View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Trade, Wages, and Employment
LeMoyne-Owen College
Memphis, Tennessee
March 25, 2004

M

y remarks today will focus on
trade, wages, and jobs.1 Workers’
anxieties about their jobs are making headlines and affecting debate
within and between both major political parties.
With jobs in February 2004 reported by the payroll employment survey at a level more than 2.3
million below their level less than three years
earlier, the fact that jobs are a major issue is far
from surprising. I am sure that many of you are
following these developments because you are
either involved in the labor market or actively
preparing for entry into the labor market.
Any discussion of jobs in the current environment must necessarily address the issues of international trade as well as wages. Indeed, some
believe that trade has a lot to do with weak job
creation in the United States. Federal and state
legislators are discussing proposals to counteract
globalization.
My plan is to outline the nature of the debate,
to discuss the powerful economic forces expanding trade, and state the case for the gains from
trade. I’m going to concentrate on the effects of
trade on the workforce, rather than on the advantages of trade for consumers. I’ll emphasize a perspective that is, I believe, sorely lacking in the
current debate. The perspective is that much of
what is happening today is an unavoidable consequence of new technology. Rather than complaining about the consequences of new technology,
or trying to roll back its effects, we need to adapt
1

and use technology in innovative and constructive ways.
Before proceeding, I want to emphasize that
the views I express here are mine and do not
necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal
Reserve System. I thank my colleagues at the
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis for their comments; Cletus Coughlin, vice president in the
Research Division, was especially helpful. However, I retain full responsibility for errors.

THE DEBATE
Much of what I hear and read about international trade these days makes me apprehensive.
Critics of free trade abound. I am convinced that
outsourcing and globalization yield important
long-run benefits for the United States as a whole.
The case for free trade should not be offered
defensively and apologetically, but clearly and
forcefully.
Unfortunately, as is true of many developments that increase the nation’s well-being, the
gains from trade are not achieved without cost.
It is true that some workers lose their jobs and a
number of these are unemployed, in some cases
for periods too long to be labeled “temporary.”
Trade and technology interact. One example
is jet aircraft, which not only replaced many passenger trains domestically but also dramatically
reduced freight transportation costs internationally. Jet freighters now carry a large fraction of

This speech is something of a companion piece to two earlier speeches on international economic issues. See “A Perspective on U.S.
International Capital Flows” (address before the Tucson Chapter of the Association for Investment Management Research (AIMR), Tucson,
Arizona, November 14, 2003) and “A Perspective on U.S. International Trade” (address before Louisville Society of Financial Analysts,
Louisville, Kentucky, November 19, 2003).

1

INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FINANCE

high-value goods in international trade. Technological change has expanded markets domestically and internationally, permitting substitution
of lower cost production locations for higher cost
ones.
The transitional costs stemming from unemployment created by economic change have generated much discussion concerning the appropriate
policy response. Some argue that public policy
should attempt to counteract the market forces
driving outsourcing and other forms of increased
international trade, while others argue that public policy should act in conjunction with the
market forces.
My concern is that fears associated with economic progress will lead to misguided policies
that will generate large costs and minimal benefits
even for those intended to benefit. My preference
is for policies that allow markets to work better,
while providing transitional assistance to those
adversely affected.

INCENTIVES TO TRADE
The basic incentive to trade arises from the
fact that it is often possible to obtain goods more
cheaply through trade. The place to begin the
analysis is with an important and obviously correct proposition in economics—the tendency of a
given good to sell for the same price in all markets.
It is worth spending a moment to think about
price equalization to understand just how powerful a force it is. If the price of the same good differs in two locations, then consumers have an
incentive to purchase the good from the seller
with the lower price. Every time you pass by a gas
station with a high price so that you can buy at a
cheaper price you contribute to price equalization.
As it is often put, buyers try to buy in cheap markets and sellers try to sell in dear markets.
I grew up in Delaware, a state without a sales
tax. Citizens of neighboring states come to
Delaware to shop, often by the busload. In principle, they are supposed to pay the appropriate
use tax in lieu of sales tax to their state governments when they bring goods from Delaware into
2

