, compensated by a fee of 0.02 percent - 2 basis points,
from each party. Placements typically range upward from $1 million to as high as $50 million. A handful of British firms with large
staffs provide up-to-the-minute information on the market to the
several hundred banks operating in the market. Their telephones
and telexes link them to participants all over the world. The
market follows the sun from regional centers in Singapore and
Hong Kong to Bahrain, on to London and continental centers,
and then to New York.
The U.S. banks are major players, both through their overseas
branches and the head office, which in most cases controls the
global "dollar book". The head office generally conducts the
funding side of the off-shore operations booked in Nassau,
Cayman Islands, and Panama branches - which operate on New
York time. Beginning in December 1981 U.S. and foreign banks
became able to conduct international operations in international
banking facilities (IBFs), which were freed from U.S. reserve
requirements and taxation. Banks in the European Economic
Community, Japan, the eastern bloc, OPEC, and the developing
countries are also important participants as bidders for, or placers of, funds.
The negotiable Eurodollar CD, introduced in 1966, has become
increasingly popular among U.S., and to a lesser extent, continental investors. Patterned after the domestic instrument, Eurodollar
CDs are usually issued for maturities of one year or less in
minimum pieces of $1 million. They are delivered and held in
London, and paid in New York by telegraphic transfer from the
London issuers. Branches of U.S. banks are the principal issuers,
but British banks and branches of Canadian, continental and
Japanese banks are also important. The negotiability feature
enables most banks to sell CDs at rates below those prevailing
on time deposits of similar maturity; the savings ranges upward
from 25 basis points. Eurodollar CD rates are generally 25 basis
points or so higher than those on domestic CDs, but the spread
can be wider on occasion. The spread reflects the absence of
reserve requirements on the issuing branch, the lesser marketability, and the possibility that the host government could
restrict the withdrawal of funds. (At times, U.S. banks have

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 73

incurred a reserve requirement on funds repatriated to the
head office.)
London branches of U.S. investment firms, as well as British
merchant banks and discount houses, provide a secondary market that is active, but less so than the domestic CD market. The
U.S. firms have a dominant position because a very large share of
Eurodollar CDs - reportedly above three quarters - are sold to
corporations, banks, and a wide range of other short-term investors in the United States. British firms have sought to expand
their U.S. sales through establishing New York outposts or entering joint ventures with domestic U.S. dealers. The quoted bidasked spread in the secondary market is usually 10 basis points
with $1 million the basic trading unit. Settlement is made in New
York in clearing house funds two days after the trade, but delivery and custody of the CDs are in London. U.S. dealers also make
an active market in New York for these Eurodollar CDs.

The Nonbank Money Market
1. The Treasury Market

page 74


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

a. The Stock in Trade: Government Securities. The U.S. Treasury is the pre-eminent issuer of short-term paper in the money
market. Each week on Monday, or the preceding Friday when
Monday is a holiday, the Treasury sells a pre-announced amount
of 3- and 6-month bills. Bids are received up to 1:30 p.m. Eastern time at each of the 12 Federal Reserve Banks and their 24
branches. Noncompetitive tenders are accepted up to a specified size limit, to be awarded at the average price of competitive bids. Competitive bidders specify in their tenders the price
that they are willing to pay in Federal funds on Thursday of that
week in return for the Treasury's promise to pay par at maturity.
A dealer in Government securities, for example, might tender for
$10 million par value of 6-month bills at a price of 93.933 involving a payment of $9,393,300 against the Treasury's obligation to pay $10 million six months hence. The discount earned
would be equivalent to a rate of discount of 12 percent of the
face value of the bills, figured on the 360-day basis used by all
money market instruments. Converted to simple interest on the
amount of money actually invested on a 365-day basis, the
bond equivalent yield would be 12.95 percent (see Chart 16,
page 75).
Each Reserve Bank office wires to the Treasury the dollar volume of bids received at each price and the amount of noncompetitive bids. The Treasury announces late in the day the lowest
price at which bids have been accepted for each bill (the stop-

out price), the average price for each ( at which the noncompetitive awards were made), and the corresponding rates of
discount and bond equivalent yields. Every four weeks the Treasury sells a 52-week bill, usually called a year bill, in a similar
auction.
The Treasury's regular bill auctions are an important part of its
program for managing the U.S. public debt, which stood at $1
trillion at the end of 1981. The marketable debt, which is traded in
an active secondary market, accounted for about three quarters
of this. The remainder consisted of nonmarketable securities for example, savings bonds and those sold principally to Government investment accounts and foreign governments.
In addition to bills, the marketable debt includes notes and
bonds, which typically bear semiannual interest coupons and are
redeemed at par at maturity. Notes have an original maturity of
up to ten years, bonds a maturity of over ten years. In its orderly
management of the debt, the Treasury routinely auctions 2-year
notes each month; 4- to IO-year notes, as well as 15- to 30-year
bonds, are sold quarterly. In auctions of coupon securities, bidding is usually on the basis of yield to maturity; after the auction
the Treasury establishes the coupon rate that produces an issue
price slightly below par.

Chart 16 Rates: 3 Month T Bills vs

Federal Funds

Treasury securities, stretching from the bills maturing on the

next Thursday to 30-year bonds, give the investor ample choice
for meeting his own maturity requirements. The secondary market for these issues provides the reference yield curve for all
participants in both the money and capital markets. Treasury
issues are held chiefly in book entry form at the regional Reserve
Banks and can be readily transferred over the Federal Reserve
wire network to buyers throughout the country.
For investors, Treasury bills offer a security free of credit risk, a
matchless secondary market, and income exempt from state and
local taxes. Banks, thrift institutions, and other financial businesses use bills as a basic element of a liquid portfolio for meeting seasonal and other predictable demands for funds as well as
for coping with unexpected financial drains. Business corporations and state and local government bodies use Treasury bills as
income earning investments. Foreign central banks hold a large
share of their dollar exchange assets in such bills, the better to
cope with sudden adverse swings in their international payments. Finally, the Federal Reserve System finds Treasury bills

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

peak of

economic cycle

trough of

economic cycle

Federal Funds Rate T Bill c==]

page 75

page 76

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

ideally suited to the management of bank reserves. The secondary market is so large that the trading desk can buy or sell large
amounts of Treasury bills with little impact on bill rates.
b. The Role of Dealers. The secondary market in Government
securities is an over-the-telephone market, in which about three
dozen dealers stand ready to bid for, and offer, Treasury issues.
The dozen or so bank dealers and the 20-25 nonbank dealers
that make up the market have one thing in common. They deal
for their own account, putting their capital at risk. In the most
actively traded Treasury bills, competition is keen. The spread
between the bid and asked markets quoted retail customers is
often only 2 basis points - $50 per million dollars on a 3-month
maturity. Most dealers are prepared to make markets on the
telephone for $5 or $10 million of each issue to a total of
perhaps $50 million; the larger dealers will often deal for up to
several hundred million dollars. The primary dealers use half a
dozen brokers to post anonymous bids and offers on issues
they wish to trade; the broker is compensated by the dealer
who hits a bid or takes an offering. Market spreads widen with
maturity since the risk of price fluctuation increases. Many
firms keep a lower profile in issues maturing beyond two years
or so. Still, almost half of the dealers maintain markets of respectable size in securities maturing in five years or beyond.
The market in even the longest issues is second to none among
capital markets around the world. In recent years the developing futures markets in bills and bonds have often had consid.erable impact on the cash market.
Government securities dealers operate three interlocking
businesses. They make markets to customers and provide information, analysis and advice to stimulate trading activity and
customer loyalty. To be able to meet customer needs, they maintain inventories of Government and other securities in which
they deal, financing them with bank loans or repurchase agreements with corporations or other lenders. Finally, they manage
their securities positions with a view to profiting from both
short- and long-term swings in interest rates.
Profitability in a dealer firm stems from the three businesses:
(1) trading profit from the day-to-day astuteness of traders earning the spread between bid and offer prices in trading with customers and other dealers, (2) financing or "carry" profit from
earning a higher return on securities owned than the cost of
financing the securities, and (3) position profit from being short

securities in falling markets and being long in rising markets, or
from correctly anticipating changes in the shape of the yield
curve. In practice, dealers are more apt to think of profits as
stemming either from trading or arbitrage. Arbitrages can be
quite complicated - involving the cash and futures markets as
well as different financing strategies. Many dealers have in-house
traders who specialize in such transactions which may be kept
separate from the trading positions of those making markets
to customers.
For most dealers, maintaining a sizable customer base is essential. Knowledge of what customer preferences are, what securities they hold, and what they are doing, or thinking of doing,
enables the dealer to make markets intelligently, to judge the
likely market impact of prospective news developments, and to
manage his own positions profitably. The key people in the effort
are the trader, who must make his markets close enough to do
business, and the salesman, who keeps the customer in touch
with the market and the firm in touch with its retail base. Many
nonbank firms have branches in important domestic and international centers to maintain close personal contact with both large
and small customers; some of the major brokerage firms also
draw in retail customers through the registered representatives
in their large network of stock-oriented branches. Other nonbank dealers, and most of the banks, rely principally on direct
telephone or telex contacts, followed up with periodic personal
visits. Leased wire information systems, which keep the customer abreast of the latest market and news developments, have
greatly reduced the need for routine informational calls by
salesmen. The sales effort has shifted toward providing computerized information on trading spreads and arbitrage possibilities,
as well as up-to-the minute analyses of economic developments
and the Federal Reserve's policy posture. The rapid availability of
information and analysis has eroded somewhat the dealers'
comparative advantage in day-to-day trading. But dealers' bidasked margins have widened to reflect the greater volatility in
interest rates that followed the Federal Reserve's adoption of a
supply-oriented approach to reserve management.
The financing of dealer positions is a business that has developed a new life of its own. Years ago, the dealer searched out the
cheapest source of financing to increase the positive interest
rate "carry" earned on his position (or to reduce the negative
carry in periods of high interest rates). Both bank and non bank

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 77

dealers developed the sale of Government and Federal agency
securities to corporations and other lenders under agreements to
repurchase the securities a day, a week, or several months later
at the same price plus an agreed rate of interest for the period.
Such repos allowed investors to earn a return on very short-term
money whereas banks could then pay no interest on deposits of
less than 30 days. The financing cost to the dealer was typically
below the Federal funds rate or the dealer loan rates posted by
the major banks - usually by an appreciable amount. Most lenders allowed the dealers the right of substitution of collateral, so
that the dealer could sell securities on demand, replacing them
with others.
Recently, bank and nonbank dealers have run matched books as
well. They buy Government securities for an extended period
under a reverse repo from a holder who needs funds. Then they
repo the securities acquired for an equivalent period at a lower
interest rate than they charge the seller. In effect, dealers have
gone into the banking business, taking care that the credit quality
of both customers assures the reversal of the transaction, which
carries no risk of price fluctuation. Dealers also protect themselves by taking a greater margin of collateral on the securities
acquired than they give when putting them out on repo. Dealers
may also run an "unmatched book" - financing securities acquired under 60- or 90-day reverse repos with shorter term repos
to increase the interest rate spread earned. Such activity runs the
risk, of course, that financing costs may rise in the interim and
result in a loss rather than a profit.
Dealer position-taking is basically a bet on the future course of
interest rates. The unmatched book is a bet on future financing
costs, since the resale value of the securities is fixed in the
original contract, the reverse repo. In a straightforward position
play, a dealer may purchase six-month Treasury bills in the auction, expecting to finance at a positive carry for 3 months and
sell them at three months to maturity for a 20 basis points gain,
about the average difference between 3- and 6-month bills rates
over the cycle. If interest rates fall over the interval, both the
carry earned and sales gain would be larger. But if interest rates
rose sharply, the carry could become negative at the same time
the price of the bill is declining. All straight position decisions
involve weighing the expected behavior of both dealer financing
costs and the prices of Government securities.
Government securities dealers are hypersensitive to the inter-

page 78


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

est rate outlook because their positions at risk can be very large
relative to their equity. A multiple as large as 50, aside from the
matched book, is not uncommon for a nonbank dealer expecting
a decline in interest rates. A one percent rise in the price of
securities held in such a situation would increase the dealer's
capital by 50 percent; a similar drop would wipe out half of
present capital. In practice, dealers tend to make substantial
gains during recessions when rates decline through acquiring
and financing an outright position. When interest rates are
choppy or rise persistently, however, dealers often encounter
moderate-to-large losses-in part, because it is difficult to maintain the effective markets customers expect with a sizable net
short position. Moreover, borrowing securities to sell short requires pledging other securities and paying a borrowing fee of
1/2 percentage point or more - imposing costs that require securities prices to fall promptly for the dealer just to break even.
Two recent market innovations have made going short significantly cheaper. First, there has been the growth of the repo
market for specific securities. Dealers bid for the securities they
want to sell short, lending the cash generated by a short sale at
a rate generally 20 to 50 basis points below the repo rate prevailing for Treasury issues. The net cost is usually cheaper than
the standard borrowing fee-collateral route. Secondly, an active
futures market in Treasury bills has developed on the Interna-

tional Monetary Market (IMM) in Chicago and in bonds and
GNMA securities on the Chicago Board of Trade (CBT). 6
Through these contracts, dealers can offset the positions they
must maintain to service customers - or establish short positions - by entering futures contracts to deliver the specified
securities at a limited number of specified dates, which reach
out over two years. The commission cost is very small - an
outside limit of $60 per million dollars for a round trip. The
futures exchanges, which are private corporations of exchange
members, issue contracts to both buyers and sellers, each of
whom must meet the low margins set - e.g., $2 ,000 per $1 million on Treasury bills. A clearing corporation marks each contract to market daily, requiring additional margin when a margin drops below the required maintenance level - $1 ,500 per $1
million for Treasury bills.
6
A contract for notes maturing in 6-1/2 to JO years began trading on the Chicago Board of
11-ade in May 1982.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 79

The futures markets have grown rapidly, attracting a large
amount of new speculative capital to interest rate futures by:
(1) the low margin, (2) marking prices to market daily, and (3)
protecting the participants against credit risk by interposing the
clearing corporation's capital between buyers and sellers. The
growth of futures market activity has spawned so much arbitrage
and trading between the cash and futures market that they function as a single market most of the time.
The Government securities dealers as a group are not only
linked to other sectors of the international money market but
also to the rest of the capital market. Through the bank's money
desk, bank dealer departments keep in close touch with the markets for Federal funds, CDs, bankers' acceptances, and overnight
loans on money market and stock exchange collateral. They
watch the Euro-dollar and foreign exchange markets closely
since international capital flows influence both the demand for
Government securities and the actions of policymakers. Bank
dealer departments often operate in close physical proximity to
the bank department responsible for trading tax-exempt securities of all maturities.
Both bank and nonbank dealers typically trade securities of
Federally sponsored agencies; many also trade the mortgagebacked securities guaranteed by the Government National
Mortgage Association GNMA. Among the nonbank firms several
specialize in Government and Federal agency issues and a limited array of other money market instruments - CDs, bankers'
acceptances, and repos and reverse repos. Others are departments of multi-line firms. At mid-1981, in addition to activity in
other money market instruments, 9 were active in commercial
paper, 17 in corporate and 16 in municipal securities, 15 in block
trading of corporate stock and 13 in the stock market with retail
customers. A further 6 had mortgage banking affiliates while 18
functioned as investment bankers to corporations and state and
local governments.
The international linkages of the Government securities dealers are also impressive. At least 9 bank and 20 nonbank dealers
at mid-1981 were active in trading with foreign central banks and
other international investors. The banks, whose dealer departments reported daily to the Federal Reserve Bank of New York,
were all represented with branch offices in London; many also
had branches in other important money centers such as Frankfurt, Paris, Zurich, Hong Kong, Singapore, and Tokyo. Among the
page 80


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

nonbank dealers, 17 firms traded Eurodollar CDs in London, 14
were active in Eurodollar bonds, and 17 participated in investment banking abroad.
The Federal Reserve Bank of New York has a special relationship with the Government securities market and the Treasury.
The trading desk's activities as agent for the FOMC, and also for
foreign central bank accounts, make it the largest single customer of most dealers. The Bank collects voluminous reports on
the daily trading activity of dealers as well as monthly and annual reports on dealer profitability. The trading desk keeps watch
daily on the performance of the market, informing the Treasury
regularly of what is happening and collecting the quotations that
provide snapshots of prices several times a day. Desk officers give
close and continuing counsel to Treasury officials on debt management issues.
The manager of the System open market account for domestic
operations provides continuity, and leadership, in ongoing official
contacts with the dealer community. He determines when a dealer's performance qualifies him to be added, first to the list of
dealers reporting daily to the Reserve Bank and then to the list of
those trading with the Reserve Bank. He or an associate serves
with senior Treasury and Board staff representatives on a committee that exercises broad surveillance over market reports,
practices, and problems. Officers of the Fed's trading desk serve
as liaison with the association of primary dealers and the senior
officers of individual dealers. They oversee staff visits to dealer
firms to review reporting procedures, management controls and
market practices.
Second only to Treasury securities in credit quality and marketability are the short-term and longer dated securities of several Federally sponsored agencies. Five of these agencies, which
were set up with U.S. Government capital and supervision, have
since been converted to private ownership, though they remain
subject to Federal supervision. Most other sponsored agencies
sell their issues to the Federal Financing Bank, which is financed
by direct Treasury borrowing.
Three of the five principal agencies extend credit to farmers,
are owned by them or their associations, and finance themselves
with debt obligations that are the collective responsibility of all
three agencies. The Banks for Cooperatives lend for short and
intermediate terms in connection with the marketing of agricul
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

2. The Market for Federally
Sponsored Agency Securities

page 81

tural products; the Federal Intermediate Credit Banks lend for
similar maturities to production credit associations, which in
turn lend directly to farmers for production. The Federal Land
Banks supply long-term credit directly to farmers for the purchase of livestock, farm machinery and land.
The Federal Home Loan Banks, supervised by the FHLB Board,
provide loans to member savings and loan associations and
other thrift institutions as a means of fostering the flow of funds
into home mortgages; they are owned by the member associations. The Federal National Mortgage Association (FNMA),
whose stock is traded on the New York Stock Exchange, operates
with guidance from the Secretary of Housing and Urban Development. When home financing is scarce, it buys governmentinsured and government-guaranteed mortgages, and conventional private mortgages, in the secondary market. It sells
mortgages when funds are readily available.
In addition, two Government agencies - the Government
National Mortgage Association (GNMA) and the Federal Home
Loan Mortgage Corporation (FHLMC)- operate in the long-term
credit market to help finance housing. GNMA functions principally by guaranteeing pass-through securities. These entitle the
investor to a pro rata share of the principal and interest payments received by individual pools of government-guaranteed
mortgages, pools assembled by mortgage bankers. FHLMC buys
conventional residential mortgages to foster a secondary market
for them; it sells pass-through securities and other bonds to
finance its activities.
The agencies use a designated fiscal agent to manage the sale
of their obligations to investors. One serves the three farm credit
agencies, another the Federal Home Loan Banks and the FHL
Mortgage Corporation, and a third FNMA. The fiscal agents sell
their coupon securities to the public through separate selling
groups ranging from about 100 to 175 banks and securities firms.
Members of each group are allocated securities on the basis of
their past performance as distributors; fees paid to each member
range from $0.50 to $3.00 per $1,000, depending on the maturity
of the security being sold.
The fiscal agents rely on major members of their selling group
for advice in choosing the maturities to be offered and the interest coupons necessary to sell the securities. Members of the
group characteristically take up the securities even when they
think the pricing is aggressive because of the long-term profpage 82


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

itability of the relationship. The farm credit agencies sell 6- and
9-month paper monthly, while maturities of ten years or more are
sold on a quarterly cycle. Both the Federal Home Loan Banks and
FNMA sell issues at least quarterly; they sell more frequently
when housing credit demands are large. The fiscal agents also
sell discount notes maturing in a range of 5 to 360 days through
designated dealers, who receive a commission of 5 basis points
(0.05 percent) on notes they distribute. Such notes are increased
or reduced in the light of cash needs between regular financings;
rates are adjusted flexibly to attract funds as needed. Most of the
paper sold is in the 30- to 60-day area.
Agency issues attract wide investor participation, because of
their government sponsorship and supervision and the good
secondary market. The securities of the five sponsored agencies
trade at yields similar to those on corresponding Treasury issues.
While the yield differentials are usually small - often as little as 5
basis points, they have risen to 100 basis points or more during
periods of tight money when quality spreads typically widen. The
Farm Credit and Federal Home Loan Bank issues enjoy exemption of their income from state and local taxation.
Most of the dealers in Government securities make secondary
markets in these issues, although trading in many outstanding
issues is inactive. The size of some issues is small - as little as
$200 million. Perhaps only a dozen dealers are willing to make
bids and offers in most of the over 200 outstanding issues. Bidoffer spreads are related to the amount of activity in the secondary market. They are generally wider than those on Government
securities of corresponding maturity, but large, recently offered
issues usually trade at spreads of 2/32 for the shorter issues
to 8/32 on longer ones. Federal agency discount notes, like
commercial paper, do not enjoy much of a secondary market. A dealer who distributes the notes is usually prepared to
make a bid to a customer who has a pressing need to sell
notes - but customers are generally expected to hold the notes
to maturity.
One of the most rapidly growing sectors of the money market
in recent years has been the market for the short-term promissory notes of credit worthy financial and other business

3. Commercial Paper 7

1
This section draws heavily on material provided by Mr. George M. Wm Cleave, partner of
Goldman, Sachs & Co.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 83

enterprises. Companies are attracted by borrowing costs below
those available from banks, investors by the yield premium they
offer over Treasury issues. To be exempt from registration
with the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), such
notes must mature in 270 days or less and be issued for
working capital purposes, for example, to finance inventories and accounts receivable.
Commercial paper is sold to money market investors either
directly by a firm's own sales force or through a dealer, who
provides a single sales force for many borrowers. Direct placement is characteristic of large finance and credit companies,
which are often affiliates of automobile and other manufacturers
and bank holding companies. Close to 55 percent of the over $160
billion in commercial paper outstanding at the end of 1981 was
placed directly by them with customers. The remainder was
placed by a group of ten major dealers, which have specialized
sales forces that typically spend 90 percent of their time selling
commercial paper. Included among about 1,000 companies issuing through dealers are several hundred industrial companies
and public utilities, and over 100 each of bank holding companies
and smaller finance companies. Foreign banks and a few foreign
government agencies also borrow in the market.
To sell commercial paper, a company must have a good credit
rating and provide back-up bank lines of credit, which can be
drawn on to pay off maturing paper, if necessary. After a careful
review of a company's balance sheet and operations, the credit
rating companies - Standard and Poor's (S&P), Moody's, and
Fitch's - assign numerical ratings. The S&P scale of A-1, A-2, or
A-3 ratings and the Moody's scale of P-1, P-2, or P-3 are the most
widely referred to. Perhaps three-quarters of all paper sold is in
the top A-1, P-1 grade, and most of the remainder is graded A-2 or
P-2. Investors generally shy away from lower-graded paper; the
failure of Penn Central in 1970 reminded buyers that credit risks
can be real.
Most paper issuers must also establish bank credit lines that
will cover the amount of paper they expect to have outstanding.
The rating agencies do not deem full coverage necessary for
financial institutions with liquid portfolios or ready access to a
central lending agency-e.g., the Federal Home Loan Banks. In
theory bank credit lines require maintenance of deposits with
the bank equal to 10 percent of the credit line, with an additional
compensating balance of 10 percent when the line is drawn on; in
page 84


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

practice, issuers rarely maintain a balance at such a level. Some
issuers pay a fee rather than maintain compensating balances.
Smaller issuers may sell "documented discount notes" under the
guarantee of a bank's letter of credit.
Allowing for the cost of the bank back-up, issuers of commercial paper can usually save between 1 and 2 percentage points
over the cost of the bank prime rate, compensating balances or
bank fees. More recently, domestic and foreign banks have recaptured some of this business by making loans for 30 days or less at
a markup over the cost of funds to the bank.
Commercial paper is sold at a discount against same day payment in Federal funds; it is redeemed at par at maturity. The
smallest denomination for dealer-placed paper is $100,000, but
blocks of $5 or $10 million are common, especially on directly
placed paper. The paper is usually tailored to the specific maturity dates desired by the customer. While directly placed paper
often has only a week or so to run, the 30-day maturity is very
popular; most paper sold matures within 60 days. Paper is lodged
by the company with a New York bank, which countersigns
and delivers the notes to the commercial paper dealer against
payment.
Dealers usually take down paper as it is sold at quoted rates,
but they also are prepared to buy paper at a yield concession for
inventory when an issuing company's needs are pressing. Some
dealers carry very little inventory for their own account; inventories of others may run above $100 million on occasion, typically financed at rates above those prevailing for Treasury
issues. Dealers are usually prepared to buy back paper they
have sold to an investor, but in fact only a small percentage does
come back ( see Chart 17).
Dealer profitability stems principally from the spread of up to
1/8 of a percentage point between the rate at which paper is
bought and sold. The paper dealers hold in inventory can be
financed at a positive carry during recessionary periods; carry
profits usually outweigh the risk of loss from inventory in such
periods. However, this changes in periods of strong credit demands when carry becomes negative. Then, rates and positions
must be adjusted quickly to avoid loss.
Investors in commercial paper tend to be weighted somewhat
toward financial institutions, which are used to making their own
credit judgments. Banks are large buyers for their own account,

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Chart 17 Rates: Commercial

Paper vs Federal Funds

peak of

economic cycle

trough of

economic cycle

Federal Funds Rate Commercial Paper -

page85

for their trust departments, which manage customer investments, and for the account of corporate customers (through
their money desks). Insurance companies and business corporations are important buyers. Money market mutual funds and
other investment companies find commercial paper's yields
and short maturities especially attractive.

