View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

U.S. Export Opportunities
Arkansas Minority Business Development Roundtable
Little Rock, Arkansas
August 17, 2007

I

n discussions about international trade,
we hear a lot more about imports than
about exports, which is why I have chosen
to discuss exports. My focus will be on
the opportunities provided by a trading environment that is free of unnecessary governmentally
imposed barriers. Such an environment is ideal
not only for providing opportunities for U.S.
exporters but also for maximizing economic
prospects throughout the United States. In light
of the recent news of unsafe products that have
been imported from China—melamine-laced pet
food, lead-tainted toys, antifreeze-tainted counterfeit toothpaste, antibiotic-tainted fish and treadseparating tires to name a few—I want to stress
that there is a role for government in protecting
U.S. consumers from unsafe products. My concern is that certain groups will attempt to use concerns over safety and job loss to restrict imports
and thereby pursue an agenda of economic isolation in an increasingly globalized world.
My key points can be made rather succinctly.
First, limiting imports into the United States tends
to also reduce exports. Second, economic growth
abroad provides export opportunities for U.S.
firms. The benefits of expanding exports are not
restricted solely to exporters. Third, the citizens
of Arkansas have gained much from international
trade, and the benefits will increase in the future
provided we can maintain an open trading environment. Fourth, trade disputes are a natural
consequence of a dynamic international environment. It is easy for retaliatory trade measures to
escalate and derail the desirable movement to a
more open trading environment. It is in the best
interests of all the countries of the world to
avoid trade wars.

Before proceeding, I want to emphasize that
the views I express here are mine and do not
necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal
Reserve System. I thank my colleagues at the
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis for their comments, particularly Cletus C. Coughlin, vice
president and deputy director of research, who
provided special assistance. However, I retain
full responsibility for errors.

SOME FACTS ABOUT U.S.
EXPORTS
International trade is playing an increasing
role in the U.S. economy. Since 1970, exports as
a share of gross domestic product (GDP) have
about doubled, from a bit less than 6 percent to
11 percent in 2006 (see Figure 1). These exports
consist of both goods, such as industrial equipment and consumer goods, and services, such as
insurance and financial services. For 2006, exports
of goods were 70 percent of total exports and
exports of services were 30 percent. This split
has held relatively constant since the late 1980s.
Some additional insight into the increasing
role of international trade can be gleaned by
adjusting exports and GDP for the impact of price
changes. Beginning in the early 1970s until the
early 1980s, export prices tended to rise at a much
faster rate than the overall price level as measured
by the GDP deflator (see Figure 2). Primarily
because of relatively rapid productivity growth,
for roughly the next 20 years, export prices
increased very little, especially relative to prices
generally. Price-adjusted, or real, exports increased
rapidly during the late 1980s and the 1990s rela1

INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FINANCE

Figure 1
Nominal Exports as a Percent of GDP, 1947 to 2006
15

EX/GDP

Percent

10

2004

1998

2001

1995

1992

1986

1989

1983

1980

1977

1974

1971

1968

1965

1962

1959

1956

1953

1950

0

1947

5

SOURCE: BEA, Haver Analytics.

Figure 2
Exports Price Index and GDP Deflator, 1947 to 2006 (2000 = 100)
(2000=100)

130

GDP Deflator

70

SOURCE: BEA, Haver Analytics.

2

2004

2001

1998

1995

1992

1989

1986

1983

1980

1977

1974

1971

1968

1965

1956

1953

1950

1947

10

1962

Exports Price Index

40

1959

Index

100

U.S. Export Opportunities

Figure 3
Real Exports as a Percent of GDP, 1947 to 2006
15

EX/GDP

2004

1998

2001

1995

1989

1992

1986

1983

1980

1977

1974

1971

1968

1962

1965

1959

1953

1956

0

1950

5

1947

Percent

10

SOURCE: BEA, Haver Analytics.