their own states, but very few do. Most people
do not even realize that they are supposed to pay
the equivalent taxes to their own states, and when
informed of the requirement they regard this legal
provision as unfair and unreasonable. A legal
provision like this one is simply unenforceable
when most citizens regard it as unjust and believe,
correctly, that enforcement is very unlikely.
Would anyone seriously argue that neighboring states to Delaware should attempt to enforce
the sales tax by installing roadblocks and inspecting every car for goods purchased in Delaware?
Such a policy would be extremely costly, and
perhaps unconstitutional. I can guarantee that the
governor of a neighboring state would be quickly
voted out of office if he were to instruct his state
police to stop every car at the Delaware border
and search for goods purchased in Delaware. For
the neighboring states of Pennsylvania, Maryland,
and New Jersey, the absence of a sales tax in
Delaware is a fact of life and everyone had better
just get used to it.
If there were more states like Delaware scattered across the country, the sales tax would all
but disappear because it would become unenforceable. Competition is a powerful force, and
the tendency for price equalization across markets
is so pervasive that governments cannot pass
effective laws against it. You may or may not like
this result, but it is a fact of life.
The tendency toward price equalization
applies to wages paid to workers as well as to
the prices paid for goods. Wages for labor of a
given skill level tend toward equality in different
markets. The economic forces are the same as
those applying to goods. People tend to move to
where wages are higher, and firms tend to locate
where wages are lower. As with prices, wage
equalization is often incomplete. Some locations
have productivity advantages over other locations,
and some areas have a higher cost of living, which
reduces the incentive of people to move. Nevertheless, when wage differences are large enough
to overwhelm such considerations, people tend
to move, or try to move, to take advantage of
higher wages.

Trade, Wages, and Employment

The United States has seen vast internal
migrations, especially from rural to urban areas,
as people have sought higher incomes. Similarly,
people have sought to migrate internationally,
braving extreme risks to come to North America.
Starting with the first English colony established
in America, people have knowingly taken difficult
ocean voyages to settle in an often hostile environment. They came because of the economic opportunity and to live in a free nation. Of course, many
were also brought here against their will, and
only slowly have their descendants been able to
enjoy the freedom and economic opportunity
that attracted so many to come voluntarily.
Today, many brave similar hazards to cross
U.S. borders, especially in the desert southwest.
We should not underestimate people’s ingenuity
and steadfastness of purpose to come to this country. Whatever your views on U.S. immigration
policy, you cannot ignore the strength of the effort
so many are willing to make to come to this country and to remain here. That is a fact, however
inconvenient it may seem.
Recent controversy over international trade
focuses on international outsourcing of activities
such as computer programming and call centers.
Many other jobs, such as tax preparation and
transcription of medical records are affected.2 In
what follows, I’ll use “call centers” as a shorthand
for all these sorts of jobs.
What we are observing is an apparently new
form of international trade—trade in services that
were previously not subject to trade. Writing
standard types of computer code and taking telephone orders are good jobs, but some of these
jobs can now be performed abroad. So, some of
these service jobs are going abroad just as did
many manufacturing jobs over the last 25 years.
What makes service outsourcing possible now
is a dramatic decline in the costs of communications. An article earlier this month in the Wall
Street Journal reports that “a telephone and data

line under the Pacific Ocean capable of handling
up to 128 voice calls at a time can cost just $11,000
a month—one-fourth its cost just two years ago.”3
The sharp decline in communications costs
is a consequence of advancing technology and
the glut of fiber optic cable installed in the late
1990s. Cutting these cables or trying to control
voice and data transmission over them is no more
realistic than state governments trying to prevent
their citizens from shopping in Delaware. This
new type of international trade is a fact of life,
and we had better get used to it.

