View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Staying Out of the Way of Entrepreneurs
“Striking the Right Notes on Entrepreneurship”
Sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis in partnership with the American Bankers Association,
CFED, Ewing Marion Kauffman Foundation and the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City
Memphis, Tennessee
April 19, 2005

I

have long had an interest in entrepreneurship. Every school boy and school girl
learns of examples of great entrepreneurs
such as Henry Ford. As I was growing up
in Wilmington, Delaware, local lore emphasized
the importance of the duPont family; evidence
of the family’s business success over many generations was obvious to everyone who lived in
northern Delaware. It is always risky to pick out
names, because there are so many who will be
left out, but here in Memphis I am sure that
those who built FedEx naturally come to mind.
Indeed, I think it accurate to say that every community in the United States can point to entrepreneurs who left at least a local mark and many
communities can point to their home-grown
entrepreneurs who have built firms of national
and international importance. It is also noteworthy that great entrepreneurs have enriched
the country not only by the businesses they have
built but also by their contributions to universities, museums, libraries and many other cultural
resources. That is certainly the case in Delaware,
where many public schools bear the names of
duPont family members who provided large gifts
to establish and expand the schools.
As suggested by the title of my talk, my inclination is that the best way to encourage entrepreneurship is for the government to stay out of the
way of entrepreneurs. After all, as the Kauffman
Foundation says, entrepreneurship is:
...associated with individuals who create or
seize business opportunities and pursue them
1

without regard for resources under their
control…Words that describe entrepreneurship
include innovative, creative, dynamic, risktolerant, flexible, and growth-oriented.1

Some will say that keeping government out
of the way of entrepreneurs is a simple-minded
approach, and it certainly is true that we can find
examples of successful entrepreneurs within
government. Nevertheless, words such as “innovative,” “creative,” “dynamic,” “risk-tolerant,”
“flexible,” and “growth-oriented” are not used
very often to describe government employees.
And it is certainly true that countries that have
relied on government enterprise rather than
private enterprise have a poor record of
achievement.
What is an entrepreneur? Entrepreneurs
organize, manage, and assume the risks of a
business or enterprise. They are willing to take
on greater risks than other individuals and
depend primarily on their individual initiative
to achieve success. When an entrepreneur goes
to work in the morning, his or her assets and
economic future are on the line.
What kinds of government policies can help
such a person to be successful? My basic theme
is that government should concentrate on providing the fundamental legal and security infrastructure necessary for a democratic society to
function, and should avoid detailed regulation
of business practices and market structures. As
much as possible, we should rely on competitive

Kayne, Jay. State Entrepreneurship Policies and Programs. Kauffman Center for Entrepreneurial Leadership at the Ewing Marion Kauffman
Foundation, Kansas City, Missouri, 1999.

1

ECONOMIC GROWTH

forces rather than government forces to constrain
private power.
That’s not to say that governments should do
nothing about entrepreneurship, but their role
should be limited to creating a policy environment that allows entrepreneurs to make their own
decisions with the absolute minimum involvement of government regulators. The Federal
Reserve, for example, plays an important role in
promoting entrepreneurship and general business
growth. Businesses in general—and entrepreneurs
in particular—benefit from price stability, a strong
banking system and an efficient payments system.
All three of these are central Federal Reserve
responsibilities.
Similarly, government has other functions of
critical importance to a market economy, such as
maintaining an efficient and honest legal system,
security of person and property, and a regulatory
system that deals effectively with conditions of
modern life such as environmental hazards. I
obviously cannot treat all the complexities of
this subject here, but simply want to emphasize
my general view that regulation should be kept
at a minimum and entrepreneurs nourished rather
than shackled.
Before proceeding, I want to emphasize that
the views I express here are mine and do not
necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal
Reserve System. I thank my colleagues at the
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis for their comments, especially Thomas A. Garrett, senior
economist, and Howard J. Wall, assistant vice
president, who provided special assistance. I
retain full responsibility for errors.