tive to real GDP (see Figure 3). After the recession
early in this decade, the rapid increase in real
exports relative to real GDP resumed.
Underlying the increases in U.S. trading
activity is the behavior of numerous firms.
Although I will confine my discussion to trade
in goods, trade in services is important and a
worthy topic for a future speech.
In recent years, researchers have generated a
number of facts about exporting firms.1 The number of firms involved in international trade in
goods is increasing rapidly, and they are shipping
more products to more foreign destinations than
in the past. Exporting firms experienced relatively
rapid employment growth and were a major force
in U.S. job creation.
Despite rapid growth in recent years, plants
and firms directly involved in exporting represent
a small percentage of the total number of U.S.
plants and firms. In 2000, for example, of the 5.5
million firms operating in the United States,
roughly 4 percent were exporters. These firms,
although relatively small in number, employ over
one-third of the U.S. workforce. Furthermore, a
1

subset of these firms does the bulk of the trading.
For example, in 2000, the top 10 percent of
exporting firms accounted for 96 percent of total
U.S. exports. These firms exhibit a number of
characteristics, such as relatively higher productivity and larger size, which likely contribute to
their export success. Moreover, exporters tend to
be more innovative and pay higher wages than
their domestic counterparts.
Not surprisingly, goods-producing firms
account for the majority of exports (and imports)
by value, although increasing numbers of firms
in wholesale and retail trade are engaging in international trade. Table 1 highlights some features
of the distribution of exporting firms across 10
manufacturing industries, ranked in terms of
industry employment as a share of total manufacturing in 2002. Across all industries, firms’
foreign shipments represent only a small share
of total shipments, as they never exceed 21 percent. In manufacturing as a whole, only 18 percent
of firms were exporters in 2002, with exports
accounting for 14 percent of total shipments.

See Bernard, Jensen, and Schott (2005) and Bernard, Jensen, Redding, and Schott (forthcoming).

3

INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FINANCE

Table 1
Firms That Trade

SOURCE: Source: Bernard et al., “Firms in International Trade,” from the 2002 Census of Manufacturers.
NAICS=North American Industry Classification System.

While my preceding comments refer to firms
that are trading goods, I would like to highlight
the linkages between firms directly engaged in
international trade and those that are linked to
such firms. While a number of small and mediumsized enterprises are exporters, numerous small
and medium-sized enterprises are also linked
via outsourcing, technology transfer and training
of local suppliers to multinational corporations.
These linkages can create business opportunities
and enhance the productivity of small and
medium-sized enterprises.
Data on international trade and trade-related
employment for Arkansas indicate that there are
undoubtedly many linkages between exporting
firms and other firms. Before discussing exports
from Arkansas, I need to provide a note of caution.
The export data I will be using, which are the
best available, allocate exports to states based on
the state from which goods began their journey
4

to the port or some other point of exit from the
United States. The transportation origin of exports
is not necessarily identical to the location where
the goods were produced. Thus, despite the inclination to think that exports from Arkansas were
produced in Arkansas, that is not necessarily the
case. Certain goods produced in Arkansas may
be counted as exports from some other state.
Keeping this note of caution in mind, the
extent of Arkansas’s involvement in international
trade appears somewhat lower than that of the
nation as a whole; however, Figure 4 indicates
that firms in Arkansas are increasingly involved
in international trade and that the increase during
recent years has tended to mirror that of the United
States as a whole. In price-adjusted terms, exports
from Arkansas as a share of gross state product
increased from 2.4 percent in 1990 to 6.1 percent
in 2006, an increase of 3.7 percentage points.
Meanwhile, U.S. exports as a share of GDP

U.S. Export Opportunities

Figure 4
AR State Exports and U.S. Exports as a Percent of Real GSP, 1990-2006
15

10
P ercent

U.S.