THE GAINS FROM TRADE
International trade arises fundamentally from
economic forces every bit as powerful as the ones
that drive desperately poor people to risk their
lives to come to the United States, and the ones
that lead you and me to find the best price of gas
when we fill up the car. These economic forces
of seeking the best price and the best place to
live improve our lives.
In our specialized economy, a typical household buys goods and services produced not only
in its home state but also throughout the United
States and the rest of the world. By specializing
in certain activities, regions as well as individuals
are able to maximize the value of work effort. By
producing most goods and services for sale to
others, we trade our output for the goods and services that we are not especially adept at producing.
Nearly 200 years ago, the economist David
Ricardo demonstrated the gains from trade. To
explain the principle of comparative advantage,
he used the example of England and Portugal
trading cloth and port wine. The trade made both
countries better off. If Portugal can produce both
port wine and cloth with fewer hours of labor
input per unit of output than can England, it will
still pay Portugal to produce wine and trade with
England for cloth, assuming that England is rela-

2

Kris Maher, “Next on the Outsourcing List,” the Wall Street Journal, March 23, 2004, p. B1.

3

Jesse Drucker, “Global Talk Gets Cheaper,” the Wall Street Journal, March 11, 2004, p. B1.

3

INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FINANCE

tively more efficient in producing cloth than wine.
The proposition generalizes to many goods and
many countries. As long as resources move into
those activities in which the country is most
advantaged or least disadvantaged, then all trading partners can be better off by trading some of
the output that they produce at relatively low
cost for some of the output that they produce at
relatively high cost.
In the absence of trade restrictions, the gains
from trade are limited by transportation costs.
For example, it would not make sense for you to
drive many miles to a cheaper gas station if those
extra miles used up $5 worth of gas to save $3
when filling the tank. Thus, price differences in
different markets can survive indefinitely if transportation costs prevent price equalization.
Over time, technological improvement has
dramatically reduced transportation costs, and
that is a prime reason for the expansion of international trade in recent decades. We can now
buy, for example, fresh fruits and vegetables in
the winter because they can be shipped by air
from the southern hemisphere, which enjoys
summer during our winter.
Changes in technology clearly produce benefits, but they also force adjustment. If you work
in a factory producing typewriters, you may not
be pleased to see people buying computers. If you
work in a call center in the United States, you
may not be pleased to see companies contracting
with call centers abroad.
Free trade contributes greatly to economic
growth, but it does create costs for workers in
industries displaced by international competition. Efforts to protect workers from the forces of
international competition, however, are costly to
the nations that pursue such policies. It is worth
spending a few minutes to discuss just how costly
protectionism can be.

THE COSTS OF PROTECTIONISM
A consistent finding in the economics literature is that trade restrictions impose net costs on
society. Despite the fact that trade restrictions
produce benefits for some, the benefits are more
than swamped by the costs borne by others.
Consider a few examples to illustrate how
costly protection can be.4 These examples are
from the early 1990s because careful estimates
of the current costs of protection on an industry
basis are not available. Gary Clyde Hufbauer and
Kimberly Ann Elliott generated estimates of the
potential net national losses by industry, as well
as the consumer losses and producer gains, associated with existing U.S. trade barriers.5
Hufbauer and Elliott provide estimates for
many individual industries, but consider just a
couple of examples. Because of the higher prices
for apparel that consumers were forced to pay as
a consequence of trade restrictions, the consumer
loss per job saved in the apparel industry was
$139,000 and the net national loss per job saved
was $51,000. Thus, consumers were effectively
paying an average of $139,000 for each job protected in 1990 in the apparel industry, an industry
in which the average wage of a production worker
was less than $15,000.
The apparel industry was not the only industry benefiting from trade restrictions. In the sugar
industry, the consumer loss per job saved was
$600,000 and in the benzenoid chemicals industry, the consumer loss per job saved exceeded
$1 million!