4. Municipal Notes

page 86


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

State and local governments finance short-term cash requirements through the sale of municipal notes maturing in a year or
less. Such notes are issued by the governmental units themselves in anticipation of taxes, other revenues or the proceeds of
selling longer term bonds. In addition, the U.S. Department of
Housing and Urban Development auctions project notes every
other month on behalf of communities using the funds to finance
Federally sponsored low-cost housing or other projects. The income from both types of notes is exempt from Federal income
taxation; the project notes also are backed by the full faith and
credit of the United States Government and their income is
exempt from state taxes. While municipal securities are exempt
from registration under the Federal securities laws, issuers provide opinions as to the legality of issuance and have provided in
recent years detailed information about their financial affairs in
order to facilitate the sale of their issues.
The public sale of notes, as opposed to borrowing from local
banks on a negotiated basis, usually involves competitive bidding. Several hundred commercial banks or investment bankers
participate, but many operate regionally rather than nationally.
The size of sales ranges from hundreds of millions of dollars for
such large issuers as California and New York State down to a
few million dollars. For the bidders, the market is far from
homogeneous. They rely on Moody's classification of issuers into
one of four classes (MIG 1 to 4) to help classify issues of the
thousands of local issuers. Typically, groups of banks and nonbank dealers will bid together, often relying on the credit evaluations of banks that follow the issuer's affairs closely. Bidding
takes into account the rates currently available in the secondary
market, the rate outlook for the immediate future, and customer
interest. The most active banks and dealers make secondary
markets for the larger issues and those in which they have been
involved, but market spreads are usually 5 basis points or more.
Trades of $50 million or more may occur in the large active
issues, but for many smaller issues it is often a negotiatied mar-

ket - not surprisingly, given the hundreds of dealers and
thousands of issuers.
Investors in municipal notes, as in municipal bonds, are
typically those to whom the tax-exempt feature is important.
Commercial banks are major holders, as are casualty insurance
companies and individual investors in high tax brackets. Nonfinancial corporations, too, are often substantial buyers. Life insurance companies and financial institutions that are taxed at
low rates on their income rarely find the low yields attractive
when compared to those available on Treasury or other taxable
securities.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page87

5

The FOMC Meeting - Setting
Operational Strategy
At each of its eight meetings a year the Federal Open Market
Committee instructs the Federal Reserve Bank of New York how
the trading desk is to conduct operations until the next meeting.
These instructions embody a strategy for achieving the annual
objectives for monetary and credit growth. But it would be a
mistake to think that the regular meetings focus chiefly on technical issues involving monetary aggregates. At each meeting the
primary concern is how the economy is likely to perform in
relation to the nation's goals. The 12 voting members, and the
seven non-voting Reserve Bank presidents who attend, reach
their own judgments on the interaction of financial and economic forces. Then they give the desk the short-term objectives
that provide monetary policy with its cutting edge.

Reports of the Managers

The FOMC's regular meetings take place in the boardroom of
the Board of Governors in Washington. The-seven governors and
12 Reserve Bank presidents gather around a long conference
table under a high ceiling. Also seated around the table are the
secretary of the FOMC, senior advisers to the FOMC, and the
managers for foreign exchange and domestic operations. Senior
research officers of the Reserve Banks, other senior Board officials, and an officer from the New York Reserve Bank's domestic
trading desk sit around the sides of the room, available to their
principals if needed.

1. The Report on International
Developments

The chairman opens the meeting. The first order of business
involves reports by the managers for foreign exchange and
domestic open market operations. The manager for foreign exchange operations, a senior officer of the New York Reserve Bank,
reviews developments in the exchange markets during the period
as well as any intervention by the foreign trading desk to maintain an orderly market for the dollar by buying or selling dollars
against foreign currencies. Such actions, covered in more detail
in written reports submitted previously, are reviewed and approved by the committee.
The FOMC is naturally interested in the manager's report on
international developments, including the response of the exchange markets to U.S. monetary developments. The committee
does not have the same degree of responsibility for exchange
rate policy as for domestic monetary policy. Within the U.S. government, the Treasury takes the lead in formulating the interna-

page 88

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

tional financial policy of the United States. The Federal Reserve,
as the nation's central bank, has close working relationships with
foreign central banks and often executes foreign exchange
transactions on their behalf in the U.S. market. The Federal
Reserve plays an important technical and consultative role in policy matters touching the foreign exchange markets. The Chairman
- drawing on the counsel of the New York Reserve Bank president, other FOMC members, the manager for foreign operations
and the Board staff - exchanges views with the Treasury Secretary on what United States policy should be with regard to the
foreign exchange markets. The Federal Reserve can operate on
its own behalf under Treasury guidance in the foreign exchange
markets and build up foreign currency balances of its own. The
Federal Reserve also serves as agent for the Treasury in the
Treasury's own foreign exchange operations.
The FOMC supervises the Federal Reserve's part in actual exchange operations, adopting general guidelines and monitoring
activity. A special subcommittee is authorized to cope with the
exigencies of changing market circumstances between meetings.
Ever since 1973, foreign exchange operations have been undertaken from time to time to counter disorderly market conditions.
The United States does not seek to achieve any particular range
of exchange rates for the dollar in such operations.
In speaking to the FOMC, the manager for foreign operations
often comments on the views expressed by the central bank
governors of major industrial countries at their monthly meeting
at the Bank for International Settlements (BIS) in Basle. At times,
the chairman or one of the committee members ( often the Board
member having primary responsibility for international developments) will report on discussions of current issues wi
fficials abroad or with the Treasury. At regular meetings commi ~e .
members routinely question the manager about the exchang
market and foreign central bank policies and operations. They
may ask his views about the market reaction that would follow a
move in the Federal Reserve discount rate or a more restrictive
approach to supplying nonborrowed reserves. They often ask the
Board staff about the U.S. balance-of-payments and international
economic developments.
A major responsibility of the committee is to oversee the Federal Reserve swap network, reciprocal credit lines established
between the Federal Reserve and other central banks. From

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

~

page 89

modest beginnings in 1962, by the end of 1981 the network had
grown to $30.1 billion of standby credit involving the Federal
Reserve and 14 foreign central banks and the Bank for International Settlements. 1 The "swap" network enables the Federal
Reserve or one of its partners to obtain the currency it needs for
intervention in the foreign exchange markets. Such drawings are
subject to repayment at the same exchange rate three months
later. This credit facility, approved by the FOMC and foreign authorities in advance of need, enables the Federal Reserve, for
example, to intervene on short notice in support of the dollar
after clearing the swap drawing by telephone with the central
bank supplying the currency needed. The drawings can be renewed for additional three-month terms by mutual consent. Over
the years the FOMC has sought to maintain the principle that
swap drawings are to be repaid in full within a year.2 On occasion, the Federal Reserve's partners have drawn on the swap
network to obtain dollars to meet short-term needs.
The manager for foreign operations reports to the committee
on those that are approaching maturity. He outlines current plans
for the drawing party to repay, especially when the debts are
more than six months old. The committee, aided by its staff, also
reviews and approves additions to individual country swap lines
and changes in the instructions under which the manager conducts foreign exchange operations.

2. The Report on Domestic
Operations

Once necessary actions have been taken on the foreign exchange side, the committee turns to the manager for domestic
operations, who reports on the implementation of the committee's directive since the last meeting. The manager typically relates how nonborrowed and total reserves have behaved relative
to their respective paths, which were based on the committee's
Ml and M2 objectives. He notes any changes made in the NBR
path to accelerate bank responses to money supply deviations.
'See Sam Y. Cross, "Treasury and Federal Reserve Foreign Exchange Operations'; Quarterly
Review (Federal Reserve Bank of New York), Winter 1981-82.
2
/n recent years the U.S. has expanded its foreign currency resources by drawing down its
reserve position at the IMF, selling Special Drawing Rights, and issuing foreign currency
denominated securities in the capital markets of other countries. These operations are
conducted by the U.S. Treasury but the Federal Reserve has participated to the extent that
some of the foreign currencies so acquired have been "warehoused" with the System. Also,
at times when the dollar was in strong demand in the market, the Federal Reserve has
accumulated foreign currency balances.

page 90


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

He also may comment on borrowing at the discount window and
the Federal funds rate in relation to what might have been expected in view of the level of nonborrowed reserves achieved.
Daily operations and changes in the System portfolio have already been reviewed fully in written reports, submitted by the
manager in advance.
Speaking to the FOMC, the manager highlights changes in
interest rates in the money and bond markets in the intermeeting
period, with special emphasis on the Treasury market. He describes changes in market sentiment about the interest rate outlook. Shifts of mood may reflect how the monetary aggregates
are behaving. Or they may reflect actual or anticipated Federal
Reserve actions on the discount rate or reserve requirements. Or
market attitudes may change in response to new economic information, the action of the foreign exchange markets, or Administration legislative or budgetary initiatives. The manager also
advises the FOMC about prospective Treasury financing plans.
Following his report, FOMC members may comment or ask the
manager what the market's reaction would be to a change in the
Federal Reserve discount rate or in the desk's operational objectives. Finally, the committee ratifies the operations conducted
over the interval.
At an ordinary committee meeting the staff updates and, at
times, refines the more elaborate analyses presented in February
and July, when the committee adopts its annual monetary and
credit objectives. (See Chapter 2.) Beforehand, the staff sends the
seven Board members and 12 Reserve Bank presidents the green
book, which contains its latest forecast for the major sectors of
the economy and for important price, production and employment data. The green book also covers financial and international developments.
In an oral report, a senior staff officer gives the staff's appraisal
of the current economic outlook, assuming monetary and credit
growth at the rates adopted by the committee at its most recent
semiannual meeting. He weaves significant economic data reported since the last meeting into an analysis of the economy's
present direction and current inflationary pressures. Current estimates of the Federal budget are a key feature of the analysis.
From the combination of oral and written reports, committee
members obtain a comprehensive estimate of the economy's

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

The Staff Input

I. The Economic Outlook

page 91

future course. The principals raise questions of both fact and
interpretation. They often query senior staff members on
whether the forecast is more likely to err on the side of over- or
underestimating growth or price inflation.

2. Policy Alternatives

page 92

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

The staff director for monetary policy next comments on the
recent behavior of the monetary and credit aggregates. He describes the emerging relationships among the growth rates of Ml,
M2 , and bank credit, commenting on whether they differ from the
assumptions made at the time the FOMC adopted its annual
objectives. He then analyzes the alternative short-run paths laid
out for Ml and M2 in the blue book for the committee to consider
in choosing its strategy for pursuing the annual objectives.
Each alternative specifies a different rate for the two aggregates over a period of months, and an associated wide range for
the Federal funds rate. Also specified is an initial level for shortterm adjustment borrowing from the Federal Reserve, which is to
be used in constructing the path for nonborrowed reserves. For
example, if the aggregates were currently below path, one alternative - call it A - might specify growth in Ml and M2 over the
current calendar quarter at rates fast enough to bring them back
to path in three months. Another - B - might specify growth that
would return the aggregates to path in six months, while a third
- C - might specify short-term growth at a lower rate. The
Federal funds rate ranges and borrowing levels, associated with
these monetary growth rates, would be lowest for the "X' alternative and highest for "C': Similarly, if Ml and M2 were well above
their desired path, the blue book alternatives might specify
growth rates returning them to path, in, say, three or six months.
In preparing the blue book alternatives, the staff director and
his colleagues estimate how these different Federal Reserve supply schedules will interact with the demands for money emanating from the economy to produce the desired growth in money
and total reserves. They begin with simulations of the Board's
monthly money market model, which estimates the response of
consumers and other money holders to the interest rates resulting from pursuing nonborrowed reserve objectives. Both individuals and businesses respond to a rise in interest rates by
economizing on Ml balances in relation to payment needs and
current income. When rates fall , they tolerate higher balances at
a given income level. The Board model suggests that about half
of the influence on Ml takes place in two to three months.

The effect of interest rates on Ml balances has become less
clear-cut with the rise in interest-paying substitutes for demand
deposits. Automatic transfer services (ATS) allow movements
from savings accounts to cover overdrafts in checking accounts.
Negotiated order of withdrawal (NOW) accounts, repurchase
agreements (RPs ), and money market mutual funds are very
close to cash; banks and others are also developing procedures
for sweeping excess household and business deposits into accounts paying a market-related rate. M2, which now includes
these instruments, responds more sluggishly to a rise in rates
than before they were available. Moreover, there is uncertainty
about the extent to which savings will flow directly to market
instruments or to accounts included in the aggregates the committee is targeting.
Weighing these factors as best he can, the staff director details
in the blue book the staff's current judgments of the growth in
total reserves to be expected over the quarter under each alternative. The blue book also indicates how interest rates on shortand long-term obligations are expected to behave under each
alternative between meetings.
In his appearance before the committee, the staff director relates the blue book alternatives to the committee's longer term
objective. He might point out, for example, that alternative").:' in
the above example would mean quarterly growth above the annual objectives and could raise doubts in the public's mind about
the FOMC's proclaimed intent to reduce monetary growth. However, this alternative would also produce the most rapid nearterm drop in interest rates should economic activity be weaker
than the staff expected. At the other end of the spectrum, holding
growth down, as in alternative "C': might well help reduce inflationary expectations. But the slower money growth and higher
interest rates expected under C could lead to slower economic
growth than the green book had forecast.
Under ground rules laid down by the chairman, each of the
voting members of the FOMC and the seven nonvoting Reserve
Bank presidents gives his view of how the economy is performing. The seven governors bring to the meeting a wide range of
contacts with businessmen and others around the country; and
with economic policymakers and staff members in the Administration, the Congress, and the independent agencies. In forming
their views, the Reserve Bank presidents draw on their own ex
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

FOMC Decision Making

page93

changes with bankers, businessmen, government officials and
others in their own regions. The staffs of the Reserve Banks
prepare their own economic forecasts. They also contribute
qualitative information on economic developments and thinking
in their districts to the red book, which is produced and circulated in advance by the Reserve Banks.

I. Sizing Up the Economic Situation

page 94


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

The FOMC seeks to assess the momentum of the U.S. economy,
to change monetary policy's emphasis in pursuit of balanced
growth, and to defend its choices to Congress and the public.
Personal assessments inevitably fuse value judgments with economic analysis. Each individual approaches the issues before the
committee with a body of experience, and a measure of conviction about the economic issues facing the society. Should the
Federal Reserve be primarily concerned at this point with restraining money growth and price inflation, or does the creation
of more jobs deserve a higher priority?
Each speaker's analytical approach provides a framework for
imposing order on the information available. Most policymakers
tend to be eclectic in this respect, building their conclusions
about the total economy from the spending dynamics evident in
the consumer, business and government sectors. But they are
mindful also of the lagged effects of monetary growth on future
demand and prices. Emphases differ. Some will be especially
interested in the housing and capital spending sectors, which
they see as most affected by interest rate changes. Others will
put a heavier emphasis on past monetary and/or credit expansion. Personal chemistry tends to affect the weight each attaches
to incoming economic data.
The committee takes the staff's latest forecast of the economy
as a benchmark for its discussion. Each of the 19 principals
indicates briefly the areas of agreement or disagreement with the
staff. Usually by the time half a dozen have spoken, the participants begin to sense whether their associates see the economy
as stronger or weaker than the staff anticipates. Some participants make trenchant capsule analyses of their own. Others
stress their particular concerns with signs of weakness or
strength. A few participants may be sensitive to signs of weakness, a visceral tendency well known to their colleagues. Others
emphasize price inflation or the dollar's performance as key indicators of the pressures monetary policy should address.
Policymakers frequently stress how business and consumer ex-

pectations are likely to affect spending decisions and economic
developments. By the time the roundup is over, most have given
their economic views and also nodded in the direction of the
policy position they will articulate later.
The committee's directive to the New York Bank recapitulates
the economic developments reviewed at the meeting and directs
that management of the reserve aggregates be consistent with
specified growth in Ml and M2 over a period of several months.
The directive also gives a range for the Federal funds rate, noting
that the manager for domestic operations is to notify the chairman promptly if fluctuations in the rate are likely to be inconsistent with the monetary and related reserve paths. The chairman
will then decide whether the situation calls for supplementary
instructions from the committee.
Discussion of directive specifications naturally follows the appraisal of the economy. Each member's reading of the economy
conditions where he or she will want to place the supply
schedule for nonborrowed reserves. A strong economy will
heighten concern about permitting overly rapid monetary
growth. A weak one will strengthen support for a more liberal
approach to providing reserves. Of course, participants may disagree on the outlook. Then, those worried about an incipient
downturn, or shortfalls in monetary growth, are likely to argue
for more rapid short-term growth in the aggregates as the prudent course to follow. At the same time, others, impressed with
the economy's performance, the strength of inflationary expectations, or the dollar's weakness in the exchange markets, may opt
for slower growth rates in money even at the risk of higher
interest rates.
Policy preferences can also reflect different appraisals of how
money and the real economy interact, or how long the lags are
from desk action to changes in money growth. Some policymakers see a strong influence running from the economy to
money demand. Their views of the outlook influence their judgment of what short-term monetary growth rates offer the best
bet for achieving the committee's objectives for the year. They
will tend to choose lower short-term growth rates for money as a
way of leaning against strong economic winds, and higher ones
when the economy is becalmed. Other policymakers may emphasize instead that the behavior of money growth in recent
months foreshadows future economic activity. If money has been

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

2. Discussing the Directive

page95

running significantly above or below the annual objective, they
are likely to favor an alternative offering a rapid return of the
aggregates to path. Both views of the matter may lead to the
same alternative. But choices do diverge at times, notably if
those leaning to the first approach see a different economic outlook than is suggested by the recent behavior of the money
supply.
Policymakers also have differing opinions about the length of
the lags between trading desk action and the response of the
monetary aggregates. Those who see a strong influence running
from the economy to money also tend to expect a lag of some
months between the achievement of reserve paths and the desired effect on the money supply. A greater movement in interest
rates may be necessary to promote quicker adjustment in bank
and public portfolios. But the lag also increases the possibility
that money growth will overshoot in the opposite direction.
Overly large and rapid declines in interest rates to reverse monetary shortfalls, in this view, run the risk of accelerating growth far
more than desired a few months later. On the other hand, other
policymakers believe the lags are, or can be made to be, fairly
short. They believe that more aggressive movements in the supply schedule for reserves will tend to shorten the lags and bring
money back on path in fairly short order - say two or three
months. Believing in shorter lags, they see less risk that such
actions will produce cycles in monetary growth.
However they read the evidence on lags, committee members
weigh the alternatives amid considerable uncertainty about the
meaning of the recent behavior of the monetary aggregates.
Money supply data are very erratic on a week-to-week basis,
even after seasonal adjustment to allow for regular patterns of
movement. On a monthly basis, the random element in Ml variations remains equivalent to a change of about 4-1/2 percentage
points at an annual rate, according to a Board staff study. In the
face of such variability, judgments about which alternative is
appropriate can differ among individuals with similar views
about the economy and the length of the lags from desk action to
money supply behavior.
Not surprisingly, the alternatives presented in the blue book
do not usually imply dramatic changes in reserve paths or
short-term interest rates. Suppose, for example, that growth in
the aggregates proceeded at the pace allowed in the relatively
expansive "N alternative. Adoption of the "C" alternative, involvpage 96


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

ing a lower growth rate and higher initial level of borrowing at the
discount window, might then result in increased borrowing at the
window of $600 to $800 million over a six- or seven-week period.
The resultant pressure in the market for reserves might push up
the Federal funds rate by 1 to 2 percentage points. Such a change
would certainly work in the direction of reducing the growth of
the aggregates, but other forces could delay, or even negate, the
return of growth to path. Committee members recognized by
early 1981 that the reserve-oriented approach probably calls for
discount rate changes and adjustment of the nonborrowed reserve path whenever the FOMC desires to accelerate the return
of money supply to path.
In the last analysis, the FOMC has to vote on a precise alternative. With 19 participating, and 12 members voting, an individual
policymaker rarely has time to explain fully the analysis behind
his choice, much less the concept of the monetary process that
has helped form his conclusion. Instead, each speaker tries to
argue the case for his own choice in terms that will be most
persuasive to his associates. When sharply different views
emerge, voting members weigh whether they are prepared to
dissent if the majority take a different tack.
In the collegial atmosphere of the committee, the desire for

3. The Vote

broadly supported decisions is strong. Many believe that unity

enhances the Federal Reserve's credibility in financial markets
and strengthens its influence in Congress and the councils of the
Administration. The voting members themselves tailor their
directive specifications to win support for the course they favor.
If a move toward the more expansive "N' alternative seems unlikely to pass muster, a member leaning that way might suggest
growth rates for the aggregates between the "N' and "B" alternatives of the blue book, but with the Federal funds rate range and
borrowing levels of ".N~ A slightly hawkish member, on the other
hand, might endorse the "B" alternative's Federal funds rate
range and borrowing levels, but the "C" specifications of Ml and
M2 growth.
After the participants have spoken, the chairman usually sets
forth a set of specifications that give promise of attracting wide
support. In subsequent discussion individual voting members
may suggest modifications that would enable them to join in
support. For example, a member who wishes to guard against a
rapid decline in interest rates might accept a lower limit than he

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page97

personally prefers for the Federal funds rate range - provided
the chairman were to consult the committee before the manager
was allowed to use the full range proposed. After discussion, the
chairman puts the issue to a vote. An extensive record of the
full committee meeting - including the main policy arguments
made and decisions reached - is published after the next meeting of the committee.3 Those who dissent record their reasons
for doing so.