5

2 00 5

2 00 2

1 99 9

1 99 6

1 99 3

1 99 0

0

AR

SOURCE: WISER Trade, BEA, and Haver Analytics.

increased from 7.8 percent to 11.4 percent, an
increase of 3.6 percentage points. These growth
rates are significant and, if projected forward,
show that exports will become increasingly important for the Arkansas and national economies.
In 2006, Arkansas’ export shipments of merchandise totaled $4.3 billion, an increase of 52
percent over its 2002 value.2 In 2006, these
exports were shipped to 159 foreign destinations.
Figure 5 provides a summary view of these destinations and the magnitude of exports. The two
largest markets are Canada ($1.1 billion) and
Mexico ($528 million). In addition to the sizes of
these markets, proximity as well as the relatively
free trade environment stemming from the North
American Free Trade Agreement contributed to
the large export shares of these markets. Other top
export markets are France, the United Kingdom,
China, Portugal, Japan, South Korea, Germany,
and Russia.
Turning to specific industries, Figure 6 provides a view of the export shares of specific indus2

tries. Transportation equipment is the largest
export category, accounting for 28 percent, or
$1.2 billion, of Arkansas’ merchandise exports
in 2006. Other leading export categories were
chemical manufactures, machinery manufactures,
processed foods and primary metal manufactures.
With regard to employment related to manufactured goods exports, Arkansas’ involvement
is also slightly below the nation as a whole. Using
data for 2003, the most recent available, estimates
by the International Trade Administration indicate that 43,100 jobs in Arkansas were related
to exports. Of these jobs, 18,400 were in the
manufacturing sector, while 24,700 were in nonmanufacturing sectors. These data show the
importance of linkages across various types of
firms. Manufacturing-related export employment
as a share of private sector employment in
Arkansas was 4.3 percent, slightly below the
national average of 4.5 percent. Thus, slightly
more than one of every 25 jobs in Arkansas was
linked to manufactured exports.

For a summary of Arkansas’ international involvement, see www.ita.doc.gov/td/industry/otea/state%5Freports/arkansas.html.

5

INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FINANCE

Figure 5
Global Pattern of Arkansas 2006 Exports ($ USD)

SOURCE: TradeStatsExpress. Presented by the Office of Trade and Industry Information (OTII),
Manufacturing and Services, International Trade Administration, U.S. Department of Commerce.

Figure 6
Product Profile of Arkansas 2006 Global Exports ($ USD)

39.2%
10.7%

Transportation Equipment
Processed Foods

28.2%
10.9%

Chemical Manufactures
All Others

11%

Machinery Manufactures

SOURCE: TradeStatsExpress. Presented by the Office of Trade and Industry Information (OTII),
Manufacturing and Services, International Trade Administration, U.S. Department of Commerce.

6

U.S. Export Opportunities

A total of 1,396 companies exported goods
from locations throughout Arkansas during 2005.
Roughly 76 percent of these companies had
employment of 500 or less and, thus, were small
and medium-sized enterprises. These firms
accounted for 19 percent of Arkansas’ merchandise exports in 2005.

THE IMPORTANCE OF FOREIGN
INCOME GROWTH FOR
EXPORTS
Increases in international trade depend on
income growth and changes in the costs of international trade. Some trade costs reflect barriers
imposed by governments and some are the result
of nature. A tariff, which is a tax imposed on
imported goods, is an example of the former,
while transportation cost is an example of the
latter. When two researchers examined the relative importance of income growth, reductions in
government barriers to trade and declines in transportation costs, they found that income growth
was the most important of these three factors
stimulating trade worldwide, with reductions in
trade barriers a distant second and declines in
transportation costs an even more distant third.3
This ranking, though, reflects experience over two
particular periods in the latter half of the 20th
century—the analysis uses the average trade of
1958-1960 and 1986-1988. We should not forget
that trade barriers were critically important in
depressing trade at certain times in the past, especially during the Great Depression, and could
be so again should the United States become
involved in trade wars.
As foreign economies grow, the purchasing
power of its residents increases. To tap into rising
purchasing power abroad, U.S. firms must provide goods and services desired by these potential
consumers. A sensible export strategy is to focus
3

See Baier and Bergstrand (2001).

4

See Morasch (2006).