TRADE, TECHNOLOGY, AND
WAGES
The United States has experienced rising
wage inequality since the late 1970s. Wages of
college graduates relative to high school graduates

4

Cletus C. Coughlin, “The Controversy Over Free Trade: The Gap Between Economists and the General Public,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
Review, January/February 2002.

5

Gary Clyde Hufbauer and Kimberly Ann Elliott, Measuring the Costs of Protection in the United States, Institute for International
Economics, 1994.

4

Trade, Wages, and Employment

have risen, and the less educated appear to be
suffering declining real wages. Growing international trade has likely played a role in the
declining real wage paid to the least skilled
members of U.S. society.
The logic of the argument that trade has
impacted wages of less skilled workers is easy to
understand. If migration into the United States
were completely open, workers of any given skill
level would tend to earn the same wages wherever
they lived, as migration would tend to equalize
wages. The United States and other high-income
countries have an abundance of high-skilled
workers relative to poorer nations. If migration
were completely open, wages of such workers in
other countries would tend to rise to U.S. levels.
However, high-income countries have far fewer
low-skilled workers than do low-income countries. For these workers, free migration would
tend to lower wages in the United States toward
the world average for such workers.
Migration is not in fact open, which means
that the migration mechanism tending to equalize wages for various skill levels operates quite
weakly. However, trade in goods also tends to produce the same result. This fact has been known
since publication of an important paper 63 years
ago, in 1941, by Wolfgang F. Stolper and Paul A.
Samuelson.6 Clearly, economists have been interested in the issue of the effects of trade on wages
and returns to capital for a very long time.
In general, equalization of wages through
trade is limited by the transportation costs to ship
the good. Declines in transportation costs through
technological change will open up trade opportunities that did not exist before. The expanding
trade will make nations as a whole better off, but
create losses for certain firms and individuals now
subject to international competition that previously was impossible because of transportation
costs. The dramatic decline in communications
costs in recent years is now creating exactly this
effect for certain service industries such as call
centers.
6

The logic of how trade can substitute for
migration is not difficult to understand. Suppose
the cost of producing a particular good were 90
percent labor, and only 10 percent from materials
and capital. Then, clearly, free trade in the good
will tend to equalize the wages of the labor skill
required to produce that good. Trade in call-center
services may make it almost irrelevant whether
the worker on the end of the phone line resides
in the United States or abroad. I say “may make”
because there are still issues of training, supervision, and proximity to face-to-face communication
that create significant differences in productivity
between workers located in the United States and
those located abroad. The services most easily
relocated abroad will be those that are routine
and relatively simple.

OUTSOURCING AND
PRODUCTIVITY
The pace of change in the IT industry has
been enormous, and much of it is quite recent. In
the late 1990s, telecom companies installed a huge
amount of fiber optic cable, under both land and
ocean. Rarely, if ever, has the cost of shipping
something declined so rapidly and so greatly. In
this case, it is information that is being shipped.
Telephonic and data transmission have become
vastly cheaper, opening up new opportunities
for trade.
The outsourcing of information technology
services, which entails some shifting of jobs from
the United States to other countries, such as India,
has generated much controversy. It is now possible to locate call centers, which are obviously
labor intensive, almost anywhere in the world.
Fiber optic cables carry messages and data in both
directions, which means that this technology is
as important for U.S. exports as for U.S. imports.
Given this fact, there is about as much chance of
stopping this new type of international trade as
there is of stopping shoppers from coming to
Delaware to avoid sales tax.

“Protection and Real Wages,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 9, November 1941, pp. 58-73.