The operational instructions of the December 1981 directive were as follows:
"In the short run, the Committee seeks behavior of reserve aggregates consistent with
growth of Ml and M2 from November 1981 to March at annual rates of around 4 to 5
percent and 9 to 10 percent respectively.... In setting the Ml target the Committee took
account of the relatively rapid growth that had already taken place through the first part of
December; it also recognized that interpretation of actual money growth may need to take
account of the significance of fluctuations in NOW accounts, which have recently been
growing relatively rapidly The Chairman may call for Committee consultation if it
appears to the Manager for Domestic Operations that pursuit of the monetary objectives
and related reserve paths during the period before the next meeting is likely to be
associated with a federal funds rate persistently outside a range of JO to 14 percent. "
3

page 98


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

6

The Trading Desk and
Its Tasks
When the manager for domestic operations returns from the
FOMC meeting to the New York Reserve Bank, he oversees seven
officers and a group of professionals, who are charged with carrying out the directive just adopted. The nerve center of operations is the trading room on the eighth floor. There, skilled traders sit at individual desks, which are clustered in rows before a
large board displaying bid quotations for each of the Treasury
issues outstanding. Each trader faces a telephone console with
direct lines to Federal funds brokers, the money desks of major
New York City banks, and primary dealers in Government securities. Other lines connect with the senior officers of the securities
and foreign departments.
News tickers provide a stream of reports on financial markets
during the day. Cathode ray tubes can be used to display any of
several hundred pages of information stored in the computer of a
financial information service. In nearby rooms are the accountants who keep the books on the System portfolio, the economists and clerks who produce reports to the FOMC, and the
traders who handle operations in bankers' acceptances.
Supporting personnel in the research department are nearby on
the ninth floor.
The trading desk has many tasks. Its primary mission is to
carry out the FOMC's instructions governing both dynamic and
defensive open market operations. But it also provides a regular
flow of information to the FOMC and the Treasury about the
markets in Treasury and other securities. Its officers counsel the
Treasury on debt management and play a leading role in relations
with the unregulated dealer market in Government securities.
The trading desk also executes a large volume of transactions in
Treasury issues, bankers' acceptances, and other instruments as
agent for foreign central bank accounts.

Dynamic Operations

page JOO


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

The manager for domestic operations and the staff director for
monetary policy confer soon after each meeting to develop the
desk's objectives for non-borrowed reserves (NBR) in accordance with the procedures described in Box B, page 102. The
manager's weekly NBR objectives allow for the seasonal variation
expected in Ml and M2 and for the growth expected in CDs
and other reservable liabilities not included in these monetary
aggregates. The NBR objectives are consistent with the specified level of adjustment borrowing at the Federal Reserve

Banks. In other words, so long as monetary growth is on track,
the banks' demand for reserves is expected to result in
no change in borrowing or the range in which Federal funds
trade.
The manager's conduct of dynamic open market operations
focuses on hitting the NBR targets established for the intermeeting period, or for separate subperiods. If Ml and M2 deviate significantly from the committee's desires, the demand of depository
institutions for total reserves will increase, or decline, relative
to the supply of nonborrowed reserves being provided by the
desk. Demand and supply, interacting in the market for reserves,
will affect short-term adjustment borrowing at the regional
Reserve Banks as banks individually seek to meet their reserve
requirement, leaving as few excess reserves as possible. Discount
officers at the Reserve Banks make clear to the institutions in
each district that such credit is available only for short periods
to allow an institution time to adjust by reducing assets or increasing its borrowing from others. Hence, changes in borrowing
that result from shifts in money growth increase, or reduce, the
pressure on banks to adjust, and the Federal funds rate will
respond accordingly.
The situation is different if monetary growth proves so weak
that the demand for total reserves falls back close to the NBR
supply. Then banks in the aggregate will have no need to borrow
from the discount window and the Federal funds rate will fall
below the Federal Reserve discount rate. Should achieving the
NBR objective appear likely to push the funds rate below the
bottom end of the committee's range on a sustained basis, the
manager reports that to the chairman.
The manager is responsible not only for trying to hit the NBR
objective, but also for consulting with the chairman and the staff
director for monetary policy whenever monetary growth is veering off course, suggesting the NBR path may need to be
modified. In the evolving practice of reserve management, the
committee has embraced the desirability of lowering the NBR
path on occasion to speed the correction of monetary overshoots. Conversely, raising the path may be in order when Ml and
M2 are falling substantially below desired levels. Such interim
adjustments accelerate the response of interest rates to monetary deviations. The advantages such path adjustments offer in
terms of closer monetary control need to be weighed against

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 101

Box B Formulating
the Reserve Paths

page 102


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

After the FOMC meeting the Board staff - in consultation with
the manager for domestic operations and, if necessary, the
chairman - translates the directive adopted by the FOMC into
reserve paths. The first step in the process is to allocate the
growth sought for Ml and M2 over individual months. There may
be at times good reasons for departing from straight line growth
at the rates adopted by the FOMC. Suppose, for example, the
Treasury expects to collect checks from individual taxpayers
more rapidly in April than has been the case in recent years, thus
causing a more rapid decline in private demand deposits. The
staff might reasonably conclude that the existing seasonal adjustment factors for Ml would not adequately reflect this April's
decline in demand deposits. Consequently, in April Ml growth
after seasonal adjustment would be weaker than allowed for by
existing seasonal adjustment factors. The reserve path might
then allow for slower Ml growth in April and somewhat faster
growth in May.
Once monthly levels of seasonally adjusted Ml and M2 are
determined, the staff deseasonalizes the data and allocates the
unadjusted data to the 6 to 8 individual weeks between one
meeting and the next. Then, it estimates the required reserves
that correspond to the desired growth in money, taking account
of the expected behavior of currency, the composition of deposits by type and maturity, the distribution of deposits among
institutions with different effective reserve ratios. The staff adds
the required reserves needed to support the growth it projects in
other reservable bank liabilities - including interbank and Treasury deposits, and large certificates of deposit. This process results in an estimated weekly path of required reserves for the
period between meetings, which is believed consistent with the
FOMC's directive. By adding an allowance for excess reserves,
based on past experience, one produces a path for total reserves
(not seasonally adjusted). From this the staff deducts the initial
level of discount window borrowing agreed to by the committee
to produce a weekly path for nonborrowed reserves.
The period is generally broken for operational purposes into
two subperiods. The average NBR objective thus established
for each subperiod becomes the desk's primary objective in
its conduct of open market operations. Table 2 shows the
derivation of an average NBR objective of $39.4 billion for a sample subperiod.

Week

1
2
3
4

Average

Actual/Projected
Total Reserves
40.1
40.3
41.8
40.4
40.4

Non borrowed
Reserves Path
39.1
39.3
39.8
39.4
39.4

Borrowed
Reserves
Implied by
NBRPath
1.0
1.0
1.0
1.0
1.0

Table2

Each week the Board staff receives new information on money
growth in past weeks and makes new projections of future weeks.
The staff then estimates the average level of total reserves that
will be demanded over the period on the basis of the actual levels
of reserves for past weeks and the projected demand in future
weeks. Assume, for example, that one week into the period data
become available which indicate stronger monetary growth and
a higher level of demand for reserves than originally projected
(see Table 3). The demand for total reserves ($40.7 billion) now
exceeds the intended NBR supply ($39.4 billion) by $1.3 billion.
Therefore the level of borrowing that corresponds to the NBR
path must rise to $1.4 billion in each of the remaining 3 weeks.
The individual weekly NBR objectives (Column 2) then are calculated by subtracting $1.4 billion from the estimated demand for
total reserves in each of the three weeks (Column 1).

Week

1
2
3
4

Average

Actual/Projected
Demand for
Total Reserves
(1)
40.2a
40.9
41.2
40.5
40.7

Non borrowed
Reserves Path
(2)
39.2a
39.5
39.8
39.1
39.4

Borrowed
Reserves
Implied by
NBRPath
(3)
l.0a
1.4
1.4
1.4
1.3

Table3

a= actual

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 103

their possible contribution to unnecessary short-run volatility in
interest rates.
The strategy of dynamic operations involves reviewing and
recasting weekly the NBR objectives. Each week new data on the
monetary aggregates and other bank liabilities become available
to the Board staff on Thursday. The data reflect preliminary reports on deposits for the week ended on the Wednesday eight
days before and the initial estimate of deposits for the week
ending the day before. By Friday morning the technicians have
recalculated the original reserve paths, based on new information on the actual behavior of currency and excess reserves, and
on the distribution of deposits by size, type, and institution. In
effect, this constitutes a weekly recalculation of the reservedeposit relationship for the intermeeting period. On Friday morning, except when holidays intervene, the manager and the staff
director review the staff estimates of how much the paths for
nonborrowed and total reserves need to be raised, or lowered, to
conform to the committee's aggregate objectives. Bearing in
mind that these adjustments may change considerably from
week to week, they then agree on the extent to which such
technical adjustments will be incorporated in the paths.

Open Market Operations and
the Discount Window

The discount window, and the discount rate, are central to
monetary management, but the decision to borrow rests with
individual institutions. Many factors influence that decision. The
Federal Reserve's guidelines prescribe the frequency of borrowing permitted. The individual banker will weigh his past use of
the window, his perceived reserve position, and his expectations
for the Federal funds rate and other rates in the weeks ahead. In
consequence, borrowing can turn out considerably higher or
lower than desired in a particular week or even several weeks. As
the end of a control interval approaches, the desk may find that
sharp, but quite temporary, changes in borrowing levels will be
needed if the NBR objective is to be achieved. An obvious conflict emerges between achieving the reserve objective and
generating interest rate volatility, which may confuse market participants. On balance, the System has tended to accept some
deviation from reserve objectives in such circumstances. 1
1
See Fred J. Levin and Paul Meek, "Implementing the New Operating Procedures: The View
from the 7rading Desk'; Federal Reserve Staff Study - Volume /: New Monetary Control
Procedures (Washington, D.C. , February /981).

page 104


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

The discount rate, it should be noted, plays a more dynamic
role in monetary management under a reserve-targeting strategy
than it did under the Federal funds rate approach. A rise or fall in
the discount rate now typically means a corresponding change
in the Federal funds rate, rather than a narrowing of the spread
between it and the discount rate. Under reserve targeting, the
desk's NBR objectives does not usually change when the discount rate changes. Since aggregate borrowing remains at the
same level after an increase, banks bid up the Federal funds
rate after a discount rate increase to maintain about the same
premium as before. (When the desk operated with a Federal
funds rate target, in contrast, it ordinarily supplied NBR after a
discount rate increase so that the spread narrowed.)
The Federal Reserve can also use a discount rate change to
initiate a move to lower rates. However, it has preferred at times
to have open market operations maintain NBR growth in such
circumstances until the Federal funds rate falls to the discount
rate or below. Reductions in the discount rate, then, merely reduce the rate spread, giving little more than a psychological
impetus to further declines in the Federal funds rate.
A key function of any central bank is to enable depository
institutions to accommodate the highly variable short-run demands of the economic system for currency, deposits, and
credit. 2 In many countries the discount window performs this
function, allowing banks to borrow against, or discount, eligible
paper at one or more discount rates to meet the reserve needs
generated by customer demands. In the United States, the FOMC
underwrites the smooth daily functioning of the financial system
by directing the trading desk to provide for seasonal variations in
Ml and M2. This policy means that shifts between money and the
other short-term assets of the money market tend to take place
on reasonably stable terms from week to week.
To conduct defensive open market operations, the manager
needs forecasts of the required reserves depository institutions
must maintain, as well as estimates of other factors affecting
reserves. Under the Monetary Control Act of 1980 each depository institution with checkable deposits must meet its reserve
requirements in the current statement week ending on Wednesday. These are based on its daily average deposit liabilities in the

Defensive Operations

2

See Meek and Cox, op. cit., pp. 50-57.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 105

statement week of two weeks earlier.3 On Thursday, at the beginning of the statement week, the trading desk has before it a set of
weekly nonborrowed reserve targets that allows for the seasonal
variation in required reserves as seen by the Board's staff. The
present week's objective is revised on Friday if required reserves
change as a result of reports of the institutions themselves for
the statement week ended two weeks before.4 By Friday, too, the
staff estimate of required reserves included in the second week's
NBR objective should be reasonably accurate, since preliminary
data for a large share of bank deposits in the week immediately
past is already in hand. For the remaining weeks in the control
period, the projector derives estimates from the forecast currently being made of the various categories of deposits in
the course of developing weekly estimates of Ml, M2, and other
bank liabilities.
On the Thursday after the FOMC meeting, the officers at the
trading desk start with estimated demand for total reserves for
that statement week. This estimate allows for the required reserves to be maintained and for a modest amount of excess
reserves necessary to lubricate the monetary machinery. From
this projected demand the staff subtracts the initial borrowing
level agreed to by the FOMC to obtain the tentative NBR objective for the current week. On Friday, this objective and those for
subsequent weeks are revised in the light of the latest reports
from depository institutions. For example, if required reserves
are expected to be $39.8 billion and excess reserves $300 million,
then the estimated demand for total reserves in the current week
would be $40.1 billion. If the FOMC specified an initial borrowing
of $1 billion, the objective for nonborrowed reserves would be
$39.1 billion ($40.1 minus $1.0 billion).
The next step is to compare the NBR objective with the level of
nonborrowed reserves being forecast for the current statement
week, assuming no further open market operations. If the desired
3
At the end of 1981 about 14,300 commercial banks, 450 savings banks, 4,000 savings and
loan associations, and 3,500 credit unions were subject to reserve requirements on checkable deposits and non-personal time deposits. Each depository institution has to hokl
reserves against transaction accounts in a ratio of 3 percent for amounts of $25 million or
less and initially at 12 percent for amounts above $25 million. Reserves on non-personal
time deposits must be hekl initially at a ratio of 3 percent. Requirements are to be phased
in for the institutions newly covered by the MCA over seven years from September 1980.
4
Reserve maintenance for institutions with a small volume of reservable deposits is based
on less frequent reports.

page 106


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

level exceeds the forecast level - by $1.5 billion, for example - it
suggests that the trading desk needs to supply additional reserves in about that volume through open market purchases.
Otherwise banks, finding themselves short of reserves in the
course of the week, would tend to bid up the Federal funds rate
and borrow more at the window than is consistent with the NBR
objective. Another way of arriving at the same estimate of necessary open market operations is to express both the desired reserve level and the forecast reserve levels in terms of net free
reserves - excess reserves minus adjustment borrowing at the
discount window.5 In the previous example, desired free reserves
equalled a minus $700 million ($0.3 minus $1.0 billion)- usually
stated as net borrowed reserves of $700 million. With nonborrowed reserves forecast at $37.6 billion, forecast net borrowed
reserves would be $2.2 billion -indicating a need to supply $1.5
billion to achieve the desired level.
The arithmetic is easy enough; it is forecasting the factors
affecting nonborrowed reserves, and free reserves, that is difficult. The broad outline of the problem is clear enough ( see
Chart 18, page 108). From early November to early January demand deposits and hence required reserves rise considerably,
only to fall back sharply by early February. Uncontrolled factors
affecting reserves alternately supply and drain reserves in
November and December, then supply reserves in large quantity
in January as currency comes pouring back into the banks after
the holiday season. As a result, if the Federal Reserve sought to
enable the banking system to meet the seasonal demand for
currency and deposits, open market operations would be called
on to supply about $2 billion of reserves through early January,
and then to turn around to absorb $4 billion in the following
month.
The problem in actual operations is that the weekly data are
very volatile, however regular the main seasonal patterns may
be. Federal Reserve float, which arises mainly in the check collection process, is notoriously erratic. Float is Federal Reserve
credit that stems from automatically crediting member banks for
checks they deposit on a time schedule somewhat shorter, on
average, than the time needed to collect the checks. In other
words, the amount due from depository institutions on Federal
5
Free reserves = (total reserves - required reserves) - adjustment borrowing = nonborrowed reserves - required reserves.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 107

Chart 18 Market Factors vs
Required Reserves
-

Billions of Dollars

Required Reserves
Market Factors
Total

3

Above the line: Cumulative Net Drain
Below the line: Cumulative Net Supply

2

-1

-2

-3

-4

-5

7 14 21
November

28

5 12 19
December

26

2 9
January

16

23

30

6 13 20
February

27

Reserve Bank balance sheets always exceeds the amount due
depository institutions for one- or two-day items not yet credited
to them. Float generally rises toward the middle of most months
with the volume of checks being processed, but periodic processing problems and the vagaries of the weather and transpor-

page 108


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

tation make it highly variable. Wire transfer and accounting
errors also result in "as of" adjustments to bank positions that
count in assessing their compliance with reserve requirements.
By comparison, the flow of currency out of institutions into circulation, and the reverse flow to them, is predictable with reasonably small errors.
Nonborrowed reserves also change because of the behavior of
the Treasury's balances at the Reserve Banks. The Treasury seeks
to maintain these balances at a relatively stable level. It transfers
funds to the Reserve Banks from its "tax and loan" balances with
depository institutions at a rate that about offsets the dollar
volume of checks expected to be presented at the Reserve
Bank's. But an error of $500 million in the volume of Treasury
checks clearing on any one day is common and misses of $1
billion are not unknown. Changes in the Federal Reserve balances held by foreign central banks and the Federally sponsored
agencies also affect bank reserves unexpectedly at times. In all,
the estimates of nonborrowed reserves prepared on the first day
of the statement week exhibit errors that average $500 million or
more, with float the major source.
Given the magnitude of these errors, the manager and his
associates use the reserve estimates as broad indicators of probable reserve availability, rather than as precise guides to action.
To some extent, they look to the Federal funds market itself for
indications that reserves are in short supply, or overly abundant.
Traders on the desk monitor closely the bid and offer quotations,
which are reported by the Federal funds brokers and the money
desks of major banks. In a week when the estimates suggest a
need to add $1.5 billion on average to reserves, the Federal funds
market should exhibit a degree of upward pressure on the rate.
When such confirmation is not forthcoming, the manager may
decide to supply only $1 billion or less in the daily routine that
will be described in the next chapter. Defensive operations involve a daily comparison between the reserve estimates and the
Federal funds rate in the interest of achieving the FOMC's nonborrowed reserve objectives.
The manager and his associates have a number of other
duties, which have a life of their own. Desk officers are in daily
contact with senior Treasury officials concerned with cash and
debt management. They also maintain contact with the primary
dealers in Government securities, playing an active role in official

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Adjunct Desk Responsibilities

page 109

surveillance of that market. The desk makes investments on a
very large scale as agent for foreign central banks, which operate
through the Bank's foreign relations department. Finally, officers
and staff contribute studies relating to monetary policy and
other financial developments.
The trading desk's relations with the Treasury have many
facets. The traders on the desk provide information several times
each day on supply and demand in the secondary market for
government securities - both through oral reports and market
quotations. Desk personnel also pass along market ideas of what
investors would like the Treasury to offer in its financings. Once
the actual offerings have been announced, they report on the
extent of investor interest. Desk officers monitor the market's
bidding ideas in each auction of Treasury issues. They also
supervise the opening of tenders for the Second Federal Reserve
District, which usually accounts for one-half to three-quarters of
the national awards of new issues. Any problems associated with
the auctions or the market are quickly brought to the Treasury's
attention.
The desk's advisory role stems naturally from its daily involvement in the U.S. Government securities market. The manager is in frequent contact with the deputy assistant secretary of
the Treasury for debt management and the fiscal assistant secretary concerning the Treasury's cash needs and its plans for meeting them. The manager and his associates regularly inform the
Treasury about foreign official interest in special Treasury issues
or in regular offerings of marketable securities. Once each quarter Treasury officials come to New York to obtain the views of the
primary dealers on how they should structure the mid-quarter
financing and what approach seems best for meeting remaining
cash needs in the months ahead. In the following week the manager and an associate typically attend the briefing sessions the
Treasury holds in Washington. There the Treasury obtains financing recommendations from special advisory committees of the
American Bankers Association and the Public Securities Association, on which leading bankers and the Government securities
dealers, respectively, are represented. The trading desk team participates in the Treasury's internal discussions, when the under
secretary for monetary affairs decides on the amount and maturity of securities to recommend to the secretary for sale.
The manager and his team have a special responsibility for
relations with the primary dealers by virtue of the desk's multiple
page 110


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

market roles. The manager must decide which firms will report
daily to the Federal Reserve Bank of New York on their activities,
and which firms will trade with the desk. Bank dealer departments or nonbank firms are usually added to the reporting list
when they have satisfactorily demonstrated the adequacy of
their capital, the experience of their management and trading
personnel, and the achievement of a significant volume of trading
activity in Government and Federal agency securities with customers and other dealers.
The manager admits a dealer to a trading relationship after
determining that this would help the desk perform its own functions. Such a decision follows an on-the-spot review of the firm's
policies, management controls, and reporting procedures. The
dealers report daily on their trading activities, their cash and
futures positions in Treasury and other securities, and their
means of financing positions. Such reports provide desk officers
with up-to-date information on the functioning of each dealer
and the market as a whole. In addition, they receive monthly and
annual profit reports, which enable them to keep close watch on
the financial soundness of the dealers. Periodic visits from a
Federal Reserve team help to strengthen their understanding of a
dealer's business approach, review management controls, and
test adherence to reporting procedures. Once a year, the manager and his associates formally discuss with the principal officers of each dealer their views of the dealer's recent performance and review any outstanding issues.
Given the institutional character of the market and the Treasury's own role, the trading desk is an active participant in the
joint Treasury-Federal Reserve oversight of the dealer market.
Trading in U.S. Government securities, as well as the issues of the
government-sponsored agencies, was left exempt from regulation
by the Securities and Exchange Commission in the 1930s. A
three-member Treasury-Federal Reserve steering committee, on
which the manager is represented, seeks to maintain general
oversight of the dealer market. The aim is to foster continuing
high standards of business conduct and responsible performance of the market-making function. Both are essential to the
Treasury's orderly sale of new debt and the trading desk's efficient
conduct of open market operations. The steering group has been
instrumental in revising dealer reporting forms to keep them
abreast of changes in the market. Its members constitute an
informal clearinghouse for information about market practices

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 111

and problems. The staffs of the Treasury and Federal Reserve,
including desk representatives, maintain a close watch on the
interrelationships developing between the cash and futures markets for Treasury issues.
On another front, a considerable part of the trading desk's time
and resources is taken up with executing orders for foreign
central bank accounts. At the end of 1981 foreign and international holdings of Treasury and other securities at the New York
Bank amounted to over $130 billion. A substantial part of the
international dollar flows affecting foreign central bank reserves
results in transactions executed through the trading desk. The
desk takes account of such transactions in planning daily System
open market operations with a view to cushioning their impact
on domestic securities markets when that seems appropriate.
The execution service provided to foreign accounts leads to outright transactions that are several times as large in dollar volume
as those undertaken for the System's own account. Most of the
outright activity is in Treasury bills, but the desk also carries out
customer orders, as requested, in the markets for bankers' acceptances, Treasury coupon securities, securities of the Federally
sponsored agencies, and negotiable CDs. Overnight funds of foreign accounts are invested daily in a special pool of repurchase
agreements involving Government and Federal agency securities.
Finally, trading desk personnel engage in a wide variety of
reporting and analytical assignments. Reporting to the FOMC
itself is a major task. Each statement week there is a comprehensive report on System open market operations, bank reserves,
and the markets for Government securities, corporate and
municipal bonds, and bankers' acceptances. Before each FOMC
meeting a special report reviews the intermeeting period in more
summary fashion. Annually the manager reports on the full
sweep of the year's events, together with his comments on the
strategy and tactics of open market policy. Beyond these, there
are special studies involving proposed modification in the Committee's approach to reserve management or to the pursuit of the
monetary aggregates. Technical matters involving Treasury
financing, the Treasury's tax and loan accounts and the record of
dealer performance are also addressed. New market developments, like the futures market for Treasury securities, are of
particular interest.