ENTREPRENEURIAL SPIRIT SETS
THE UNITED STATES APART
Before discussing the relative merits of the
various policies to encourage entrepreneurship,

let’s consider the reasons that the level of entrepreneurship differs across areas. Although the
largest differences in entrepreneurship exist
between countries, the lessons that these differences provide can be useful for understanding
differences between regions and states within
the United States. Observers comparing the U.S.
economy to the economies of other countries
often note that Americans seem to be much more
willing to become entrepreneurs. Indeed, a recent
survey found that more than 70 percent of adult
Americans would prefer being an entrepreneur
to working for someone else.2 In contrast, the
same survey showed that fewer than half of the
adults in Western Europe and Japan would prefer
being an entrepreneur.
So, what is it that sets the United States apart?
When economists try to explain differences in
entrepreneurship across countries or regions,
they typically examine a long list of economic
and institutional factors. What they tend to find
is that, while these factors are important, a large
component of the differences in entrepreneurship
has nothing to do with economics or institutions.3
Clearly, there is something intangible at work—
which we can call “entrepreneurial spirit”—a set
of attitudes independent of economic policies.
In other words, even if all countries had the same
economic conditions and policies, some would
still be more entrepreneurial than others, and
the United States would be among the leaders.
The best explanation for this finding is that there
are social factors at work that are difficult or
impossible to quantify. The United States has
been relatively successful in creating a policy
environment that takes advantage of these intangible, yet vital, assets.
Policymakers in the European Union, for
instance, have been grappling with their perceived gap in entrepreneurial spirit. What they
have come to recognize from comparing their
countries with the United States is that it is not
enough to have appropriate laws and regulations.

2

Blanchflower, David; Oswald, Andrew and Stutzer, Alois. “Latent Entrepreneurship Across Nations.” European Economic Review, 2001,
45(4-6), pp. 680-91.

3

Georgellis, Yannis and Wall, Howard J. “Entrepreneurship and the Policy Environment.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper
No. 2002-019B, 2004.

2

Staying Out of the Way of Entrepreneurs

After all, in many respects, compared with the
United States, some European countries have
equivalent or superior institutional arrangements
for allowing entrepreneurship.
Americans stand out in other ways regarding
their attitudes toward entrepreneurship.4 For
example, many more Europeans than Americans
say that the idea of starting a business has never
entered their minds. Americans also have a
greater tolerance for the risk associated with
entrepreneurship, whereas many Europeans
appear to be extremely averse to risk. Nearly
one-half of Europeans who were surveyed said
that one should not start a business if there is
any risk at all that it might fail.

PASSIVE VS. ACTIVE POLICIES
Discussion of the role of government in the
entrepreneurial process should recognize the
relative abundance of entrepreneurial spirit in
the United States. To this end, we can draw a
distinction between passive and active policies
directed toward entrepreneurs. Passive policies
are those meant to facilitate entrepreneurship by
establishing institutions, laws, and regulations
to reduce the transactions costs of running a business. Passive policies create an entrepreneurfriendly environment without concern for the
type and form of entrepreneurial activity. Active
policies, on the other hand, are things such as
targeted tax breaks, subsidies and so forth that
are meant to direct resources into particular
business activities by creating specific incentives. These policies require direct intervention
by state and local governments into the entrepreneurial process.
Given the entrepreneurial energy we have in
the United States, active policies are of relatively
limited importance. The focus has been and
should continue to be on ensuring that we have
the proper passive policies in place to allow our
entrepreneurial spirit to thrive. Entrepreneurship
cannot be planned or managed centrally. Rather,
4

we should have in place basic institutions to
facilitate business transactions, along with minimal interference in the actual operation of businesses. In writing our regulations, we should
carefully weigh the costs and benefits while keeping in mind that excessive interference can squash
or misdirect our greatest advantage.
A particular advantage of passive policies is
that entrepreneurs themselves pick the most
promising areas of innovation to pursue. In contrast, active policies involve the efforts of government officials to select specific businesses or
individuals eligible for tax breaks or other financial incentives. Special interests, of course, try to
influence government decisions either by seeking
subsidies and tax breaks or by seeking to disadvantage competitors. Experience indicates that
governments have a poor track record in identifying promising new technologies. Consequently,
subsidies often prove wasteful, as they direct
resources toward ultimately unproductive ventures. At the same time, taxes imposed to support
the subsidies create disincentives to entrepreneurs in general.

PASSIVE TAX POLICIES
Taxes are one of the biggest expenses a business incurs. Certainly some minimal level of taxation is required to have a functioning government.
While few people would disagree with this statement, disagreement does arise over what constitutes “minimal.” One fact is clear—a tax raises
the cost of an activity, thereby discouraging it.
Entrepreneurship is an activity that requires
investment, consumption and income generation
to be successful. Economics tell us that a sales
tax reduces personal consumption; personal
income taxes reduce the incentive to work; corporate income taxes reduce the incentive to start
or expand a business; and capital gains taxes
reduce the incentive to invest. Policymakers
concerned with entrepreneurship should understand that a tradeoff exists between entrepreneur-

EOS Gallup Europe. Flash Eurobarometer 146. Entrepreneurship. European Commission, Brussels, 2004.