5

INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FINANCE

Nor should we want to stop international
voice and data transmission. Recent research by
Catherine Mann concludes that the globalization
of information technology services will propel a
new wave of productivity growth.7 Mann envisions this process unfolding in the following
manner:
In response to market incentives, the globalization of software and information technology
services requires that some work will be done
overseas. Note that I said that some, not all, work
will be done abroad. Coinciding with the spread
of these new information technologies throughout the United States, high-skill U.S. jobs to
design information technology implementations
for specific uses will increase. Moreover, jobs
requiring skills to use the new technology will
spread throughout the economy. Mann’s reasoning
is consistent with estimates from the Bureau of
Labor Statistics that occupations requiring information technology skills will increase at three
times the rate of job growth in the overall economy.
Looking forward, Mann stresses that the
globalization of software and services, enhanced
use of information technology, productivity
growth, and job creation are intertwined. Public
policies that inhibit this process will necessarily
have adverse effects on growth and job prospects
in the United States.
In a highly competitive market, firms cannot
afford to forego the cost savings associated with
outsourcing or buying required inputs from the
least-price source. It is true that buying the services from abroad might mean that the firm will
have fewer employees in the United States. However, jobs in the United States remain because
the firm survives. Foregoing the cost reductions
would mean that all the firm’s jobs in the United
States would be placed at a much higher risk.
Legislation that bars companies from government
contracts if they plan to carry out some or all of
the work abroad is fundamentally at odds with
the efficiency and productivity gains that a free
market will yield.
7

6

JOBS AND SAFETY NETS
Despite the inevitability, and desirability, of
enlarged trade in IT services, the question remains
of how to limit adverse impacts on affected
workers. The loss of a job often imposes substantial costs on workers and their families. These
costs occur during the period of unemployment
as well as later if workers have to adjust to a lower
level of pay. Older workers are especially prone
to suffer wage cuts as they tend to be less flexible
in adapting to new production techniques. They
may lack the educational background to transfer
to well-paid service-sector jobs.
Trade liberalization is often the focal point
for anxiety about jobs. The focus on trade occurs
despite the fact that job losses result from many
non-trade factors, such as changes in technology,
shifts in consumer demand, environmental regulations, and the general state of the overall economy. Most of these changes have little direct
connection to the growth of international trade
as a consequence of technological change or
reduction of trade barriers such as tariffs.
Firms have an obligation to do whatever they
reasonably can to cushion the effects of job losses.
The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis is no
stranger to these issues. As a consequence of
declining check volume and federal law that
requires the Federal Reserve to cover its costs in
the check processing business, the St. Louis Fed
is closing its check processing operations in its
Louisville and Little Rock Branches. What we
have done is to provide ample notice to our
employees whose jobs will be disappearing,
substantial severance payments, and relocation
assistance to other Federal Reserve facilities for
employees who can find jobs at those locations
and who are willing and able to move.
But there is only so much that individual
firms can do. Costs incurred by U.S. workers
stemming from job insecurity are therefore a
public policy issue. Policy experts have long
been interested in how government can more
effectively assist displaced workers.

Catherine Mann, Globalization of IT Services and White Collar Jobs: The Next Wave of Productivity Growth, Institute for International
Economics, International Economics Policy Briefs, Number PB03-11, December 2003.

Trade, Wages, and Employment

It is noteworthy that, relative to other countries, in the United States many fewer individuals
are unemployed for long periods. Using data
from the Organisation for Economic Co-operation
and Development (OECD) for 2002, the distribution of unemployment by duration showed that
in the United States 35 percent were unemployed
for three months or longer. For all OECD members,
the comparable figure is 62 percent.8 Meanwhile,
roughly 9 percent were unemployed for more
than one year in the United States versus 30 percent for all OECD countries. Despite the extensive
welfare state policies pursued in many European
countries, the United States actually does a much
better job in minimizing the trauma of long-term
unemployment.
A basic public policy issue is how to compensate the unemployed while simultaneously
providing incentives for them to seek to become
re-employed. Since 1974, in certain cases where
job losses can be tied to international trade, U.S.
unemployment insurance has been supplemented
by a program known as trade adjustment assistance. Qualified individuals may receive 52 additional weeks of unemployment insurance if they
are enrolled in an approved training program. A
similar program was set up for those who lost
their jobs as part of the North American Free
Trade Agreement.
Without question, many people have legitimate fears about the short-run consequences of
free trade and globalization. Jagdish Bhagwati, a
professor at Columbia University and a leading
defender of globalization, has tied these fears to
the lack of institutional support for those at risk
of becoming unemployed or underemployed.9
Bhagwati argues that the safety net for those at
risk is much less in the United States than in
other countries.
How might the safety net be expanded? A proposal by Lori Kletzer and Robert Litan suggests