page 112


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

7

The Conduct Of Open
Market Operations
The FOMC's adoption of a reserve-oriented approach to monetary management changed significantly the framework within
which the desk carries out the Committee's directive. Before the
1979 decision, desk operations - their timing and magnitude provided clear signals to financial market participants of the
Federal funds rates at which the desk was prepared to provide, or
absorb, reserves. The levels of nonborrowed reserves and discount window borrowing that emerged reflected the banking
system's demand for reserves, and the relation between the Federal funds rate and the discount rate. Since October 1979, in
contrast, the desk has concentrated on achieving a nonborrowed
reserve path, which is consistent with desired monetary growth.
Discount window borrowing and the Federal funds rate then
emerge as the banking system's demand for reserves impinges
on the nonborrowed reserves supplied by the central bank.
The process is an interactive one. The desk has a nonborrowed reserve objective each week, and adds to, or subtracts
from, the volume of nonborrowed reserves expected to result
from developments beyond its control. But the banks have no
clear fix on the desk's reserve objectives or what they imply
about pressure on bank reserve positions. Individually, the banks
have reasonable information about their own present and prospective reserve positions. They also have some sense of the
current Federal funds rate, and expectations about the outlook
for short-term borrowing rates in the current week and beyond.
Not surprisingly, banks collectively may borrow at the Federal
Reserve discount window considerably more, or less, in any one
week than is consistent with the desk's nonborrowed reserve
objective. They may then discover on Wednesday, the end of the
statement week, that banks as a group have overborrowed, leaving them with surplus reserves, which have to be sold at sharply
declining Federal funds rates. Or the banks may find themselves
on Wednesday short of meeting their reserve requirements, forcing them to bid up the Federal funds rate and borrow heavily at
the discount window. Moreover, extremes of tightness or ease on
a Wednesday often tend to carry over to the following week.
Against this background the trading desk considers bank behavior as it tries to keep reserve conditions in line with System
objectives. It tries to cope with large swings in reserves in a
manner that is readily understood by the banks and others, who
are trying to duplicate the Federal Reserve's projections of fac-

page 114


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

tors affecting reserves. Each day the desk weighs both the action
indicated by the day's reserve projections and the wide margins
of error that it knows such estimates involve. The desk must
judge whether the market for reserves primarily reflects underlying reserve availability or the action of banks in building sizable
surpluses or deficiencies in the early part of the statement week.
The main concern is to maintain a degree of reserve pressure on
banks consistent with the nonborrowed reserve objective for the
period or subperiod.
The trading desk uses the System's portfolio to achieve its
reserve objectives. The FOMC spells out the manager's authority
in a special directive, which is reviewed annually but may be
amended as necessary. It authorizes outright transactions at
market prices in Treasury and Federal agency securities with
Government securities dealers or with foreign and international
accounts at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. 1 The FOMC
also authorizes the desk to make repurchase agreements involving those securities, and bankers' acceptances, for periods of up
to 15 days for the New York Reserve Bank's account. The desk
is allowed to interpose the Reserve Bank as intermediary when
concluding repurchase agreements in the market on behalf of
foreign and international accounts. Finally, the FOMC imposes a
limit on the aggregate change permitted in the System's portfolio
in the interval between meetings - $4 billion at the end of 1981.
The manager seeks an increase in this portfolio leeway whenever
circumstances suggest that may be needed to deal with the scale
of reserve changes expected for the intermeeting period.
Within the FOMC's basic authorization and operational directive, the manager and his associates have substantial flexibility in
carrying out Committee instructions. To convey a steadiness of
purpose, their tactics take account of the expected outlook for
bank reserves. Are the banks expected to be short of reserves for
a period of several weeks? Or is a reserve need only temporary
- perhaps because the monthly rise in float will soon be adding

The Strategy of Reseroe
Management

1
The Federal Reserve operated on its own account in the market for bankers' acceptances
until 1977 when the FOMC concluded that market was sufficiently developed that Federal
Reserve participation was no longer appropriate policy The authorization to buy acceptances under repurchase agreements was retained because such operations remain
useful in managing reserves.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 115

to Federal Reserve credit? In the first case, an outright purchase
of Treasury issues may be in order. In the second, the desk might
choose to buy securities under repurchase agreements that expire a week later. Intermeeting tactics also may be conditioned
by the prospective timing and scale of Treasury financing operations, the foreign exchange markets, changes in holdings of foreign official acounts at the Bank, and at times, the state of the
financial markets.
The manager's daily decisions involve a conscious, subtly
changing blend of the dynamic and the defensive. His task is to
generate the pressure on bank reserve positions that accords
with the weekly nonborrowed reserve targets, despite his own
uncertainty about how bank reserves are behaving. In 1981, less
than $50 million a week had to be added to member bank reserves to achieve a 6 percent annual rate of growth. But the
average error in forecasting reserves at the beginning of the
statement week was about ten times as large. The size of the
forecast error gives zest to the game. Each day the manager must
decide whether to buy or sell outright, or to do so with a string
attached so that the impact on reserves is reversed a few days
later. Daily decisions seek to weave a pattern, which is consistent
with the intermeeting objectives for nonborrowed reserves.
1. Outright Operations

page l/6


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

In buying and selling securities, the manager functions within
an established framework of Federal Reserve-Treasury relations,
one designed to keep monetary policy and debt management
separate. In 1981 the Federal Reserve lost its legal authority to
buy up to $5 billion of securities directly from the Treasury after
authorization by five members of the Board of Governors. The
1951 Accord between the Treasury and Federal Reserve freed the
monetary authorities from supporting the prices of Treasury securities in the secondary market. It obligated the Treasury to
design and price its issues to attract private investors and
underwriters.
For many years thereafter, the Federal Reserve avoided monetary policy changes just before, and after, major Treasury financings to enable the Treasury to price issues fairly and the private
market to distribute them to investors. However, in the 1970s the
Federal Reserve could no longer maintain such "even keel" conditions if monetary policy were to pursue its own objectives. The
Treasury increased the frequency of its offerings to reduce each
to a manageable size, and also adopted competitive bidding for

nearly all offerings of notes and bonds. Market participants could
then allow for the future course of monetary policy in the prices
they bid, up to the moment of sale. The Treasury continued to be
able to place its debt efficiently without holding monetary policy
hostage.
The Federal Reserve acquires all of its holdings of Government
and Federal agency securities in the secondary market. The
FOMC does not permit the manager to subscribe for new Treasury issues that are sold for cash. Nor in a refunding can he
subscribe for a larger amount of the issues offered than the
System holds of the maturing securities. The trading desk is
allowed, however, to reduce the System's portfolio by redeeming
a part of maturing holdings - bidding at a lower price than the
Treasury is likely to accept. The desk often uses this technique in
Monday's weekly Treasury bill auctions as a means of absorbing
reserves in the next statement week, which begins on the Thursday the bills are paid for and delivered. It also may choose to run
off a part of maturing Federal agency issues, either for reserve
management or to promote better portfolio balance.
In the secondary market, the manager's key choices involve
when to buy or sell outright, when to operate in securities other
than Treasury bills, and whether transactions will be in the market or with foreign accounts. The timing of outright activity depends principally, but not exclusively, on the outlook for bank

reserves. When the reserve forecasts show a large reserve need
stretching several weeks ahead, the manager may buy a sizable
volume of Treasury or Federal agency securities in the market. In
selecting the actual day, however, market conditions come into
play. Trading desk officers prefer to buy when available supplies
are sufficient to accommodate a large purchase without much
impact on prices. They try to avoid buying in rapidly rising, or
falling, markets, not wishing either to add to market volatility or
to forestall price adjustments. Market participants must evaluate
monetary policy for themselves. Desk officers try not to increase
the price risks private market participants must bear, nor to
insulate participants from such risks.
There are occasions when the manager does use outright
market activity to underscore the thrust of policy. For example, if
monetary growth is excessive, the desk may sell a sizable volume
of Treasury bills in the market to make it clear that interest rates
are going to experience upward pressure. Conversely, when demand for reserves is falling relative to the nonborrowed reserve

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 117

path, outright purchases of Treasury coupon issues, used sparingly, may help generate quicker market responses to subpar
monetary growth.
Most System outright activity is in Treasury bills, reflecting the
depth of that market and the consequent ease with which operations can affect bank reserves. At times, the desk can purchase $1
billion or more of bills with little impact on bill rates. Dealers are
normally somewhat better sellers than buyers in view of their
own inventories, but on many occasions desk sales of $600
million to $700 million of bills would cause hardly a ripple. In
more troubled times, transactions half as large could affect rates
significantly.
Trading desk officers usually have a reasonable idea of
supply-demand conditions in advance through market contracts
and daily operations in Treasury bills for foreign accounts. The
scale of activity can be adjusted once the array of dealer offers,
or bids, is before the officers. All purchases or sales are made on
a best yield basis in relation to the prevailing yield curve. At the
margin the System tends to buy issues that are in excess market
supply, or supply to the market those that are particularly scarce.
The desk uses market purchases of Treasury coupon securities and Federal agency issues to supply a share of the growth of
the reserves needed for monetary expansion in a growing economy. It buys such issues when a sustained reserve need is projected and market availability is great enough to limit the price
effects of buying. Sometimes when the economy is weakening
and interest rates are falling, FOMC members will suggest purchases of intermediate- and longer-term Treasury issues to
encourage interest rates to move lower in the capital markets.
But no one believes that this affects long-term rates more than
marginally beyond the impetus provided by maintaining the desired growth of nonborrowed reserves. The desk has not in practice sold Treasury coupon issues from its portfolio in the market,
although it is theoretically possible to do so.
As an occasional buyer of notes and bonds, the Federal Reserve contributes to the orderly marketing of the Treasury's
coupon issues. Dealers and other underwriters of Treasury
issues, to be sure, have no guarantee as to when the Federal Reserve may come in to buy; nor can dealers be sure
that their occasional sales to the Federal Reserve will be profitable. But the desk's role as a buyer offers encouragement
occasionally to underwriters, and investors too, to acquire
page 118


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

notes and bonds in Treasury auctions.
The scale of System buying depends on the availability of
issues in the market - either in dealers' hands, or readily available from the trading and investment accounts of financial institutes. Generally, the desk buys somewhat less of Treasury notes
and bonds than it would of Treasury bills, to reduce the impact
on market prices. Purchases of $750 million to $1 billion would
not be uncommon; the ready availability of coupon issues in all
maturity sectors expanded with the growth of the marketable
debt in the 1970's. The desk can also buy $500 million to $700
million of Federally sponsored agency securities routinely because of the growth of that market. On occasion, the desk sells
agency issues at the shorter end of the maturity spectrum in the
course of managing bank reserves.
When buying Treasury coupon issues, the desk purchases
those issues whose yields are on, or above, the yield curve represented by offerings throughout the spectrum. Purchases reflect
market availability and a desire for maturity balance, rather than
any desk view of the interest rate outlook. Federally sponsored
agency issues are available at a yield spread over Treasury issues.
The market is continually evaluating the credit risk of each
issuer and the desk buys at the yield spreads prevailing in the
market. Otherwise, its portfolio would become top heavy with
the securities of a single issuer. The issues of the Federal National Mortgage Association, a private corporation, sell at a
somewhat higher yield than those of the other agencies - in part,
because they are not exempt from state and local income taxes.
In addition to transactions in the market, the trading desk has
the option daily of buying Treasury bills from foreign official
accounts, if they are selling. Or it may sell issues from its own
portfolio to meet the buy orders of such accounts. Transactions
with foreign accounts are put through at the middle of the latest
bid and asked prices in the market.
The option to deal with these accounts enables the desk to
add, or withdraw, reserves to the extent of their orders without
any of the announcement effects that accompany a market entry
for the System Account. The desk may be on the buy side rather
consistently, if foreign orders permit, when there is a need to
supply reserves, and on the sell side when reserves are overly
abundant. Often, the desk buys the net of foreign gross sales and
purchases, after transactions have been crossed between different foreign accounts. But on occasion, the desk will buy all the

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

1

page 119

bills sold by accounts, executing the gross purchases of other
accounts in the market. Similarly, desk sales to foreign accounts
may meet either the net or gross volume of their buy orders.
The desk's role as agent for foreign accounts helps it cushion
the shocks to the U.S. money market stemming from international money flows. The desk can shift its reserve supplying effort
toward bills when foreign accounts are large sellers on a sustained basis, or away from bills when the accounts are heavy
buyers. The Federal Reserve and Treasury have likewise worked
together when foreign demand is very large, enabling foreign
accounts to buy market-based special securities issued by the
Treasury. Such actions do not insulate the money and Treasury
securities markets in the longer run from the effects of international flows. But they do help maintain the orderly functioning of
those markets, which are inextricably linked to the international
reserve currency status of the dollar.

2. RPs and MSPs

page 120

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

In managing bank reserves, the manager needs to be able to
put reserves in, or take them out, in large volume for a few days
at a time. Suppose the forecast suggests nonborrowed reserves
are in short supply for the remainder of the current statement
week, but are about as desired for the next week. One possibility
would be to buy Treasury bills outright now and then sell bills
from the portfolio a few days later. But such a course would
expose dealers to an unnecessary market risk and whipsaw the
Treasury bill market. There would be downward pressure on bill
rates in the first instance, and then upward pressure later, when
dealers had to bid on the bills being resold. How much better to
buy the bills under repurchase agreements (RPs ), which obligate
dealers to buy them back on the desired date. The RP approach
injects reserves temporarily, without affecting the interest rate
risks market participants have to bear; it provides financing of
existing dealer positions for a few days, rather than requiring a
change in positions.
When the manager wants to absorb reserves for several days,
matched sale-purchase transactions (MSPs) with dealers provide
a natural response. He sells Treasury bills from the System's
Account for immediate delivery and simultaneously buys them
back for delivery on the date desired. This procedure provides
securities to be financed for a few days, rather than adding to
dealer positions at risk.
The desk relies heavily on RPs and MSPs in dealing with the

uncertainties that affect bank reserves. Even when the reserve
forecasts on Thursday indicate no need for System action, reserves for the week may actually turn out $500 million or so
higher - or lower -than projected. RPs or MSPs enable the desk
to respond quickly when reserves fall short of desired levels or
prove excessive. For example, suppose, on the opening day of the
statement week, the manager concluded that reserves were
probably in short supply because of the Federal funds rate was
rising sharply, even though there was little projected need to add
reserves. The desk could then do a large volume of overnight RPs
without much risk of making reserves overly abundant for the
week as a whole. Overnight RPs would add to the daily average
reserve level only one-seventh of the dollars paid out through
RPs. By using RPs, or MSPs when reserves are in surplus, the
desk can defend against unexpected swings in nonborrowed reserves, which lead away from the week's objective.
When it makes RPs, the desk notifies each of the bank and
nonbank dealers that it wants to do RPs involving eligible collateral of both dealers and their customers for a specified period of
up to 15 days. 2 For System RPs the acceptance division will make
a similar go-around of the acceptance dealers. Within thirty minutes, dealers will begin to call in offerings of the amount that
they and their customers want to do, and the interest rate they
are willing to pay on each lot. Typically, traders on the desk will
have to round up the stragglers to complete the array of competitive bids for funds. The principal traders consolidate the offering amounts by rate, and inform the manager. While the manager
will usually have in mind the total he wants to do, he may do
somewhat more if large offerings, or a stringent Federal funds
market, suggest a larger-than-expected need for reserves. Once
the decision is made as to how low a rate to accept, traders on
the desk quickly notify all dealers of the propositions accepted
and rejected. In a flurry of market calls, participants then compare notes to see what the "stop out" rate was.
Later, each dealer notifies the traders on the desk of the specific securities that dealers or customers are selling to the Federal
Reserve under RP. When notified, the desk's trader will value each
security at a price set somewhat below the current bid price
2
0bligations eligible for purchase under RP are US. government securities; obligations
that are direct obligations of, or fully guaranteed as to principal and interest by, any agency
of the United States,· and prime bankers' acceptances.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 121


page 122
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

being quoted in the market, affording protection against declines
in market price during the term of the contract. The task of
pricing securities continues into the early afternoon. The accounting section prepares tickets, which authorize the government bond department to pay specific amounts as it takes delivery of the separate blocks of securities. Because of the length of
the process and the possibility of early dealer withdrawals,
which further complicate the accounting, RPs are made for the
account of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York rather than
the System Open Market Account. The System Account must
be divided each business day among the twelve Federal Reserve Banks. RPs are subject to the terms of a comprehensive
collateral agreement, which affirms the right of the Reserve
Bank to sell the securities in the event the dealer fails to
repurchase them.
In form, MSPs are a different kind of animal, even though they
are just the reverse of an RP in their effect on reserves. The sale
side of a matched sale-purchase transaction is an outright sale of a
specific Treasury bill from the System's portfolio. The purchase
side is a contract to buy that bill for deli~ry at a particular future
date. In making MSPs, System traders notify dealers of the market
rate at which the desk will sell the particular bill. Dealers then
submit the amount they are willing to buy and the rate at which
they will reoffer. The manager may raise or lower the amount he
has in mind if the bidding seems to indicate a bigger, or smaller,
volume of the reserves in the banking system than he expected.
The rate of discount set by the desk determines the price realized
by the System on its sale while the competitively set reoffering
rate determines the prices at which it reacquires the same issue
of bills one or more days later. Such sales also result in a System
profit or loss recorded in relation to book value.
Both the desk and the dealer retain the option to terminate the
usual RP contract before maturity. In practice, the desk does not
exercise the option. Dealers often do, repurchasing their securities when they make cash sales or refinance them at a lower RP
rate than was established on the Federal Reserve contract. The
right of withdrawal on contracts maturing beyond one day,
means that the desk is uncertain at the time it makes RPs what
the effect will be on average reserve levels for the week. This can
be an advantage. If nonborrowed reserves turn out too high,
dealers are apt to repurchase their securities early and absorb
reserves in the process.

The withdrawal feature also can lead to difficulty in maintaining desired reserve levels - for example, when a strong demand
for securities, rather than an abundance of reserves, causes the
decline in RPs. When the desk wants to be sure that its reserve
injection sticks, it offers nonwithdrawable RPs - most commonly
for a week. MSPs, for their part, are not subject to withdrawal
since they are literally matched outright transactions with specified delivery dates.
The desk integrates its RP and MSP operations with the temporary investment activity of foreign accounts to achieve reserve
objectives and to reduce the number of market entries. Many
foreign official and international accounts maintain a portion of
their dollar holdings in a daily investment facility provided by the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York. Each daily forecast of nonborrowed reserves assumes that the System will sell securities from
its own portfolio at market rates to this RP pool, under a contract
to buy them back the next day (MSPs ). The manager also has the
option of investing part, or all, of these pooled funds by making
customer-related RPs in the market. Both a pass-through of customer orders and RPs made for the System Account supply
reserves to the banking system and increase nonborrowed
reserves relative to the levels shown in daily projections.
The choice depends largely on the magnitude of RPs that the
desk wants to make. When the reserve need is less than about
$1.5 billion and RP collateral is readily available in the market,
the manager usually will pass through foreign account orders.
When the reserve need is larger, or there is likely to be a problem
in rounding up sufficient securities to be bought under RP, the
manager is likely to make System RPs in the market in the first
instance and to make MSPs with the foreign account pool as
assumed in the projections. With System RPs, bankers' acceptances become available as eligible collateral.
In varying the mix between outright and RP transactions, the
manager and his associates take account of the availability of
eligible securities, and bankers' acceptances in the hands of
dealers, banks and other market-oriented investors. At times, it is
possible to do $5 billion or $6 billion of overnight RPs at rates
only 25 basis points below the rate at which Federal funds are
trading. At other times, to do $1 billion of such RPs may be
difficult because of a scarcity of such collateral.
To some extent, the availability of securities being financed
day-to-day is a function of the interest-rate outlook of dealers

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 123

and others making an interest-rate play. When market players are
optimistic that interest rates will soon decline, they tend to add
substantially to positions. Accessible collateral becomes plentiful and the RP rate rises toward the Federal funds rate. When
gloom settles over the fraternity, positions are cut back sharply
and the RP rate may fall 100 basis points or more below the
Federal funds rate. Other investors, especially money market
funds, also tend to move large amounts of funds between RPs
and other short-term instruments as their own interest rate expectations change.
The l'iew from the Desk

The working day at the trading desk has a regular rhythm,
which flows naturally from the task at hand. Activity radiates
from the trading room itself, a busy room on the eighth floor of
the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. The officers begin the day
at 9 a.m. with a series of meetings with Government securities
dealers. Traders at the desk are simultaneously preparing for a
day of gathering information from the market. 3 At the same time
research personnel are pulling together the previous day's data
on reserves and bank activity. A little after 10 a.m. the manager
learns how total and nonborrowed reserves turned out the previ-

ous day and what the revised reserve outlook will be for the
current week. The manager, or an associate, discusses with the
fiscal assistant secretary of the Treasury how the Treasury plans
to manage its balance in the days ahead. Before 11 a.m. the
manager and his associates review developments in the money
and securities markets, assess the new forecast of bank reserves,
and formulate a program of action for the day.
About 11:15 a.m. a telephone conference call begins, in which a
desk officer reviews the situation and outlines the day's program
for one of the Reserve Bank presidents serving on the FOMC, and
the senior staff of the Board of Governors. Any action to affect
reserves that day is usually undertaken soon after the call. Purchases or sales for next day delivery may be undertaken later in
the day. The accounting section sees that the books reflect whatever is done, while deliveries and payments are carried out by
the Government bond department. By 1:30 p.m. or slightly later,
the possibility is past for action to affect reserves the same day.
Traders in the dealer market are those authorized to deal, or take positions, for the Finn
whereas Federal Reserve traders have the more circumscribed responsibility of carrying out
transactions authorized by officers in charge of the desk.
3

page 124


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Traders and clerks struggle with the paperwork needed to complete the day's activity. The traders maintain their watch on the
financial markets, while the officers turn to other tasks.
A few minutes before 9 a.m., two or three officers of the securities department walk up the back stairs from the eighth floor of
the Bank to a room on the tenth floor. At the same time, a senior
officer or trader of one of the Government securities dealers with
which the desk trades, and one or two colleagues are making
their way down Liberty Street. The Bank, with its Florentine
facade of massive stone blocks, contrasts sharply with the sleek
60-story steel and glass structure of the Chase Manhattan Bank
across the street. The dealers pass under the massive wrought
iron candelabra that flank the bank's entrance, enter the high
ceilinged lobby, and proceed to the special elevator that whisks
them to the tenth floor. Entering the subdued elegance of the
executive floor, they join the Reserve Bank officers around the
rectangular table of the room, in which weekly press briefings are
held for business reporters each Friday afternoon.
These morning discussions with leading members of the
dealer community help the manager and desk officers keep abreast of the forces at work in financial markets. Representatives
of each of the dealers operating from a New York base made the
trip to Liberty Street once every two weeks on a prearranged
schedule; out-of-town dealers phone in on a schedule of their
own. Each weekday morning representatives of two or three
dealers typically arrive in succession for a chat with desk
officers.
These morning conversations are free flowing, covering a wide
range of subjects in IS-minute installments. To the outsider they
are full of market jargon, shorthand references to the prices,
practices and pressures that are an everyday concern. To insiders they are an efficient way of exchanging information, albeit
the desk officers must remain silent on the policy issues of
greatest interest to the dealers. Daily meetings face-to-face
emphasize it is real people who make markets. However sensitive they are to the subtlest changes in financial flows, they
are individuals first and foremost - quiet or articulate, cool or
emotional, analytical or with the sixth sense of a born trader.
At times they will be caught up in the collective enthusiasms
or fears that make bull or bear markets. The fraternity is not
large - a few hundred at most. Desk officers have to know

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

I. Daily Dealer Meetings

page 125

the major players and their personal chemistry to interpret
properly the comments that flow across the table.
A dealer representative may open the meeting by giving the
firm's operating assumptions about what Federal funds rate
levels are consistent with the desk's current reserve objectives.
The dealer usually elaborates on how rates are expected to
change in coming weeks. The firm's money market economist
often comes along to outline the economic analysis and interest
rate outlook the firm is presenting to clients. Desk officers are
studiously noncommital as dealers outline alternative scenarios
or their own conclusions. But they do try to get each visitor to
assess the general market view on the outlook for interest rates.
Dealer comments on what their customers are actually doing in
the market are helpful. Are customers sitting on the sidelines or
clearly favoring short-term securities? Or are they reaching out to
intermediate- or longer-term issues? Dealers may touch as well on
whether their firm has an aggressive short position in the expectation rates will soon move sharply higher, is close to shore in a
choppy market, or is placing a sizable bet on a near-term fall in
interest rates. The visitors will often give their own estimate of the
technical position of the Street. Are dealers in the aggregate short
or long? Do shortages in particular maturity areas, or excess
supplies, explain the way the market has been behaving in recent
days? For the desk officers, the succession of meetings each day,
day after day, keeps them in touch with the changing analyses,
moods, and concerns of the market makers themselves.
Treasury financings provide a recurring theme for the dealer
meetings. The manager and his associates may inquire about
how much the market expects the Treasury to sell of marketable
issues in the current or following quarter. They get running
reports on how the distribution of recently sold issues are
progressing, as well as on customer interest in coming offerings. To dealers, bidding in Treasury auctions of bills and coupon issues is just an extension of the daily task of making
markets in outstanding issues. They readily provide desk officers with their estimates of what concessions to the yield
curve will be necessary to sell new securities. Dealer opinions
on the weekly auction are apt to be similar, but approaches to
the Treasury's quarterly coupon offerings often differ. From
these conversations and other market contacts, desk officers
can keep Treasury officials posted on the apparent public
appetite for new securities and the amounts and maturities
page 126


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

the market expects for nonroutine financings.
Desk officers use these sessions to keep up with developments
throughout the financial system. Each dealer brings to the discussion the special strengths of the firm. Both bank and nonbank
dealers trade with major national and regional banks.
They comment on bank trading activity and on the strength of
business loan demand, current and prospective issuance of CDs,
whether current rate relationships favor recourse to CDs or
Eurodollars, and developments in the foreign exchange markets.
Dealers keep the desk informed of what they see foreign central
banks doing directly in the market. Others, especially tuned in to
savings banks and savings and loan associations, alert desk officers to the mortgage demands, and the liquidity and earning
pressures, such institutions are experiencing. A number of dealers can answer questions about activity in commercial paper and
bankers' acceptances from their own experience. Desk officers
also keep up with prospective corporate and municipal bond
flotations by quizzing the dealers with large investment banking
operations.
The morning sessions enable a dealer to bring up matters of
particular interest to the firm. Senior management may use the
occasion to report its plans for redirecting its manpower or
entering new lines of activity. Personnel changes in the firm, or
the industry, often come up, and new senior personnel may be
introduced at a morning session. Dealers raise questions about
the desk's procedures or operational problems they may be having with the Federal Reserve's wire transfer network. Desk officers, for their part, may bring up the need for a particular dealer
to be more attentive to bidding when the desk or the Treasury is
selling securities. They also may ask about a dealer's position,
recent profit experience, or the present state of industry plans for
self-regulation.
After concluding the dealer meetings at 10 a.m. or a bit before,
the officers hurry back to the trading room on the eighth floor.
There the traders have already been making calls in both the
Federal funds market and the Treasury market. Typically, Federal
funds brokers will have opened trading for the day and will be
quoting bids and offers to the customer they are bringing together. Desk traders will have clipped important news developments from the three news tickers. They also will be checking
the information screens for the opening quotes on the most


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

2. The 'Jreasury Call

page 127

A Day at

the Trading Desk

Discussing the market with dealers.