3

ECONOMIC GROWTH

ial growth and taxes. The benefits of additional
government programs funded through taxation
must be weighed against the costs of reduced
economic growth and entrepreneurial activities.
That’s not to say that the correct policy is to
provide lower taxes to particular businesses to
encourage their ventures. Tax breaks targeted to
a particular type of business necessarily require
a higher tax burden on other businesses and/or
on households. We lack clear standards and evidence that permit a government agency to accurately judge the relative merits of thousands of
existing and potential businesses. Thus, inevitably, political clout weighs quite heavily in government decisions providing subsidies and tax
breaks. A passive tax policy would be neutral in
terms of the type and location of business activities that may occur. Not only would this neutrality limit the role of political clout, but it would
leave government officials out of the process of
deciding which businesses are more worthy
than others and allow all businesses to operate
in a lower-cost environment.

ACTIVE ECONOMIC
DEVELOPMENT POLICIES
The National Governors Association (NGA)
has produced a best-practices guide for strengthening states’ entrepreneurship policies.5 This
guide provides a number of sound suggestions to
streamline the operations of government and to
limit the scope of some regulations. The guide
also recognizes the important role of entrepreneurial spirit and suggests ways to foster it through
the public education system. However, unfortunately, along with these sound suggestions are
other suggestions that would inject state governments directly into the decision-making process
of entrepreneurs.
One such unattractive active policy is the
integration of entrepreneurship into state economic development efforts. Through various
5

4

government centers and agencies, states act as
brokers for entrepreneurial services such as marketing, business strategies, and technology.
States also manage capital and entrepreneurial
networks. The idea here is that states can direct
entrepreneurs to capital sources, investors and
other entrepreneurs. The problem with these
policies is that the direction of entrepreneurship
is, at least in part, in the hands of state agencies.
Are government officials really qualified to determine the resources that potential entrepreneurs
need? Providing entrepreneurs with information
on where to obtain resources is one thing, but
active participation by state government in the
management of entrepreneurial services is likely
to limit and misdirect entrepreneurial activity.
In addition, state economic development agencies and associated programs require funding,
which comes from tax revenue. Such state programs reduce the pool of private funds, which
can stifle entrepreneurship. Is it really true that
the private sector fails to provide information
and other services required by entrepreneurs?
The NGA report also suggests that states
should invest in diverse sources of risk capital.
Specifically, the report suggests that states should
award certain investors with tax breaks and other
financial incentives, and also ensure that adequate
capital is available in underserved areas. However,
through targeted tax breaks and financial incentives state officials are managing and, to some
degree, controlling entrepreneurship. Yet, if tax
breaks and financial incentives are seen by states
as a means of fostering entrepreneurship, then
the more appropriate policy is to lessen the overall tax burden faced by all potential and existing
entrepreneurs. This approach would create a
more positive environment for entrepreneurs by
removing state management and oversight from
the process.
The NGA also recommends that the costs of
complying with regulations should be lowered
to foster entrepreneurship. While reducing compliance costs certainly cannot be harmful to

Psilos, Phil; Harpel, Ellen and Crawford, Steve. A Governor’s Guide to Strengthening State Entrepreneurship Policy. NGA Center for Best
Practices, 2004.

Staying Out of the Way of Entrepreneurs

entrepreneurs, the NGA fails to recognize that it
is not only compliance cost that hurts entrepreneurs but also the regulations themselves that
can place unnecessary burdens on entrepreneurs.
The question that should really be asked is
whether a given regulation is necessary in the
first place. Many regulations can be eliminated
without detrimental effects on society, while at
the same time unshackling entrepreneurs and
setting the entrepreneurial spirit free.
While the NGA offers some positive policies
to foster entrepreneurship, several other NGA
policies I just discussed place state governments
in control of fostering entrepreneurship. History
has proven time and time again that, if left unfettered, the free market will provide entrepreneurs
ample resources and ample opportunities to be
successful.

CONCLUSION
Government involvement in entrepreneurship
can be both active and passive, and although
much of the policy discussion involves active
policies it is the passive policy environment that
is more important for supporting entrepreneurship. It is unfortunate that active policies receive
so much attention, even while states are sometimes neglecting their most basic responsibilities
such as maintaining a court system that resolves
disputes quickly.
A passive policy environment that is friendly
to entrepreneurs, and to all businesses, is one
that balances the use of regulations and taxes
against the burdens that they impose. More
broadly, an entrepreneur-friendly government is
one that respects private property rights and provides a well-functioning legal system that recognizes and protects these rights. A good rule might
be to never impose a new regulation or establish
a new agency without disbanding an old one.
With such a policy environment, governments
would be allowing entrepreneurship to flourish
by staying out of the way of entrepreneurs.

5