5

See Smith (2007).

attention on foreign countries that are growing
the most rapidly.
U.S. export growth to a country and the
growth of that foreign country are closely related.
When we examine export growth from 2002 to
2006 and the top 50 U.S. export destinations in
2006, we find that the simple correlation between
export growth and income growth is 0.63. Given
this high correlation, it is not surprising that U.S.
exports to China and India, two rapidly growing
countries, increased at a rapid pace between 2002
and 2006. U.S. exports to each of these countries
increased by a factor of roughly 2.5, which is
substantially greater than the 1.5 factor by which
overall U.S. exports increased. As with the United
States as a whole, Arkansas’ exports to China
and India grew rapidly between 2002 and 2006.
In fact, Arkansas’ exports increased more rapidly
than for the total United States—by a factor of 4
to China and by a factor of 7.3 to India. Arkansas’
total exports to all destinations abroad increased
by a factor of 1.5.
Consider an example of how China’s growing
economy is providing opportunities for firms
based in Arkansas. An inevitable consequence of
economic growth is trash. A Springdale, Arkansas
company, JV Manufacturing, is providing technology for hydraulic compactors that smash the
refuse before it is taken to a landfill.4 Currently,
these compactors are being used in Huaibei,
China. Plans are in the works to export the technology to other regions of China.
Another consequence of economic growth is
increased demand for food products. Increases
in income from low levels invariably lead to
increased demand for animal protein. Chicken,
pork and beef are all exported from Arkansas to
China.5 Tyson Foods exported the majority of
frozen chicken cuts, which is the leading food
export from Arkansas to China.
The key role that income growth plays in
international trade suggests that, from a national

7

INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FINANCE

perspective, exports and imports are linked. One
linkage is as follows: Foreign income growth
affects U.S. exports, which help to determine U.S.
income and, therefore, imports. Consequently,
changes that affect exports will affect imports and
vice versa. Thus, actions that limit U.S. imports
will also tend to reduce U.S. exports because they
depress income growth abroad. Few people seem
to understand that raising import barriers will
tend to reduce export opportunities. Countries
with high trade barriers and relatively low levels
of imports will also have relatively low levels of
exports.

THE CURRENT POLITICAL
ECONOMY OF INTERNATIONAL
TRADE
Earlier in my presentation I discussed some
key findings concerning firms that export. I’ll
return to one of these findings and then use it as
a foundation for a brief discussion of trade policy.
Let’s look more closely at the finding that exporting firms have relatively higher productivity
than non-exporting firms do.
Research shows that the higher productivity
of exporting firms relative to non-trading firms
exists even before they enter export markets.
Furthermore, the productivity of exporting firms
after they enter export markets does not grow more
rapidly than the productivity of non-exporting
firms. The conclusion is that higher productivity
is a requirement for, rather than a consequence
of, engaging in international trade. A possible
reason for the requirement of high productivity
is that high entry costs of becoming an exporter
can only be borne profitably by the most efficient
firms.
Interestingly, research has shown that after
firms enter export markets they do experience
faster growth of employment and output than
non-exporters do. A reduction in trade barriers

would increase profit opportunities from exporting to a specific destination and would reduce
the initial productivity level necessary to enter
the export market. Reduced barriers will induce
more firms to export. Increased exports in turn
would generate an increased demand for labor
and, therefore, higher wages. Low-productivity
non-exporting firms would be forced to exit the
industry, and both capital and labor would be
reallocated from the less productive non-export
firms to the more productive exporting firms,
increasing average productivity. Because the
reallocation of productive factors is found to
occur both within and across industries, this
process creates aggregate productivity gains.
The productivity facts relating to exporting
firms suggest an important role for trade liberalization in improving the aggregate productivity
of the economy. Productivity gains stemming
from trade liberalization allow for increases in
output and income. Recent research indicates
that the payoff to the United States of liberalization of trade and international investment has
been quite large.6 Based on several different statistical approaches, the estimated payoff ranged
from 7.3 percent to 13.2 percent of U.S. GDP in
2003. Using 2006 dollars, these estimates suggest
a higher per capita income in the United States
ranging from $3,000 to $5,436. These are not
small effects.
The preceding reasoning, supported by
empirical estimates, implies that negotiations
that reduce trade barriers can be very beneficial.7
Conversely, legislation that imposes trade barriers
will likely be harmful. To my disappointment, as
I survey the current state of trade negotiations
and numerous legislative proposals, I am troubled
that the direction of trade policy in the immediate future may not be the right one. Let me give
you four examples that create my concern.
First, fast-track negotiating authority expired
on June 30. This authority allows the president
to negotiate trade agreements that Congress can

6

See Bradford, Grieco, and Hufbauer (2006).