10:00
Reviewing market developments in
the trading room.

10.15
Consulting the Treasury by phone
about its balances at the Reserve Banks.

10:45
Developing a plan of action for the day.

page 128


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

11.15
Confe"ing by phone with FOMC
representatives on the day's program.

11:45

.~j/

Buying bills from dealers in
a market go round.

·,. / ·.

-~.·

'

'

'

.:

Sizing up market reactions to the
Friday money supply data.

Photos by Arthur Kranisky

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 129

actively traded Government securities and for the latest opinions
of money market analysts who use this device to get their views
before customers. A few calls to dealers through the direct lines
of the telephone console enable each trader to put down the
opening price levels on the ruled tablets used to track each day's
market developments. Meanwhile, the clerks have posted the
price quotes established for yesterday's close on the long
chalkboard, which wraps around one end of the room. They
begin to get opening price runs from each of the five active
dealers the desk uses to compile its composite snapshot of the
market's price behavior. When the officers arrive, they take only a
few minutes to catch up with what is happening and to pass on
to the traders at the desk any points of particular interest picked
up in the dealer meetings.
The daily call from the Treasury provides one of the fixed
points in the desk's well-organized day. In preparation for this
call, the manager or another senior officer reviews data on
member bank reserves and borrowing, which have just been
telephoned to his secretary by the research department. He
notes how much the reserve outcome differs from the forecast
made the day before. The reserve forecaster soon arrives from

the ninth floor to brief the manager on how this reserve miss will
affect nonborrowed reserves in the current statement week. The
worksheet also shows how the Treasury's balance at the Reserve
Banks is expected to behave for that day and the two following
days. About 10:15 a.m., the Fiscal Assistant Secretary calls to
compare Treasury staff forecasts of these changes with the New
York estimates. He must decide whether to move funds between
commercial banks and its balances with the Reserve Banks.
The Treasury's system of tax and loan accounts at commercial
banks provides an important buffer to the monetary system,
shielding the reserves of the banks from the large net flows of
funds between the Treasury and the remainder of the economy.
The conception is straightforward enough. A large part of the
Treasury's tax receipts flow through the direct investment facilities provided it by depository institutions across the country. 4
The '/reasury's depositories can choose whether to remit '/reasury receipts immediately to
the Reserve Banks or to retain them, incurring a note liability to the '/reasury that is fully
co//ateralized and pays 25 basis points less than the Federal funds rate. The depositories
are divided into A, B, and C categories depending on their activity as depositories. As of
mid-1981, there were 484 C depositories, 1,751 B depositories, and 2,578 A depositories.
4

page 130


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

It then transfers funds between these accounts and its checking
accounts at the twelve Federal Reserve Banks as necessary to
keep its Reserve Bank balances reasonably steady - at about $3
billion in early 1982. Since the Treasury's checks are drawn
against its accounts at the Reserve Banks, the Treasury routinely
covers the estimated value of checks to be presented by making
"calls" on depository institutions to transfer funds to the Federal
Reserve. On other days there can be a net inflow to Treasury
accounts at the Federal Reserve - usually when the Treasury
receives cash from the sale of new securities in excess of the
volume of securities maturing. Then, to offset the reserve drain
that would result from subscribers' payments to the
Federal Reserve in exchange for the securities, the Treasury can
place excess funds in the direct investment facility it maintains
with depositories.
In the daily telephone call, the Fiscal Assistant Secretary decides on the call, or direct investment, of funds to be made with
the larger institutions - the C depositories - on the next business day. But on occasion the C depositories are asked to transfer, or receive, funds by 11 a.m. the same day because the Treasury must rebuild a depleted balance at the Reserve Banks or
wishes to redeploy surplus funds . The manager of the account
has a keen interest in these decisions because of their effect on
bank reserves. Frequently, the daily calls split the difference between the Treasury and New York Reserve Bank estimates of
what needs to be done. On occasion, however, the manager may
ask that the balance be allowed to ride up or decline to assist
with the management of reserves. For example, if RP collateral
were in short supply relative to a short-run reserve need, the
manager would welcome the help that a lower-than-assumed
balance would give in achieving his reserve objectives.
Other topics come up at the Treasury conference call as well.
Senior desk officers may pass along information about foreign
central bank subscriptions to forthcoming Treasury issues,
which often affect the projected cash position. The timing of
future Treasury offerings and the associated payment dates may
also come up. On other occasions, the desk officers will talk in
more detail with the Deputy Assistant Secretary for Debt Management about the Treasury cash outlook and financing plans.
After the Treasury call, the desk officers usually discuss a
tentative program of action for the day. The reserve data have

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

3. Formulating the Day's Program

page 131

132
Digitized for page
FRASER
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

already shown yesterday's reserve miss and whether discount
window borrowing is close to desired levels. The reserve projector has given a rough estimate of what he now thinks nonborrowed reserves will average during the current statement week.
The practical question is: What is to be done in pursuit of the
nonborrowed reserve target? Desk officers always know less
today about current bank and reserve behavior than they will
know a day or two later. They are very conscious that reserves
may vary substantially from the forecast, and that banks may
behave quite differently than desired.
The approach banks take to reserve management can substantially affect the market for reserves for much of the week, quite
aside from the general availability of reserves in the system. All
other things being equal, the Federal funds rate and borrowing at
the Reserve Bank are likely to rise when the major banks elect to
play it safe by accumulating excess reserves early in the week for example, when holidays fall around the weekend. Conversely,
if the major banks expect the Federal funds rate to be trending
downward because money growth or economic activity is sluggish, they often are willing to accumulate sizable deficiencies
early in the week in hopes of covering them at a lower Federal
funds rate toward the end of the week.
The discussions in the manager's office review the new information available on both reserves and borrowing. On Thursday,
of course, there is only a projection for the current week. But the
officers may discuss whether any tightness or ease that developed in the money market on Wednesday, the settlement date,
will carry over to affect bank attitudes toward the discount window in the week just beginning. A carryover of tightness may
suggest an early beginning on meeting any projected reserve
need to reduce the likelihood of a big bulge in discount window
borrowing over the weekend. Alternatively, a very comfortable
atmosphere may suggest allowing forecast reserve deficiencies
to bite first in hopes that borrowing will not fall much below the
levels implicit in the reserve path.
On Monday desk officers will know from the borrowing average of Thursday-Sunday how much discount window borrowing
must rise, or fall, in the remaining three days to be consistent
with the reserve path. Low use of the window during the first
four days will require a very sharp rise for the remainder of the
week. Conversely, very heavy borrowing early in the week will
require a sharp fall in borrowing in the days remaining. In some

cases, heavy Friday borrowing will virtually guarantee that borrowing for the week and total reserves will exceed desired levels
if the nonborrowed objective is met.
The desk's operational objective is the average level of nonborrowed reserves for the intermeeting period or subperiod as
a whole. If one pumps in reserves to hit the weekly objective
when borrowing has been excessive, ease at the end of the
week tends to carry over to the beginning of the next statement week and lead banks to be more relaxed in managing
their reserve positions. Alternatively, the desk can accept a
moderate shortfall from its NBR objective with a view to making it up in subsequent weeks. Toward the end of the week,
desk officers also have to weigh the possibility that the banking system's demand for excess reserves was incorrectly
estimated at the time the week's reserves objective was set,
and that nonborrowed reserves should be somewhat higher or
lower on that account.
Such questions arise inescapably in the pursuit of reserve
targets. If the desk plunges ahead mechanically, the likely consequence is interest rate instability, which tends to confuse the
banks and other portfolio managers the Federal Reserve is trying
to influence. But, if the desk is too ready to adjust each week's
reserve objective, there is the opposite risk of deferring needed
adjustments in borrowing and market interest rates. In fact, the

manager usually has pursued a middle course, one which partially compensates for the vagaries of bank borrowing, while
assuring that deviations in aggregate growth have their desired
impact on interest rates during the intermeeting period.
When the desk officers discuss the tentative design of the day's
program, the amount of reserves to be added, or withdrawn, to
reach the nonborrowed objective is clear enough. But individual
recommendations to the manager may differ, reflecting different
degrees of confidence in the forecast and independent assessments of bank behavior in the current week. Market considerations, such as the availability of securities in the market for
outright purchase or as RP collateral, also enter. A ten-minute
discussion will air the most promising courses of action open to
the manager. Much of the time there will be general agreement in
this informal review on what is to be done. But there also are
times when the choice is sufficiently close that the manager
defers the decision until all can get a better reading on what is
happening in the market for reserves that day.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 133

4. The 'Jrading Room Scene

page 134

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

A short stroll from the manager's office brings the desk officers
back to the bustle of the trading room a little after 10:30 a.m. The
senior traders on the desk quickly report the forces at work
behind the price changes shown for the key issues they track on
the working pads in front of them. They also recap the market's
bidding ideas on any Treasury securities coming to market during the next few days. The behavior of the corporate and municipal bond markets and their interaction with the Government
market is another point of interest.
The behavior of the Federal funds market and the success of
dealers in financing their positions are important matters. Substantial misses in the projector's estimates of nonborrowed
reserves may show up as greater, or lesser, pressures in the reserves market as banks seek to cover their requirements. A
senior desk trader keeps close touch throughout the day with the
Federal funds brokers and the money desks of major banks in
New York City and in other major cities. She reports on the
balance in the market between the demand for, and supply of,
funds, and also on how major banks plan to meet their need for
funds. Timely data on the reserve positions and Federal funds
transactions of 15 major banks for the previous day provide good
background for her discussions with the banks. Another trader is
simultaneously tracking the progress the nonbank dealers are
making in financing their positions. Both banks and nonbank
dealers are, in fact, searching for overnight funds.
Other senior traders have been in touch with the foreign department to find out what foreign official accounts will be doing
that day. By 11 a.m., or shortly before, they will know the aggregate purchases and sales of Treasury bills to be made and the
volume of funds to be invested overnight in the RP pool. As the
morning progresses, the totals are apt to change. But they
usually are accurate enough at this point for desk officers to
decide how foreign account transactions are to mesh with open
market operations that day.
The officers on the receiving end of this information use it to
refine their assessment of what needs to be done that day. Does
the behavior of the Federal funds market suggest that reserves
are more, or less, plentiful than the projector's tentative estimate
at the time of the Treasury call? Are the banks approaching
reserve management cautiously or with a willingness to let
deficiencies accumulate?
Shortly before 11 a.m. the officers receive from the reserve

projector several sheets, detailing the latest forecasts of nonborrowed reserves, and a comparison with the week's nonborrowed
reserve objective. With luck the Board staff's estimate of nonborrowed reserves will also be available. After a brief huddle with
other officers, the manager or a senior officer writes a program
of action, one which details the reserve situation and any other
considerations that have influenced the approach taken. On Friday the program also will review the latest information on the
monetary aggregates, and present adjustments being made in
the NBR objective, either for technical reasons or for speeding
the return of the aggregates to their desired paths.
Meanwhile, preparations are going forward elsewhere in the
trading room for a staff pre-call to the Board and the Reserve
Bank whose president will be sitting in on the 11 :15 a.m. telephone conference call. On the staff call, which begins shortly
before 11 a.m., a trader at the desk will provide in a standard format a formidable array of data on the behavior of financial
markets, the reserves of the banking system, and the latest
forecasts of nonborrowed reserves. Simultaneously, one of
the desk officers will be reviewing all aspects of the data
and the financial markets preparatory to speaking on the 11:15
a.m. call.
Each working day at 11:15 a.m. the manager, other officers, and
senior staff members gather in the manager's office for a conference call, which links the desk with the Board's staff director for
monetary policy and his staff, and with one of the Reserve Bank
presidents serving on the FOMC. The call provides the Board
staff with the desk's review of market and reserve developments
and the manager's plan for open market operations. The staff
condenses this in a brief report, which is placed before each
governor by early afternoon and wired to each Reserve Bank
president. The call enables the Manager to consult daily with one
of the Committee members concerning the desk's execution of
FOMC instructions. The president on the call not only has an
opportunity to comment daily on the desk's approach, but also
experiences all of the uncertainties and difficulties with which
operations must contend between meetings. When the FOMC
reviews operations at its next meeting, he will be well equipped
to provide a policymaker's perspective on the events of the
period.
The call itself usually runs 15 to 20 minutes. The desk officer

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

5. The Conference Call

page 135

speaking on the call opens with a review of price and rate
movements in the principal securities markets and the influences
market participants see at work. Mention is made of current
developments in the gold and foreign exchange markets, although the staff director at the Board usually has a good fix on
those markets from prior conversations with the foreign exchange trading desk. The desk officer turns then to the Federal
funds market, giving the latest information on rates and on what
progress the major banks are making in covering their reserve
needs. Then he or she compares the New York's reserve estimates with those prepared by the Board staff. Early in the statement week, the estimates may differ by $500 million or more. The
call provides a convenient opportunity for learning whether the
discrepancy stems largely from differences in projected float behavior or from other sources. Over the statement week the estimates usually come closer together, but differences of several
hundred million dollars sometimes still remain on the Wednesday statement date. Finally, the desk officer reads the proposed
program of action and asks the Reserve Bank president for his
comments. Occasionally, a governor, sitting in at the Board, will
also comment.
The responses of the presidents on the call vary considerably.
Often a president will concur in the manager's approach with
little comment. If a president has any concern about the way
operations are unfolding, he is more likely to call later in the day
to discuss them with the manager than to air his misgivings on
the morning call. On the other hand, if it is an operational question, a president may ask whether the manager has considered
an alternative approach and elicit from him or the officer on the
call further elaboration of the reasoning that has gone into formation of the proposed program. Such a question might be
whether consideration is being given to buying Treasury coupon
issues as a means of meeting a reserve need, which stretches
over the next several weeks. The discussion is unfailingly
friendly as well as informative. If more discussion of recent developments seems needed, the manager usually calls the president after the day's operations are launched. With four Reserve
Bank presidents outside New York participating regularly each
year, the call provides the presidents first-hand contact with the
translation of policy decisions into day-to-day desk actions. The
New York Bank president is, of course, regularly briefed by the
manager or other desk officers.
page 136


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

The staff director for monetary policy also uses the 11:15 a.m.
call to give to the desk the latest information on the monetary
aggregates. Usually by Wednesday morning his staff has a fairly
good fix on bank deposits for the week ended the previous
Wednesday. These will be incorporated in the Ml measure of
the money supply to be published on Friday. The staff director,
or his alternate, will give Ml estimates for the previous week.
Often he also will give a first estimate of the current week's Ml ,
based on reports by the larger institutions for part of the week
and on similar reports from a sample of other institutions.
These data are subject to further refinement on Thursday; by
Friday morning the staff director will give the monetary data
to be published that afternoon, the preliminary estimate for
the week just passed, and the revised projections of these
aggregates for the current month. The data already have been
communicated to the New York Bank staff, along with the Board
staff's projection of the demand for total reserves over the intermeeting period.
Friday is a special day, since the manager and staff director
must review with their staffs the recalculation of reserve paths.
This is the time for making any modifications warranted by
technical factors or a need to augment the automatic response
to deviations of the aggregates from path (Chapter 5). The difference between the Board staff's revised projection of total

reserves over the intermeeting period or subperiod, and the
nonborrowed reserve objective establishes the level of adjustment borrowing in the current and subsequent weeks that is
consistent with the committee's Ml and M2 objectives. After
preliminary discussion with the manager, the staff director
reviews the matter with the chairman of the FOMC. In the desk's
Friday program the manager details the reserve objectives for
the week and the subperiod, with a brief explanation of how
they were developed.
The manager and staff director keep the chairman fully informed
of all significant matters relating to open market operations. The
manager makes sure the chairman is informed in advance about
large outright transactions, or operations that could have an appreciable market impact. The manager also is responsible under
the directive for notifying the chairman whenever the Federal
funds rate appears likely to be outside the range set by the Committee for an extended period. The chairman then decides
whether consultation of the full committee is in order.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 137

6. Executing the Daily Program

page 138


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

When the call ends, a bit after 11:30 a.m., the officers usually
carry out the program outlined fairly quickly. To emphasize the
break with the Federal funds rate operating strategy, the desk
concentrates most of its reserve management operations between 11:30 a.m. and 12:15 p.m. This approach seeks to assure
market participants that open market operations are directed at
reserve objectives, rather than at maintaining the Federal funds
rate within any particular band. On rare occasions, usually when
an unusual rise or fall in the Federal funds rate suggests the
reserve estimates are substantially in error, the desk may operate
outside the normal time, but they are the exceptions that prove
the rule. In conducting outright transactions, the desk frequently
buys or sells securities during the afternoon for delivery a day or
two later. These transactions have no immediate impact on reserve availability or the Federal funds rate; often, the reserve
effect takes place in a subsequent statement week.
As noted earlier, System open market operations are generally
meshed with foreign account investment activities to reduce the
number of market entries by the trading desk. There will be no
outright market transactions at all if the desk chooses to buy the
net of Treasury bills being sold by foreign accounts or to sell
from the System portfolio to meet the net buy orders of foreign
accounts. Frequently, however, foreign accounts will be net
sellers or net buyers of bills, when the desk has no need to be
involved. If the net of foreign orders is small, less than $100
million to $150 million, the desk may shop them around the
market to a handful of dealers. Larger foreign orders will require
a go-around of all dealers to get competitive bids or offerings.
System operations in RPs or MSPs for reserve management purposes may either precede or follow the entry for foreign accounts. The desk does not announce the magnitude of its own
operations for reserve management purposes, although market
participants are usually able to establish the scale by comparing
notes after the operation is over. The desk does announce the
approximate size of foreign account transactions to the market
at the time of market entry.
Once the desk enters the market, operations proceed expeditiously under the supervision of the two officers charged
with primary responsibility for the trading room. If the trading
desk makes either RPs or MSPs in the market, six or eight traders, often with the aid of two or three officers, quickly announce
the System's intent to the dealers with whom the desk trades in

a go-around of the market. The traders take pride in completing these notification calls quickly- usually in less than 60 seconds. Normally, the operation can be completed within 45
minutes, allowing time to assemble and aggregate the competitive dealer propositions and then decide on the stop-out rate,
which determines the amount of reserves actually pumped in
or withdrawn.
Outright transactions in either bills or coupon securities are
more time-consuming, both because dealers contact a large
number of customers and because a larger number of bids or
offers have to be priced and recorded. Choosing among the
propositions is also more complicated because a yield curve
involves more choices than the single interest rate comparison
typical of RPs and MSPs. Generally, an hour or more is required
for a go-around in Treasury bills. A similar operation in Treasury
coupon securities or Federal agency issues can easily require
two hours, largely because of the increased number of maturities
and the operational time required by desk personnel to compare
offering yields relative to the yield curve.
The trading room is busy while a major operation is in process. The buttons on all the telephone turrets light up initially as
the traders make their calls to traders at the dealer firms. A lull
follows while the dealers' salesmen contact their customers and
each firm's traders decide what they want to do for the firm's own

account. Then, the phones begin to ring insistently as the dealers
try to reach a trader at the Federal Reserve to take down their
propositions. Traders record dealer bids or offerings on strips
preprinted with two dealer names at the top of each strip. The
issues involved have already been posted on each strip so that
the amounts and prices bid for, or offered, can be listed quickly.
Desk traders read back each dealer's propositions to guard
against errors. The officers assemble the go-around strips used
by the traders on one or more big boards. These allow a quick
and accurate comparison of the rates or prices being quoted for
different maturities.
After carefully choosing the better propositions from the array
before them, the officers return the strips to the individual traders so they may notify the dealers as to which propositions were
accepted and which rejected. Then, the traders must turn to
writing tickets on the individual transactions with the dealers
they cover. The tickets on outright transactions and MSPs are
quite straightforward; the accounting unit in the adjoining room