adding wage insurance upon re-employment and
subsidies for medical insurance to the current
unemployment insurance for full-time workers
who have been dislocated, regardless of the reason, from jobs they have held for two or more
years.10 The wage insurance provision would pay
the worker for a period of time some percentage
of the difference between the worker’s old wage
and new wage. The medical insurance subsidy
would increase the likelihood that an unemployed
worker could afford to buy medical insurance
while unemployed. I have no position concerning the specifics of their proposal. However, in
terms of making markets work rather than attempting to inhibit markets from allocating resources
to their most productive ends, the proposal has
merit.11

JOBS, HIGHER EDUCATION,
AND THE FUTURE
One of the key points of the preceding discussion is that a worker’s skills are crucial in today’s
global labor market. Technological change, which
is the driving force for economic growth and
higher standards of living, is constantly changing
the value of those skills. It is easy to identify many
cases in which technological changes have altered
employment opportunities and the value of jobspecific skills. As employment has declined in
many manufacturing industries in the United
States, workers have experienced these consequences first-hand. These employment changes
highlight the importance of life-long learning.
The United States provides large subsidies to
higher education, and a high fraction of its population completes college and university degrees.
College can teach some job-specific skills, but no
one should believe that those specific skills will

8

These data are published by the OECD in Labor Force Statistics.

9

Jagdish Bhagwati, In Defense of Globalization, Oxford University Press, 2004.

10

Lori G. Kletzer and Robert E. Litan, A Prescription to Relieve Worker Anxiety, Policy Brief 01-2, Institute for International Economics,
February 2001.

11

Mann (2003) notes that a modified version of this proposal was included in recent trade promotion authority legislation.

7

INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FINANCE

last a lifetime. The fact is that many jobs do not
last a lifetime and, even for those that do, technological changes will alter how those jobs are done.
The most important education college can offer
is to provide the foundation that will allow students to learn and acquire new skills over time.
College should instill in students a passion for
life-long learning.
No skills are more important and more transferable to different jobs than logical thinking and
good communication. Generating sound decisions
involves a number of steps, such as acquiring
data, assessing the usefulness of the information,
understanding the role of risk and thinking
through the immediate and long-terms consequences of specific decisions. Communicating
effectively entails speaking, listening, and writing
in both formal and informal settings. Regardless
of the setting, the communication has to be wellorganized and suited to the audience.
In my own experience as a university professor I was frequently frustrated by the minimal
attention many of my students paid to good writing. Quite frankly, I was struck by the difference,
on average, in the attention paid to writing by my
American students and my international students.
Too many of my American students seemed not
to care about good writing, whereas most of my
international students were eager to learn to use
the English language effectively.

8

IN A NUTSHELL
In a nutshell, my argument is this. Technology
will continue to change rapidly. Trade and production patterns within the United States and in
the world economy are also changing rapidly.
Trade in goods will tend to equalize wages for
given skill levels just as surely as would open
migration of people from low-wage countries to
high-wage countries.
Today’s workforce must adapt to the dynamic
environment in which we live. The forces of
change are too powerful for any government to
control, without making its people much poorer
than they need to be. No example of this process
is clearer than the outsourcing of call-center jobs.
A repressive government might try to cut off
communication with the rest of the world by
severing fiber optic cables, but that will not happen in a free society. Voice and data flow in both
directions in these cables, and only a tiny part
of the traffic is related to job loss in the United
States.
Only pessimists believe that U.S. entrepreneurs will be unable to compete successfully in
world markets using new technology. I myself
am a productivity optimist because there is no
society more entrepreneurial, more open, more
resourceful than the United States.