7

Bradford, Grieco, and Hufbauer (2006) conservatively estimate that global free trade would produce higher per capita income ranging from
$1,540 to $2,069 using 2003 dollars or from $1,635 to $2,255 using 2006 dollars.

8

U.S. Export Opportunities

either accept or reject, but cannot amend or filibuster. The lack of fast-track authority matters
because trading partners are extremely reluctant
to negotiate with the United States when experience indicates, unfortunately, that agreements
may be substantially altered during the legislative
process.
Second, the Doha Development Agenda
multilateral trade negotiations are on the verge
of collapse. A collapse of the Doha round would
raise doubts about the future effectiveness of
the World Trade Organization, which is the key
international organization for negotiating,
implementing and enforcing multilateral trade
agreements.
Third, many in the United States seem to
favor a more confrontational approach with the
Chinese.8 China is an increasingly frequent target
for anti-dumping actions. In international trade
law, “dumping” is said to occur when a firm sells
a product at a higher price in its home market
than the price it charges when it exports the same
product to another country. If U.S. manufacturers
can establish that they are being harmed by dumping on this definition, then duties (i.e., import
taxes) are imposed to counteract the calculated
extent of the dumping. The illogic of anti-dumping laws is clear: Would we prefer that U.S. consumers pay higher prices than charged abroad?
Would U.S. consumers be harmed in the most
extreme possible “dumping” scenario in which
they received goods from abroad for free?
Currently, the Chinese share of anti-dumping
actions is nearly double its share of U.S. imports.
Moreover, in March 2007, the Commerce Department began applying anti-subsidy laws to China.
This action reversed 23 years of policy and led
to filings that China has illegally subsidized
exports of tires, paper bags, steel pipes and steel
nails. These legal actions are anti-consumer.
The U.S. is also pursuing complaints against
China within the World Trade Organization. The
U.S. trade representative has initiated four cases
against China, which is more than against any
other country at this time. The charges include
8

illegally high Chinese tariffs on automobile parts
imported from the United States. U.S. pressure
to reduce barriers for U.S. exports should ideally
encourage a more open world trading system;
however, the prospects for successful negotiations
dim when, simultaneously, the United States is
itself imposing import barriers.
Some U.S. legislative proposals seem to be
based on a presumption that trade retaliation is
an effective strategy; however, economic history
suggests otherwise. Rather than passive compliance with trade restrictions, the targeted country
tends to retaliate. Successive rounds of retaliation
can spiral into a trade war. Actually, the process
should be called “an anti-trade war.” Restriction
of a country’s exports forces it to reorient its economy toward alternative suppliers and markets.
Such a reorientation is facilitated by the fact that
a trade retaliation policy tends to expand the
role of government in the targeted country. In the
present case, U.S. interests are likely best served
by an increasing role for individual consumers
and firms in a more market-oriented Chinese
economy.
A tragic episode from economic history provides additional reasons for my concerns about
the future course of trade policy. The Great
Depression was a global catastrophe. Most
researchers agree that the Smoot-Hawley tariffs
of 1930 precipitated retaliation and likely worsened the effects of the Great Depression by contributing to the collapse of trade throughout the
world in the early 1930s. An all-out trade war
seems unlikely today but a series of smaller barriers inflicting economic costs on a trading partner
has the possibility of inflicting harm far beyond
the original target. I am very uncomfortable with
the numerous actions and proposed legislation
that not only are unlikely to affect the large U.S.
trade deficit but also are increasing the chances
of escalating trade frictions.
There is a role, of course, for protecting U.S.
consumers from unsafe products but this role
should not depend on whether goods are produced in the United States or abroad. A key

See Weisman (2007).