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 139

will translate them through computerized processing into a
multipart form , which specifies the securities to be received or
delivered and the amount of money that is to move. The completed transaction form is then whisked by pneumatic tube to
the government bond department on the second floor, where the
actual exchange of securities and payments will take place
through the Federal Reserve's computerized system. With RPs,
the dealer calls in the collateral involved and the desk's traders
set a price that allows a margin against the risk of price fluctuation. Once the pricing is completed, the tickets written by
the traders follow the same channels as those for outright
transactions.
Cash transactions - those that are settled the same day affect the reserves of the banking system in short order. For
example, securities purchased from the dealers, either outright
or under RPs, are paid for by immediate credit directly to the
reserve accounts of bank dealers and to the accounts of nonbank
dealers at the commercial banks that clear for them.
When a dealer has served as an intermediary for a customer,
he or his clearing bank tells the Federal Reserve Bank the name
of the institution that will deliver the securities and receive payment over the Federal Reserve wire network. Purchases of the
dealer's own securities also typically lead to a stream of payments after the initial credit, since the dealer has probably been
financing them with RPs or bank loans, which must be paid off.
Individual banks across the country benefit from an infusion of
reserves, although they may not distinguish it from all the other
bank and customer transactions that are flowing through their
reserve accounts. In a similar fashion, sales of securities, either
outright or under RPs, reduce the reserves of individual banks
and the banking system.
The reserve effects of System transactions are quite predictable, but the reaction of the Federal funds market appears somewhat less certain with reserve targeting than was the case when
the System's strategy focused on the Federal funds rate. As will
be examined more fully in Chapter 8, banks seem to be somewhat more influenced in their reserve management than before
by their interest rate expectations within the statement week and
beyond. The Federal funds rate can, and often does, trade for a
few days or even longer above - or below - what one might
expect from average past relationships to discount window
borrowing.

page 140


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Accordingly, the desk may find that its actions have little immediate effect on the market for reserves, especially early in the
statement week - unless its actions are quite large indeed. As the
statement week progresses, the market becomes more likely to
reflect the underlying relationship between nonborrowed reserves and required reserves. By Wednesday, the banks' room to
maneuver is limited. Then the desk can estimate reasonably well
how much the banks will be forced to borrow that night at the
window if the week's nonborrowed reserve objective is achieved.
In other circumstances, the volume of excess reserves to be
pressed on the market can be estimated.
In conducting open market operations, the desk must focus on
reserves day by day. It operates in a world of uncertainty uncertainty about how nonborrowed reserves will behave, how
much excess reserves banks will retain and what tactics banks
will use in managing their reserve positions. Reserve management is also an interactive game. Beset by uncertainties of their
own, banks need the buffer of the discount window as protection
against the vagaries of daily money flows. For the money market
banks these are quite large in relation to the reserve balances
that they must maintain. The banks' freedom to maneuver may
complicate the attainment of the desk's weekly nonborrowed reserve objectives at times, but such complications are a small
price to pay for a smoothly functioning financial system.
The Committee's strategy for monetary control envisages hitting reserve objectives over intermeeting periods of six weeks or
longer. That permits ample time for smoothing aberrant shortrun behavior without sacrificing sustained responses to meaningful monetary deviations. The desk operates with incomplete
information amid conflicting signals that cannot be fully understood at the time. But Committee members can be confident that
the outcome over longer periods will be close to the Committee's
desires - at least as far as reserves are concerned.
The desk operates in an environment in which the emotions
and reactions of traders move global financial markets more from
minute to minute than do the analyses of economists. There is
no substitute for the "feel of the market" as participants try to
sort out emerging trends in bank behavior and portfolio management from ephemeral market movements. Caught up in the
churning life of the financial markets, those on the trading desk
may well suffer from market myopia. At the same time, they also

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Communications Within
the System

page 141

are exposed daily to the judgments that market people are making about the effectiveness of monetary policy. One of the desk's
functions is to keep others in the System posted, not only about
how operations are carrying the committee's thrust forward into
the financial arena, but also about the kind of feedback that
policy is getting. Visits by System research personnel to the desk
and regular desk reports to the committee are important means
of maintaining a clear understanding of both key aspects of the
monetary policy process.
Most policymakers can spare little time to visit the desk for
firsthand exposure to the System's interface with financial markets. They pose their questions to the manager in the formal
sessions of the committee, or buttonhole him in the corridors of
the Board during breaks in the committee's discussions. The
Reserve Bank presidents also frequently ask about market perceptions during the camaraderie that marks the regular ritual of
checking into a nearby hotel on the night before the meeting,
going out for dinner, and shuttling over to the Board for breakfast the next morning. But policymakers understandably rely
primarily on their staffs to monitor open market operations and
the financial markets.
The trading desk has a regular flow of staff visitors from both
the Board and the Reserve Banks, who come to observe operations to help them brief their principals or do monetary research.
Usually visitors participate in the desk's daily routines for a
week, as well as spending time with Government securities dealers, a bank money desk and a Federal funds broker. Desk officers
lead the visitors through the morning dealer visits, the Treasury
call, and the 11:15 a.m. call, explaining the array of data that feed
into daily decision making. Interviews with the research personnel that project both reserves and money supply acquaint visitors with the current state of the projector's art, while the daily
experience of reserve misses drives home the range of uncertainties within which operations are conducted.
For desk personnel these recurring contacts with System
economists with diverse points of view, contribute to the intellectual challenge that makes the desk a stimulating place to
work. The personal interchanges that mark these visits make it
easy for any visitor to get on the phone to a desk officer whenever a question arises about the current conduct of operations or
technical issues related to financial markets.
The desk's main channels for communicating with the rest of
page 142


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

the System are the daily wires and written reports sent from New
York to the Board and the Reserve Banks. Wires sent daily from
the trading desk inform everyone of developments in the money
and Government securities markets at mid-morning and in late
afternoon. As already noted, the Board staff report on the 11 :15
a.m. call gives a full view of reserve data, the markets, and the
desk's program for the day.
On Friday of each week the trading desk mails a comprehensive report on operations for the statement ended on the preceding Wednesday. This report, prepared in the analytical division
under an officer's direction, describes the daily conduct of operations and tracks the behavior of the reserve measures in relation
to their desired paths. It also conveys the latest data on the
monetary aggregates, as well as the projections being made by
the Board and New York Bank staffs. Separate sections are included on bank reserves and the money market as well as the
Government, corporate and municipal securities markets. Statistical appendices summarize all transactions in the System account, as well as information on the financial markets. Before
each FOMC meeting, the desk also prepares a brief summary
report of operations and financial markets since the last Committee meeting; a supplementary page, distributed on the day of the
meeting, summarizes developments in the three previous business days. Annually, the officers most closely involved with the
reports prepare a comprehensive report for the year, which
analyzes policy implementation and financial market developments from this longer perspective. In modified form, major
sections of this report have been published annually since 1963.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 143

8

The Transmission of Monetary
Policy: The Financial Markets.
The desk's execution of the Committee's reserve strategy
sends strong impulses coursing through the financial system.
The influence exerted on financial markets appears to have become both more powerful and yet paradoxically, more uncertain
in recent years. By changing its own strategy, the Federal Reserve
altered significantly the process through which policy affects
expectations and decisions, in ways still imperfectly understood
by policymakers and market participants alike.
Changes in the financial markets and institutions have also
affected the outreach of policy. The integration of world financial
markets has strengthened policy's external effects, while domestic markets also reflect the feedback from other economies and
national policies. Meanwhile, U.S. markets and institutions are
adapting rapidly as the savings and investing public displays
growing sophistication in coping with inflation. Institutional
strategies for survival and growth in a hotly competitive
environment are affecting more and more the cyclical patterns of
behavior so familiar from the past. How these changes will
modify further the interrelation of monetary policy, the financial
mechanism, and the world economy remains a conundrum for
the future.

A Reserve Strategy- New
Challenge to Financial Markets

page 144


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

The FOMC's adoption of a reserve-oriented approach to open
market operations in 1979 forced financial managers everywhere
to rethink their strategies for managing assets and liabilities.
When the Federal funds rate was the target of desk operations,
interest-rate forecasting fell into two distinct, but related, exercises. At the short end of the spectrum, market participants forecast interest rates by judging how rapidly the monetary authorities would raise or lower the Federal funds rate; the judgment often depended as much on assessing policymakers'
willingness to allow interest rates to change as on how the
economy was behaving. For longer term interest rates, market
participants weighed the appropriateness of policy actions in
relation to their own forecasts of economic activity. If policymakers seemed reluctant to allow short-term rates to rise
rapidly in periods of economic growth to restrain money and
credit growth, nominal long-term rates would increase to allow
for the possibility of increased inflation. The yield curve was
anchored at the short end by the Federal funds rate, but the
further one moved out the maturity scale the more expecta-

tions of economic activity and inflation came into play.
The switch to reserve targeting changed the signalling system
on which the market had come to rely. The new approach assured that monetary overruns would bring immediate countervailing pressures on interest rates. Subsequently, through
changes in the basic discount rate and a newly introduced surcharge for large banks, the System drove home the point that it
would resolutely resist excessive monetary growth.
Market participants had to shift their emphasis when making
interest rate forecasts. The Federal funds rate no longer served as
a reliable day-to-day or week-to-week guide to the leverage the
authorities were trying to exert on financial decision. Analysts had
to forecast the behavior of money over the next few months to
project the timing of interest rate changes, since money growth
had quasi-automatic effects on interest rates. Analysts also had to
look to the economy's performance, since that conditioned money
demand as well as credit requirements, resource deployment, and
inflationary pressures over a longer horizon.
The practical effect of the new procedures was to make more
immediate the influence that money supply behavior and the
economic outlook had on interest rates. Paradoxically; confidence had eroded in the ability of economists to make accurate
forecasts of either. Increased uncertainty on both counts caused
rates on intermediate and long-term securities to swing as widely
from week to week as during major cyclical changes in less
inflationary and uncertain times. Short-term rates were also affected. Changes in expectations about either money supply or
economic behavior changed bank and market ideas of how the
Federal funds rate would change in the weeks ahead. Yet, over a
few weeks, the Federal Reserve's management of reserves set
limits on the length of time that market expectations could sustain rate movements inconsistent with its supply schedule for
reserves.
In the new environment market participants keep tabs on how
the Federal Reserve pursues its aggregate objectives as well as
on the economic outlook and supply-demand conditions in the
money and capital markets. Money market economists help
risk-takers anticipate emerging trends and track developments
against expectations. The banks, as noted earlier, help transmit
monetary policy impulses in addition to accommodating customer demands for credit. Equally sensitive are dealers and

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 145

underwriters whose highly leveraged positions force them to
tack quickly to take advantage of favorable winds or to move
close to shore whenever the situation becomes too uncertain or
threatening. Sustained monetary pressures spread from the
money market to the capital markets, affecting not only borrowers and the activities they seek to finance, but also society's
collective choice between savings and consumption.
Monetary policy's impulses also spread quickly to affect the
foreign exchange market and the international money market. As
governments and central banks abroad respond, they affect
financial and economic developments in their own economies;
these feed back to the U.S. economy. No country is an island in
the world economy.

Monitoring the Fed and
the Economy

page 146


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

All players in the money and capital markets watch what the
Federal Reserve is doing. They try to put themselves in the desk's
shoes, both to understand the basic thrust of policy and to detect
any signs that objectives are changing. Money market
economists help track the trading desk and its activities, as well
as monitor the FOMC and the economy. Forecasting interest rates
is the specialty that sets them apart from those business
economists who make detailed forecasts of economic activity.
Money market economists are a diverse group. If there is any
common thread in their backgrounds, it is likely to be a stini
somewhere in the Federal Reserve System. Working knowledge of
some aspects of monetary policymaking or its implementation
has proved a highly marketable skill over the past three decades.
Federal Reserve alumni form a redoubtable group of money market advisers. Other economists have become equally adept at
using the analytical tools of their arcane trade, often through
apprenticeships at commercial banks or financial firms.
Some degree of specialization exists within the fraternity. Quite
a number are masters of the nitty gritty of Reserve Bank balance
sheets, the Treasury's financial statements, and transactions of
the off-budget government agencies. Many analysts have had to
venture also into projecting the money supply, given the importance of the monetary aggregates to central bank policy and
practice. Still another group of economists focuses more on a
broad picture of the economy than on the inner workings of the
money market. However, they too are primarily concerned with
the financial system, often with particular attention to the flows
of funds expected in major sectors of the financial markets. A few

have achieved sufficient stature that their appraisal of the economy's problems and policies exerts significant influence on the
financial markets; the markets themselves can influence, in turn,
the course of national economic policies.
Analysis must, of course, be communicated to be effective.
There are few shrinking violets in the trade. Analysts generally
are able to articulate quickly opinions on a sizable number of
abstruse issues. Those who work for banks or dealer firms provide regular briefings to their own managers of risk, and are close
at hand to analyze current developments during the day. The
sales force at most firms circulates rapidly the current views of
their in-house experts. The economists also meet with clients at the home office, regional financial centers or abroad. Analysts
also are available to customers for telephone consultation in
varying degrees. Their expertise, or boldness, in making interest
rate forecasts helps them achieve visibility through the financial
press. They are much in demand as speakers to forums of bankers and others who manage assets and liabilities for a living.
The independent entrepreneurs among the fraternity often
present their basic analyses to clients through a market letter,
usually a weekly commentary on recent and prospective developments. These analysts find it hard to meet customer demands
for instant analysis through telephone consultations. Accordingly, several provide daily commentary on prospective and actual Federal Reserve operations through computer information
systems, which can be accessed by paying customers. The popularity of the service has led to its expansion to Europe and the Far
East through news wire systems operating abroad. Surveys of
their fellow forecasters have been developed so that subscribers
can learn the range of the estimates being made by money market economists of the money supply and other key economic
variables.
In tracking and anticipating the desk's actions, money market
economists begin with a close reading of the FOMC directive and
policy record; both are released for each meeting a few days after
the subsequent FOMC meeting. The economists try to understand the Committee's concerns, the analysis of its staff, and the
balance of opinion within the Committee. They project what the
FOMC will decide even before it meets. After the meeting, they
formulate the initial instructions they think the Committee has
given the trading desk.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

I. Projecting Reserves, the Money
Supply and Desk Activity

page 147

The initial assumption for adjustment borrowing provides a
reference point for assessing future changes in the amount of
pressure being exerted on the banks. Even without knowledge of
the reserve paths and the rates of Ml and M2 growth embodied in
them, changes in average borrowing at the Federal Reserve discount window over a few weeks should provide unambiguous
information on the relation between bank demand for reserves
and the desk's supply schedule. Most analysts start with the
assumption that borrowing will continue initially near the level
recently prevailing. They also will give a range of one percentage
point or so for the Federal funds rate that they think will be
consistent with such borrowing- usually also close to prevailing
conditions.
Approximating the Committee's choice of Ml and M2 objectives is another basic element. To develop a view of money market conditions over the coming month or two, one must estimate
how Ml and M2 are likely to behave compared to the growth
assumed acceptable to the FOMC. The policy records for previous FOMC meetings are helpful. If growth thus far in the calendar
year has been below the annual objective, there is some disposition to expect the Committee will allow growth to be a bit faster
until it gets closer to path. Conversely, rapid growth thus far
might lead an analyst to expect the Committee to reduce the
future growth desired.
In making actual projections of money for the current month
and the one following, analysts examine carefully seasonal factors and patterns of past behavior at similar stages of the business cycle. The weekly publication of money supply data each
Friday gives market analysts the same basic data as their Federal
Reserve counterparts. If Fed-watchers expect a large aberration
in monetary growth because of well-known factors, they may
assume the monetary authorities will themselves allow for that
fact when establishing reserve targets for the desk. Any marked
deviation expected from a reasonable guess at FOMC objectives
usually results in a more, or less, unqualified opinion that the
pressure on the banks will increase, or decrease, accordingly.
To track desk operations against money stock forecasts, analysts try to distinguish between the defensive and dynamic aspects of open market operations. They start with a forecast of the
factors affecting bank reserves, just as do the desk's research
associates. A basic source is the weekly data on the combined
balance sheets of the Reserve Banks for the week ended
page 148


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Wednesday; these are published each Friday, except when a holiday delays publication. The weekly data include information on
member bank and Treasury balances, Federal Reserve float, the
System portfolio, and other asset/liability categories, both on a
weekly average basis and for Wednesday alone. The analyst uses
the data to revise estimates of how much the trading desk will
have to add to, or withdraw from, reserves during the current and
subsequent statement weeks to maintain borrowing at the
assumed level.
To add spice to the projections, the money market economist
often forecasts what the desk is likely to do in the market each
week, even each day. The outside forecaster operates under a
handicap during the week since he does not have the daily flow
of reserve information available to his Federal Reserve counterparts. While he can estimate the scale of daily desk operations in
the open market, he can only guess at how Federal Reserve float
is behaving or the size of the desk's transactions with foreign
accounts. An analyst's expectations of Federal funds rate behavior during a week will also allow somewhat for the effect that
tight or easy Wednesdays tend to have on bank and Federal funds
rate behavior in the following week.
The analyst is a keen observer of the trading desk's actual
operations. The Federal funds rate is closely watched, however
much desk officers admonish that the rate is free to respond to
supply and demand in the market. The rate may indicate reserve
shortfalls or overshoots, which require a correction of reserve
estimates. It also responds, as noted earlier, to changing reserve
management tactics of the banks. But more importantly from the
analyst's viewpoint, the Federal funds rate can respond to a
change in reserve pressure engineered by the desk. The stakes
on making a correct call are so high that there is a subliminal
tendency for the analyst to evaluate daily desk operations with
reference to the Federal funds rate. Fed watchers have to be on
guard against overestimating the certainty of the desk's own
knowledge of reserves and money supply growth at the time it
operates. Given the uncertainties with which they must contend,
these economists perform well in providing relevant counsel to
their principals.
Detecting changes in reserve pressure is so important that
money market economists use both their monetary projections
and daily analysis of the desk's activities in judging whether a
change is in process. Monetary overshoots or shortfalls seem to

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 149

run in strings, so that analysts become increasingly tense if the
weekly data begin to show persistent strength or weakness in
relation to their expectations. The watch on the Fed then becomes even more anxious than usual, and the entrails of daily
operations are examined intently for confirmatory evidence of a
change. Periodically there are false starts, with individuals baying in hot pursuit of a presumed change, while others interpret the same signs as being within the usual range of variation.
Even before the full chorus joins in identifying a change, the
market's tendency to charge off in the anticipated direction
can be startling.

2. Economic Forecasting and
Related Matters

page 150


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

The financial economist's specialty is projecting interest rates
and the flow of funds through the different sectors of the financial
markets. The economist is likely to be especially skilled at interpreting the continuing adjustments in recent and projected data
on the Federal budget, because of the budget's economic significance and its importance in determining the volume of marketable securities to be sold to the public. Financial economists
pore over the fine print in the budget documents, then estimate
what new spending commitments and tax actions are likely to
emerge from the Congressional mill. Since the Treasury and offbudget agencies are by far the largest borrowers in the financial
markets, their future activities have a major influence on the
outlook for interest rates.
The tribe is not bashful about differing with the Administration concerning the prospective size of the Government deficit
and the net cash borrowing to be done by the Treasury. Those
bankers and investment bankers who consult with the Treasury
just prior to its quarterly financings depend on these analysts a
great deal. The Treasury's debt managers benefit from knowing
the range of estimates circulating in the market, as they design
the borrowing program. Adverse market reactions to the Government's tax and spending program can at times generate
strong pressure for a change in the program.
To forecast private economic behavior, financial economists
make comprehensive forecasts of the supply and demand for
funds by the consumer, business, government and foreign sectors of the economy. They trace the flow through different financial intermediaries and markets to the extent that savings and
investment are not made directly by the economic actors themselves. Such forecasts typically require iterating between pro-

jected behavior of the real economy and the financial flows, until
the two forecasts appear reasonably consistent. The modeling
involved relies heavily on individual judgment; experience with
econometric techniques plays a supporting role.
One benefit to the investment banking community of this approach is that it builds up a picture of the demands likely to fall
on particular financial markets. Detailed consideration is given to
sectoral income and investment plans. Flow-of-funds analysts
can also give due regard to the desire of business corporations
to maintain balance between short- and long-term debt. In developing their estimates, they develop as well a sense of the
interest rate changes likely to be needed to bring saving and
investment into balance in the economy. The predictive value of
interest rate forecasts often depends more on how well the analyst anticipates developments in the real economy than on the
numerical array of estimated flows compiled.
Other financial economists concentrate on the spending behavior of the various economic sectors in relation to the Federal
Reserve's announced objectives for monetary growth. Building
estimates of nominal GNP growth sector by sector, analysts ask
themselves what velocity of money turnover is consistent with
the annual monetary goals. If the required rise in velocity seems
high by historical standards, they will expect upward pressure
on interest rates. Alternatively, if they foresee sluggish GNP
growth and a lower rate of turnover in money than has recently
prevailed, they are likely to forecast a decline in interest rates.
When forecasting interest rates on short-dated instruments,
money market analysts are likely to be strongly influenced by
their analysis of recent money supply developments and desk
operations. For longer term rates, their expectations of the economic outlook and inflation become more important. A rule of
thumb frequently used is that the long-term Government rate
should be three percentage points above the expected inflation
rate over the long term. In less inflationary times, analysts did
not expect a rise in the inflation rate to lead to a corresponding
change in long-term rates because price pressures and interest
rates were expected to recede toward previous levels in the next
economic downturn. After experience with the upward ratcheting of prices in successive economic cycles in the 1970's, analysts
may at times project current inflation rates when the economy is
growing. Pessimists, on occasion, may even anticipate further
ratcheting. The dispersion of inflationary expectations can lead

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 151

to quite different interest rate forecasts, even when projections of
nominal GNP growth are similar.
Money market economists hew closely to the adage, "If you
have to forecast, forecast often." An economist revises his estimates when incoming evidence does not square with his expectations. Most practitioners reach their judgments in a disciplined
and reasoned way, free from the hair-trigger reactions of market
traders to every new bit of information. They do not change
opinions lightly or capriciously. Continuity is one mark of professionalism. If one of the more respected among the group
changes his mind in a public speech or other pronouncement,
the market may well react sharply until it can evaluate the
change of view.
The hunger of market participants for information has placed
new demands on the economists who work in financial markets.
They now produce advance estimates of key economic statistics
to give market traders a benchmark for evaluating the data when
they are released. As noted earlier, the weekly money supply
report is important in tracking monetary policy, although the
volatility of Ml makes it difficult to predict. Somewhat less variable are the monthly series on the economy - retail sales, production, employment and prices. Advance estimates of these
numbers are widespread. Participants learn what the range and
mean of market estimates are a day or two before the official
data come out.

Decision Making in
the Money Market

The ripples set in motion by the trading desk spread in everwidening circles with great rapidity to affect the banking system,
domestic and international money and capital markets, and economic activity at home and abroad. The banks provide much
of the dynamism of policy's thrust. But the speedy transmission
of information and analyses assures all players a near-equal start
in the adjustment process.

1. The Banks

The System's reserve targeting approach to open market operations has complicated the asset-liability management process
described in Chapter 3. Asset planning at banks always reflects a
longer term view of the economy's performance and the probable
credit demands of customers. But the increased short-run variability of the Fereral funds rate has transformed the process of
raising funds and making investment decisions. Asset-liability
committees (ALCOs) have to contend not only with cyclical rate

page 152


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

changes, but also with rapid swings in interest rates in response
to variations in monetary growth or market expectations. Longer
term strategies can come unstuck when rapid swings in credit
demand and borrowing costs threaten the stability of quarterly
earnings.
The banks find the new environment as troublesome as other
participants. Their own money market economists are as skilled
as any, but bankers are not immune to the enthusiasms of the
market. Nor can their funding decisions always await confirmation that the central bank is exerting more or less pressure on
bank reserves. When interest rates are volatile, the larger banks
place greater emphasis on risk aversion and arbitrage. To reduce
their exposure to interest rate risk, they have increased the proportion of business loans made on a floating rate basis. The
markup over cost such lending makes possible affords considerable protection to bank earnings from unexpected changes
in rates.
Bank activities cannot escape for very long the sustained
changes in interest costs generated by the central bank's
reserve-oriented strategy. Sometimes, the banks will anticipate
the changes flowing from the behavior of Ml and M2, pushing the
Federal funds rate sharply in the appropriate direction. At other
times, the Federal funds rate may respond sluggishly because the
trading desk has difficulty in hitting its nonborrowed reserve
target, or because the major banks operate as though reserves
are in shorter supply, or are more abundant, than is actually the
case. But the message of the reserve path will get across to those
on the firing line at the banks, usually within two or three weeks.
The strategic decisions banks make, and their methods of carrying them out, continue to be geared to the interest rate outlook, but with much greater emphasis on hedging than before
October 1979. Once bankers convince themselves that higher or
lower interest rates are ahead, they are aggressive in carrying
that view to the market. In periods of rising rates, their bidding
for CDs accelerates the increase in short-term rates. When
aggregate growth slows, the willingness of major money market
banks to replace CD maturities with Federal funds purchases
likewise reinforces the fall in rates. Banks adjust lending terms
with dispatch. The cost of acceptance credit moves directly up
or down, of course, with money market rates. Short-term loans
are increasingly priced at a markup over corresponding bank
costs. The prime business lending rate moves up quickly to re
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 153

fleet rising marginal costs. The downward adjustment is typically
more sluggish, in part because borrowing in the bond market is
the alternative source businesses rely on for intermediate-term
credit. Banks also price term loans at a markup over the London
interbank offering rate (LIBOR).
Banks, both domestic and foreign-based, carry the impetus of
reserve pressures quickly into the international markets they
serve. Through overseas branches and international banking
facilities, the U.S.-based banks bid up, or down, Eurodollar rates
in step with domestic CD rates. They become net placers of funds
in that market, or takers of funds from it, depending on the
relative strength of loan demand in the two markets. Terms on
outstanding Euroloans adjust automatically either with the
LIBOR rate on six-month deposits in London, or the prime loan
rate in the United States. A general tightening of credit terms
also may develop when banks come close to self-imposed prudential limits for selected borrowing countries. To the extent that
developments in U.S. monetary policy and the balance of payments affect the dollar, bank activities transmit that influence to
the exchange markets.
2. Dealers and Underwriters
in Securities

page 154


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

The transmission of monetary policy impulses through the
financial system may appear more complicated now than it used
to be, but the process probably is also more powerful. Since
market participants can no longer look to the Federal funds rate
as a reliable policy indicator, they look more to prospective economic developments in forming rate expectations. New economic data and changing expectations regarding fiscal policy,
Treasury financing, and international developments are also important. Swings in market sentiment about the rate outlook can
influence the Federal funds rate and financing costs for a time,
either reinforcing or reducing the impact of the Federal Reserve's
management of reserves.
The ability of markets to run on their own fuel is limited to a
few weeks at most. A burgeoning of market inventories, when
dealers anticipate falling interest rates, cannot be sustained if
the trading desk's reserve objectives fail to validate market expectations. A rise in inventories to be financed usually prompts
a rise in the RP rate closer to the funds rate and touches off a
corresponding correction in position. The enhanced sensitivity of the yield curve to financing costs, in part through
operation of the futures market, ensures that reserve pressures

will exert a pervasive force on all maturities.
The capacity of financial markets to take large positions and to
distribute securities grew enormously in the 1970s. The drumbeat of the large Treasury financings needed to cover recurring
Federal deficits necessitated greater underwriting by the primary
dealers in Government securities. Trading accounts at banks and
brokerage houses, as well as private speculators, augmented distributive capacity. Collectively, these participants took the risk of
bidding in Treasury auctions with a view to selling within a few
days at a higher price to more permanent holders. The scale of
the Treasury's needs, and the frequency of its trips to market,
assured profitable opportunities for trading and underwriting to
well-capitalized risk takers. The facility with which Treasury
financing was accomplished testified to the market's ability
to position itself properly before Treasury sales, to take on
very large amounts of new issues, and to redistribute them
quickly - at a profit over the long haul, though by no means
on every occasion.
The growth of the futures market in Treasury and GNMA securities helped expand the underwriting capacity of all debt markets and integrate them more tightly. Futures contracts on Treasury bills and bonds, in particular, enable dealers in all securities
to manage their risks better in treacherous markets. Market
makers can deal directly with customers in the cash market
while making offsetting transactions in the two active futures
contracts. Underwriters of corporate and municipal bonds can
reduce their underwriting risk on new issues by shorting the
Treasury bond futures contract as well as by entering into
standby contracts and forward transactions.
Futures market activity mushroomed in the late 1970s as the
volatility of interest rates increased. Additional speculative capital was attracted by the enormous leverage implicit in being able
to buy a $1 million bill contract or a $100,000 bond contract with
the payment of only a few thousand dollars. The risks are great,
of course, and losses can be large, as many participants discovered. But presumably, participants as a group have shared
in enlarged underwriting profits. For their part, debt issuers
probably benefit from the increased availability of underwriting capital.
Futures markets also strengthened the links between shortterm rates, which the System's reserve strategy affects most
directly, and rates in the capital market. A heavy volume of arbit
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 155

page 156

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

rage serves to keep prices in line with cash and futures markets.
In the process the primary dealers in Government securities
normally acquire large outright positions in Treasury issues
against short positions in the futures market. In effect, dealers
provide a service to speculative buyers, financing the outright
positions that are the counterpart of the speculative long positions held in futures contracts. Arbitrage profits provide a return
on the capital and manpower used in the financing activity. The
futures market is also important to the dealer in establishing
accurate prices - especially for individual longer term issues
that trade much less actively than does the bond future contract.
Prices in the futures contracts - whether for Treasury bills,
bonds or GNMAs - differ from those on the underlying instruments by the estimated financing costs over the period until the
securities are to be delivered under terms of the contract. Hence,
unexpected changes in the Federal funds rate and the RP rate
immediately generate a realignment in securities prices in the
futures and cash markets that allows for the changed perception
of financing costs. Since dealer positions are substantially larger
than they would be without the futures market, a change in the
pressure on bank reserve positions exerts a considerably
stronger force on all maturities than it did in the mid-1970s. The
management of reserves also affects related debt markets, whose
participants hedge interest rate risk through the purchase of
futures contracts.
The critical importance of financing costs to trading and underwriting decisions forces market participants to focus on the
Federal funds rate from day to day, sometimes even hour to hour.
What the market wants to know, needs to know, is the Federal
funds rate that corresponds to the bank reserve positions the
trading desk is trying to achieve. Participants could then judge
what the RP rate should be, given their knowledge of market
positions and the availability of financing.
If the desk does not provide signals concerning the likely relationship between reserves and the RP rate , the market has to
develop its own estimates in order to function. The desk may
protest that it is only managing reserves, not interest rates. But
market analysts and traders will watch its every move for suggestions of what Federal funds rate level the desk thinks is consistent with its reserve objective. From the market's viewpoint, the
exercise is eminently rational. The desk has a better view of its
reserve objectives than anyone in the market, and is expected to

have some sense of the central tendency in the Federal funds
rate. Also it is known that the desk uses the rate, at least marginally, to evaluate the accuracy of its own reserve projections.
In fact, the trading desk's concern is with its reserve objectives; it feels free to operate over a wide range of rates. Market
analysts generally recognize how importantly reserve misses and
bank behavior contribute to short-run changes in the Federal
funds rate. Still, traders have to contend with the possibility that
observed short-run changes in the rate will not be merely transitory. Securities prices tend to move up or down whenever Federal
funds trade at new levels for a few days.
The financial markets perform in some ways like a great computer, registering individual judgments about the implications of
current desk operations, monetary policy, and economic developments, for the future course of interest rates. They are subject
also to all the emotions that move people - hope, fear, greed.
Their behavior is often a heady mixture of rational analysis and
mob psychology.
Participants trade anything longer than the shorter maturities
on the basis of where Federal funds and other rates are expected
to be over the weeks and months ahead. Often they are uncertain
about where the funds rate is and where it is going. At other
times, the direction of change, if not the speed, will be clear.
Market expectations are then likely to push the Federal funds
rate, and related short-term rates, up or down more than the
desk's underlying reserve targets would suggest. Expectations
themselves accelerate portfolio adjustments in the direction of
returning the monetary aggregates to path. However, the extent
of this effect should not be exaggerated. By far the greater part of
significant movements in rates reflect deliberate Federal Reserve
decisions to change the reserve paths or the discount rate.
The transmission of policy impulses to the capital markets is
rapid, but their effect on interest rates is less certain. Dealer
arbitrage between the cash and futures markets insures that
changes in financing costs produce corresponding adjustments
in the long-term markets. Still the lasting effects on long-term
interest rates depend on the conclusions borrowers and lenders
reach about the future course of economic activity and inflation.
Expectations of long-term interest rates depend in large measure on economic forecasts. Credit demand in the aggregate tends
to rise and fall with the business cycle. Long-term credit demands typically rise in the recession-recovery phase of the cycle,

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 157

when the Federal deficit increases, housing credit expands, and
the corporations are refinancing short-term debt incurred in the
previous expansion. One expects long-term rates to be under
less downward pressure than short-term rates when the economy slows down. The transmittal to long-term interest rates of
any rise, or fall, in short-term rates depends heavily on how far
along the expansion, or recesion, is in relation to past cycles and
how long participants expect the current phase to last.
Market participants have a hard time concluding what rates of
future inflation should be built into long-term interest rate levels.
Expectations of inflation tend to rise and fall with the business
cycle and the behavior of prices. In the recession-recovery
phase , price increases are typically restrained by the availability
of capacity and by productivity gains. In the later stages of an
expansion, price pressures intensify and markets tend to raise
their expectations of future inflation.
In assessing the long-term outlook for prices, a key question is
the priority society is likely to give to reducing the rate of inflation. Experience has made investors skeptical of the assurances
of political leaders and monetary policymakers. The struggle of
groups within American society to maintain or increase real incomes in the face of a decline in productivity also makes analysts doubtful of a rapid reduction in wage demands. To the
extent monetary policy has credibility in the market place, attention tends to turn to fiscal policy, since government spending has
tended to outpace revenue gains for many years. Inflationary
expectations, once established, become difficult for policymakers to dislodge.

page 158


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

9

The Transmission of Monetary
Policy: The Credit Markets
And The Economy
Monetary policy influences economic activity by affecting the
cost and availability of money and credit to those who produce
and consume the nation's output. The Federal Reserve's supplyoriented approach to open market operations interacts with the
banking system's demand for reserves to establish the Federal
funds rate. Given the outlook for the economy, inflation, and
credit demands, interest rates emerge in the credit markets that
allow for variations in the maturity, credit risk, and tax status of
debt outstanding.
Confronting choices of interest rates and maturities, holders of
assets and those saving from current income distribute their
resources between money and other assets in ways that tend to
restore money and credit growth to the pace desired by the
central bank. Interest rates affect how consumers divide their
incomes between consumption and the savings set aside to provide future income. They also influence spending by affecting
consumer wealth, the value of real and financial holdings. Interest rates also affect investment plans and credit demands by
businesses, and state and local governments. Monetary policy
affects aggregates demand, employment and prices.

Monetary Polley and Yield Curves

page 160


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Open market operations affect first the market for bank reserves and the Federal funds rate. In the overnight market for
bank reserves, the interest rate is a joint product of Federal
Reserve actions and the banking system's demand for reserves. A
reserve-oriented strategy insures that rapidly rising demands for
money and credit in an expanding economy will raise the Federal
funds rate while economic weakness will produce downward
pressure on the rate. Judgmental adjustments of the reserve path
or the discount rate can be used to speed changes in rates.
Beyond the overnight market, interest rates reflect the strength
of the economy's current demands for money and credit, and
market participants' expectations of future economic activity, inflation, and interest rates.
Participants in the financial markets speak, somewhat wistfully,
of a "normal" yield curve, one in which interest rates rise as the
term to maturity increases. Even when interest rates are expected to be stable near current levels in the future, investors
require a higher yield on longer term obligations for giving up
the liquidity of short-term instruments. Owners of a security
maturing in 2, 10 or 30 years assume the risk that they may have

to sell it at a loss before maturity. The higher yield also allows for
the possibility that inflation and interest rates may not remain
stable but rise secularly. In practice, expectations of future interest rates strongly influence the shape of the yield curve. A steep
upward slope between three-month and one-year maturities
suggests that market participants expect the rates on threemonth issues to rise sharply over the period. A buyer of a oneyear issue realizes a return that is the sum of the expected
Chart 19 Yield Curves

Fig.A

i
Flat Normal -

Inverted -

time
Fig.B

i

time
Fig. C Inflationary Expectations

i


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

time

page 161

returns from a succession of three-month investments plus a
liquidity premium for holding the longer security. When shortterm rates rise above those available on longer term issues, this
"inverted" yield curve reflects market expectations that shortterm rates will decline from their current levels.
The yield curve for Treasury securities serves as the reference
standard for all market participants (see Chart 19, page 161).
Such securities lack the credit risk attached to other securities
and enjoy a broad and active secondary market. Debt instruments issued by the federally sponsored credit agencies and by
private business typically have higher yields for corresponding maturities. The size of the rate differential reflects the
market's allowance for lesser marketability and the risk that the
borrower will not repay.
The normal yield curve exists only when the economy is
operating well within its capacity limitations. An upward sloping
yield curve is characteristic of recessions when short-term rates
are falling and of recoveries as long as upward pressure on
prices is modest. Once, however, demands for money and credit
exceed Federal Reserve objectives, the Federal funds rate and
other short-term rates rise. The yield curve then tends to flatten
out (see Chart 19, Figure A, page 161). Short-term rates rise
more than long-term rates as long as participants believe that
monetary and fiscal policy will effectively contain inflationary
pressures.
When an economic expansion seems likely to encounter
bottlenecks and push up prices, the risk increases that excessive
credit demands will lead to overshooting the Federal Reserve's
monetary goals. When the Federal Reserve acts promptly to contain monetary growth, short-term rates will rise still further, but
long-term rates will not rise as much, because participants do
not revise their inflationary expectations appreciably higher.
(Fiscal policy can help stabilize such expectations if it generates
a budget surplus as the economy approaches full employment.)
An inverted - i.e., downward sloping, yield curve (see Chart 19,
Figure B, page 161) will then reflect market views that short-term
interest rates are high enough to slow money growth, the economy and inflation; interest rates will be expected to decline again
in the foreseeable future. If participants conclude, however, that
monetary and fiscal policy will not brake excessive demand, then
long-term rates will move up with short-term rates to reflect the
worsening price outlook (see Chart 19, Figure C, page 161).
page 162


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

So long as society wants to contain or reduce inflation, the
Federal Reserve has to allow short-term rates to rise in economic
expansions to the point necessary to restrain growth in money
and credit. Should an expansion generate excessive demands for
both, then the rise in rates will lead in time to a weakening of the
credit-sensitive sectors of the economy. Economic buoyancy, or
excessive wage demands, thus can produce economic weakness,
which may culminate in economic recession and reduced demand for money and credit as real incomes decline. At such
times the Federal Reserve's efforts to maintain nonborrowed reserve growth contributes to the fall in short-term interest rates.
Reductions in the discount rate may be used to accelerate the
process. When a recession is under way, the yield curve becomes
sharply upward sloping because of the fall in short-term rates.
How far long-term rates will fall depends upon market assessments of how deep and long the recession will be and how much
progress will be made in reducing the underlying rate of inflation. The greater the progress expected, the larger the decline in
long-term rates that should accompany the fall at the short end
of the maturity spectrum.
Monetary policy exerts its influence by affecting portfolio and
spending decisions in the different sectors of the economy. All
economic sectors finance most of their spending from current
income, but all rely as well as on raising funds in credit and equity
markets to finance part of their activities. By affecting the cost and
availability of financing in these markets, monetary policy tries to
keep credit-financed spending in balance with the economy's
production capacity. It may also affect such decisions directly as
well by its effect on expectations (see Chart 20, page 164).
During the buoyant phase of the economic cycle, monetary
policy works to restrain credit-financed spending so that pent-up
demands can be reactivated when the economy turns sluggish.
In the cyclical competition for funds , the business sector gradually bids away resources from consumers and other borrowers as
monetary policy seeks to restrain the growth of money and
credit. Once economic activity tops out and credit demands
shrink, Federal Reserve efforts to maintain monetary and credit
growth help re-energize the sectors held back earlier by the
credit squeeze.
The net funds raised annually by the nonfinancial sectors are
usually equivalent to about one-sixth of GNP. Of the total flow,

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Policy's Effect on the
Economic Sectors

page 163

Chart 20 Transmission
of Monetary Policy II

Money Targefs

,_

Stock
Prices

Mortgage
·Rates

Availability

of Financing

l
Non-Residential
Construction

page 164


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Cost of
Credit

Producers
Durable
Equip.

Municipal

Int. Rates

State and Local
Construction

households take up almost 40 percent and business about 30
percent. The U.S. government has accounted for 15 to 20 percent
of the total. Foreign borrowers and state and local governments
account for the remainder. Of the funds advanced, the household
sector supplies about two-thirds and the business sector most of
the remainder. About four-fifths of household funds are placed
with depository institutions or money market funds, while the
remainder are invested directly in credit market instruments.
Sectoral credit demands, and their interaction with supply;
have a distinct cyclical pattern. As the economy expands, the
business sector's need for external financing rises. Increased
profitability on expanding volume enables businesses to pay the
higher short-term rates generated by the growing economy. At
the same time, Federal Government operations ordinarily exert a
restraining influence on the demand for credit, since tax receipts
rise faster than the economy while recession-related spending
declines. Households increase their use of consumer credit as
employment and incomes rise. But the ability of families to obtain and carry home mortgages is gradually undermined by the
higher interest rates and. stiffer eligibility requirements resulting
from economic expansion. State and local governments, too, find
it somewhat harder to finance the construction of long-lived
projects providing public services. With the onset of a recession,
private credit demands and interest rates usually fall. Funds become available to the Federal Government to cover enlarged
deficits while increased credit availability at lower rates helps
maintain private spending and generate recovery.
Monetary policy's cumulative impact on the household sector,
and thereby on the economy, is pervasive and substantial. The
cost and availability of credit influence households in their
choice between consumption and savings, while interest rate
changes affect consumer wealth in ways that tend to restrain
spending as an expansion continues and revive it when recovery
begins. Consumer investment in housing and consumer durables
is subject to similar influences. The more sustained the expansion, and the rise in interest rates, the more postponable spending is deferred to be reactivated when other sectors' economic
demands subside.
Changes in interest rates affect household spending in a
number of ways. One might expect a rise in short-term interest
rates to encourage households to save more and spend less, and

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

1. The Household Sector

page 165

a fall in rates to have the opposite effect. In fact, such influences,
if they exist, are difficult to disentangle from the stronger effects
generated by the business cycle. Cyclical changes in interest
rates and the behavior of money itself, may influence the expectations and spending plans of households. Consumers do have
considerable experience with the cyclical rise and fall in interest
rates, while the proposition that rapid money growth leads to
inflation is also widely understood. A sharp rise in interest rates
may suggest that greater economic uncertainty and rising unemployment lie ahead, leading to greater consumer caution. On
the other hand, if a rapid rise in money growth develops, consumers may also expect inflation to accelerate, and as a result
tend to reduce saving and borrow in order to increase spending.
In recessions, a sharp fall in rates and a rise in money supply
could lead to expectations of economic recovery and increased
consumer spending. But at other times the actuality of persisting
unemployment may tend to delay such a response.
Financial market developments influence household spending
decisions by affecting household wealth. In times of rising interest rates, short-term instruments become increasingly attractive
alternatives to investments in stocks and bonds. The value of
existing bond holdings declines when long-term interest rates
rise; corporate stock prices, and hence the value of stock portfolios, are also adversely affected. Rising mortgage interest rates
reduce the attractiveness of refinancing existing homes to provide additional resources for spending. Households may also feel
less wealthy when homes become harder to sell or the prices of
existing houses actually decline. Through a number of channels,
then, rising interest rates affect household wealth apversely, tending to restrain consumer expenditures. Declines in interest rates
in recession work in the opposite direction, raising the value of
real and financial household assets and encouraging spending.
Household investment in housing is particularly sensitive to
the cost and availability of credit. Whenever short-term interest
rates rise, increased institutional reliance on money market certificates and similar sources of funds leads to a rapid rise in the
costs of mortgage lenders. Mortgage rates rise accordingly.
Moreover, thrift institutions tend to curtail mortgage lending for
prudential reasons when their short-term interest costs exceed
the average earning rate embedded in the portfolio acquired in
earlier years. They tend instead to place a sizable part of the high
cost, short-term money they attract in money market instrupage 166


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

ments offering an interest rate pickup over cost.
In this environment many prospective home buyers find themselves squeezed out of the market. Initial downpayment requirements and monthly carrying costs increase significantly. The
reduction in single-family housing starts can be dramatic, with
peak-to-trough declines of 40 percent or more. Substantial resources are released by such a decline, since residential construction typically accounts for more than one-quarter of private
fixed investment. Conversely, when a recession occurs and interest rates fall, the activation of deferred demand can be a powerful
force contributing to economic recovery.
Monetary policy also influences household spending over the
business cycle by affecting consumer credit. Consumers depend
heavily on such credit, especially for purchases of automobiles
and other durable consumer goods. Historically, their use of such
credit has not been very sensitive to the level of interest rates
charged. However, the rise of short-term interest rates does
squeeze the profit margins of lenders when maximum lending
rates are fixed by state usury laws. Banks and consumer finance
companies often reduce advertising and tighten up lending
standards to reduce loss exposure. In periods of easing interest
rates, the widening of gross profit margins tends to encourage
greater credit availability. To the extent that usury ceilings are
relaxed, consumer credit rates in the future may become more
variable than in the past. Consumer use of such financing may
then become more sensitive to interest rates.
Monetary policy exerts much of its force by affecting business
decisions on inventories and new investments. Corporate and
small businesses produce most of the goods and services consumed by the other sectors. They must anticipate and respond to
the demands of consumers, other businesses, governmental
units and foreign buyers.
Businesses depend heavily on the credit markets to finance
the inventories and productive capacity needed to meet customer demands. Their cash flow from retained earnings and depreciation allowances provides only about three-fifths of the
funds used for capital spending, for extending trade credit, and
for acquiring other financial assets. The remainder comes chiefly
from borrowing in the credit markets. Moreover, business credit
demand typically grows more rapidly than the economic in the
expansive phase of the business cycle. If businessmen expect

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

2. The Business Sector

page 167

strong sales, they try to keep inventories growing ahead of demand so that sales are not lost because of shortages. Similarly,
expectations of strong demand lend greater urgency to plans for
additional capacity, which may require several years to accomplish. The longer an expansion continues, the greater are the
needs of business for external financing.
As short-term interest rates rise, businessmen have to weigh
the increasing cost of financing inventories against the possible
sales gain from having ample supplies. Price expectations also
enter their calculations. Business buying of raw material and
other inputs, and planned levels of finished inventories, are apt to
increase if inflation is expected to accelerate. Expectations can
then become self-fulfilling. Monetary policy has to allow shortterm interest rates to rise rapidly enough during expansions to
make inventory building an increasingly costly strategy. Businessmen respond by keeping inventories under tight control. At
the same time, rising rates sap the buoyancy of household demand through the channels already noted. Business profitability
begins to suffer both from high borrowing costs and a softening
of demand. At some point inventories become heavy in relation
to sales, requiring a reduction in current production to bring

them back in line.
Growing business credit demand tends to accentuate the rise
in short-term rates during economic expansions. Capital spending appropriations rise as existing capacity is used more efficiently and as margins of excess capacity decline. External
financing needs rise substantially because inventory and investment spending outstrip the cash flow generated by current sales.
A large part of this financing is short-term in character either
because it relates to inventories or because businesses postpone long-term borrowing in hopes of doing it later at lower
interest rates. The effect is to add to the upward pressure on
short-term rates.
As an expansion continues, the rise in rates undermines business profitability, especially for those companies that are heavily
dependent on credit. Managers, encountering sustained pressure
on profit margins, step up their efforts to cut costs. Among heavy
credit users, a review of capital spending may produce some
trimming, or stretching out, of present plans - especially if there
is lender resistance to providing additional financing. The rise in
long-term rates may itself reduce the attractiveness of projects
under consideration by increasing the rate at which projected

page 168


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

income streams are discounted in the process of evaluating their
merits. However, well-capitalized firms are less likely to retrench
signifiantly on projects already under way, given the time necessary to complete major additions and the extra costs involved in
delay. Aggregate capital spending tends to be sustained well into
a recession, diminishing only as the rising margin of capacity
available reduces the desirability of further additions.
One feature of the cyclical process in a market economy is
that business investment for meeting future customer demand
gradually undermines the strength of current consumption, even
in a balanced expansion. Business wins the competition for
funds and for real resources, but its success in the financial
markets undermines production and income in rate-sensitive
sectors. Consumer demand falls at some point below the pace
assumed in current production schedules, so that unwanted inventories accumulate. High interest rates, which were tolerable
as long as sales were rising, force a reduction of production
schedules so that sales can be met from existing stocks. As
production cuts spread and workers are laid off, the general belt
tightening prolongs the inventory correction.
When businessmen cut inventories, they repay short-term
loans, contributing importantly to a reduction in credit demands.
Interest rates fall, sometimes dramatically, as the Federal Reserve
maintains the provision of reserves to the banking system. As
noted earlier, this works to increase the flow of credit to housing
and other areas that were squeezed during the expansion. The
stage is gradually set for the end of the inventory runoff, and
the restoration of production to the levels needed to meet current sales.
Most units of government below the Federal level operate essentially on the basis of balancing current spending with receipts
from taxes or grants-in-aid from a higher level of government.
Annual budgets may include capital spending for a wide variety
of projects. But major capital outlays on schools, roads, sewers
and the like usually depend on long-term financing, which is
often authorized separately by public referenda. General obligations of governmental issuers are secured by the taxes that can
be levied on taxpayers, and enjoy exemption from Federal income taxation. The current expense budget of the issuing body
usually provides for interest and authorization charges on such
projects. States, in particular, have also established separate

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

3. State and Local Governments

page 169

corporations to run business-like enterprises, which charge for
the services they render through bridges and turnpikes, utilities,
mortgage lending, and other operations. The capital spending of
such corporations is usually finance- by revenue bonds, which
are secured by the stream of revenues expected from the
facilities they finance .
Monetary policy's direct impact on governmental units takes
place chiefly through credit market effects on capital spending. A
general rise in interest rates increases the rates which governmental units have to pay on their bonds. At the margin this
tends to lead to some reduction in, or postponement of, capital
spending programs. Some issuers may also be unable to borrow
because rates rise above ceilings established by state law on
what they can pay. The volume of tax-exempt offerings in the
long debt market usually declines in boom periods. The direct
effects on spending are likely to be modest. Debt financing by
such governments is usually only 5 to 6 percent of their total
expenditures, so that reducing their capital outlays slightly does
not involve much cutback in total spending.
Spending of state and local governments is affected much
more by the current state of the economy itself. Revenues grow
with the economy, often more than proportionally because of
progressivity in income taxes. A climate of expanding revenues
often leads to new spending initiatives. Conversely; disappointing revenues in times of recession often lead fairly quickly
to a need to economize because of the need for balancing
income and outgo.