9

INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FINANCE

principle is that identical standards that address
genuine safety issues be applied to a good regardless of where it is produced. One unfortunate
possibility is that product safety issues become
part of a trade war. For example, recently the
United States suspended some Chinese seafood
imports after finding traces of cancer-causing
chemicals. Shortly thereafter, the Chinese suspended imports of chicken feet, pig ears and other
animal products from seven U.S. companies, one
of which was Tyson Foods.9 The Chinese justification for their action was that the products contained bacteria as well as residues of drugs and
pesticides. There is no reason why the two countries should not work cooperatively on a food
inspection program to serve their common interests in high-quality food.
Somewhat ironically, the recent problems
involving defective Chinese goods, produced for
Chinese as well as foreign consumers, highlight
an important fact. Rather than being overtaken by
production sourced in China, it is clear that in
numerous industries U.S. firms are substantially
ahead of Chinese firms. Moreover, significant
parts of the services sector as well as high-tech
manufacturing have yet to appear in China.
Undoubtedly, given China’s environmental problems, U.S. firms with environmentally friendly
technology as well as firms involved in clean-up
operations should prosper. Assuming a trading
environment relatively free of barriers, U.S. firms
will have an opportunity to use their advantages
to serve the Chinese market.

CONCLUDING COMMENTS
U.S. exporters are formidable competitors in
international markets and can become even more
formidable competitors in an international trading
environment as free as possible of governmentally
imposed barriers. The increasing involvement in
markets globally serves the best interests of U.S.
residents, both as consumers and as workers. In
terms of income, the payoffs from prior liberal9

See Irvin (2007).

10

izations of trade and investment flows have been
quite large. I am certain that actions hindering
entry of U.S. innovators and entrepreneurs in
global markets will ultimately prove harmful to
economic well-being in Arkansas and the United
States generally. Thus, we should all be concerned
about the current lack of progress in liberalizing
trade flows and the increasing threat of legislation tending toward economic isolation. Such
actions, if they occur, will depress exports in the
future from Arkansas and the United States as a
whole. More importantly, governmental actions
that depress exports will ultimately harm U.S.
income prospects by inhibiting productivity and
income growth.

REFERENCES
Baier, Scott L. and Bergstrand, Jeffrey H. “The Growth
of World Trade: Tariffs, Transport Costs, and Income
Similarity.” Journal of International Economics,
February 2001, 53(1), pp. 1-27.
Bernard, Andrew B.; Jensen, J. Bradford; Redding,
Stephen J.; and Schott, Peter J. “Firms in
International Trade.” Journal of Economic
Perspectives, forthcoming.
Bernard, Andrew B.; Jensen, J. Bradford; and Schott,
Peter J. “Importers, Exporters, and Multinationals:
A Portrait of Firms in the U.S. that Trade Goods.”
Institute for International Economics, Working
Paper 05-10, September 2005.
Bradford, Scott C.; Grieco, Paul L.E.; and Hufbauer,
Gary Clyde. “The Payoff to America from
Globalisation.” The World Economy, July 2006,
29(7), pp. 893-916.
Irvin, David. “Tyson Says Chinese Ban Is a Narrow
One.” Arkansas Democrat-Gazette, July 17, 2007,
p. 21.
Morasch, Charlie. “Springdale Mayor Cements
Relations in China; Trash Firm Opens Sister City

U.S. Export Opportunities

System.” Arkansas Democrat-Gazette, August 14,
2006, p. 7.
Smith, David. “China a Growing Market for State;
Nation of One Billion Forming a Taste for Arkansas
Goods.” Arkansas Democrat-Gazette, January 21,
2007, p. 79.
Weisman, Steven R. “China-U.S. Talks Continue,
Amid Legal Volleys.” New York Times, July 30,
2007, p. 1.

11