4. The U.S. Government

page 170


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Monetary policy's impact on Federal spending and revenue
decisions is also limited. The changes in interest rates that accompany economic expansion and recession do affect the interest cost of financing the outstanding debt. The budgetary impact
can be sizable since about one third of the debt has to be refinanced each year at prevailing interest rate levels. But changes
in Treasury interest costs over the cycle appear to have influenced Federal fiscal policy only marginally.
The Treasury is, however, a major independent force in financial markets, competing with other borrowers for funds and
command over real resources. Federal credit demands over the
cycle tend to run counter to those of other borrowers. As the
economy expands, income taxes grow more rapidly than the
economy, assuming unchanged income tax rates; they also exert a

restraining influence on the rise in consumer income. Conversely, borrowing needs expand in recessions when revenues
fall at a time of increased spending on unemployment compensation and other income-sustaining programs. This increase in
Treasury financing typically coincides with a high level of savings
and a subsidence of credit demands from other sectors. This
contra-cyclical borrowing pattern corresponds reasonably
closely to fiscal policy's built-in stabilization of final demand.
Accommodating Treasury requirements ordinarily leaves room
for other borrowers in periods of economic slack.
Financial market participants are concerned about whether
the Treasury can always satisfy its needs without adversely
affecting the flow of funds to others. The rise of government
deficits in relation to GNP in the late 1970's from a decade earlier
suggested to some that the Treasury's demands could prove
excessive in relation to the rates of money and credit growth
planned by the Federal Reserve. In this view, Treasury and private
demands during an expansion could drive up interest rates
rather quickly, perhaps causing the economy to stall out well
before production had reached its noninflationary potential. In
both early 1980 and again in the summer of 1981, financial market
fears about the scale of future budget deficits caused long-term
interest rates to rise sharply and helped bring on subsequent
economic downturns. In this manner expectations concerning
fiscal policy and previously announced monetary objectives can
produce significant effects. Such expectations may also feed
back into the fiscal policy process, exerting a measure of discipline over the extent to which the government can sustain
policies that appear likely to place unduly heavy demands on
the credit markets.
The effect of U.S. monetary policy on the credit markets is not
national, but international. The leverage exerted affects the balance between global monetary demand and the availability of
real resources. The prices set in the market for internationally
traded commodities feed back to the U.S. economy, as do the
income effects generated by the financial flows set in motion by
U.S. monetary policy. Policymakers around the world are dealing
collectively with a closed economy.
U. S. monetary policy impinges first on the international
money market. The core of that market is the extraterritorial
banking system that has grown up during the last two decades,

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

The lntemational Dimension

page 171

as national banks have escaped the costs and restrictions imposed by national banking authorities. This Eurobanking system accepts deposits of all maturities in what is basically a
wholesale market. Because of the absence of reserve requirements, insurance fees and state taxes, its constituent banks
have the signal advantage of being able to pay higher rates to
depositors through their extranational branches and subsidiaries than they could pay at home. Deposits are taken in all
major currencies, but the dollar component of the market is
by far the largest. The foreign exchange markets link the deposit markets in the various currencies. Interest rates in those
markets relate closely to those prevailing in the home money
market of the relevant currency. Arbitrage usually keeps the
relationship between spot and forward exchange transactions
close to the interest-rate differentials prevailing in the respective deposit markets.
As befits a wholesale money market, the constituent banks
have developed a loan mechanism that places funds on a large
scale on terms that protect the banks from most of the interest rate risk. Loans are made in large size for four to 12
years to major governmental and corporate borrowers
through loan syndications among the banks. Such loans are
usually priced at a markup over the cost of 6-month deposits
to the banks. The markup and front-end fees constitute the
banks' primary source of earnings and their protection against
credit risk.
The Eurobond market complements this Eurobanking system.
In it, banks and investment bankers underwrite 5 to IO-year loans
for top quality corporate and sovereign borrowers. They place
them largely with individual and institutional clients, in part because there is usually no withholding of income tax from the
interest earned. Eurobond flotations thus involve retail placement, and underwriting costs of such issues usually exceed
those paid in the New York market for foreign bonds. The
Euromarkets together constitute a very large and efficient mechanism for collecting funds internationally and redistributing
them to borrowers, chiefly for an intermediate maturity. A feature
of the system is that two-thirds or more of the credit volume
goes to instrumentalities of sovereign governments. The lending
capacity of the system grew so rapidly in the 1970's that it played
a major role in rechanneling OPEC surpluses to oil-importing nations.
page 172


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

The explosive growth of the system's credit to sovereign governments also contributed importantly to the emergence of excessive demand and inflationary pressures during the decade.
The ready availability of credit enabled major countries in the
industrial and developing world to escape for a time restrictive
domestic economic policies, which would otherwise have been
forced by balance-of-payments developments or recourse to the
International Monetary Fund. Prudential concern by banks and
their supervisory authorities emerged with considerable force
once individual countries experienced difficulties in meeting
their obligations. That and the expansion of the IMFs credit
facilities, with attendant concern about domestic policies, appear
to be reducing somewhat the system's potential for spurring international monetary expansion.

As expansion continues, banks in the U.S. gradually shift from
being net lenders to net takers of funds from the Euromarket in
order to meet domestic credit demand. To some extent bidding
for more dollars abroad may reflect some recycling of domestic
deposits through the Euromarkets. 1
When monetary policy is restrictive and short-term rates rise
above long-term rates, the U.S. economy is likely to draw funds
from the rest of the world. The Euromarket may still be expand-

1. U.S. Economic Expansion

ing because of its competitive advantage with other national

markets at the higher rate levels. Its pulling power then exerts a
restrictive influence on credit availability in other countries. The
rise in U.S. short-term rates also means a proportional rise in
debt service of those countries that have large amounts of outstanding Eurocredits. Hence, the borrowing needed to maintain
their domestic growth increases accordingly. The result tends to
be a widening of the markup they must pay on new loans, and
strong pressure to scale back plans for their own domestic
growth.
When U.S. short-term rates rise sharply, the dollar tends to
appreciate. The extent of the dollar's appreciation will be influenced by how high U.S. interest rates rise in relation to domestic
1
The competitive advantage of Eurobanks increases as rates rise since the yield equivalent
of a given reserve requirement increases with the rate level. For example, if the domestic
requirement on CDs were 5 percent, the London branch of a US. bank could pay 50 basis
points more than the head office when the rate level was JO percent. At a 20 percent rate
level, it could offer JOO basis points more on the same maturity.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 173

page 174

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

inflation, and by the credibility of U.S. actions to reduce inflation.
It also depends on how much the U.S. current account is expected to deteriorate. The appreciation of the dollar will perforce
tend to reduce demand for U.S. exports at the same time that
imports are expanding. Concerns about political or military
developments abroad may also contribute to capital inflows and
the dollar's strength.
When the dollar appreciates, foreign governments in the major
industrial countries have to weigh the long-term benefit to their
export sectors against the immediate increase in the real costs of
energy and other imports, which work in the opposite direction.
An important consideration is how rapidly any increase in import
prices is likely to be translated into rising wages - in other
words, how fast the competitive gains of their currency's depreciation will be eroded.
A country's choice of when, and how much, to intervene in the
exchange markets to keep its currency from depreciating depends on the state of its domestic economy and balance of payments, as well as on its international creditworthiness and reserve position. In most other countries, the export sector looms
larger in the national economy than is true in the United States
and governments have to consider how well placed their industries are to benefit from an improved competitive position. Import prices also feed through more quickly and have a greater
effect on the domestic price level. The greater deterioration of an
exchange rate against the dollar, the more likely an industrial
country's central bank is to support its currency. To do so, it can
draw on exchange reserves, or international credits.
When intervening, a central bank must also decide whether to
permit the sales of dollar assets to drain reserves from the
domestic banking system, or whether to use other measures to
maintain domestic monetary conditions as before. The more inflation is deemed a long-term domestic danger, the more apt the
central bank is to allow a tightening of bank reserve positions.
The central bank can maintain a degree of insulation from the
forces the Federal Reserve's policy has set in motion - perhaps
for a somewhat longer time if it has reasonably effective controls
over its banking system's access to the international money market. But there is little doubt that the longer U.S. interest rates
remain high as the Federal Reserve pursues its monetary objectives, the more powerful are the restrictive effects likely to be on
foreign economies.

When the U.S. economy weakens and short-term interest rates
fall, Eurodollar rates decline immediately. Banks resident in this
country typically change from being net takers of Eurodollars to
being net placers as domestic business credit demands decline.
This reversal typically enhances the ability of the Euromarkets to
make loans for balance-of-payments and other purposes, and
thereby tends to foster a higher level of economic activity abroad
than might otherwise prevail.
The decline in U.S. and Eurodollar short-term rates also tends
to depress the U.S. dollar in relation to foreign currencies. Funds
tend to flow away from dollar investments, putting downward
pressure on the spot dollar exchange rate until the spread from
the 3-month forward rate equals the new interest rate differential
between the two currencies. The extent and duration of a decline
in the dollar exchange rate depend in part upon how rapidly
market participants expect the U.S. balance of payments to improve. In a recession U.S. imports fall with domestic income while
exports tend to be maintained or increase. The decline in the
dollar exchange rate tends to improve the competitive position
of United States exporters; this feeds back with a lag to the
demand for U.S. exports, assisting economic recovery.
Foreign governments may be of two minds when the dollar
depreciates in such circumstances. They may not welcome the
erosion it brings in the competitive position of their own industries, but welcome the decline in real costs to their economies of
oil and other goods, priced in dollars. In practice, the more the
dollar declines, the more likely foreign central banks are to intervene to acquire dollars and stem the appreciation of their own
currencies. One effect of this can be an increase in bank reserve
growth in the country intervening with attendant expansive
monetary effects there. The resultant stimulus to economic activity abroad may help spur U.S. exports and sustain U.S. activity
in the near-term. The improved U.S. competitiveness works in
the same direction but typically develops over a longer time
period. The central bank, can, of course, raise reserve requirements or take other steps to counter the addition to reserves. In
practice, since domestic borrowers can often borrow from the
Euromarkets, many countries find it difficult to insulate their
domestic economies completely from the effects of U.S. policy.
(Foreign economic policies likewise affect international financial
markets and the U.S. economy.)
The feedback to the U.S. economy from the external impact of

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

2. US. Recession

page 175

monetary policy is difficult to quantify, but is doubtless significant. The U.S. export sector accounts for about one-eighth of
domestic output and exceeds nonresidential investment in plant
and equipment in quantitative importance. Moreover, in recent
years nominal exports have grown almost twice as fast as the
whole economy. Policymakers need to allow for the impact on
domestic demand of the international effects of their own
policies. The lags involved may, in fact, be analogous to those
experienced with business capital spending in the domestic
economy.
The monetary and other economic policies of the United
States and its chief trading partners are not made in a vacuum.
Federal Reserve policymakers need to appraise the balance between monetary demand and effective world production capacity
when they chart domestic policy. Policymakers abroad are even
more sensitive to that balance since external demand is relatively more important to their economies. U.S. policymakers find
it difficult enough to project the behavior of domestic activity,
which contributes so importantly to the way the world economy
performs. The dynamics of the larger economy, and the lagged
feedback of monetary policy's global thrust to domestic developments, add to the uncertainties of projecting economic behavior. In all nations, but perhaps in the U.S. more than most,
policymakers tend to focus on the home economy and the levers
they can move, as though their actions had little effect on the
world economy. Still, central bankers, operating in domestic markets, generate changes in rate relationships and financial flows
that spread to the international money market. Collectively, they
are making monetary policy for the world.

page 176


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

JO

Monetary PolicyThe World Scene
Monetary policy moved to center stage in the industrial, as
well as the developing, countries in the 1970s, as inflation disrupted the existing economic structure and threatened social
cohesion. During the decade central banks found it perplexing
and difficult to counter the forces producing inflation, and often
found monetary and credit growth exceeding their desires. As
the 1980s began, governments, beset by popular dissatisfaction
with inflation, found it politic to rely more heavily on monetary
policy to constrain aggregate demand, while the political process
mediated the more insistent claims within society.
Whether inflation could have been avoided in the 1970s is open
to question. The rapid growth of money during much of the
decade helped disguise the substantial real tax imposed by the
rise in oil prices on a consuming public accustomed to regular
increases in real income. Governments responded to the initial
shock with expanded budget deficits to maintain employment
and social stability. Monetary policy accommodated much of the
resultant increase in global credit demands. Societies slowly regrouped through the political process, modifying the rigidities
imposed by rising expectations, wage bargaining procedures,
and a technology and production capacity geared to lower
energy prices. Money illusion provided time for the social fabric
to stretch with considerable discomfort, but generally without
breaking.
The emergence of inflation as a major social issue greatly
increased public support for bringing monetary policy to bear
effectively on reducing the rate at which prices were increasing.
The control of monetary growth became the natural focus of
attention, given the well-documented relation between monetary
expansion and inflation. As discussed in Chapter 2, U.S. monetary policy progressed during a decade from Federal Reserve
preoccupation with money and credit growth over a few months
to a law mandating annual growth objectives. With inflation a
worldwide phenomenon, governments in other industrial countries also accepted monetary targeting as indispensable to a
credible program for lowering the inflation rate. Monetary targeting helped central banks themselves win public support for antiinflationary policies, and relief from the conventional interest
rate constraints developed in less inflationary times.
Operating strategies had to adjust to the higher priority assigned to monetary targets. In the United States the money mar-

page 178


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

ket strategy of monetary control, used with considerable success
earlier, proved inadequate. Policymakers were unable to break
through the interest rate modalities of past experience with the
speed and vigor required. The adoption of reserve-oriented
operating procedures in October 1979 sought to restore credibility to the central bank's long-term strategy for containing, and
then reducing, inflationary pressures. Self-imposed rules gave
the public assurance that open market operations would generate automatic resistance to monetary overruns while continuing
to provide flexibly for the economy's cash requirements. Central
bank inertia would no longer lead to cumulative slippage in the
struggle to contain inflation.
The adoption of new rules did not change the need for judgment, but did encourage its use. Once the pattern of creeping
marginal adjustments in the Federal funds rate was abandoned,
the Federal Reserve employed discount rate changes and
reserve-oriented open market operations forcefully to affect
portfolio decisions. The central bank impressed the financial
markets with its determination to keep abreast, or ahead, of the
inflationary expectations at work in the markets. U.S. monetary
policy became more credible in pursuing its announced goals,
enhancing the force brought to bear on inflationary expectations
and the economy. The prospects of damping inflation and the
amplitude of cyclical swings in interest rates over the years
ahead improved significantly.
Central bankers do not operate in a vacuum. Financial market
participants always look through the monetary veil to see what
demands the several sectors are making on the real resources of
the economy. The size of the Treasury's demands, in particular,
are always a major concern, given the historical evidence that
the soverign's political decisions precede the monetization of the
public debt. Central banks often have difficulty resisting the impetus governmental decisions can give to expectations and real
demands on productive capacity. Except when national survival
seems at stake, central bankers traditionally argue within government for moderating the government's net demands on financial markets and the economy.
The Federal Reserve's present policymaking structure and operational procedures will continue to change as the financial
system adapts to meet changing social needs and priorities. The
new operating procedures themselves are a matter of current

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 179

debate. Views diverge over how effective the new procedures
have proved in controlling monetary growth and what lines of
further development appear most promising. Many of the
monetarist persuasion worry that monetary growth rates still
vary too much from quarter to quarter, fearing the public will
lose confidence in the Federal Reserve's ability to achieve its
annual objectives. Another view, concerned about the adverse
effect of interest rate variability on exchange rates and the cost
of capital, would see merit in reducing short-run rate volatility
while continuing reserve targeting.
One school of thought believes that operating procedures, reserve periods and the discount window should be reformed in
the interest of controlling money over much shorter time intervals than the annual periods now mandated by law. Some analysts believe that the monthly and quarterly variations in money
growth experienced since October 1979 engender uncertainty
about the course of monetary policy and the economy. Those
holding this view would redesign operating procedures and institutional arrangements substantially in hopes of reducing the
variation of money growth around its stated objectives. Greater
week-to-week volatility in short-term interest rates would be
acceptable to proponents of this approach, although they tend
to believe others overstate the risks on this score. They believe
any resultant costs would be more than outweighed by the
greater certainty that annual money growth objectives woukl
be achieved.
Others give a different reading to the experience to date. To
many Federal Reserve and market observers familiar with the
short-run behavior of money, its variability seems more the result of the changing demands of a complex, and rapidly changing,
economy than of the Federal Reserve's procedures. They see the
present procedures as a reasonable approach to screening out
the noise in weekly and even monthly data. In this view, trying to
control money or credit more tightly than at present would be
likely to result in greater volatility in both short and long-term
interest rates, greater uncertainty among decision makers, and
higher costs for capital and for foreign trade. Proponents of this
view would opt for steps to reduce day-to-day and week-to-week
changes in interest rates, even at the cost of somewhat greater
short-run variability in money growth rates.
The issue is one of system design. A system that accommodates monetary noise will involve a brief lag whenever a sustained
page 180


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

and cumulative deviation begins. Conversely, one that treats
weekly deviations as significant is likely to generate a great deal
more noise in short-term interest rates than has yet been experienced. Many economists and market participants are skeptical
that greater variability in rates can improve monetary control, or
policy's influence over the economy's performance. In this view
changes in procedures should be in the direction of reducing the
interest rate uncertainties within which the trading desk, market
participants and the public must work.
A more fundamental question is whether financial innovation,
the product of regulatory reform and double-digit inflation, is not
undermining the legitimacy, and feasibility, of monetary targeting. The demand for a narrow aggregate like Ml may continue to
allow reasonable control since it responds to the differential between the low return it affords the holder and money market
interest rates. But the economic rationale for Ml 's use may become increasingly attenuated as it shrinks relative to GNP and
the relationship between the two becomes harder to predict. Demand for M2 and M3, on the other hand, may prove less responsive to interest rate differentials in the 1980s than heretofore,
as they become increasingly dominated by components bearing market-related rates. These developments could push monetary policymaking eventually toward targeting nominal GNP and
allowable inflation, and away from the use of monetary objectives. For the present, however difficult the annual selection of
these objectives may be, they remain very useful for communicating basic policy objectives to the public and providing a standard for judging the appropriateness of Federal Reserve actions.
To foreign central bankers, there has been something unreal
about the preoccupation of the Federal Reserve and U.S.
economists with weekly money supply data. Few countries can
match the regularity and accuracy of the Federal Reserve's information on key economic variables. Other major central banks
that have set themselves monetary objectives often rely on
monthly reports of money supply and bank credit. Often, two or
three months may pass before they feel sufficiently sure of developing trends to take action. To be sure, a few have chosen
a reserve measure as their annual target, but none has yet
attempted any approach as automatically geared to operating
reserve targets as that adopted by the Federal Reserve. The shortrun variability of the money supply in the principal industrial
countries continues to exceed that in the United States, but that

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

page 181

is much less a matter of discussion or concern abroad than in
the U.S. Foreign central banks remain unsettled by the volatility
of U.S. interest rates and the resultant vibrations in credit and
foreign exchange markets.
Whatever international coordination of monetary policy there
is, functions primarily through maintaining a flow of information
among national participants, who remain responsible for the deployment of individual national strategies. The monthly meetings
of central bankers at the Bank for International Settlements in
Basie provide a very useful forum for such exchanges. The regular meetings of committees of the Organization for Economic
Cooperation and Development also provide member governments with opportunities to elucidate and defend their own economic policies, and comment on those of others. Periodic summit meetings among the major industrial powers have sought to
achieve some degree of harmony in their approach to world
economic issues, with rather mixed results. The annual meetings
of the international Monetary Fund - and the more frequent
sessions of working groups within it - provide still another
mechanism for discussing world problems and institutional
changes that may improve the international monetary system.
The sustained pursuit of annual monetary objectives by leading countries seems very likely to affect world monetary and
financial developments during the next decade. If the United
States succeeds in reducing monetary growth rates, a success
that depends significantly on fiscal policy, the monetary climate
should be notably less expansive in the 1980s than during the
previous decade. Policy's thrust, carried through the international money and foreign exchange markets, also would condition the policies of other countries in the same direction. Such a
development could work to improve the balance between demand and resources over the near-term, establishing conditions
conducive to sustained economic development. Many countries
could also find external financing less readily available on acceptable terms, holding their economic performance below their
perceived need to grow. Political pressures to expand the funds
available from the IMF, reduce the conditionality of lending,
and lower the interest costs of borrowing seem likely to be continuing prospects for the 1980s. Monetary policy always must
be rooted in the political process, and the IMF clearly embraces
the body politic appropriate to the 1980s and beyond: the
world itself.
page 182


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

0


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

332.11 Federal

198~

Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
U.S. Monetary Policy and
Financial Markets
DATE

ISSUED TO

332.11 Federal 1982
U.S. monetary policy and £i
nancial markets

DEMCO

0


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

\)

I